Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-07T06:18:48.976Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

European Integration from Nation-States to Member States Christopher J. Bickerton Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012, pp. 213.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 December 2015

Samuel B. H. Faure*
Affiliation:
Sciences Po Paris-CERI
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Reviews/Recensions
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association (l'Association canadienne de science politique) and/et la Société québécoise de science politique 2015 

The European Union (EU) is an “unidentified political object” in the words of Jacques Delors, “less than a federation, more than a regime,” in those of William Wallace (Reference Wallace, Wallace and Webb1983). How to conceptualize this persistent puzzle? For some, the EU is a “regulatory state” (Majone, Reference Majone1994), an “intergovernmental regime” (Moravcsik, Reference Moravcsik1998), for others, a “multi-level governance” (Hooghe and Marks, Reference Hooghe and Marks2001), a “neo-medieval empire” (Zielonka, Reference Zielonka2006) and a “system of differentiated integration” (Leuffen et al., Reference Leuffen, Rittberger and Schimmelfenning2012). Christopher J. Bickerton defines the EU as a “union of member states” (vi) that is the result of the transformation of the state in Europe. The member states are at the centre of the Union and the decisions are made by national representatives, not European agents, as we might think. With the end of the “Golden Age,” in the 1970s to1980s, and the redesign of the social contract, Europe saw the transition of nation-state to the member state.

According to Bickerton, member state is not a legal category but a concept created by social scientists. It is an ideal type of the state that is structured by horizontal bureaucratic expertise and consensus relations among different governments. It aims to address technical problems and is structured around two trends, populism and technocracy. Bickerton also qualifies the member state as a “populist technocracy” (188). This model differs from the nation-state in that it is characterized by vertical political ideological and conflict ties between government and society. The nation-state is to manage political disagreements over the nation (47) and is organized around the left/right divide. To sum up, the member state is less a political community than an administrative machine or, to paraphrase Engels, the “administration of things” (69).

Bickerton contributes to our knowledge on European integration by defining a clear thesis and a concise argument. He successfully avoids falling in the euro-jargon to reconcile the politician and the scientist. The shift in focus from Brussels to the state and its transformations is innovative and useful in explaining the European integration process. Indeed, few studies (Schmidt, Reference Schmidt2010) in European studies focus on elites (national or European) and societies (national and transnational). In addition, identifying the change from the nation-state to the member state in the 1970s and 1980s, rather than after the Second World War, is an original and compelling historical argument. Finally, Bickerton expresses his concern about the trend to research specialization in the social sciences in general (Lahire, Reference Lahire2012) and particularly in the European studies. To understand the EU as a whole, to qualify the polity-building rather than to complete the “series of postcards” (Hall, Reference Hall2007: 126) on the policy-making, is useful.

While acknowledging the premises of the argument, I have a few reservations. First, the European integration is thought as a unified process and as a static system. On the one hand, the units (member states) seem interchangeable because the structure of power relations is not specified. Some EU states correspond to the member state model, others less so. There is an assumption that the smaller the state and its relative “dependence” (Estonia, Malta and Romania, for example), the more emphatic the confirmation of the thesis of the member state. The greater the state and the more “independent” (Germany, France, Poland and the United Kingdom, for example), the more likely the thesis will be less persuasive. In addition, the starting point (the nation-state) is suitable for the states of Western Europe but, for historical reasons, not so appropriate for the states of Central and Eastern Europe. On the other hand, variations between sectors seem to have been lost. The empirical analysis of high politics only (foreign policy, macroeconomic policy, justice, internal and external security policies) does not invalidate the idea that political sectors matter. In the absence of hard evidence, the idea that all states of the EU (Germany and Greece as well as Denmark) hold, in all policy areas (defense and justice as well as agriculture and competition), the same central position seems more essentialist than realistic.

