Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-d8cs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-12T04:33:37.878Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal premium pricing policy in a competitive insurance market environment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 August 2012

Athanasios A. Pantelous*
Affiliation:
Institute for Financial and Actuarial Mathematics (IFAM), Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Liverpool, UK
Eudokia Passalidou
Affiliation:
Institute for Financial and Actuarial Mathematics (IFAM), Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Liverpool, UK
*
*Correspondence to: Athanasios A. Pantelous, Institute for Financial and Actuarial Mathematics (IFAM), Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Liverpool, L69 7ZL, Liverpool, UK. Tel. +44 151 79 45079. E-mail: A.Pantelous@liverpool.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In this paper, we propose a model for the optimal premium pricing policy of an insurance company into a competitive environment using Dynamic Programming into a stochastic, discrete-time framework when the company is expected to drop part of the market. In our approach, the volume of business which is related to the past year experience, the average premium of the market, the company's premium which is a control function and a linear stochastic disturbance, have been considered. Consequently, maximizing the total expected linear discounted utility of the wealth over a finite time horizon, the optimal premium strategy is defined analytically and endogenously. Finally, considering two different strategies for the average premium of the market, the optimal premium policy for a company with an expected decreasing volume of business is derived and fully investigated. The results of this paper are further evaluated by using data from the Greek Automobile Insurance Industry.

Type
Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Institute and Faculty of Actuaries 2012 

1. Introduction

Nowadays, the number of products from different insurance companies has been significantly increased because of several micro and macro economical challenges, of the strong market competition and of the boosting securitization needs of the new era after the last (global) financial crisis. However, there is still little literature available in actuarial science on modelling how insurance premiums should be determined in competitive market environments, and how the competition actually affects the determination of the company's premiums; see for further discussion Daykin et al. (Reference Daykin, Pentikäinen and Pesonen1994) and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007).

It is well-known in the insurance industry that the fair pricing process for non-life products is a crucial issue for every General Insurance company, especially within the unfolding of the time-bound de-tariffing road map by Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority (IRDA) which is once again under a great concern and publicity; see the recent article in Insurance Chronicle, Ramana (Reference Ramana2006). Consequently, the failure of a uniform and global price in any Insurance Market, which can be based only on the premium rates, the policy terms and the conditions applicable to a particular portfolio of risks, force the insurance companies to provide more competitive prices. Especially, nowadays because of the global financial crisis, the premium strategy must be determined more accurately and competitively in order to ensure the viability of each company and to increase the volume of business in a long-term.

Inevitably, several questions can arise. For instance, in this part of the paper, we would like to mention just a few of them: “What is the optimal premium strategy for an individual insurance company and for a specific portfolio of homogeneous or/and heterogeneous risks?”; “how is this related to the competitive market?”; “how does the volume of business affect the premium strategy?” are only some of the questions that can be stated, and with non-trivial or straightforward answers.

The first attempt towards this direction was carried out by Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) who investigated the relation between the market's behaviour and the optimal response of an individual insurer. Actually, he has assumed that this relation depends upon various factors including:

  1. (a) the predicted time which will elapse before a return of market rates into profitability,

  2. (b) the price elasticity of demand for the insurance product under consideration, and

  3. (c) the rate of return required on the capital supporting the insurance operation.

Taylor (Reference Taylor1986) investigates the appropriate response of an insurer, and he maximizes the expected present value of the wealth arising over a pre-defined finite time horizon. Additionally, he assumes that the insurance products display a positive price-elasticity of demand. Thus, if the market as a whole begins underwriting at a loss, any attempt by a particular insurer to maintain profitability will result in a reduction of his volume of business.

Consequently, following Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986) ideas, for a given sequence of average market prices over fixed years to the planning horizon, the demand function fk(·) is given by a relation of the following type $$\[--><$>{{f}_k}:{{{\Bbb R}}_ + }\:\times \:{{{\Bbb R}}_ + }\:\times \:{{{\Bbb R}}_ + }\:\times \:{\Bbb R}\: \rightarrow \:{{{\Bbb R}}_ + }<$><!--\]$$ (where $$\[--><$>{{{\Bbb R}}_ + }\:{\triangleq}\:(0,\infty ]<$><!--\]$$ ),

$${{f}_k}\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}},{{p}_k},{{{\bar{p}}}_k},{{\theta }_k}} \right),$$

where pk denotes the premium rate charged by the insurer in year k, $$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k}<$><!--\]$$ denotes the average premium rate charged by all insurers in the market in year k, Vk −1 denotes the company's volume of business for the previous year, i.e. k−1 and θk denotes the set of all other variables considered to be relevant to the demand function in year k. Obviously, as the demand function (1.1) is too general, Taylor (Reference Taylor1986), and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) considered and investigated some special cases. Moreover, they assumed that the optimal pricing strategy prescribes a sequence of prices (premium rates) over the k years such as to maximize the expected profit of those k years discounted at rate of return per annum.

Taylor (Reference Taylor1986) made several assumptions, however one of them can be further relaxed here in order to make the model a little more realistic. Thus, the assumption that the discarding of the unspecified set of variables amounts effectively to treating the sequence of market rates $$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k}<$><!--\]$$ as given, exogenously to the strategy of the insurer is under consideration here. Additionally, Taylor (Reference Taylor1986) considered two different demand functions and he assumed a constant price for the elasticity demand. Thus, according to his results, it is found that the optimal strategies do not follow what someone might consider as obvious rules. For instance, it is not the case that profitability is best served by following the market during a period of premium rate depression. In particular, the optimal strategy may well involve underwriting for important profit margins at times when the average market premium rate is well short of breaking even.

The very interesting paper by Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) can be considered as an extension of Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) ideas into a continuous-time stochastic framework, since they have used a stochastic process for modelling the market average premium, $$\[--><$>\bar{p}<$><!--\]$$ . In particular, they adapt Taylor's demand function and they model $$\[--><$>\bar{p}<$><!--\]$$ using a geometric Brownian motion, i.e. $$\[--><$>\frac{{d\bar{p}}}{{\bar{p}}}\: = \:\mu dt\: + \:\sigma dZ<$><!--\]$$ where Z is a Wiener process and both the drift μ and the volatility σ are assumed to be constant. Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) handled the problem as a stochastic optimal control problem assuming that the premium policy is a control function where q(t) denotes the volume of exposure at time t and p(t) denotes the premium rate (per unit of exposure) charged by the insurer at time t. Therefore, the demand process is described by $$\[--><$>\frac{{dp}}{q}\: = \:\log f(p,\bar{p})dt<$><!--\]$$ , where $$\[--><$>p\: = \:p\left( {\bar{p},\pi, t} \right)<$><!--\]$$ is the premium at time t. Moreover, the utility function takes the linear form U(w,t) = e βtw, where β is the inter-temporal discount rate, and finally they defined the linear maximization problem $$\[--><$>{\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{p}} \,{\Bbb E}{\int}_{\!0}^{T} {U\left( {w\left( t \right),t} \right)dt} <$><!--\]$$ over a choice of strategies p and a finite time horizon T.

Rather than Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987), Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) studied fixed premium strategies and the sensitivity of the model to its parameters involved. In their approach, the important parameters which determine the optimal strategies are the ratio of initial market average premium to break-even premium, the measure of the inverse elasticity of the demand function and the non-dimensional drift of the market average premium.

In our new approach, we introduce a stochastic demand function for the volume of business of an insurance company into a discrete-time framework extending further Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) ideas. Additionally, using a linear discounted function for the wealth process of the company, see also Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007), we provide an analytical, endogenous formula for the optimal premium strategy of the insurance company when it is expected to lose part of the market. Mathematically speaking, we create a maximization problem for the wealth process of a company, which is solved using stochastic dynamic programming. Thus, the optimal controller (i.e. the premium) is defined endogenously by the market as the company struggles to increase its volume of business into a competitive environment with the same characteristics as in Emms & Haberman (Reference Emms and Haberman2005); Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) and Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987). Finally, we consider two different strategies for the average premium of the market, and the optimal premium policy is derived and fully investigated. The results of this paper are further evaluated by using data from the Greek Automobile Insurance Industry.

The paper is organized as follows: In section 2 a discrete-time model for the insurance market is constructed. We discuss appropriate values for the model parameters and adopt suitable parameterizations. The next section considers each strategy in turn: we find analytical forms for the optimal strategies. In Premium Strategy I, the average premium of the market is calculated considering all the competitors of the market, and their proportions regarding the volume of business. In Premium Strategy II, the average premium of market is calculated considering the top 5 competitors of the market. Finally we summarize these results and make suggestions for modelling improvements in section 4.

2. Model Formulation

2.1 Basic Notation and Assumptions

Following Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) approaches, we propose a stochastic, discrete-time premium pricing model to describe a competitive insurance market. Thus, the following notation is needed:

Vk: denotes the volume of business (or exposure) underwritten by the insurer in year [k, k + 1). This volume may be measured in any meaningful unit, e.g. number of claims incurred, total man-hours at risk (for workers’ compensation insurance). In our paper, we consider the number of claims incurred as the volume of exposure.

πk: denotes the break-even premium in year [k, k + 1), i.e. risk premium plus expenses per unit exposure.

pk: denotes the premium charged by the insurer in year [k, k + 1). This is our control parameter.

$$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k}:<$><!--\]$$ denotes the “average” premium charged by the market in year [k, k + 1). We further assume that this process is stochastic, see also Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007). Let $$\[--><$>\left( {\Omega, {\cal F},{\cal P}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ be the probability space and $$\[--><$>\left\{ {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}|k\: = \:1,2, \ldots } \right\}<$><!--\]$$ be the sequence of random variables defined on this probability space.

r: denotes the rate of return on equity required by shareholders of the insurer whose strategy is under consideration. We further assume that this rate is deterministic.

$$\[--><$>\upsilon <$><!--\]$$ : denotes the corresponding discount factor, $$\[--><$>\upsilon \: = \:{{\left( {1\: + \:r} \right)}^{{\rm{ - }}1}} <$><!--\]$$ .

θk: denotes the set of all other stochastic variables (which are assumed to be independently distributed in time and Gaussian) and it is considered to be relevant to the demand function in year [k, k + 1), such as inflation, interest rate, exchange rate, marketing etc. In other words, this stochastic parameter tries to number the contracts that the company loses or gains due to these disturbances, which actually affect the volume of business of the insurance company. However, for the purposes of the present version of the paper, further analysis of the micro and macro economics parameters that get involved in θk is omitted. We will leave it as a future direction to our research.

In this paper, as in Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) and Taylor (Reference Taylor1986), we make the following assumptions.

Assumption 1: There is positive price-elasticity of demand, i.e. if the market as a whole begins underwriting at a loss, any attempt by a particular insurer to maintain profitability will result in a reduction of his volume of business.

Assumption 2: There is a finite time horizon.

Assumption 3: Demand in year k + 1 is assumed to be proportional to demand in the preceding year k.

Assumption 4: θk affects the volume of business in a linear way (i.e. additive noise).

Additionally, extending Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) assumptions, we assume that the demand function is stochastic (because of θk and $$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k}<$><!--\]$$ ). Here, we denote the wealth process wk as the insurer's capital at time [k, k + 1), following Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) ideas, so we obtain

$${{w}_{k + 1}}\: = \:{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}\: + \:({{p}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{\pi }_k}){{V}_k},$$

where ak∈[0,1] denotes the excess return on capital (i.e. return on capital required by the shareholders of the insurer whose strategy is under consideration). Thus, −akwk is the cost of holding wk in the time interval [k,k + 1).

Following Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987), the volume of business (or exposure) of an insurance company for a given sequence of average market prices over the k th year is given by a relation of the following type

$${{V}_k}\:{\triangleq}\:{{f}_k}\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}},{{p}_k},{{{\bar{p}}}_k},{{\theta }_k}} \right),$$

where pk is the controller and θk denotes the set of all other random variables (disturbances) which are considered to be relevant to the demand function. Under this assumption Vk is a stochastic variable and depends on k.

Our aim is to determine the strategy which maximizes the expected total utility of the wealth at time k over a finite time horizon T. As it has been also considered by Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007), we use a linear discounted function (of wealth).

Analytically, we want to maximize

$${\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \,{\Bbb E}\left[ {\mathop{\sum}\limits_{k\: = \:0}^T {U({{w}_k},k)} } \right],$$

where $$\[--><$>U({{w}_k},k) = {{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}<$><!--\]$$ is the present value of the wealth wk.

Consequently, substituting (2.2) into (2.1), the wealth process wk is given by (2.4)

$${{w}_{k\: + \:1}}\: = \:{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}\: + \:({{p}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{\pi }_k}){{f}_k}({{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}},{{p}_k},{{\bar{p}}_k},{{\theta }_k}),$$

and w 0, V 0, V −1 (the volume of business now and for the previous year) a 0 and π 0 are the initial conditions.

Extending Taylor's (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987) ideas, who assumed that the volume of business in year k+1 is proportional to the demand of the preceding year, in this paper we propose that the volume of business is proportional to the average premium charged by the market (see Assumption 3), but reverse proportional to the premium rate charged by the insurer in year k. Empirically speaking, this new approach might be considered as a little more realistic, since it is true that whenever the average premium stays unchanged and the premium charged by the insurer increases, unavoidably the company's volume of business might decrease. On the other hand, whenever the premium calculated by the insurer stays unchanged and the average premium decreases, the volume of business might decrease as well. These thoughts lead to the assumption that the volume of business should be proportional to the rate $$\[--><$>\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}<$><!--\]$$ .

Additionally, it is realistic to assume that there might be an unexpected set of parameters, which can modify (i.e. decrease or increase) the volume of business. Consequently, we can assume that this set of parameters can be modelled using the stochastic variable θk, which can take either positive or negative values. In this paper, since we are more interested in investigating the premium strategy of an insurance company when it is expected to lose part of the market, we assume that the expected values of θk is positive (i.e. $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,\mu <$><!--\]$$ , where μ > 0 is a deductible parameter which can be pre-defined by the managerial team), and then the volume of business is strictly decreasing, i.e. losing part of the competitive market. Obviously, within the next lines, the case $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \lt \,\mu <$><!--\]$$ is also discussed, however this case is not very interested since it implies that the insurance company is increasing gradually its volume, and any change in its premium policy might affect it negatively.

Consequently, we can assume that the volume of business is given by

$${{V}_k}\: = \:{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{{\theta }_k},$$

where θk is being involved as an additive white noise.

2.2 Calculation of the Optimal Premium

After the basic notations, and the mathematical formulation of the problem, we need to calculate the optimal premium, which maximize the expected total utility of the wealth (2.3).

Following the general ideas about stochastic dynamic programming and control theory in a discrete-time framework, see for instance the classical books by Bertzekas (Reference Bertzekas2000) and Kushner (Reference Kushner1970), we determine the strategy which maximises the expected total utility of wealth (2.3) over a finite time horizon T, and over a choice of strategies p. This is similar to the objective function used by Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987), and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007).

The next Theorem provides us with the optimal premium strategy for the finite time horizon maximization problem (2.3)–(2.5), see also Jacobson (Reference Jacobson1974) and Kushner (Reference Kushner1970).

Theorem 1 For the wealth process {wk}k ∈0,1,…,T −1given by

$${{w}_{k\: + \:1}}\: = \:{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}\: + \:({{p}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{\pi }_k})\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{{\theta }_k}} \right),$$

where $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,\mu <$><!--\]$$ , μ > 0, and for the maximization problem defined by

$${\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \,{\Bbb E}\left[ {\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:k}^{T{\rm{ - }}1} {{{\upsilon }^i} {{w}_i}} } \right],$$

with initial conditions w 0, V 0, V −1, a 0, and π 0, the optimal strategy process $$\[--><$>p_{k}^{\ast} <$><!--\]$$ is given by

$$ p_{k}^{\ast} \: = \:{{\left( {\frac{1}{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{{\bar{p}}}_k})} \right)}^{1/2}} \ {{for}} \ k\: = \:0,1, \ldots, T{\rm{ - }}1, $$

where $$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k} <$><!--\]$$ , πk is the “average” and the break-even premium respectively, in year k;Vk −1is the volume of exposure underwritten by the insurer in year k−1, and $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ is the expectation of the (stochastic) disturbance θk in year k, and the maximum value of (2.7) is given by

$${{w}_0}{{d}_0}\: + \:{{e}_0}.$$

Moreover, we define

$${{d}_k}\: = \:{{\upsilon }^k} {\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\: \gt \:0\,, \ {{and}} \ {{d}_T}\: = \:0,$$
$$ no{\quad \qquad {{e}_k}\: = \: {\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\left( {{{{\left( {\frac{1}{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{{\bar{p}}}_k})} \right)}}^{1/2}} {\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)} \right) \cr & \quad\: + \:{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}\left( {{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right){{{\left( {\frac{1}{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{{\bar{p}}}_k})} \right)}}^{{\rm{ - }}1/2}} } \right)\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}\,,\ {{and}} \ {{e}_T}\: = \:0. $$

Proof Define

$${{J}_k}({{w}_k})\:{\triangleq}\:{\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k},{{p}_{k\: + \:1}}, \ldots, {{p}_{T{\rm{ - }}1}}}}} {{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}\left[ {\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:k}^{T{\rm{ - }}1} {{{\upsilon }^i} {{w}_i}} } \right].$$

Then, as it is known [6], the optimal performance criterion satisfied the Bellman equation

$$no{ \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \quad {{J}_k}({{w}_k}) = {\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \,{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}\left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}\: + \:{{J}_{k\: + \:1}}({{w}_{k\: + \:1}})} \right\} \cr = {\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}\: + \:{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}{{J}_{k\: + \:1}}({{w}_{k\: + \:1}})} \right\} $$

where $$\[--><$>{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)\: = \:{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right) <$><!--\]$$ and $$\[--><$>{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: = \:{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu \: \gt \:0 <$><!--\]$$ , and $$\[--><$>J{\pre}_{T}({{w}_T})\: = \:{{w}_T}{{d}_T}\: + \:{{e}_T}\: = \:0 <$><!--\]$$ ; see (2.10), and (2.11).

We now show by induction that

$$ {{J}_k}({{w}_k})\: = \:{{w}_k}{{d}_k}\: + \:{{e}_k} $$

solves (2.13) by noting that (2.14) is true for k = T by assuming that (2.14) is true for k+1 and by proving is true for k. Substituting the assumed expression for Jk + 1(wk + 1) into the right hand side (2.13) we obtain

$$ {{J}_k}({{w}_k})\: = \:{\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}\: + \:{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}{{J}_{k\: + \:1}}({{w}_{k\: + \:1}})} \right\}\: = \:{\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}\: + \:{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}({{w}_{k\: + \:1}}){{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right\}, $$

and from (2.6) we have

$$ no{ {\mathop{{\max }}\limits_{{{{p}_k}}}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}\: + \:{{{\Bbb E}}_{|{{w}_k}}}\left[ {{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}\: + \:\left( {{{p}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{\pi }_k}} \right){{V}_k}} \right]{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right\} \cr \quad= \mathop {\max }\limits_{{{p}_k}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}} + {{d}_{k\: + \:1}}({{p}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{\pi }_k})\left. {\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)} \right)} \right]\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right\} \cr \quad= \mathop {\max }\limits_{{{p}_k}} \left\{ {{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}{\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{w}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\left( {{{p}_k}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)} \right)\: + \:{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}\left( {{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{{{p}_k}}}} \right)\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right\} \cr \quad= \mathop {\max }\limits_{{{p}_k}} \left\{ {{\rm{ - }}{{w}_k}({{a}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{\rm{ - }}{{\upsilon }^k} ){\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\left( {{{p}_k}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)} \right)\: + \:{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}\left( {{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{{{p}_k}}}} \right)\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right\}. \cr$$

The controller that maximizes the above expression, (2.15), is given by (2.8), since

$$ A\: = \:{{w}_k}\left( {{{\upsilon }^k} {\rm{ - }}{{a}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}} \right)\: + \:\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{p}_k}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)} \right){{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}\left( {{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)} \right)\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}. $$

The first derivative of A with respect to pk is given

$$ \frac{{\partial A}}{{\partial {{p}_k}}}\: = \:{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{p_{k}^{2} }}{\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: = \:{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\left( {{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{p_{k}^{2} }}{\rm{ - }}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)} \right). $$

If we equalize the first derivative with zero, i.e. $$\[--><$>\frac{{\partial A}}{{\partial {{p}_k}}}\: = \:0 <$><!--\]$$ , we obtain

$$ {{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\left( {{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{p_{k}^{2} }}{\rm{ - }}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)} \right)\: = \:0{\mathop{ \Leftrightarrow }\limits^{{{{d}_{k + 1}}\: \ne \:0,\,{}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu \: \gt \:0}}} \;{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)}}{{p_{k}^{2} }}{\rm{ - }}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: = \:0. $$

The above expression gives the optimal strategy (2.8) as

$$ \frac{{\partial A}}{{{{\partial }^2} {{p}_k}}}\: = \:{\rm{ - }}2{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{\bar{p}}_k}){{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\frac{1}{{p_{k}^{3} }}\: \lt \:0, $$

where $$\[--><$>{{\pi }_k},{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}},{\Bbb E}(\overline{{{{p}_k}}} ),\frac{1}{{p_{k}^{3} }} <$><!--\]$$ and $$\[--><$>{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}\: \gt \:0 <$><!--\]$$ .

Now, let's substitute the above into (2.15), we obtain

$${ {\rm{ - }}{{w}_k}({{a}_k}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{\rm{ - }}{{\upsilon }^k} ){\rm{ - }}{{d}_{k\: + \:1}} \left( {{{{\left( {\frac{1}{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{{\bar{p}}}_k})} \right)}}^{1/2}} {\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)} \right) \cr & \qquad+ {{d}_{k\: + \:1}}{{\pi }_k}\left( {{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right){\rm{ - }}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{{{\left( {\frac{1}{{{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{{\bar{p}}}_k})} \right)}}^{{\rm{ - }}1/2}} } \right)\: + \:{{e}_{k\: + \:1}}. \cr} $$

Substituting (2.10) and (2.11) in the above expression yields the fact that (2.14) is true. Thus, the proof of the Theorem 1 by induction is complete. □

Remark 1 As it is quite likely in practice, the optimal premium strategy given by (2.6) expression depends endogenously on the volume of business of the previous year, the break-even premium rate, the expected value of the average premium rate of the market and the (stochastic) variable θk.

Remark 2 In order to calculate the optimal premium strategy, initially we have to calculate the expectation of θk which models the set of all other parameters considered to be relevant to the demand function of each company, and the insurance market (i.e. financial environment, managerial policy etc); see also Assumption 4. In particular, as it has been clearly stated in the introduction; see also Remark 3, and Proposition 1, we are interested to modify the premium strategy when our volume of business is strictly decreasing because of the positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu <$><!--\]$$ . Note that as it came clear from the relation (2.5) θk is equal to $$\[--><$>{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{{V}_k}<$><!--\]$$ for each previous year.

Remark 3 In a competitive market environment, we have considered that the volume of business in each company is strictly decreasing when the expectation of the stochastic variable (disturbance) θk in year k = 0,1,…,T−1 takes positive values. Thus, the company should change the premium policy in order to enlarge its volume. On contrary, for negative or below the deductible point μ > 0 values for the expectation of θk, i.e. $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \lt \:\mu <$><!--\]$$ , the previous premium strategy might stay unchanged (see next corollary), since the company does not lose (significant) part of the market (i.e. by decreasing its volume).

The following proposition considers the case where the volume of business changes either above or below μ > 0 (i.e., for decreasing or increasing the volume of business above or below the required level, respectively).

Remark 4 Moreover, we can show that the optimal expected wealth of the company at the year k + 1 is given by (2.16)

$${\Bbb E}(w_{{k\: + \:1}}^{\ast} )\: = \:{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}({{\bar{p}}_k})\: + \:{{\pi }_k}{\Bbb E}({{\theta }_k}){\rm{ - }}\left\{ {{{a}_k}{{w}_k}\: + \:2{{{\left( {{\Bbb E}({{\theta }_k}){{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}{\Bbb E}\left( {{{{\bar{p}}}_k}} \right)} \right)}}^{1/2}} } \right\} \ for \ {\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu .$$

As Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987), and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) propose, and in order to take benefit of the analytical formula derived by Theorem 1 for the determination of the premium strategies into a competitive environment, in the next section we use data from the Greek automobile insurance industry, see also the tables of the Hellenic Association of Insurance Companies (2010). Moreover, we assume that the premium strategies concern the price of a contract which refers to a six-month insurance for a car that is 1400cc, 10 years old and its value estimated at 5.000€.

3. Premium Strategies

3.1 Premium strategy I: Considering the Entire Market

In the first premium strategy, the expected average premium is calculated considering all the competitors of the market, and their proportions regarding the volume of business. In mathematical terms the expected average premium of the market can be estimated by

$${\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{b}_{i,n}}{{p}_{i,n}}}, $$

where $$\[--><$>{{b}_{i,n}}\: = \:{{V}_{i,n}}{{\left( {\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{V}_{i,n}}} } \right)}^{{\rm{ - }}1}} <$><!--\]$$ and $$\[--><$>\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{b}_{i,n}}} \: = \:1<$><!--\]$$ for every year n, pi ,n is the premium of the company i th for the year n; K is the number of the competitors (including also our company's premium) in the insurance market and m is the number of years for the available data (i.e. we assume that we have the uniform distribution for the weight of every year). Moreover, for the calculation of the expected values of the premium of each company and the average market premium respectively, we use the available Greek data, see next paragraphs.

Proposition 1 Considering (2.6) and (3.1), the optimal controller (i.e. premium) for the premium strategy I is equal to

$$p_{k}^{\ast} \: = \:\sqrt {\frac{1}{{m{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{b}_{i,n}}{{p}_{i,n}}} }, \,{\rm{for}}\,{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu \: \gt \:0, \,k\: = \:0,1, \ldots, T{\rm{ - }}1.$$

Proof The proof derives straightforwardly, and it is omitted. □

This premium strategy considers the premium and the volume of business of the entire market. The expected average premium of the market is estimated using the (3.1) expression, i.e. as an expected weighted average of each competitor that gets involved in the market. Moreover, it is clear that the premium of the company with the largest volume of business affects most of the market (see also Premium Strategy II). In Table 1, the premium prices and the number of contracts for the 12 major non-life Greek insurance companies for a standard six-month cover of a 10-year old, 1400cc car (with 5.000 Euros covered amount) are presented for the years 2006, 2007, 2008 and 2009.

Table 1 Premium prices in Euros and number of contracts for the 12 major non-life Greek insurance companies, see Hellenic Association of Insurance Companies (2010).

As we can observe in Table 1, and according to the oligopoly theory which began in 1838 with Cournot's oligopoly model, see for more details Friedman (Reference Friedman1983) and the references therein, the Greek non-life insurance industry has an oligopoly market characteristic, since there are only a few main competitors, the insurance products are almost identical (with non-significant differences) and the ownership of the key inputs and barriers imposed by the government. Thus, in the case of oligopolistic market, the revenues of the firms depend on the actions of other competitors as we have considered in our premium strategies; see also Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007) and Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987).

According to the premium strategy I, the average premium of the market is equal to the weighted average of the premiums of all the companies involved in the market for every year. Moreover, the volume of business of each company for the years 2006–2009 is presented in Table 2. Finally, Table 3 summarizes the results of the (3.1) expression.

Table 2 (The volume of business, b, in % for the 12 major non-life Greek insurance companies).

Table 3 (The expected average premium in Euros of the market for the year 2010 is given by $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{b}_{i,n}}{{p}_{i,n}}} .<$><!--\]$$ ).

As it has already been mentioned above in order to calculate the optimal premium for each company first, we have to estimate the expectation of θk which models the set of all other parameters considered to be relevant to the demand function of each company, and the insurance market (i.e. financial environment, managerial policy etc). As it is clear from the relation (2.5) $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$ (estimation of θk) can be calculated by $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}\: = \:{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{{V}_k}<$><!--\]$$ .

Thus, considering the above expression, and for the available Greek data we are able to calculate $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$ for the years 2007, 2008 and 2009 as it is shown at Table 4. So, the expected value of θk for the year 2010 can be given by

$${\Bbb E}({{\theta }_k})\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:1}^m {{{{\hat{\theta }}}_i}} $$

Table 4 (The values of $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$ , the change in percentage for the volume of business for the years 2007-2009, and the expected values of θk for the year 2010).

Then, in Table 4, we present the expected values of θk (using the estimations of θk). As has been already mentioned before, θk denotes the number of contracts that the company loses or gains because of the parameters that affect the volume of business and they have not been included in the model. In our application, the large fluctuations in the expected values of θk occur due to a) the limited number of the available data, and b) the impact on each company's volume of business into the market. (Note that since we have available data for only 4 years, it is difficult to provide a good estimation for the expected values of θk. However, for the purpose of our application, this drawback is not crucial.)

The values of the stochastic variable θk can be either above or below μ > 0. As we have extensively discussed in section 2, we will determine the optimal premium strategy for the year 2010 only for those companies which have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}({{\theta }_k})\, \gt 0<$><!--\]$$ .

These companies are A, B, E, G and L, see Figure 1.

Figure 1 (The real and the expected volume of business for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,\mu <$><!--\]$$ ).

In Table 5, we present the premium for each company for the different values of the break-even premium rate.

Table 5 (The optimal premium strategy in Euros for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate).

As it is expected, for greater values of the πk, greater the optimal premium values become. Consequently, since the optimal premium depends on the break-even premium rate, the company should choose its competitive strategy considering the market's construction and its marginal costs; see also Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007). Thus, each company should pre-determine its break-even premium rate, in order to calculate the optimal premium strategy which will enlarge its volume of business. The results of Table 5 are shown also at Figure 1.

The results of Table 5 (see also Figure 2) are seemingly interesting. For the five insurance companies (A, B, E, G, and L) which expected to experience losses on their volume of business, for a break-even premium rate of 20–30% calculated by the formula 3.2, premiums are below the market average premium of 364.68€. Additionally, it is true that the insurance companies E and L which face similar losses (see Tables 1, 2, and 4) should provide similar premiums, which appear to be the most expensive premiums compared with the premiums of the other 3 companies.

Figure 2 (The optimal premium strategy in Euros for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate)

At this point, it should be mentioned that in this paper, we are not able to analyze further the results of Table 1, and consequently of Table 5 (and Figure 2), since the analysis of the Greek insurance market, and the micro/macro conditions that get involved for the determination of the premium strategy is far beyond the scopes of the present version of the paper. Additionally, the macro-micro economic analysis of the parameters that affect θk is a purpose of future research.

