Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-mzp66 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T15:29:23.894Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Folk-economic beliefs as “evidential fiction”: Putting the economic public discourse back on track

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 August 2018

Alberto Acerbi
Affiliation:
Department of Industrial Engineering and Innovation Sciences, Technische Universiteit Eindhoven, 5600 MB Eindhoven, The Netherlands. alberto.acerbi@gmail.comhttps://acerbialberto.com
Pier Luigi Sacco
Affiliation:
Department of Humanities, IULM University of Milan, 20143 Milan, Italy. pierluigi.sacco@iulm.it Department of Romance Languages and Literatures, Harvard University, Cambridge MA 02138. pierluigi_sacco@fas.harvard.edu FBK-IRVAPP [Fondazione Bruno Kessler – Research Institute for the Evaluation of Public Policy], 38122 Trento, Italy. psacco@irvapp.it

Abstract

Folk-economic beliefs may be regarded as “evidential fictions” that exploit the natural tendency of human cognition to organize itself in narrative form. Narrative counter-arguments are likely more effective than logical debunking. The challenge is to convey sound economic reasoning in narratively conspicuous forms – an opportunity for economics to rethink its role and agency in public discourse, in the spirit of its old classics.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

In their target article, Boyer & Petersen (B&P) offer a compelling explanation of the success and endurance of folk-economic beliefs, based on the influence of evolved, panhuman, cognitive modules. Folk-economic beliefs fit with our intuitions and expectations, and thus they have a cultural advantage with respect to other beliefs, independently of whether they are true. A question that emerges from the article is whether and how we can change these beliefs, given their intuitiveness.

Different approaches to cultural evolution (see Acerbi & Mesoudi Reference Acerbi and Mesoudi2015) propose that various factors can have a role in the cultural diffusion of beliefs. An important distinction in cultural evolution is made between content- and context-based biases. Content-based biases refer to intrinsic features of the cultural traits at stake, which is what B&P focus on. Context-based biases refer instead to contextual factors, independent of the content of the cultural traits, such as popularity (the majority of other individuals believe x) or prestige (experts, or famous individuals, believe x). It is an open question how content- and context-based factors interact in different domains, and whether context-based biases can overcome the intuitiveness of folk-economic beliefs.

Another framework, epistemic vigilance (Sperber et al. Reference Sperber, Clément, Heintz, Mascaro, Mercier, Origgi and Wilson2010), proposes that, under certain conditions, trust and argumentation can enable the spread of counter-intuitive beliefs against the intuitive ones – in this case, folk-economic beliefs. However, argumentation works better in long, face-to-face, interactions, and its strength is inversely proportional to the complexity of the topic. Moreover, trust in economic experts (Bookstaber Reference Bookstaber2017) and politicians (Tormey Reference Tormey2015) is at historical lows. The situation presents some analogies with counteracting anti-vaccination beliefs (Miton & Mercier Reference Miton and Mercier2015).

To understand the success of folk-economic beliefs, we can also characterise them as examples of the “evidential fictions” studied in the cognitive science of narratives (Oatley Reference Oatley2016). The importance of narratives for the social dimension of economic interactions has recently been acknowledged by economists (Shiller Reference Shiller2017). However, economists have so far largely ignored these issues and their implications for cultural transmission – and this is all the more surprising in view of the role of beliefs and expectation-formation processes (Shiller Reference Shiller2015) and self-fulfilling prophecies (Farmer Reference Farmer1999) in the assessment of the allocative efficiency of markets and of the effectiveness of economic policy. Not incidentally, Adam Smith's famous “invisible hand argument,” which is a cornerstone of modern economics, is essentially a powerful narrative rather than a rigorous theorem, and significantly draws upon a complex cultural and even theological tradition (Harrison Reference Harrison2011).

The characterisation of folk-economic beliefs in terms of narratives also suggests possible ways in which they can be counterbalanced. Humans tend to organise their mental models of social situations and contexts in narrative form, and this cognitive strategy need not be regarded as a form of bounded rationality or a source of bias (Mar & Oatley Reference Mar and Oatley2008; Oatley Reference Oatley1999). It has been suggested that engagement in fiction has substantial developmental implications for empathy and theory-of-mind (Oatley Reference Oatley2016), and increases the likelihood of engaging in prosocial behaviour (Johnson Reference Johnson2012). Narratives can prompt individual changes through involvement in the story, including emotional participation and identification with characters, and through the content of the story, by simulating events and situations that are unlikely to be experienced in real life. Narratives, moreover, enable individuals to perform complex social computations that they would be unable to carry out in non-narrative form (Boyd Reference Boyd2009). Therefore, contents that are presented in narrative form elicit judgmental self-confidence in individuals, are felt as less threatening than technical ones, and elicit (possibly biased) non-reflective decision-making (Winterbottom et al. Reference Winterbottom, Bekker, Conner and Mooney2008). Highly technical content that is not cast into narrative form calls on the contrary for an act of trust in the epistemic authority of the proponent – for example, the economic expert (Trinkaus Zagzebski Reference Trinkaus Zagzebski2012). If such authority is challenged by the very narrative that supports folk-economic beliefs, its credibility is fundamentally disqualified and it becomes hard to counteract in non-narrative terms (Smith Reference Smith2017).