Second, the union of member states offers an approach intergovernmental of the EU. The institutionalization of Europe (Stone Sweet et al.,Reference Stone Sweet, Sandholtz and Fligstein2001) is considered marginal since the emergence of a “Eurocracy field” (Georgagakis, Reference Georgakakis2012), that is to say, Bickerton rejects the empowering of European institutions over the member states. The idea that the EU is limited to 28 member states seems restrictive, even in the high politics such as security, justice (Bigo, Reference Bigo1996; Guiraudon, Reference Guiraudon2000) or defence (Mérand, Reference Mérand2008). Even if the significance of national identity can hardly be disputed, studies such as Lewis (Reference Lewis, Peterson and Shackleton2006) on the functional and institutional socializations process of political representatives in the EU show their plural identity.

Third, the shift from the nation-state to the member state appears linear because governments make “conscious policy choices” (Bickerton, Reference Bickerton2012: 149). This analysis leaves no room for the “unintended consequences” (Pierson, Reference Pierson1996) and hysteresis phenomenon (Neumann and Pouliot, Reference Neumann and Pouliot2011), the “chaotic way” that characterizes the formation of European foreign policy (Buchet de Neuilly, Reference Buchet de Neuilly2005), the constrained decisions or non-decisions leading to the creation of a European defense policy (Mérand, Reference Mérand2008) or the “unlikely strategy” of the policy makers who formed the single market (Jabko, Reference Jabko2009). This linearity of the process gives a teleological impression which excludes the possibility of a reversal or a disintegration of Europe. In other words, after a radical change (the genesis of the member states paradigm), there is a strong “path dependency” (Pierson, Reference Pierson2000) toward the European integration process.

The cover of the book, the great black-and-white photo of Chris Killip's “True Love” shows a man, alone, facing a wall. On the sidewalk, newspapers are tossed and scattered by the wind. A world is disintegrating without another taking its place. This is the pessimistic and complex reality that Christopher J. Bickerton presents.

References

Bickerton, Chris J. 2012. European Integration: From Nation-States to Member States. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bigo, Didier. 1996. Polices en réseaux. L'expérience européenne. Paris: Presses de Sciences Po.Google Scholar
Buchet de Neuilly, Yves. 2005. L'Europe de la politique étrangère. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Georgakakis, Didier, ed. 2012. Le champ de l'Eurocratie. Une sociologie politique du personnel de l'UE. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Guiraudon, Virginie. 2000. “L'espace sociopolitique européen, un champ encore en friche?Cultures et Conflits 38–39: 737.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 2007. The Dilemmas of Contemporary Social Science. Boundary 2 34 (3): 121–41.Google Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet and Marks, Gary. 2001. Multi-level Governance and European Integration. Boulder: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Jabko, Nicolas. 2009. L'Europe par le marché. Histoire d'une stratégie improbable. Paris: Presses de Sciences Po.Google Scholar
Lahire, Bernard. 2012. Monde pluriel. Penser l'unité des sciences sociales. Paris: Seuil (La couleur des idées).Google Scholar
Leuffen, Dirk, Rittberger, Berthold and Schimmelfenning, Frank. 2012. Differentiated Integration. Explaining Variation in the European Union. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan (The European Union Series).Google Scholar
Lewis, Jeffrey T. 2006. “National Interests: Coreper.” In The Institutions of the European Union, ed. Peterson, John and Shackleton, Michael. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Majone, Giandomenico. 1994. “The rise of the regulatory state in Europe.” West European Politics 17 (3): 77101.Google Scholar
Mérand, Frédéric. 2008. European Defence Policy: Beyond the Nation State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1998. The Choice for Europe. Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Neumann, Iver B. and Pouliot, Vincent. 2011. “Untimely Russia: Hysteresis in Russian-Western relations over the past millennium.” Security Studies 20 (1): 105–37.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 1996. “The New Politics of the Welfare State.” World Politics 48 (2): 143–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” The American Political Science Review 94 (2): 251–67.Google Scholar
Schmidt, Vivien A. 2010. La Démocratie en Europe : l'Union européenne et les politiques nationales. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
Stone Sweet, Alec, Sandholtz, Wayne and Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Institutionnalization of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wallace, William. 1983. “Less than a Federation, More than a Regime : The Community as a Political System.” In Policy-Making in the European Community, ed. Wallace, Helen and Webb, Carole. Chichester: Wiley.Google Scholar
Zielonka, Jan. 2006. Europe as Empire. The Nature of the Enlarged European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar