Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T07:26:15.788Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 April 2018

Nicolas Baumard*
Affiliation:
Institut Jean Nicod, Département d'Etudes Cognitives, ENS, EHESS, CNRS, PSL Research University, 75005 Paris, France. nbaumard@gmail.comhttps://nicolasbaumards.org
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Since the Industrial Revolution, human societies have experienced high and sustained rates of economic growth. Recent explanations of this sudden and massive change in economic history have held that modern growth results from an acceleration of innovation. But it is unclear why the rate of innovation drastically accelerated in England in the eighteenth century. An important factor might be the alteration of individual preferences with regard to innovation resulting from the unprecedented living standards of the English during that period, for two reasons. First, recent developments in economic history challenge the standard Malthusian view according to which living standards were stagnant until the Industrial Revolution. Pre-industrial England enjoyed a level of affluence that was unprecedented in history. Second, behavioral sciences have demonstrated that the human brain is designed to respond adaptively to variations in resources in the local environment. In particular, Life History Theory, a branch of evolutionary biology, suggests that a more favorable environment (high resources, low mortality) should trigger the expression of future-oriented preferences. In this paper, I argue that some of these psychological traits – a lower level of time discounting, a higher level of optimism, decreased materialistic orientation, and a higher level of trust in others – are likely to increase the rate of innovation. I review the evidence regarding the impact of affluence on preferences in contemporary as well as past populations, and conclude that the impact of affluence on neurocognitive systems may partly explain the modern acceleration of technological innovations and the associated economic growth.

Type
Target Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019 

1. Introduction

1.1. Two debates: The “Great Divergence” and the “Great Enrichment”

In the past 20 years, quantitative approaches to ancient societies have revealed a massive acceleration of economic growth in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries (Broadberry Reference Broadberry, Guan and Li2018; Maddison Reference Maddison2007; Morris Reference Morris2013). Although per capita income increased slowly, from $400 per year in early farming societies to $2,000 in early modern Britain (expressed in 1990 international or Geary-Khamis dollars), it has exploded in the past two centuries, reaching $40,000 in North America, Western Europe, and Eastern Asia. This increase is two orders of magnitude greater than any experienced before the Industrial Revolution. As Deirdre McCloskey writes: “in the two centuries after 1800 the … goods and services available to the average person in Sweden or Taiwan rose by a factor of 30 or 100. Not 100%, understand – a mere doubling – but in its highest estimate a factor of 100, nearly 10,000%, and at least a factor of 30, or 2,900%. The Great Enrichment of the past two centuries has dwarfed any of the previous and temporary enrichments” (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a, p. 10).

What are the origins of modern growth? Two distinct debates are involved in addressing this question.

The first, traditional debate concerns the localization and the timing of the Industrial Revolution: Why did it occur in England? Why not in Holland, France, or China? What were the advantages of England? This is the debate about the “Great Divergence” (Pomeranz Reference Pomeranz2009) between Europe and Asia, and also about the “Little Divergence” (De Pleijt & Van Zanden Reference de Pleijt and Van Zanden2016) between northwestern Europe and the rest of Europe. A range of solutions has been proposed to explain these two divergences: geography and the abundance of coal (Wrigley Reference Wrigley2013), better institutions (Acemoglu & Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; North & Weingast Reference North and Weingast1989), an early specialization in the textile sector (Allen Reference Allen2009b), greater human capital (Kelly et al. Reference Kelly, Mokyr and Ó Gráda2014), the development of the Atlantic trade (Acemoglu et al. Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005), and more (for a recent review, see Van Neuss Reference Van Neuss2015).

In recent years, however, a second debate has emerged concerning the very nature of modern growth. This is the debate about the “Great Enrichment” (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a). Why was growth limited in ancient societies? And how have modern societies been able to achieve such astonishing growth rates? Here, standard approaches to the Industrial Revolution are of little use (Clark Reference Clark2007; McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a; Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016). Even if these approaches can account for the temporary superiority of England in terms of institutions or human capital, they do not explain the discontinuity created by the Industrial Revolution, nor its magnitude. As Clark puts it: “What makes the Industrial Revolution so difficult to understand is the need to comprehend why – despite huge variation in the customs, mores, and institutions of preindustrial societies – none of them managed to sustain even moderate rates of productivity growth, by modern standards, over any significant time period. What was different about all preindustrial societies that generated such low and faltering rates of efficiency growth?” (Clark Reference Clark2007, p. 207)

Recent work in economic history points to the central role of technology in modern growth (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2009b; Reference Mokyr2016). And indeed, what made England richer was a wave of inventions and innovations in the clothing industry, the mining industry, and so on. Newcomen and Watt invented the steam engine; Arkwright, Hargreaves, Crompton, and Cartwright revolutionized the textile sector; Darby and Cort found new ways to produce iron and more. To take but one example of the scale of these technological improvements, the amount of work needed to turn a pound of cotton into cloth went from the equivalent of 18 man-hours in the 1760s to 1.5 man-hours in the 1860s, an 1,200% increase in productivity. As Joel Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2009b, p. 5) writes: “The best definition of the Industrial Revolution is the set of events that placed technology in the position of the main engine of economic change.”

One possible explanation for a high rate of innovation is the presence of well-functioning institutions (Acemoglu & Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; North Reference North1991). Since the work of Douglas North, it has been argued that the rate of innovation increased in England in the eighteenth century because institutions created a better incentive structure for potential innovators. According to the institutionalist approach, the English crown was more constrained by institutional rules and less likely to infringe on the property rights of innovators than its European counterparts (North & Weingast Reference North and Weingast1989). However, although the institutionalist approach may explain the exceptional political climate of eighteenth-century Britain, it is at odds with the history of the Industrial Revolution. The British institutions of the eighteenth century actually offered little to no incentive to innovate. The last significant reform of the patent system was in 1689, more than a hundred years before efficiency gains became common (Clark Reference Clark2007), and, throughout the eighteenth century, innovators rarely made use of the patent system to defend their property rights (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2009a). The invention of the flying shuttle is a case in point: The flying shuttle was technically illegal because it saved labour, the patent was immediately pirated by competitors to little avail, and Kay was forced to move to France, hounded out of the country by angry weavers who threatened his property and even his life. Kay faced no special incentives – he even innovated despite some formidable social and legal barriers (Howes Reference Howes2016b).

One of the most puzzling facts about the Industrial Revolution is that many of the innovations did not require any scientific or technological input, and could actually have been made much earlier. Paul's carding machine, Arkwright's water frame, and Cartwright's improvements to textile machinery were not “rocket science” (Allen Reference Allen2009b) and would not have “puzzled Archimedes” (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2009b). Thus, the puzzle of the Industrial Revolution: If these innovations were so simple, why then did it take so long for many of them to emerge? As McCloskey puts it: “If the spinning jenny was such a swell idea in 1764 C.E., why was it not in 1264, or 264, or for that matter in 1264 B.C.E.?” (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2010, p. 377).

1.2. A Life History Theory approach to the puzzle of modern growth

Following a growing number of economic historians (Clark Reference Clark2007; McCloskey Reference McCloskey2006; Reference McCloskey2010; Reference McCloskey2016a; Mokyr Reference Mokyr2009b; Reference Mokyr2016), this paper proposes that the most important change that occurred during the Industrial Revolution may not have been in the incentive structure faced by innovators (e.g., better property rights, higher wages, larger markets), but in the preferences of individuals. Specifically, the sustained acceleration of the rate of innovation might partly be a result of a switch from a “scarcity mindset” to an “affluence mindset,” which rendered people more patient, optimistic, and curious.

Why might there have been such a change in individual preferences at this time, in this place? In many parts of Eurasia, living standards slowly increased during Antiquity and the Middle Ages because of the gradual accumulation of technological knowledge in the industrial sector (Dutta et al. Reference Dutta, Levine, Papageorge and Wu2018). England, in particular, achieved an unprecedented level of affluence in the eighteenth century (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015). English people at the time (in particular, members of the upper-middle class) were richer, healthier, taller, better nourished, better equipped, and better educated than individuals in any previous society (Allen Reference Allen2001; Kelly et al. Reference Kelly, Mokyr and Ó Gráda2014). I hypothesize that this increase in living standards may have triggered a limited and gradual modification in neurocognitive processes such as time discounting, optimism, reward orientation, and trust. This hypothesis is based on Life History Theory (LHT), a branch of evolutionary biology that studies how organisms allocate their resources to different activities (development, reproduction, body maintenance, etc.) across the life span (Roff Reference Roff1993; Stearns Reference Stearns1992). The basic idea of LHT is that organisms have a finite budget of resources and they must optimize the use of this budget across the life span. To do so, organisms must make trade-offs between different activities (growth vs. reproduction) and invest, at each moment in their lives, in the activity with the greatest marginal reproductive benefit. For example, if their risk of dying is high and their time horizon short, they should not invest in growing a large body or in developing a strong immune system but start reproducing as soon as possible (Charnov Reference Charnov1991; Promislow & Harvey Reference Promislow and Harvey1990). LHT thus offers an explanation of why species living in different environments with different levels of resources may display drastically different physiological and behavioral traits (e.g., shorter or longer life spans, smaller or bigger bodies, lower or higher levels of investment in offspring).

Although Life History Theory was first developed to account for differences in life history across species (e.g., between species with shorter and those with longer life spans), it has been extended to account for differences in life history within the same species (Stearns & Koella Reference Stearns and Koella1986). In humans, recent empirical works has demonstrated that individuals tend to adopt different “life strategies” depending on their environment (Ellis et al. Reference Ellis, Figueredo, Brumbach and Schlomer2009; Figueredo et al. Reference Figueredo, Vásquez, Brumbach, Schneider, Sefcek, Tal, Hill, Wenner and Jacobs2006; Frankenhuis et al. Reference Frankenhuis, Panchanathan and Nettle2016; Pepper & Nettle Reference Pepper and Nettle2017). In scarce environments, humans tend to grow faster, reach the age of sexual maturity earlier, reproduce earlier, and have more children. By contrast, in more favorable environments, humans adopt a different strategy, reaching maturity later, debuting sexuality later, and having a smaller number of children. These opposite “life strategies” are often referred to as “fast” and “slow” strategies (also called ‘pace-of-life syndromes’ or ‘behavioral constellation’) (see Fig. 1), although it should be emphasized that time preferences are one among many other preferences involved in life history strategies. Crucially, the environment also affects behavior and cognitive level: Individuals growing and living in scarce environments tend to be more violent (McCullough et al. Reference McCullough, Pedersen, Schroder, Tabak and Carver2013), more mistrustful of others (Petersen & Aarøe Reference Petersen and Aarøe2015), more materialistic (Carver et al. Reference Carver, Johnson, McCullough, Forster and Joormann2014), more likely to vote for an authoritarian leader (Safra et al. Reference Safra, Algan, Tecu, Grèzes, Baumard and Chevallier2017), and more intolerant of deviance (Murray et al. Reference Murray, Trudeau and Schaller2011). Crucially, all of these traits are intercorrelated and indeed appear to be coordinated by a single underlying life history variable (Brumbach et al. Reference Brumbach, Figueredo and Ellis2009; Mell et al. Reference Mell, Safra, Algan, Baumard and Chevallier2018).