For these reasons, insisting on the falsification of folk-economic beliefs on the basis of factual evidence, or even stigmatising such beliefs for their foundation on conceptual fallacies and “fake news” might be a generally ineffective strategy, from the point of view of B&P and from ours. However, cognitive science of narratives and fiction and cultural evolution could suggest possible ways in which intuitive folk-economic beliefs could be addressed, by providing alternative narratives that cast highly technical processes and events in real and financial markets into an intelligible and meaningful form, while being at the same time suitably designed and tested to control for biases. The use of metaphorical arguments and rhetorical tropes is deeply ingrained in the economic discourse (McCloskey Reference McCloskey1998), and economics has an inescapable, although poorly acknowledged, narrative dimension (McCloskey Reference McCloskey1990). It is not just for self-irony that George Akerlof (Reference Akerlof1984) gives to the collection of some of his major theory papers the title: An Economic Theorist's Book of Tales. In the book's introduction, he explicitly equates the single economic idea presented in a theory paper with the powerful narrative proposition of a good short story. The issue posed by folk-economic beliefs may be a healthy challenge for economics to rethink its role and agency in the public discourse, looking back to the teachings of its own old classics. Is it possible to convey good economic reasoning through emotional involvement, identification with characters, and simulations of events, so as to crowd out the deceiving simplicity and intuitiveness of folk-economic beliefs? This is, in our opinion, a promising avenue for future research, at the crossroads of economics, social psychology, cultural evolution, and the humanities.

References

Acerbi, A. & Mesoudi, A. (2015) If we are all cultural Darwinians what's the fuss about? Clarifying recent disagreements in the field of cultural evolution. Biology and Philosophy 30:481503.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1984) An economic theorist's book of tales. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bookstaber, R. M. (2017) The end of theory: Financial crises, the failure of economics, and the sweep of human interaction. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Boyd, B. (2009) On the origin of stories: Evolution, cognition and fiction. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Farmer, R. (1999) The macroeconomics of self-fulfilling prophecies, 2nd edition. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Harrison, P. (2011) Adam Smith and the history of the Invisible Hand. Journal of the History of Ideas 72:2949.Google Scholar
Johnson, D. R. (2012) Transportation into a story increases empathy, prosocial behavior, and perceptual bias toward fearful expressions. Personality and Individual Differences 52:150–55.Google Scholar
Mar, R. & Oatley, K. (2008) The function of fiction is the abstraction and simulation of social experience. Perspectives on Psychological Science 3:173–92.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. (1990) If you're so smart: The narrative of economics expertise. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. (1998) The rhetoric of economics, 2nd edition. University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Miton, H. & Mercier, H. (2015) Cognitive obstacles to pro-vaccination beliefs. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 19:633–36.Google Scholar
Oatley, K. (1999) Why fiction may be twice as true as fact. Review of General Psychology 3:101–17.Google Scholar
Oatley, K. (2016) Fiction: Simulation of social worlds. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 20:618–28.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. (2015) Irrational exuberance. Revised and expanded 3rd edition. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. (2017) Narrative economics. American Economic Review 107:9671004.Google Scholar
Smith, N. (2017) Economists lose credibility when they're too certain. Bloomberg View, December 21, 2017. Available at: https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2017-12-21/economists-lose-credibility-when-they-re-too-certain.Google Scholar
Sperber, D., Clément, F., Heintz, C., Mascaro, O., Mercier, H., Origgi, G. & Wilson, D. (2010) Epistemic vigilance. Mind and Language 2:359–93.Google Scholar
Tormey, S. (2015) The end of representative politics. Polity Press.Google Scholar
Trinkaus Zagzebski, L. (2012) Epistemic authority: A theory of trust, authority, and autonomy in belief. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Winterbottom, A., Bekker, H. L., Conner, M. & Mooney, A. (2008) Does narrative information bias individuals' decision making? A systematic review. Social Science and Medicine 67:2079–88.Google Scholar