3.2 Premium Strategy II: Following the Leaders of the Market

In this premium strategy, the average premium is calculated considering the premiums of the top K top competitors of the market (including the leading company of the market). In mathematical terms the expected average premium of the market is estimated by

$${\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^{top}} } {b_{{i,n}}^{{top}} p_{{i,n}}^{{top}} }, $$

where $$\[--><$>b_{{i,n}}^{{top}} \: = \:{{V}_{i,n}}{{\left( {\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^{top}} } {{{V}_{i,n}}} } \right)}^{{\rm{ - }}1}} <$><!--\]$$ and $$\[--><$>\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^{top}} } {b_{{i,n}}^{{top}} } \: = \:1<$><!--\]$$ for every year n, $$\[--><$>p_{{i,n}}^{{top}} <$><!--\]$$ is the premium of the i th top company for the year n; K top is the number of the top competitors (including also our company's premium) in the insurance market and m is the number of years for the available data (i.e. we assume that we have the uniform distribution for the weight of every year). Next, similar to the Proposition 2, we obtain the following Proposition.

Proposition 2 Considering (2.6) and (3.4), the optimal controller (i.e. premium) for the premium strategy II is equal to

$$p_{k}^{\ast} \: = \:\sqrt {\frac{1}{{m{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)}}{{\pi }_k}{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\mathop{\sum}\limits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^{top}} } {b_{{i,n}}^{{top}} p_{{i,n}}^{{top}} } }, \,{\rm{for}}\,{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\: \gt \:\mu \: \gt \:0,\,{\rm{for}}\,k\: = \:0,1, \ldots, T{\rm{ - }}1.$$

Proof. The proof derives straightforwardly, and it is omitted.□

For the purpose of this application, we consider the premium and the volume of business of the top 5 Greek insurance companies. Consequently, the expected average premium of the market is calculated using the (3.4) expression.

In Table 6, the premiums and the number of contracts for the 5 leading non-life Greek insurance companies are presenting for the years 2006, 2007, 2008 and 2009.

Table 6 (Premiums prices in Euros and number of contracts for the top 5 non-life Greek insurance companies; see Friedman, Reference Friedman1983).

Thus, for the years 2006, we calculate the average premium considering the premium and the volume of business for the companies B, C, D, F, and L; for the year 2007 and 2008: B, F, G, J and K, and for the year 2009: D, F, I, J and K. In Table 7, the volume of business is presented.

Table 7 (The weights in % for the calculation of the average premium for the top 5 non-life Greek insurance companies).

According to the premium strategy II, the average premium of the market is equal to the weighted average of the premiums of the top 5 companies in the market for every year. Finally, Table 8 summarizes the results of the (3.4) expression.

Table 8 (The expected average premium in Euros of the market for the year 2010 is given by $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^ + } } {b_{{i,n}}^{ + } p_{{i,n}}^{ + } } <$><!--\]$$ .).

Now, we calculate again the estimation of θk, since the average premium of the market for the years 2006, 2007, 2008 and 2009 has changed. Additionally, the average premium in the Premium Strategy I is higher than in the Premium Strategy II. So, in Table 9, we present the expected values of θk.

Table 9 (The values of $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$ , the change in percentage for the volume of business for the years 2007–2009, and the expected values of θk for the year 2010).

Next, we will determine the optimal premium strategy for the year 2010 only for those companies which have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}({{\theta }_k})<$><!--\]$$ with μ > 10,000 (the managerial team is not interested in modifying the premium when it expects to lose only a few thousand contracts), i.e. A, B, E, G and L.

The results of Table 10 (see also Figure 3) are also similar with those of the Premium Strategy I, since the five insurance companies have premiums significantly below the market average premium of 382.50€ for a break-even premium rate of 20–40%.

Table 10 (The optimal premium strategy in Euro for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,10,000<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate).

Figure 3 Optimal premium for the year 2010 (Premium Strategy II).

Now, if we would like to compare the findings of the two Premium Strategies, we can easily see that the Premium Strategy II is cheaper (i.e. it provides lower premiums) than the Premium Strategy I for all the A, B, E, G and L insurance companies. This result was expected, as in the Greek insurance market, the leader (dominator) companies have expensive premiums, above the average premium of the market.

4. Conclusions – Further Research

In this paper, extending further the ideas proposed by Taylor (Reference Taylor1986, Reference Taylor1987), Emms & Haberman (Reference Emms and Haberman2005) and Emms et al. (Reference Emms, Haberman and Savoulli2007), we develop a model for the optimal premium pricing policy of a non-life insurance company into a competitive market environment using elements of dynamic programming into a stochastic, discrete-time framework when the insurance company is expected to lose part of the market competition. For that reason, a stochastic demand function for the volume of business $$\[--><$>{{f}_k}({{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}},{{p}_k},{{\bar{p}}_k},{{\theta }_k})\: = \:{{V}_{k{\rm{ - }}1}}\frac{{{{{\bar{p}}}_k}}}{{{{p}_k}}}{\rm{ - }}{{\theta }_k}<$><!--\]$$ of an insurance company into a discrete-time has been applied. Additionally, in our approach, the volume of business, Vk which is related to the past year experience, the average premium of the market, $$\[--><$>{{\bar{p}}_k}<$><!--\]$$ , the company's premium, pk, which is a control function, and a stochastic disturbance, θk, have been also considered. Thus, by maximizing the total expected linear discounted utility of the wealth $$\[--><$>U({{w}_k},k)\: = \:{{\upsilon }^k} {{w}_k}<$><!--\]$$ over a finite time horizon, the optimal premium strategy is defined analytically and endogenously for $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,\mu \, \gt \,0<$><!--\]$$ .