Figure 1. Fast and slow strategies. Adapted from Griskevicius (Reference Griskevicius, Ackerman, Cantú, Delton, Robertson, Simpson, Thompson and Tybur2013).

In this paper, I apply insights and results from work in LHT to explain the puzzle of the Great Enrichment. To innovate is inherently costly. It requires time and resources, more so as technological complexity increases (Bloom et al. Reference Bloom, Jones, Van Reenen and Webb2017; Gordon Reference Gordon2012; Jones Reference Jones2009; Mesoudi Reference Mesoudi2011). I argue that it is only in sufficiently affluent and stable environments that humans can afford to invest in activities whose benefits are delayed, unpredictable, or (at least initially) moderate. If this is true, then rising living standards are likely to influence the rate of technological innovation. As more people are able to satisfy their basic needs, they will become more patient, more optimistic, and more interested in exploring new technological solutions or in tweaking existing ones (see Fig. 2).

Figure 2. The causal role of the life history switch.

In what follows, I first present LHT in more detail and explain why becoming more exploratory and patient when resources are more abundant is adaptive (sect. 2). I then review the empirical evidence regarding the effect of affluence on human behavior (sect. 3). In particular, I show that resources can impact the expression of a range of psychological traits related to innovation: time discounting, self-control, optimism, cognitive exploration, and social trust. Finally, I review the evidence demonstrating the unprecedented level of affluence in eighteenth-century England (sect. 4) and discuss whether the English indeed displayed a “slow” psychology (in LHT terms) outside the domains related to innovation (sect. 5). I conclude the paper by discussing the points of convergence and divergence between this approach and other work emphasizing psychological mechanisms, as well as the potential of such a mechanism to explain the broader “civilizing process” (declining violence, declining impulsivity, increasing openness, increasing social trust; Elias Reference Elias1982).

2. Life History Theory and the variability of innovativeness

2.1. The mechanism of adaptive plasticity

One common assumption in the social sciences is that biological mechanisms are fixed and, thus, cannot change. Historical change would thus require exogenous forces such as new ideas or new institutions. But this assumption is based on a common misconception about natural selection, which is wrongly thought to favor mechanisms that produce uniform and unchanging behaviors. In fact, most evolved mechanisms, physiological or psychological, actually come with a certain level of flexibility in response to local contexts. When the environment changes at a rate that is too high relative to generation time, natural selection does not have enough time to produce genetic adaptations for each and every environmental state (Moran Reference Moran1992; Stearns & Koella Reference Stearns and Koella1986). In this case, natural selection instead favors a genotype that can react flexibly to the environment. Individuals are characterized not by a single phenotypic profile (organs, behaviors), but by what is called a “reaction norm”: a range of phenotypes expressed conditionally depending on the current state of the environment. The expression of a variety of locally adapted phenotypes from the same genotype is called adaptive plasticity.

To take but one example, Bateson et al. (Reference Bateson, Brilot, Gillespie, Monaghan and Nettle2015) tested the impact of scarcity on a population of starlings. Pairs of chicks were placed in nests where they faced either a high or low level of competition for 12 days as juveniles (Fig. 2a), after which they were all transferred to the laboratory for hand-rearing under uniform conditions. As expected, this manipulation affected the birds’ telomeres, a biomarker of poor biological state and life expectancy. Birds in the high-competition condition traded their investment in growth and body maintenance for increased competitiveness. Impulsivity was measured when the birds were fully grown (6–12 months later) (Fig. 2b). Birds with greater developmental telomere attrition (those that reacted the most to the high-competition treatment) had a stronger preference for smaller but more immediate food rewards than birds with less developmental attrition or longer telomeres. A subsequent study from the same team found that biological aging in starlings is associated with higher levels of risk aversion (Andrews et al. Reference Andrews, Nettle, Reichert, Bedford, Monaghan and Bateson2018).

Bateson et al.’s experiment perfectly illustrates the potential of adaptive plasticity and LHT, in particular, to help us understand historical changes. When impulsivity was measured, the birds in the two groups were living the same life: They were fed the same way, lived in the same aviary, and were being taken care of by the same people. They also had the same kinds of social interactions with the same conspecifics. In other words, they were facing the same incentive structure with the same information about their environment. And yet their preferences regarding time differed according to how much they had been stressed when they were juveniles. Likewise, behavioral changes can occur without any change in political institutions, religious beliefs, or useful knowledge. They can result simply from change in adaptive calibrations.

2.2. Life history plasticity in humans

In the past decade, a range of studies has shown that human plasticity obeys the same evolutionary logic employed by other animals (see Fig. 1). When the environment deteriorates, individuals tend to accelerate their life history in every domain of life: reproductive investments, somatic investment, and social investment. In this section, I briefly review this literature.

2.2.1. Somatic investment

It is well documented that individuals growing up in a harsh environment are less likely to invest in their health. People in a lower socioeconomic position smoke more, exercise less, have a poorer diet, comply less well with therapy, use medical services less, and ignore health and safety advice more than their more-affluent peers (Nettle Reference Nettle2011; Smith & Egger Reference Smith and Egger1993; Stringhini et al. Reference Stringhini, Sabia, Shipley, Brunner, Nabi, Kivimaki and Singh-Manoux2010). The evolutionary reason is that health behavior competes for individuals’ time and energy with other activities that contribute to their fitness. When resources are low, individuals invest less in their immune systems and in protecting their bodies (Nettle Reference Nettle2010b; Nettle et al. Reference Nettle, Frankenhuis and Rickard2013) (see Fig. 3).

Figure 3. (a) Brood-size manipulation. The diagram shows the creation of a single family of four focal chicks. (b) Intertemporal choice task. One colored key (here, green) was assigned to the smaller sooner option (a 1-s delay to obtain one 45-mg pellet), and the other color (here, red) was assigned to the larger later option (a longer x-s delay to obtain five 45-mg pellets) (Bateson et al. Reference Bateson, Brilot, Gillespie, Monaghan and Nettle2015).

In line with this reasoning, Nettle (Reference Nettle2014) showed that a lower level of parental support during childhood is associated with accelerated deterioration of health as well as increased levels of the C-reactive protein (an inflammatory biomarker of the somatic damage caused by social and environmental stressors). These associations are robust, persisting after adult socioeconomic position has been controlled for, and do not appear to be a consequence of an accelerated reproductive strategy, smoking, or body mass index. Similarly, Mell et al. (Reference Mell, Safra, Algan, Baumard and Chevallier2018) showed that childhood poverty is associated with lower somatic investment (e.g., effort in looking after health) in a representative sample of French individuals. Crucially, Mell et al. showed that lower investments in health are associated with “faster” behaviors in the reproductive domain, supporting the existence of an overarching general life history strategy explaining both reproductive and health choices.

2.2.2. Reproductive investments

The basic prediction of LHT concerning reproduction is straightforward. As the level of resources decreases, investment in self-repair and bodily systems decreases (Nettle Reference Nettle2010b; Nettle et al. Reference Nettle, Frankenhuis and Rickard2013). This, in turn, accelerates the speed of aging and lowers the optimal age for initiating reproductive effort. These predictions have been confirmed by a large number of studies: Humans living in harsh environments reach sexual maturity earlier (Brumbach et al. Reference Brumbach, Figueredo and Ellis2009; Ellis Reference Ellis2004), reproduce earlier (Belsky et al. Reference Belsky, Steinberg, Houts and Halpern-Felsher2010; Ellis Reference Ellis2004), and have more children (Guégan et al. Reference Guégan, Thomas, Hochberg, de Meeûs and Renaud2001). Further studies have shown that people living in harsh environments also tend to invest less in their children. For example, using data from the British Millennium Cohort Study (N = 8,660 families), Nettle (Reference Nettle2010a) showed that in harsher neighborhoods, breastfeeding duration is shorter, co-residence of a father figure is less common, and contact with maternal grandmothers is less frequent. Similar relations between environmental harshness and parental investment have been observed cross-culturally, with maternal care being inversely associated with famine, warfare, and high levels of pathogens (Quinlan Reference Quinlan2007; Quinlan & Quinlan Reference Quinlan and Quinlan2007).

2.3. Life history and attitude toward innovation

In the preceding sections, I reviewed the core domains studied by behavioral ecologists and evolutionary biologists working on LHT. However, in the last decades, scientists have started to apply the insights of LHT to a range of psychological domains that are likely to affect the rate of innovation.

2.3.1. Time discounting

Innovation takes time to yield benefits. Even where an individual is simply tweaking and adapting an existing invention (as was often the case of English innovators in the eighteenth century), individuals need to be ready to waste years trying to improve a device without knowing whether they will ever succeed. In his British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective, Allen (Reference Allen2009b) discusses in detail the issues involved in inventing mechanical spinning (e.g., how much the speed should increase from one set of rollers to the next, how to arrange the gears to connect the main power shaft to the rollers and coordinate their movements, and the spacing between rollers). His discussion emphasizes that the most difficult part was not to come up with the idea of the roller, but to make the roller work in this application. Wyatt and Paul had spent decades on this problem but never succeeded, and it took several years for Arkwright and the clockmakers to find their solution. As Allen points out, many of the innovations of the eighteenth century involved what we would today call an “R&D program,” in which the innovators constructed prototypes and performed careful experimentation.

How should time discounting be affected by increased living standards? From an LHT perspective, individuals living in a harsh environment cannot allocate resources to activities that have large but delayed benefits, because they cannot afford to wait (Houston & McNamara Reference Houston and McNamara1999). Thus, in a harsh environment, individuals are more likely to postpone investing in innovation and to focus on more pressing needs. By contrast, individuals surrounded by abundance can afford to invest in long-term endeavors such as building prototypes, conducting careful experiments, and trying out new models. Note that time discounting is a very abstract construct. People's time discounting will be visible not only in time-discounting tasks (i.e., $10 now rather than $20 later), but also in tests of psychological characteristics such as self-control and impulsivity. People living in affluent environments should show higher levels of self-control in tasks such as the marshmallow test or on questionnaires concerning impulsive actions.

2.3.2. Optimism

English innovators were particularly optimistic. As Howes (Reference Howes2016a) writes, they had an “improving mentality,” seeing room for improvement everywhere. Henry Dircks, who improved steam engines and designed optical illusions, expressed the new mentality thus: “No work of art appears perfect to an enterprising mind. However simple its purpose, it may possibly be made lighter, stronger, more efficacious, or be done away with altogether. The man whose mind is thus constituted becomes an Inventor” (Dircks 1867, p. 9, cited in Howes Reference Howes2016a, p. 8).

How should optimism be affected by increased living standards? LHT modeling, inspired by optimal foraging theory (Stephens Reference Stephens1981), suggests that individuals with low resources should have a high threshold for responding to reward cues because they have few resources to invest. As a result, they should be reluctant to initiate reward-approach behaviors (Nettle Reference Nettle2009a; Nettle & Bateson Reference Nettle and Bateson2012). At the subjective level, they should feel that taking action will not be pleasurable, that they probably will not succeed, and that they do not have the energy to try. By contrast, individuals with high resources should be ready to initiate reward-approach behavior when given only minimal cues that a reward may be available. In humans, this state is associated with subjective feelings of optimism, with attentional biases toward reward-related stimuli and with willingness to try out novel reward-oriented strategies.

2.3.3. Materialism and intrinsic motivation

Edison famously observed that “invention is 1% inspiration and 99% perspiration” (cited in Allen Reference Allen2009b, p. 149). In other words, innovation requires a high level of discipline and conscientiousness. Innovators need to focus on the many little challenges they face rather than on the big material rewards associated with developing a successful innovation. Thus, they need to be intrinsically motivated by the process of inventing, tweaking, and adapting existing technologies.

How should materialism and intrinsic motivation be affected by increased living standards? Individuals living in harsh environments are unlikely to invest in activities with a moderate return on investment because other, more vital activities need more urgently to be performed (Kenrick et al. Reference Kenrick, Griskevicius, Neuberg and Schaller2010). It is only when they have fulfilled their vital and basic needs (food, self-protection, affiliation, social status) that they can afford to pursue activities such as free exploration. The predictions of LHT are somewhat well known, as they correspond to the “pyramid of needs” described by Maslow in the 1940s (Kenrick et al. Reference Kenrick, Griskevicius, Neuberg and Schaller2010). What LHT does is explain why humans’ needs are prioritized as they are. Individuals have all kinds of needs whose return on investment depends on the individual's state. When an individual is poor or young, some needs have a very high return on investment (food, self-protection, affiliation), and others have lower returns on investment (exploration: what Maslow lumped together with other activities under the heading of “self-actualization”). By contrast, when the same individual has fulfilled these needs (growing a body, making some friends), their return on investment diminishes (the marginal benefit of having an extra friend depends on the number of friends). Other activities, with a moderate return on investment, then start to be more advantageous. As a result, these activities become a priority.

2.3.4. Cognitive investment and cognitive exploration

The history of technology reveals that most macro-innovations came from outside of the field of the industry concerned (Allen Reference Allen2009b, p. 141). They required innovators to ignore existing technological traditions and show little reverence for existing solutions. This was indeed the state of mind of many eighteenth-century innovators who were no experts in their industry and who discarded existing tradition. For example, Henry Bessemer (steelmaking process) explained that he was very aware of his ignorance and that he thought of it as an advantage:

My knowledge of iron metallurgy was at the time very limited … but this was in one sense an advantage to me, for I had nothing to unlearn. My mind was open and free to receive any new impressions, without having to struggle against the bias which a lifelong practice of routine operations cannot fail more or less to create. (cited by Howes Reference Howes2016b, p. 10)

What are the costs and benefits of individual and social learning? In behavioral ecology, social information is usually regarded as cheaper because individuals can piggyback on others’ knowledge, but also as less accurate because individuals may not be in the same situation as others (Boyd & Richerson Reference Boyd and Richerson1985; Laland & Williams Reference Laland and Williams1998; Rieucau & Giraldeau Reference Rieucau and Giraldeau2011; Webster & Hart Reference Webster and Hart2006). There is thus a trade-off between cost and accuracy. When resources are abundant, individuals should favor accuracy, be interested in cognitive investment and cognitive exploration, and thus be curious, independent, and open-minded. On the contrary, when resources are low, individuals should not waste more resources in exploring their environment; they should rather be conservative and conformist (Jacquet et al. Reference Jacquet, Safra, Wyart, Baumard and Chevallier2018).

2.3.5. Social trust

Innovation is likely to be favored by social trust, which promotes open discussions and furthers the circulation of innovation (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016). As McCloskey notes, one important difference between Renaissance Florence and Early Modern Britain is that “Leonardo da Vinci in 1519 concealed his engineering dreams in secret writing,” whereas “in 1825 James Watt of steam-engine fame was to have a statue set up in Westminster Abbey” (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016b, p. XXXIV). In line with this idea, Howes (Reference Howes2016a) showed that British innovators were almost all committed in some way to advancing, proselytizing, or disseminating further improvement by contributing to societies, authoring books, funding schools, or abstaining from patenting their inventions. Eighty-three percent shared innovation in some way; only 12% tried to stifle it, and only 5% are known to have been secretive.

From an LHT perspective, cooperation can be seen as an investment. Individuals invest their time and resources in collective action in the hope that these activities will produce bigger benefits than solitary work will (Baumard et al. Reference Baumard, André and Sperber2013; West et al. Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007). From this perspective, cooperation is intrinsically forward-looking. It is thus expected that individuals should invest less in cooperation, and therefore be less trustful, when they cannot afford to lose their investment or when they discount time at too high a rate to wait for their partners to reciprocate.

2.4. Why innovation is not always the best strategy

LHT runs against the common sense according to which “necessity is the mother of invention.” Common sense suggests that individuals in poverty should innovate more or show greater self-control, because they are in a situation where they would benefit more from innovating and restraining their impulses. And yet, clearly, innovation is more frequent in more affluent societies, those that already perform better. Even in nonhuman animals such as birds and monkeys, a growing body of data suggests that individuals are more innovative in captivity than in the wild (Forss et al. Reference Forss, Schuppli, Haiden, Zweifel and van Schaik2015; Haslam Reference Haslam2013; van Schaik et al. Reference van Schaik, Burkart, Damerius, Forss, Koops, van Noordwijk and Schuppli2016).

The explanation for this paradox is that the opportunity costs of innovation are higher in poorer societies. Individuals living in poverty actually have more pressing needs than the need to innovate: they must find food for tomorrow, rebuild their house before the next rain, watch out for potential dangers, and so on. As counterintuitive as it may be, medieval laborers had better things to do than improve the productivity of their tools. If these laborers had invested in innovation, their fields might have been more productive in the long run. But the time spent on innovation, or the risks associated with tweaking traditional techniques, could also have led to the ruin of their families. Innovation is a luxury that few could afford in pre-industrial societies.

So, a lack of innovativeness should not be seen as suboptimal behavior. Exploration and exploitation are two different strategies with different advantages and drawbacks. Exploration can bring greater rewards in the form of profitable innovations, but it is often more risky in the sense that it requires time and resources and may not automatically lead to successful innovation. By contrast, exploitation brings lower rewards, but these rewards are safer because they require a lower level of investment and are more certain. Consequently, the potential benefits of exploration and exploitation are context-dependent. Exploration is a better strategy under conditions of relative safety, in which individuals can afford to divert some resources and even lose them in the pursuit of an innovation. Exploitation is a better strategy under harsh conditions, where any error can lead to starvation and death.

Importantly, this implies that individuals living in scarcity will not show impaired cognitive or behavioral performance. Instead, according to evolutionary theory, the preferences and behaviors of individuals should be contextually appropriate, and people living in scarcity are simply better adapted to that type of environment. Recall, here, that the stressed starlings were impulsive but not cognitively impaired. In line with this idea, individuals living in an environment of scarcity perform better at tasks related to actual challenges created by scarcity. Recent studies indicate that, compared with individuals living in affluent environments, people living in scarcity exhibit improved detection, learning, and memory in tasks involving stimuli that are ecologically relevant to them (e.g., dangers: Dang et al. Reference Dang, Xiao, Zhang, Liu, Jiang and Mao2016; Frankenhuis & de Weerth Reference Frankenhuis and de Weerth2013; Frankenhuis et al. Reference Frankenhuis, Panchanathan and Nettle2016; Mittal et al. Reference Mittal, Griskevicius, Simpson, Sung and Young2015).

3. The impact of affluence on innovativeness

In section 2, I reviewed the theoretical evidence in favor of the view that an increase in resources is likely to affect a range of attitudes in a way that is conducive to innovation. In this section, I review the empirical evidence in favor of this view. In recent years, a number of scholars have demonstrated that poverty makes individuals more present-oriented, more loss-averse, less exploratory, and more conformist. In behavioral economics, these are often referred under the term “psychology of poverty” (Haushofer & Fehr Reference Haushofer and Fehr2014) or the “scarcity mindset” (Mani et al. Reference Mani, Mullainathan, Shafir and Zhao2013; Mullainathan & Shafir Reference Mullainathan and Shafir2013). In this section, I focus on the other side of the coin, the “psychology of affluence” or the “abundance mindset,” that is, evidence that affluence makes people more future-oriented, less loss-averse, more exploratory, and less conformist.

3.1. Time discounting, self-control, and impulsivity

Affluence has a substantial impact on time discounting. In a recent study, Haushofer and Fehr reviewed the effect of poverty on time discounting and showed that the level of resources has a strong effect on people's relationship to the future (Haushofer & Fehr Reference Haushofer and Fehr2014). For example, the discount rates of poor U.S. households are substantially higher than those of rich households (Lawrance Reference Lawrance1991). Likewise, studies of Ethiopian farm households (Yesuf & Bluffstone Reference Yesuf and Bluffstone2008) and a South Indian sample (Pender Reference Pender1996) have found that poverty is significantly associated with higher (behaviorally measured) discount rates.

People living in harsh environments where unemployment and violence are high also have less self-control and are more impulsive. Carver et al. (Reference Carver, Johnson, McCullough, Forster and Joormann2014) studied the impact of harshness during childhood on self-control in adults. They used validated psychometric scales assessing self-control, urgency, and perseverance. Their results show a consistent association between childhood harshness and lack of self-control. Similarly, Duckworth et al. (Reference Duckworth, Kim and Tsukayama2013) demonstrated that negative life events in the past year (events such as getting fired or laid off from job, “major change in emotional closeness of family,” or divorce) were associated with diminished self-control in children and adolescents. In line with these results, poverty (i.e., inadequate housing, economic insufficiency) is associated with higher resting levels of salivary cortisol during the first four years of life which, in turn, is associated with worse performance on executive function tasks (Blair & Raver Reference Blair and Raver2012; Blair et al. Reference Blair, Granger, Willoughby, Mills-Koonce, Cox, Greenberg, Kivlighan and Fortunato2011).

3.2. Optimism and feeling of internal control

Studies with large cohorts have demonstrated a strong socioeconomic status (SES) gradient in optimism and pessimism, with higher SES being associated with higher optimism scores and lower pessimism scores (Boehm et al. Reference Boehm, Chen, Williams, Ryff and Kubzansky2015; Heinonen et al. Reference Heinonen, Räikkönen, Matthews, Scheier, Raitakari, Pulkki and Keltikangas-Järvinen2006; Robb et al. Reference Robb, Simon and Wardle2009). Importantly, in line with the idea that part of life history is calibrated early in childhood, childhood family SES has been found to be associated with overall optimism and pessimism component scores, even after controlling statistically for SES in adulthood (Heinonen et al. Reference Heinonen, Räikkönen, Matthews, Scheier, Raitakari, Pulkki and Keltikangas-Järvinen2006). A number of other psychological variables are related to optimism, such as “locus of control” and “self-efficacy,” which measure people's confidence in their ability to control their environment. To test the association between poverty and locus of control, Haushofer (Reference Haushofer2013) used questions from the World Values Survey such as: “Some people believe that individuals can decide their own destiny, while others think that it is impossible to escape a predetermined fate. Please tell me which comes closest to your view on this scale on which 1 means ‘everything in life is determined by fate,’ and 10 means that ‘people shape their fate themselves.’” Both within and across countries, affluence is associated with a higher feeling of internal control. This study replicates previous studies in a diversity of populations (e.g., Kiecolt et al. Reference Kiecolt, Hughes and Keith2009; Lundberg et al. Reference Lundberg, Bobak, Malyutina, Kristenson and Pikhart2007; Poortinga et al. Reference Poortinga, Dunstan and Fone2008).

3.3. Materialism and intrinsic motivation

Materialism is typically understood as “the belief that it is important to pursue the culturally sanctioned goals of attaining financial success, having nice possessions, having the right image (produced, in large part, through consumer goods), and having a high status (defined mostly by the size of one's pocketbook and the scope of one's possessions)” (Kasser et al. Reference Kasser, Ryan, Couchman, Sheldon, Kasser and Kanner2004). Using longitudinal data on American twelfth graders between 1976 and 2007 (N = 355,296), Twenge and Kasser (Reference Twenge and Kasser2013) measured materialism (through questions measuring young people's attitudes on “how important it is ‘to have lots of money’” or to have “a job which provides you with a chance to earn a good deal of money”). In line with LHT, they showed that societal instability was associated with higher levels of materialism (for similar results, see Briers et al. Reference Briers, Pandelaere, Dewitte and Warlop2006; Cohen & Cohen Reference Cohen and Cohen1996; Kasser et al. Reference Kasser, Ryan, Zax and Sameroff1995; Sheldon & Kasser Reference Sheldon and Kasser2008). Carver et al. (Reference Carver, Johnson, McCullough, Forster and Joormann2014) studied another kind of extrinsic goal, namely, social success. Using a scale measuring hubristic pride, popular fame, and financial success, they showed that childhood adversity is associated with a greater tendency to set implausibly high goals (“I will be famous,” “I will run a Fortune 500 company”). Finally, sensation seeking is another behavioral construct that is related to intrinsic motivation. Carver et al. (Reference Carver, Johnson, McCullough, Forster and Joormann2014) showed that childhood adversity is associated with higher levels of sensation seeking, as well as greater consumption of illicit drugs and alcohol (Droomers et al. Reference Droomers, Schrijvers, Stronks, van de Mheen and Mackenbach1999; Legleye et al. Reference Legleye, Janssen, Beck, Chau and Khlat2011).

At the other end of the spectrum, affluence has been shown to positively impact intrinsic motivation: As people get richer, they are less interested in immediate material rewards. Using the World Values Survey, Haushofer (Reference Haushofer2013) showed a consistent association between intrinsic motivation and income, both across and within countries (Haushofer approximated intrinsic motivation with two questions: agreement with the statements “Working for a living is a necessity; I wouldn't work if I didn't have to” and “I do the best I can regardless of pay” (Haushofer Reference Haushofer2013). Affluence has also been found to affect personality consciousness (Akee et al. Reference Akee, Copeland, Costello and Simeonova2018). Using the Great Smoky Mountains Study of Youth, Akee et al. (Reference Akee, Copeland, Costello and Simeonova2018) demonstrated that cash transfers increased conscientiousness and reduced drug consumption independently of income or education.

3.4. Cognitive investment and cognitive exploration

Individuals with low resources should invest less in cognitive exploration and information gathering, and, consequently, they should rely more on cheaper sources of information such as others’ opinions (Nettle Reference Nettle2019). Jacquet et al. (Reference Jacquet, Safra, Wyart, Baumard and Chevallier2018) studied the calibration of cognitive investment in information gathering through variables such as childhood scarcity and childhood unpredictability (assessed through agreement with statements such as “Things were often chaotic in my house” and “People often moved in and out of my house on a pretty random basis”). The results indicated that, independent of their current situation, participants who experienced scarcity and unpredictability during childhood are more likely to follow the opinion of the group in a standard face evaluation task.

Affluence should also impact cognitive investment in more abstract tasks. In a series of experiments, Mani et al. (Reference Mani, Mullainathan, Shafir and Zhao2013) studied the impact of scarcity on individuals’ performance in Raven's Progressive Matrices and in a spatial compatibility task. They induced richer and poorer participants to think about everyday financial demands. They hypothesized that for the rich, these little financial demands would be of little consequence, whereas for the poor, these demands would trigger persistent and distracting concerns. In line with their hypotheses, poor participants performed worse. Mani et al. (Reference Mani, Mullainathan, Shafir and Zhao2013) also conducted a field study that used a quasi-experimental variation in actual wealth. Indian sugarcane farmers receive income annually at harvest time and find it hard to smooth their consumption. As a result, they experience cycles of poverty: they are poorer before harvest and richer afterward. (On average, farmers had 1.97 more loans before harvest than they did afterward. They were also more likely to answer “Yes” to the question, “Did you have trouble coping with ordinary bills in the last fifteen days?” before harvest than after). This allowed the researchers to compare the cognitive capacities of the same farmer in poorer (preharvest) versus richer (postharvest) circumstances. Again, the farmers’ performance was worse in times of scarcity.

3.5. Trust

Cooperative behaviors have been found to vary with the harshness of the environment (Holland et al. Reference Holland, Silva and Mace2012; Nettle et al. Reference Nettle, Colléony and Cockerill2011; Silva & Mace Reference Silva and Mace2014; Reference Silva and Mace2015; but see Wu et al. Reference Wu, Balliet, Tybur, Arai, Van Lange and Yamagishi2017). Independent of their current level of resources, people who grew up in a deprived environment are more likely to defect (McCullough et al. Reference McCullough, Pedersen, Schroder, Tabak and Carver2013), more likely to steal from others (Schroeder et al. Reference Schroeder, Pepper and Nettle2014), and less likely to forgive others (McCullough et al. Reference McCullough, Pedersen, Schroder, Tabak and Carver2013; Pedersen et al. Reference Pedersen, Forster and McCullough2014), trust them (Mell et al. Reference Mell, Safra, Algan, Baumard and Chevallier2018), and punish cheaters (Schroeder et al. Reference Schroeder, Pepper and Nettle2014). Importantly, life history theory predicts that cooperative behaviors should be part of a more general life history strategy. In line with this prediction, Petersen and Aarøe (Reference Petersen and Aarøe2015) report an association between low birth weight, low self-control in childhood, and lower social trust in adulthood (on the early calibration of prosociality, see also Benenson et al. Reference Benenson, Pascoe and Radmore2007; Safra et al. Reference Safra, Tecu, Lambert, Sheskin, Baumard and Chevallier2016). Similarly, lab studies show a correlation between high time discounting – an indicator of a faster life strategy – and low levels of cooperation in economic games (Curry et al. Reference Curry, Price and Price2008; Espín et al. Reference Espín, Brañas-Garza, Herrmann and Gamella2012; Harris & Madden Reference Harris and Madden2002; Kocher et al. Reference Kocher, Myrseth, Martinsson and Wollbrant2013; Kortenkamp & Moore Reference Kortenkamp and Moore2006). Finally, Mell et al. (Reference Mell, Safra, Algan, Baumard and Chevallier2018) demonstrated that the impact of environmental harshness on social trust is mediated by a latent psychological construct corresponding to life history strategy.

3.6. Assessing the causal impact of affluence

Most studies presented in this section are correlational, and it could be that the association between affluence and a slow life history is driven by other factors (notably genetics). Similarly, experimental studies may reveal real but fleeting effects on human behaviors. However, in recent years an increasing number of studies in econometrics have aimed to assess the causal impact of the environment using natural experiments. There is now a consensus that exogeneous shocks in utero or during early childhood (disease, famine, malnutrition, pollution, war) have dramatic, long-lasting effects on physical and mental health, height, IQ, and income (for a review, see Currie & Vogl Reference Currie and Vogl2013). A growing number of studies show similar effects on psychological traits such as risk attitudes (Moya Reference Moya2018), materialism (Kesternich et al. Reference Kesternich, Siflinger, Smith and Winter2015), and prosociality (Cecchi & Duchoslav Reference Cecchi and Duchoslav2018; Gangadharan et al. Reference Gangadharan, Islam, Ouch and Wang2017). The Great Smoky Mountains Study of Youth (cited in sect. 3.3) is a case in point. This study takes advantage of the opening of a casino in the Eastern Band of Cherokee Indians tribal reservation. Following the opening of the casino, permanent transfers were provided to all adult Cherokees (but not to non-Cherokees living in the same area), regardless of employment conditions, marital status, presence of young children in the household, or residence on the reservation. Comparing Native American children with non-Native American children before and after a casino opened on tribal land, Akee et al. (Reference Akee, Copeland, Costello and Simeonova2018) found that receipt of casino payments reduced criminal behavior, drug use, and behavioral disorders associated with poverty such as depression, anxiety, and oppositional disorders, and it also increased agreeableness (i.e., the tendency to be cooperative and get along well with others) and conscientiousness (i.e., the propensity to be hard-working and organized). Similarly, Hörl et al. (Reference Hörl, Kesternich, Smith and Winter2016) used the hunger episode in occupied Germany after WWII as an instrument to test the effect of an exogenous variation in caloric input in childhood on social trust in adulthood. They found that individuals exposed to lower caloric input in 1944–1945 showed decreased social trust later in life. Twin studies offer another way to disentangle the causal impact of genetic and environmental factors. Using this method, Cronqvist et al. (Reference Cronqvist, Previtero, Siegel and White2015) found that individuals with higher birth weight (within pairs of identical twins) are more likely to participate in the stock market (a proxy of risk-taking preference).

To conclude, levels of resources shape individual preferences in a predictable way. Individuals living in conditions of affluence tend to have lower rates of time discounting, to be more optimistic, and to be more conscientious and trustful. But why should this set of preferences be found in eighteenth-century England more than in another place and time? Why were the English the first people to lose the “scarcity mindset” and embrace the “affluence mindset”?

4. The unprecedented affluence of eighteenth-century England

It has long been thought that living standards and GDP per capita were more or less stagnant before the Industrial Revolution (Clark Reference Clark2007). This was based on the Malthusian assumption that any per capita income above some subsistence level would lead to population increases and, consequently, to a decrease in per capita income. However, the Malthusian reasoning is based on the false premise that all innovations should occur in the agricultural sector and should translate into an increased quantity of calories. This is sometimes true – as, for example, during the Neolithic Revolution – but not always. In many cases, in sectors such as clothing, construction, and luxury goods, innovations do not automatically increase the quantity of available calories but instead increase some other aspect of living standards (Dutta et al. Reference Dutta, Levine, Papageorge and Wu2018).

Recent work in historical economics and quantitative history confirms this conclusion and demonstrates that some societies – Classical Greece, Roman Italy, Song China, Medieval Italy – experienced some period of growth (Allen Reference Allen2001; Maddison Reference Maddison2007; Morris Reference Morris2013; Ober Reference Ober2015). Here, I review the evidence concerning the growth of purchasing power, GDP per capita, urbanization, and health. The evidence leads to three conclusions: (1) England enjoyed a long period of growth in living standards from the fifteenth century on; (2) England was richer than any other country, in Europe or elsewhere, on the eve of the Industrial Revolution; and (3) England was richer than any previous society in the history of humanity, including Classical Greece, Roman Italy, Song China, and Medieval Italy.

4.1. Purchasing power

Allen's (Reference Allen2001) seminal work on pre-modern European wages clearly demonstrated that English (and Dutch) workers were much richer than their European counterparts. There was little difference in 1400, but over the following centuries welfare ratios increased in England and The Netherlands and decreased in the rest of Europe. (The welfare ratio is the average annual earnings divided by the cost of a basket of goods necessary for the minimal subsistence of a family of four. A welfare ratio greater than one indicates an income above the poverty line, whereas a ratio less than one means the family is in poverty.) In 1750, the welfare ratio of English craftsmen was 2.21, compared with 1.20 in Paris and 0.97 in Florence. Similarly, the welfare ratio of English laborers was 1.58, versus 0.80 in Paris and 0.90 in Florence (Allen Reference Allen2001; but see Malanima Reference Malanima2013; Stephenson Reference Stephenson2017). Later studies have found that the welfare ratios of Chinese, Indian, and Japanese workers were similar to continental European welfare ratios and much lower than those of the English and the Dutch (Allen et al. Reference Allen, Bassino, Ma, Moll-Murata and Van Zanden2011; Deng & O'Brien Reference Deng and O'Brien2016). Using Diocletian's Price Edict (301 AD), Allen (Reference Allen, Bowman and Wilson2009a) reconstructed the welfare ratio of Roman workers. His estimation points toward a very low welfare ratio, lower than eighteenth-century European and Asian welfare ratios (see Fig. 4). Similar work confirms that workers in ancient economies, even at the peak of the Roman Empire, were probably much poorer than their eighteenth-century English counterparts (Scheidel Reference Scheidel2010).

Figure 4. Welfare ratios of laborers in Europe, Asia, and the Roman Empire (Allen Reference Allen, Bowman and Wilson2009a).

English purchasing power at that time has probably been underestimated, partly because it is difficult to compare luxury goods (furniture, sweets, etc.) across countries and across time. However, it is likely that luxury goods played an important but hidden role in increasing the living standards of the English (De Vries Reference de Vries1994; Hersh & Voth Reference Hersh and Voth2009; Morris Reference Morris2013). For example, Hersch and Voth (Reference Hersh and Voth2009) estimated in a recent paper that the introduction of sugar and tea transformed the English diet in the eighteenth century and increased the welfare of the English by 15%, a gain much larger than those associated with the introduction of the Internet (2%–3%) or mobile phones (0.46%–0.9%). Including tomatoes, potatoes, exotic spices, polenta, and tobacco would show an even larger increase in living standards in eighteenth-century England. During the same period, technological products became much more widely available in England. Nordhaus (Reference Nordhaus, Bresnahan and Gordon1996) famously examined the history of lighting to show that previous studies on the evolution of living costs had vastly underestimated the decline in the cost of many goods. For example, in a recent paper Kelly and Ó Gráda (Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2016) showed that, during the eighteenth century, the real price of watches fell by an average of 1.3% a year, equivalent to a fall of 75% over a century (Kelly & Ó Gráda Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2016). Peter King's study on a small number of English paupers’ inventories shows that, in 1700, they rarely possessed clocks, books, candlesticks, lanterns, fire jacks, or fenders. A century later, paupers were materially better provided for than the middle class of a century earlier (King Reference King, Hitchcock, King and Sharpe1997). Just as in the case of the colonial goods referred to above, the impact of these new products on people's welfare is probably underestimated. Dittmar (Reference Dittmar2011) found that the welfare impact of the printed book was equivalent to 3%–7% of income by the 1630s (again exceeding similarly measured welfare effects associated with the Internet or mobile phones).

Including luxury goods thus increases the estimate of growth in living standards in eighteenth-century England (Clark Reference Clark2007, p. 255). It also increases the gap between England and the rest of the world. For example, in 1800, the average English individual consumed 10 times as much sugar as the average French individual and 20 times as much as individuals living elsewhere in Europe (De Vries Reference de Vries1994; Hersh & Voth Reference Hersh and Voth2009). In a recent paper, Lindert (Reference Lindert2016) argued that because of a range of biases in previous estimates, including the difficulty of including luxury goods, the difference between England and the rest of the world was even bigger. His new estimates suggest that purchasing power per capita in England was already higher than in Italy by the beginning of the sixteenth century. At the onset of the Industrial Revolution (in 1775), it was 75% higher than in Italy and 100% higher than in France (in 1820, the earliest year for the England/France comparison). Differences with respect to non-European economies were even larger: In 1750, purchasing power per capita in England was 300% that of Japan; in 1595, it was 280% that of India (the only year for which data are available before the Industrial Revolution); and in 1840 (the earliest year for the England/China comparison), it was 280% that of China. Book consumption confirms this pattern: In 1750, Chinese, Japanese, and Indian book consumption was one-tenth to one one-hundredth of British consumption (Buringh & Van Zanden Reference Buringh and Van Zanden2009; Xu Reference Xu2017).

Finally, recent work by Humphries and Weisdorf (Reference Humphries and Weisdorf2016) suggests that the rise in English wages has been underestimated because of the use of daily wages instead of annual wages. Using income series of workers employed on annual rather than daily contracts shows that incomes rose continuously from 1650, that is, a century before the onset of the Industrial Revolution.

4.2. GDP per capita

In an influential study, Stephen Broadberry and colleagues reconstructed the British economy over the past 800 years. Their work suggests that England experienced a continuous period of growth from the thirteenth century ($711 per capita in 1280) to the eighteenth ($2,097 in 1800). This continuous growth contrasts with the absolute decline of other affluent societies of the time such as China (from $1,032 in 1400 to $597 in 1800) and Italy ($1,477 in 1500 to $1,243 in 1800). More important, English GDP per capita in 1800 was higher than those of all European countries (with the exception of The Netherlands) and much higher than those of non-European countries such as China ($723), Japan ($640), and India ($573) (see Fig. 5). Although Pomeranz (Reference Pomeranz2009) famously argued that there is little sense in comparing China as a whole with England, a small part of Europe, recent studies show that even the wealthiest parts of China, such as the Yangtze Delta, were much poorer than England at the time of the Industrial Revolution ($988 in 1840 vs. $2,718 for Britain in 1850; Li & Luiten van Zanden Reference Li and Luiten van Zanden2012). Reconstructions of ancient economies also suggest that English GDP at the time was higher than that of Roman Italy at its peak (estimates range from $820 to $1,400), Abbasid Iraq ($940), Song China ($1,006 in 1020 under the Songs), or medieval Italy ($1,596) (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Guan and Li2018; Cascio & Malanima Reference Cascio and Malanima2009; Malanima Reference Malanima2011; Pamuk & Shatzmiller Reference Pamuk and Shatzmiller2014; Scheidel & Friesen Reference Scheidel and Friesen2009).

Figure 5. GDP per capita in 1990 international dollars. Adapted from Broadberry (Reference Broadberry, Guan and Li2018) for China, Japan, Italy, Great Britain and the Low countries, from Pfister (Reference Pfister2011) for Germany, and from Ridolfi (Reference Ridolfi2017) for France.

4.3. Urbanization rate

The rate of urbanization is also a good indicator of economic development (Jedwab & Vollrath Reference Jedwab and Vollrath2015). Using Bairoch's database with a threshold of 10,000 inhabitants, Bosker et al. (Reference Bosker, Buringh and van Zanden2013) showed that England was urbanizing at a high rate in the early modern period, going from 2.1% of its population living in urban settlements in 1500 to 23.14% in 1800. Similarly, Scotland went from 3.6% in 1500 to 17.3% in 1800 (see Fig. 6). In the same period, the urbanization of China or Italy was rather stagnant (Xu et al. Reference Xu, van Leeuwen and van Zanden2015). More important, the urbanization rate of England in 1800 (23%) was much higher than in all other societies in 1800, with 4% in China (but 15% in the Yangtze Delta), 9% in France, 13% in Japan, and 17% in Italy and Iraq (Bassino et al. Reference Bassino, Broadberry, Fukao, Gupta and Takashima2015; Bosker et al. Reference Bosker, Buringh and van Zanden2013; Xu et al. Reference Xu, van Leeuwen and van Zanden2015). From a historical perspective, few societies had ever been as urban as England was at the beginning of the Industrial Revolution. Although the rate of urbanization in ancient Greece and Rome was extremely high for ancient societies, it is estimated that it was about 16% in Classical Greece and 20% in Roman Italy (the latter mostly because of the size of Rome; Bowman & Wilson Reference Bowman and Wilson2011; Ober Reference Ober2015).

4.4. Health

Biological indicators also suggest that England enjoyed steady growth in living standards before the Industrial Revolution. A range of approaches, using the genealogy of the British royal family (David et al. Reference David, Johansson and Pozzi2010), the genealogy of European nobility (121,524 individuals between 800 and 1800; Cummins Reference Cummins2017), the Index Bio-Bibliographicus Notorum Hominum (300,000 individuals before 1879; De la Croix & Licandro Reference de la Croix and Licandro2015), and Wikipedia (Gergaud et al. Reference Gergaud, Laouenan and Wasmer2017) point toward the same result: Life expectancy was on the rise in Europe from 1650 onward. More important, life expectancy in northwestern Europe was higher than in the rest of Europe from 1000 AD onward, and it continued to rise at a higher rate than in the rest of Europe from 1450 onward (Cummins Reference Cummins2017). As a result, life expectancy on the eve of the Industrial Revolution was 42.1 years in England and Wales, compared with 24.8 years in France, for example (Wrigley Reference Wrigley1997). In line with these data, Kelly and Ó Gráda (Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2014) show that although the positive check – in the sense of the short response of mortality to price and real wage shocks – was powerful in the Middle Ages, it had weakened considerably in England by 1650, unlike in France. Similarly, the last widespread, killing famine occurred in 1597 in southern England and in northern England in 1623. By contrast, the last famine occurred much later in the rest of Europe: in 1710 in France, in 1770 in Germany, Scandinavia, in 1770–1772 in Switzerland and in 1866–1868 in Finland (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a). Even bigger contrasts can be observed when comparing England with Asian countries (Clark Reference Clark2007).

Other biological indicators, such as nutrition and height, confirm this difference. In a recent study, Kelly and Ó Gráda (Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2013) estimated that the English in 1750 consumed an average of 2,900 kcal per day, whereas the French consumed only 1,700 to 2,000 (Fogel Reference Fogel1964; Kelly & Ó Gráda Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2013). The effects of better nutrition are most obviously noticeable in the differences in the height of adult males. For cohorts born between 1780 and 1815, comparisons suggest that the gap between French and English heights on the eve of the Industrial Revolution was more than 5 cm (Nicholas & Steckel Reference Nicholas and Steckel1991; Weir Reference Weir, Steckel and Floud1997).

4.5. The impact of affluence on upper tail human capital

So far, I have discussed the living standards of the average individual in England, but a growing literature has been documenting the role of an elite of skilled artisans and merchants – the “upper tail of human capital” – in driving technological progress and economic development (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016; Squicciarini & Voigtländer Reference Squicciarini and Voigtländer2015). In seventeenth- and eighteenth-century England, for example, merchants, lawyers, and capitalists were overrepresented among innovators. They made up 4.6% of the population but accounted for 32.8% of inventors (Allen Reference Allen2009b). This suggests that what matters for economic development is the emergence of a dynamic urban upper middle class.

Of course, skilled elites had existed for a long time before the Industrial Revolution, in Athens, Rome, and Florence. So, what set eighteenth-century England apart from previous societies? The data reviewed below suggest that eighteenth-century English society was simply more affluent than any of those previous societies. This greater affluence had two consequences. First, it increased the absolute number of individuals displaying a slower strategy and, thus, the pool of potential innovators. In other words, the upper tail of human capital was bigger, and it ran further than in previous societies. Not only were the English elites richer, but also all social classes were comparatively more affluent than in any previous society (see Milanovic et al. Reference Milanovic, Lindert and Williamson2011 on pre-industrial inequality). As we have seen, bad harvests ceased to increase mortality rates, first for the elite and then for everyone; life expectancy increased, again first in the elite but soon in the middle class as well; and data on literacy suggest that lower-class English individuals were actually more educated than upper-class Romans (see sect. 4.2).

The second consequence of this English affluence is that the proportion of people displaying a slower strategy was also higher. This means that the levels of social trust, tolerance, and optimism expressed by the average English citizen were higher than elsewhere. This is likely to have had consequences at the global level in terms of interpersonal violence, governance, and even public health, for the simple reason that better-fed people invest more in their immune system and are less likely to transmit pathogens, including to the upper classes (for a discussion about the consequences of poverty on the psychology of the upper class, see Wilkinson & Pickett Reference Wilkinson and Pickett2010; Nettle Reference Nettle2017). Even the circulation of information is likely to be affected, because anxious people tend to focus on, believe, remember, and spread negative information to a greater extent (Fessler et al. Reference Fessler, Pisor and Navarrete2014; Rudaizky et al. Reference Rudaizky, Basanovic and MacLeod2014). This means that, with the same absolute level of material resources, upper-class English individuals in the eighteenth century lived in a better social, political, and biological environment than their fifteenth-century Florentine or first-century Roman counterparts, just because the individuals around them were better fed, healthier, better educated, less violent, and more tolerant.

5. Life History Strategy of the eighteenth-century English

As we saw in section 1, LHT suggests that the environment triggers a set of coordinated behaviors, a global life history strategy. In a recent article, Pepper and Nettle (Reference Pepper and Nettle2017) coined the term “behavioral constellation of deprivation” to refer to the set of behaviors associated with poverty (e.g., early reproduction, low investment in health, present orientation). In the same way, people living in affluent environments should display a “behavioral constellation of affluence”: late reproduction, higher investment in health and cognitive skills, higher levels of trust and cooperation, and a more future-oriented attitude. This last section will examine whether the eighteenth-century English indeed displayed this “behavioral constellation of affluence.”

Obviously, direct measurement of individual behaviors and preferences in the eighteenth century is impossible (at least given current technology, scientists are starting to measure stress through cortisol analysis in archaeological hairs; see, e.g., Webb et al. Reference Webb, Thomson, Nelson, White, Koren, Rieder and Van Uum2010). But a range of indirect evidence is available concerning violence, self-discipline, and long-term investment in human capital. In fact, Norbert Elias had already shown in The Civilizing Process (1982) that from the late Middle Ages on, Europeans, and in particular northwestern Europeans, displayed lower levels of violence, decreasing impulsivity, higher literacy levels, and greater sensitivity to the psychological states of others – in short, a slower life strategy.

5.1. Reproduction and fertility rates

Although the demographic transition has been thought to have occurred quite late in England (at the end of the nineteenth century), long after the Industrial Revolution (Wrigley & Schofield Reference Wrigley and Schofield1983), new studies show that, starting with the generation that married in the 1780s, there was a significant decline in net fertility among the middle and upper classes in England (Clark & Cummins Reference Clark and Cummins2015). Although rich men tended to have more children than poor men before 1780, at this point, they switched from a net fertility of more than four children to one of three or fewer, no different than the general population. This large change in behavior had been hidden in aggregate English data, because at the same time the net fertility of poorer groups (the majority of the population) increased to equal that of the rich. This rapid transition from a fast reproductive strategy to a slow reproductive strategy seems to have started as early as 1780, in parallel to the Industrial Revolution. Crucially, and in line with LHT, it does not seem to have been driven by economic factors such as an increase in returns on investment in education or in children's wages (Clark & Cummins Reference Clark and Cummins2015), but rather by changes in attitudes in the wealthiest part of English society.

5.2. Somatic investment and human capital

LHT holds that individuals living in an affluent environment should invest more in their soma, that is, in both their body and their skills (see sect. 2.2.1). I already noted in section 4 that the English were taller than their European counterparts, a clear cue that they indeed invested more in their soma (on muscular strength; see Kelly et al. Reference Kelly, Mokyr and Ó Gráda2014). Regarding investment in cognitive skills, English literacy clearly increased greatly between 1500 and 1750, as England shifted from a society of illiterates to one where half of all individuals could at least sign their names (Stephens Reference Stephens1990). Although England was behind The Netherlands and Scandinavia, it was clearly ahead of other continental countries on the eve of the Industrial Revolution. For example, although only 39% of men and 19% of women were literate in France in 1750, the figures in England were 61% of men and 37% of women (Henry & Houdaille Reference Henry and Houdaille1979; Schofield Reference Schofield1973).

The study of numeracy through age heaping shows similar patterns: English numeracy increased from 1500 onward, and it was higher in 1750 than in most European countries, with the exception of Germany and Scandinavia (A'Hearn et al. Reference A'Hearn, Baten and Crayen2009) (age heaping is the tendency of innumerate people to round their age to the nearest 5 or 10 and is a convenient sign of numeracy in historical documents). Indirect evidence suggests that levels of numeracy in England were also much higher than in India, China, or Japan (Baten et al. Reference Baten, Ma, Morgan and Wang2010; Clark Reference Clark2007), as well as in ancient Rome (Clark Reference Clark2007). For example, the study of age heaping in English, Italian, and Roman censuses reveals that the poor in England around 1800 had more age awareness than officeholders in the Roman Empire (Clark Reference Clark2007). Another indicator of literacy and investment in human capital is the consumption of books, again much higher in England than in other European countries (Baten & Van Zanden Reference Baten and Van Zanden2008; Buringh & Van Zanden Reference Buringh and Van Zanden2009).

