We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
We consider the hard-core model on a finite square grid graph with stochastic Glauber dynamics parametrized by the inverse temperature $\beta$. We investigate how the transition between its two maximum-occupancy configurations takes place in the low-temperature regime $\beta \to \infty$ in the case of periodic boundary conditions. The hard-core constraints and the grid symmetry make the structure of the critical configurations for this transition, also known as essential saddles, very rich and complex. We provide a comprehensive geometrical characterization of these configurations that together constitute a bottleneck for the Glauber dynamics in the low-temperature limit. In particular, we develop a novel isoperimetric inequality for hard-core configurations with a fixed number of particles and show how the essential saddles are characterized not only by the number of particles but also their geometry.
In this chapter, the aim is to visualize wave dynamics in one dimension as dictated by the Schrödinger equation. The necessary numerical tools are introduced in the first part of the chapter. Via discretization, the wave function is represented as a column vector and the Hamiltonian, which enters into the Schrödinger equation, as a square matrix. It is also seen how different approximations behave as the numerical wave function reaches the numerical boundary – where artefacts appear. This numerical framework is first used to see how a Gaussian wave packet would change its width in time and, eventually, spread out. Two waves interfering is also simulated. And wave packets are sent towards barriers to see how they bounce back or, possibly, tunnel through to the other side. In the last part of the chapter, it is explained how quantum measurements provide eigenvalues as answers – for any observable physical quantity. This, in turn, is related to what is called the collapse of the wave function. It is also discussed how a quantity whose operator commutes with the Hamiltonian is conserved in time. Finally, the concept of stationary solutions is introduced in order to motivate the following chapter.
Business groups are ubiquitous in Asia. They are networks of firms bound together through formal and informal family ownership. Some are massive; most are highly diversified, and they are often the dominant players in their home country. Business groups are a uniquely well-suited format for the connections world. Opaque cross-holdings and pyramids of stocks ensure that families can exert effective control, even if their actual shareholdings are relatively small, and provide opportunities for playing reciprocity games with politicians, civil servants and members of other oligarchic dynasties. Although there are examples of efficient and well-run business groups, most are not. Furthermore, while it has often been argued that business groups are a response to institutional and market weaknesses – for example in relation to securing finance – they have not faded with growth and the improvement in institutions. Rather, we show how business groups have become more entrenched in Asia over time and their revenues constitute a huge share of GDP. Such concentrated ownership has also had an impact on extreme wealth, with a staggering growth in the number of billionaires.
The Korean Stewardship Code is remarkably similar to the UK Code in terms of language, although it differs significantly in motivation. A major concern in the UK is institutional investorsʼ dormancy in widely held shareholding. Conversely, a primary purpose of stewardship in Korea is to keep controlling shareholders in check, particularly by curbing tunnelling of controlling family members. This chapter elucidates contents, the enforcement mechanism, the features, impacts and implications of stewardship in Korea and its related shareholder activism. A unique feature in Korea is the National Pension Service (NPS), the largest institutional investor in Korea and the worldʼs third largest public pension fund. As a keen advocate of shareholder activism, the NPS acts as a catalyst in spreading stewardship in Korea. However, since it is a quasi-government agency, the concern is that its investee companiesʼ autonomy may be damaged in the name of stewardship. Another concern is that the government may use stewardship as a powerful policy tool to steer the private sector in line with its own socio-political agenda that has less to do with the financial benefits of the NPS’s beneficiaries.
The disproportionately low level of equity owned by controllers of dual-class firms can incentivise various behaviours in the way that they manage, or cause to be managed, their firms.With controllers feeling less of the consequences from their actions, controllers may be incentivised to ‘tunnel’ profits from the company, pay themselves high executive remuneration, cause the company to take decisions primarily in the pecuniary or non-pecuniary interests of the controller rather than in the interests of shareholder wealth, pass control to unsuitable heirs, block lucrative takeovers and, when takeovers do occur, extract control premia.Management is entrenched, meaning that when controllers take such actions, the public shareholders cannot change the management team.However, controller benefits may not just harm public shareholders, and certain controller benefits can incentivise actions that are neutral or beneficial to shareholder wealth, such as profitable related-party transactions, the bonding of a visionary founder to the firm, maximising takeover value, taking a long-term approach and risk-taking.A dual-class stock tradeoff exists, and if legal regulatory and market constraints can limit the extraction of pernicious controller benefits so that they are outweighed by benign controller benefits, the structure can be net beneficial for controllers and public shareholders alike.
In this paper, we use case studies to document how dominant shareholders have circumvented mandatory bid rules to appropriate wealth from minority shareholders. Dominant shareholders are numerous in Continental Europe. Creative compliance with mandatory bid rules reveals the failure of boards and regulators to protect minority shareholders and the difficulties of legislating in this area. We propose enhanced means for protecting their interests.
A simple model of a neuron is proposed, not intended to be biologically faithful, but to incorporate dynamic and stochastic features which seem to be realistic for both the natural and the artificial case. It is shown that the use of feedback for assemblies of such neurons can produce bistable behaviour and sharpen the discrimination of the assembly to the level of input. Particular attention is paid to bistable devices which are to serve as bit-stores (and so constitute components of a memory) and which suffer a disturbing input due to mutual interference. Approximate expressions are obtained for the equilibrium distribution of the excitation level for such assemblies and for the expected escape time of such an assembly from a metastable excitation level.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.