Finally, we consider two different strategies for the average premium of the market. In the Premium Strategy I, the average premium is calculated considering all the competitors of the market, and their proportions regarding the volume of business. However, in the Premium Strategy II, the average premium is calculated considering the premiums of the top K top competitors of the market (including the leading company of the market). The results of this paper are further evaluated by using data from the Greek Automobile Insurance Industry, which is an oligopoly market.

As a further extension of the proposed model, we would like to consider the following:

  • To use a more general stochastic, non-linear demand-function for the volume of business.

  • To analyze further the stochastic parameter θk, since several macro-micro economic parameters get involved.

  • Additionally, to include into our model the inflation rate, the taxation and different other quantitative parameters, such as legislation constraints etc, regarding the insurance market environment.

  • Finally, to consider a different non-linear maximization criterion.

Acknowledgement

The authors are very grateful to the referee for the valuable comments and remarks which have improved significantly the quality of the paper, and the encouragement for further research in this area. Finally, we would like to express also our gratefulness to Dr. Alexandros Zimbidis for the preliminary discussion of the paper.

References

Bertzekas, D.P. (2000). Dynamic programming and control theory. Athens Scientific Press, USA.Google Scholar
Daykin, C.D., Pentikäinen, T., Pesonen, M. (1994). Practical risk theory for actuaries. Chapman and Hall, USA.Google Scholar
Emms, P., Haberman, S. (2005). Pricing general insurance using optimal control theory. ASTIN Bulletin, 35(2), 427453.Google Scholar
Emms, P., Haberman, S., Savoulli, I. (2007). Optimal strategies for pricing general insurance. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 40(1), 1534.Google Scholar
Hellenic Association of Insurance Companies (2010). Statistical Tables (2006–2009), see http://www.eaee.gr/cms/Google Scholar
Jacobson, D.H. (1974). A General result in stochastic Optimal Control of Nonlinear Discrete-Time Systems with Quadratic Performance Criteria. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 47, 153161.Google Scholar
Kushner, H.J. (1970). An introduction to stochastic control theory. John Wiley & Sons, USA.Google Scholar
Friedman, J. (1983). Oligopoly theory. Cambridge University Press, UK.Google Scholar
Ramana, B.V. (2006). Detariffication of Non-life Insurance Product Pricing in India: Impulses of Industry Experts vis-à-vis Perceptions of Public at Large (article). Insurance Chronicle Magazine: Reference # 11M-2006-12-08-01.Google Scholar
Taylor, G.C. (1986). Underwriting strategy in a competitive insurance environment. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 5(1), 5977.Google Scholar
Taylor, G.C. (1987). Expenses and underwriting strategy in competition. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 6(4), 275287.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Premium prices in Euros and number of contracts for the 12 major non-life Greek insurance companies, see Hellenic Association of Insurance Companies (2010).

Figure 1

Table 2 (The volume of business, b, in % for the 12 major non-life Greek insurance companies).

Figure 2

Table 3 (The expected average premium in Euros of the market for the year 2010 is given by $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^K {{{b}_{i,n}}{{p}_{i,n}}} .<$><!--\]$$).

Figure 3

Table 4 (The values of $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$, the change in percentage for the volume of business for the years 2007-2009, and the expected values of θk for the year 2010).

Figure 4

Figure 1 (The real and the expected volume of business for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,\mu <$><!--\]$$).

Figure 5

Table 5 (The optimal premium strategy in Euros for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate).

Figure 6

Figure 2 (The optimal premium strategy in Euros for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have positive $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate)

Figure 7

Table 6 (Premiums prices in Euros and number of contracts for the top 5 non-life Greek insurance companies; see Friedman, 1983).

Figure 8

Table 7 (The weights in % for the calculation of the average premium for the top 5 non-life Greek insurance companies).

Figure 9

Table 8 (The expected average premium in Euros of the market for the year 2010 is given by $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {\bar{p}} \right)\: = \:\frac{1}{m}\mathop{\sum}\nolimits_{i\: = \:1}^{{{K}^ + } } {b_{{i,n}}^{ + } p_{{i,n}}^{ + } } <$><!--\]$$.).

Figure 10

Table 9 (The values of $$\[--><$>{{\hat{\theta }}_k}<$><!--\]$$, the change in percentage for the volume of business for the years 2007–2009, and the expected values of θk for the year 2010).

Figure 11

Table 10 (The optimal premium strategy in Euro for the 5 Greek insurance companies that have $$\[--><$>{\Bbb E}\left( {{{\theta }_k}} \right)\, \gt \,10,000<$><!--\]$$ for the different values of the break-even premium rate).

Figure 12

Figure 3 Optimal premium for the year 2010 (Premium Strategy II).