What is striking about this high level of investment in human capital is that it cannot be explained by direct incentives. As Clark (Reference Clark2007) notes: “We find absolutely no evidence as we approach 1800 of any market signal to parents that they need to invest more in the education or training of their children” (p. 225). The skill premium in the earnings of building craftsmen relative to unskilled building laborers and assistants was actually lower in eighteenth-century England than in fourteenth-century England, and it was lower than in other European and non-European countries (Van Zanden Reference van Zanden2009). Clark concludes: “If there was ever an incentive to accumulate skills it was in the early economy” (Clark Reference Clark2007, p. 181).

5.3. Prosociality and violence

From a life-history perspective, as the environment improves, individuals should invest increasingly in cooperation (see sect. 2.3.5). The behavior of the English in the eighteenth century seems to have fit this prediction. Data on homicide rates show that the worldwide decline in violence started in England. In the sixteenth century, the homicide rate in England was about 7 per 100,000 inhabitants, versus 25 in the Netherlands, 21 in Scandinavia, 11 in Germany, and 45 in Italy. On the eve of the Industrial Revolution, although the gap had decreased, England was still ahead of the rest of Europe, and indeed the world (Eisner Reference Eisner2003; Pinker Reference Pinker2011a).

Although it must be tempting to think that this decline of violence resulted from the development of the police force and the penal system, evidence shows that they are uncorrelated (Eisner Reference Eisner2003; Pinker Reference Pinker2011a). One reason is that official authorities long treated homicide leniently, as the result of passion or a defense of honor (Eisner Reference Eisner2003). Another relevant fact is that the decline of violence occurred in the same way both in the absolutist regime of Tudor England and in the decentralized Dutch Republic. Similarly, although the police forces in medieval and early modern Italy were particularly large compared with those in England, Sweden, and The Netherlands, levels of violence remained very high in Italy until the end of the nineteenth century (Eisner Reference Eisner2003).

Therefore, people did not stop killing each other for fear of an increasing level of punishment. They rather stopped killing each other because their reaction to offenses and insults became less violent (Eisner Reference Eisner2001), that is, because their psychology became more and more cooperation-oriented. In line with this idea, attitudes toward capital punishment, slavery, judicial torture, and dueling also changed at the same time in Europe. Slavery is a case in point here; it has been shown that slavery was not abolished in response to economic (selfish) incentives, but rather as a result of intense public campaigns based on moral and emotional arguments (see Wedgewood's famous “Am I not a man and a brother?” plate; Carey Reference Carey2005; Davis Reference Davis1999). It is noteworthy that on all of these moral issues, England led the trends throughout the eighteenth century (Eisner Reference Eisner2003; McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a; Pinker Reference Pinker2011a). More generally, eighteenth-century Europe was clearly ahead of non-European societies as well as ancient societies such as Athens and Rome, which tolerated or even celebrated much higher levels of violence (Pinker Reference Pinker2011a).

Other indicators, such as the flourishing of societies and associations (Clark Reference Clark2000; Sunderland Reference Sunderland2007), suggest that the English were more prosocial and more trusting than other populations in the eighteenth century. Thus, in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, England was the first state to implement a system of poor relief. By the end of the seventeenth century, Poor Law expenditure was about 1% of GDP, and it was sufficient to provide complete subsistence for 5% of the population. By the end of the eighteenth century, it further increased to about 2% of GDP (Kelly & Ó Gráda Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2014). Kelly and Ó Gráda (Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2014) argue that the system was effectively able to minimize outright starvation. In line with this idea, the link between harvest failure and crisis mortality progressively vanished after the midseventeenth century. Other European countries took much longer to implement such a large-scale system of poor relief.

5.4. Preferences involved in innovativeness

So far, we have explored the standard predictions of LHT. But LHT also predicts that the eighteenth-century English should also have been more patient and optimistic, and less materialistic. These behaviors are obviously harder to observe and quantify than reproduction and somatic investment. But does the evidence point in the right direction?

5.4.1. Time discounting

Measuring self-discipline is difficult, but literacy could be seen as an indirect indicator. As Eisner (Reference Eisner2014) notes, “reading and writing are in themselves training sessions in self-control. They require mastery over abilities such as sitting still, fine-motor control of hand movements, self-directed information processing, and training of mnemonic and thinking skills – all of which are core components of self-control” (p. 43). From this perspective, the very high level of literacy in early modern England suggests high levels of self-discipline.

5.4.2. Optimism

Cultural historians have long noted that the early modern English people became unexpectedly optimistic. In his famous study on the decline of magic, Keith Thomas noted that:

In many different spheres of life the period saw the emergence of a new faith in the potentialities of human initiative. … The change was less a matter of positive technical progress than of an expectation of greater progress in the future. … It marked a break with the characteristic medieval attitude of contemplative resignation. (Thomas Reference Thomas1971)

What was striking, noted Thomas, is that this optimism in the power of technical progress could not be based on actual evidence. “It is often said that witch beliefs are a consequence of inadequate medical technique. But in England such beliefs declined before medical therapy had made much of an advance” (Thomas Reference Thomas1971, p. 1221). In the same way, the popularity of the work of Francis Bacon in the seventeenth century, that is, before the great wave of technical progress, attests that the English were very receptive toward optimistic ideas (Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016). As Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2016) notes, they no longer subscribed any more to “the Ecclesiastes view of history,” which holds that long-term change is impossible, because “there is nothing new under the sun” (p. 19). (See also Wootton [Reference Wootton2015] on the contrast with late Renaissance scholars.) Although words such as “innovation” and “novelty” often used to have negative connotations, these same words started to look more positive, and the emotional attachment to traditional ways of doing things progressively decreased (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a, p. 94). And again, the phenomenon seems to have been exacerbated in England. For example, Voltaire, in his Letter on the English, reports that science is much more popular in England than on the Continent. “The message of Voltaire's book was that England had a distinctive scientific culture: what was true of an educated Englishman in 1733 would not be true of a Frenchman, an Italian, a German or even a Dutchman” (Wootton Reference Wootton2015, p. 35). The national funerals of Newton attest that science and the pursuit of novel knowledge had achieved a very high status in eighteenth-century England.

5.4.3. Materialism and conscientiousness

More indirect and qualitative evidence of a change in reward orientation can be found in the historical literature. For example, the popular success of etiquette books such as Erasmus's De civilitate morum puerilium, studied by Elias (Reference Elias1982), suggests a growing interest in self-discipline. Similarly, the spread of Puritan movements in England and northwestern Europe shows that a substantial part of the population in these areas favored higher levels of discipline with regard to alcohol, sex, and violence. The first large-scale campaigns aimed at reducing excessive alcohol consumption were launched during the same period (Eisner Reference Eisner2014), and some evidence suggests that alcohol consumption did in fact decrease in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries (Martin Reference Martin2009). Finally, the views of the English on work changed during the early modern period. Work started to be valued for itself (i.e., for its intrinsic value), and not for what it produced (i.e., extrinsic value) (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a). Concomitantly, economic historians observed an increase in working days over the year (Humphries & Weisdorf Reference Humphries and Weisdorf2016; Voth Reference Voth2000) and a reduction in people's leisure time, a phenomenon that economic historian Jan de Vries famously called the “industrious revolution” (De Vries Reference de Vries2008). It is usually assumed that this increase in the length of the working year resulted from a desire to buy more goods, but it could also be the product of increased motivation to work and self-discipline, in line with the concomitant rise of investment in education and health.

6. Discussion

6.1. The bourgeois values, the industrial enlightenment, and Protestant ethics

The LHT approach presented here converges with a number of recent studies emphasizing the importance of noneconomic mechanisms in economic history (Clark Reference Clark2007; McCloskey Reference McCloskey2006; Reference McCloskey2010; Reference McCloskey2016a; Mokyr Reference Mokyr2009b; Reference Mokyr2016), as well as older work, such as Weber's influential thesis that Protestant ethics favored the emergence of capitalism. The approach taken in this article was in fact very much inspired by these works. For example, as demonstrated in section 5, on the behavioral constellation of affluence, there is a strong convergence between LHT and the theory of the “bourgeois virtues” defended by Deirdre McCloskey (Reference McCloskey2006). The “virtues” McCloskey describes – temperance, honesty, integrity, trustworthiness, hope, and love – are part of the “slow strategy,” or “behavioral constellation of affluence,” predicted by LHT. Individuals born into affluence are more apt to trust (Petersen & Aarøe Reference Petersen and Aarøe2015), less likely to take revenge (McCullough et al. Reference McCullough, Pedersen, Schroder, Tabak and Carver2013), have a larger social circle (Nettle et al. Reference Nettle, Colléony and Cockerill2011), are less materialistic (Carver et al. Reference Carver, Johnson, McCullough, Forster and Joormann2014), have more self-control (Duckworth et al. Reference Duckworth, Kim and Tsukayama2013), are less sexually promiscuous (Schmitt Reference Schmitt2008), form longer-lasting bonds (Simpson et al. Reference Simpson, Collins and Salvatore2011), and so on. In other words, they are bourgeois in McCloskey's sense.

In her work, McCloskey credits a set of key events in European history (the four “R's”: Reformation, Revolt, Revolution, and Reading) as the ultimate source of the emergence of the bourgeois virtues. But the reason for this series of events remains elusive. Why did northwestern Europe in particular experience such a lucky alignment of the stars? What made reading, religious reformation, and political revolution so appealing to northwestern Europeans? Why at this time and not before? Why there and not somewhere else before? LHT suggests that what made tolerance, democracy, education, and free trade so much more successful than in the earlier modern periods could be that in eighteenth-century Britain, hundreds of thousands of people were ready for such ideas. They were future-oriented enough, cooperative enough, and trusting enough to find these ideas cognitively appealing, just as two millennia earlier, the increasing living standards of the Greeks and the Romans led people to embrace new ethical ideals based on temperance, patience, sexual restraint, and cosmopolitanism (Baumard & Chevallier Reference Baumard and Chevallier2015; Baumard et al. Reference Baumard, Hyafil, Morris and Boyer2015). Thus, LHT could provide a missing link in the Bourgeois Virtues theory: It may explain why this particular set of values (“slow” behaviors) became popular at this particular time (early modern period) and at this particular place (northwestern Europe) in history (see Fig. 7).

Figure 7. The Bourgeois Revaluation and the Republic of Letters in an LHT perspective. As indicated in the figure, increasing political liberalism and scientific advances may also have contributed to the acceleration of growth (see Acemoglu & Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016a; Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016).

Similarly, the “behavioral constellation of affluence” could contribute to an explanation for the cultural evolution described by Mokyr in early modern England, and more generally in Western Europe (see Fig. 6). In A Culture of Growth, Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2016) suggests that the European “République des lettres” formed a marketplace where ideas were in competition with each other. It is certainly true that the Europe of this time was unique in its pluralism and that this competition between ideas helped the best scientific ideas to triumph eventually. But why were so many people willing to participate in the Republic of Letters in the eighteenth century and not earlier? It is striking that, in the period when Bacon was writing (early seventeenth century), there was not yet any evidence that science and technology could make the world a better place. The scientific revolution had just begun, and it would take another century for the Industrial Revolution to take off (in 1704, one of Jonathan Swift's “Ancients” remarks devastatingly that “if one may judge of the great genius or inventions of the Moderns by what they have produced, you will hardly have countenance to bear you out” (Swift Reference Swift1704/2018, pp. 185–86, cited in Mokyr Reference Mokyr2016).

Why were Europeans persuaded by optimistic, but still unproven, ideas? Why was the Baconian program so appealing, and why was it so appealing in England in the eighteenth century? The current success of antivaccine beliefs, climate change skepticism, and conspiracy theories suggests that open competition does not guarantee the triumph of truth. Cognitive approaches to cultural evolution have shown that cultural evolution is constrained by the architecture of the mind (Boyer Reference Boyer2001; Sperber Reference Sperber1996). For example, people tend to pay more attention to rumors or legends containing information about threats (Blaine & Boyer Reference Blaine and Boyer2018; Fessler et al. Reference Fessler, Pisor and Navarrete2014). There is nothing inherently appealing in Bacon's optimism: Pessimism could very well have triumphed, as it did everywhere else in earlier periods (see, e.g., Wootton Reference Wootton2015 on the pessimism of medieval scholars).

From this cognitive perspective, the popular success of the Republic of Letters across Europe may be partly the result of increasing optimism in the European population, and in the English population in particular (see Fig. 7). LHT contributes to explaining the success of cultural entrepreneurs such as Bacon and the very existence of a “marketplace for ideas” in early modern Europe. To summarize, the psychological shift toward innovation, optimism, and non-conformism produced by improving living standards likely rendered the Republic of Letters, and Enlightenment ideas, more cognitively attractive. In other words, when Bacon published his work advocating for more experimental research, European elites were ready for such a change.

LHT is also compatible with Weber's famous observation that the ethics of Puritanism favored the emergence of modern capitalism. As we saw in section 5, there is indeed a very visible association between economic growth and a certain form of religion, advocating self-discipline, hard work, trust in others, and long-term investment in education, and it is very tempting to infer from this association that Protestantism contributed to the economic dynamism of the Protestant countries. But LHT suggests that the relationship between religion and economic growth is probably the opposite of Weber's proposition. From an LHT perspective, Protestantism should be a consequence of economic growth, rather than its cause. On this account, it is because living standards and human development were increasing in Britain, Germany, or Scandinavia in the sixteenth century that Protestant ideas became popular in these countries. Protestant leaders’ insistence on self-discipline and education resonated with people's growing preference for future-oriented behaviors. In the same way, the economic boom in Western Europe during the central Middle Ages (1000–1300) had an impact on the preferences of the urban upper middle class and led to the emergence of ascetic movements advocating for greater self-discipline and charity, both within the Church (e.g., Franciscans, Dominicans) and outside it (Beguins, Waldesians, Cathars; Little Reference Little1983).

Finally, there is a clear convergence between the LHT approach and Gregory Clark's approach in A Farewell to Alms (Clark Reference Clark2007), in the sense that both approaches argue that there was a transformation of individual preferences before the onset of the Industrial Revolution (see, in particular, chapter 9, “The Emergence of Modern Man,” in Clark Reference Clark2007). In addition, the LHT approach advocated here and Clark's selectionist theory both rely on the tools of evolutionary biology (see also Galor & Moav Reference Galor and Moav2002 for a selectionist approach to economic growth). However, the mechanisms put forward by the two theories are rather different: For the selectionist approach, modern preferences were genetically selected in Europe during the medieval and modern periods, whereas in the life history approach, modern preferences are the product of universal mechanisms that modulate individual behaviors in response to environmental changes. The two theories make different predictions because the two mechanisms (natural selection and adaptive plasticity) do not work at the same time scale: Favorable alleles need several centuries (several dozen generations) to invade a human population while adaptive plasticity mechanisms allow behaviors to change within a single generation (sometimes in a very short time span). The selectionist approach thus predicts that it will take some time for non-English and non-European populations to exhibit modern behaviors. By contrast, Life History Theory predicts that the “culture of innovation” will spread very quickly. As soon as a society reaches a certain level of affluence, individuals should exhibit the same level of innovative behaviors as the English did, which is what happened very quickly in continental Europe (France, Germany, Scandinavia), the United States, and Japan.

6.2. Endogenous growth theories and long-run development

The approach taken here is agnostic on why England was the wealthiest society in the eighteenth century. It is certainly the case that England benefited from the heavy plow revolution (Andersen et al. Reference Andersen, Jensen and Skovsgaard2016), specialization in new draperies (Allen Reference Allen2009b), and the explosion of Atlantic trade (Acemoglu et al. Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005), to name but a few contingent and temporary advantages. But if England had not existed, the same acceleration of innovation would probably have occurred anyway, albeit probably a bit later. Living standards were already improving in other countries, such as France, Germany, and the United States. The most productive areas of the Western hemisphere would probably have sooner or later achieved eighteenth-century-English living standards and experienced a similar acceleration of innovation. A similar observation can be made for China and Japan: Many indicators (literacy, urbanization, etc.) suggest improving standards of living in these countries on the eve of the Industrial Revolution (Clark Reference Clark2007). If Europe had not existed, the gradual rise in living standards as a result of technological progress would eventually have triggered an industrial revolution, probably first in Japan and then in Korea or in China (Baten & Sohn Reference Baten and Sohn2013).

In this perspective, the LHT approach is very much in agreement with endogenous growth theories, and in particular with unified growth theory (Galor Reference Galor2011), in which growth and technological progress are endogenous and do not require any external input (political revolution, technological breakthroughs, etc.). LHT provides a plausible mechanism by which economic prosperity can be self-sustaining: Technological progress leads to higher standards of living, which lead to more future-oriented preferences, in turn increasing technological progress, and so on. However, in contrast with unified growth theory, here the main mechanism is not rising demand for human capital triggered by rising technological levels, but simply rising levels of human, physical, and social capital allowing individuals to increase their investments in technological progress.

Capital is thus central in LHT. A certain level of human, social, and technological capital is indeed required to develop the kind of preferences that are conducive to learning and mastering the new innovation. This idea fits well with the growing body of work on the long-run determinants of wealth: Because capital accumulates over time, the early starters in economic development still enjoy some advantages today, and despite institutional reforms and technological transfers, most developing countries still have a hard time catching up with the most advanced countries (Abramson & Boix Reference Abramson and Boix2014; Chanda & Putterman Reference Chanda and Putterman2007; Comin et al. Reference Comin, Easterly and Gong2010; Diamond Reference Diamond2011; Olsson & Hibbs Reference Olsson and Hibbs2005). From this long-term perspective, there is actually nothing special about the Industrial Revolution. The rate of innovation has been increasing exponentially since the Neolithic, and the Industrial Revolution is just the moment at which the exponential nature of the acceleration became undeniable. What LHT brings to this literature is that this acceleration is partly a result of psychological changes in individual goals.

6.3. Testing the theory

6.3.1. Were English people really richer and slower?

One way to falsify the theory presented here would be to show that northwestern Europe, and England in particular, were not so wealthy or not so slow (see, e.g., Allen Reference Allen2017a; Stephenson Reference Stephenson2017 about whether English wages were lower or higher than in other countries). Also, I have taken for granted that English industrial success reflected the greater innovativeness of the English population. However, it could be that the English were no more innovative than other Europeans, but only better at tweaking and marketing existing inventions (thanks, e.g., to better institutions). Therefore, another way to falsify the theory would be to test whether English people were indeed more innovative, using, for example, large biographical databases such as Freebase and Wikipedia (Gergaud et al. Reference Gergaud, Laouenan and Wasmer2017; Serafinelli & Tabellini Reference Serafinelli and Tabellini2017), comparing the number of innovating individuals (scientists, artists, engineers, inventors) across European countries.

6.3.2. Is the association between affluence and innovation really causal?

Even if it is confirmed that England was indeed ahead both in terms of living standards and innovativeness, the historical evidence presented here remains correlational. Is it possible to test the causal role of affluence in shifting attitudes? To do so, we would need (1) an external shock on individual income and (2) some measures of psychological variables in the longue durée. Along with others, I have studied the effect of economic growth on individual psychology during the Middle Ages (Baumard et al. Reference Baumard, Huillery and Zabrocki2018). We used the introduction of the heavy plow as an instrument for economic growth to identify the causal impact of economic growth. Following Andersen et al. (Reference Andersen, Jensen and Skovsgaard2016), our instrument exploits two sources of variation: variation over time arising from the adoption of the heavy plow on the one hand, and cross-sectional variation arising from differences in regional suitability for adopting the heavy plow on the other hand. We focused on two behaviors – asceticism and romantic love – that can be quantified over the long term through relatively homogenous sources (the biographies of the saints for asceticism, and the topics of narrative fictions for romantic love). Our results show that economic growth measured through higher population density indeed caused an increase in behaviors associated with a slow life history (i.e., both more ascetic and more romantic behaviors). Future research should use similar instruments to test and quantify the impact of affluence during the early modern period.

6.3.3. Are there more parsimonious explanations of changes in attitudes?

One final way to falsify the theory would be to show that there is no need for psychological changes to explain increasing levels of innovativeness. In a purely rational choice approach or the critical revision of such approach (à la Kahneman and Tversky, for example), individuals are able to compute the risks of their investments, and are aware that these risks are greater when their resources are scarce or when their time horizon is short. Thus, in principle, a large part of the Industrial Revolution could be explained without resorting to LHT: English people were more innovative not because their preferences had changed, but simply because they had an unprecedented amount of resources. In this view, Wedgwood, for example, was able to improve ceramic mixtures and glazes only because, unlike his predecessors, he had the time and money to perform his famous 5,000 experiments.

How can we disentangle the LHT approach from the more standard rational choice approach? A life-history switch from a fast to a slow strategy makes a range of predictions not just about decision-making, but also about human psychology in general. For example, LHT predicts that the rate of innovation in England should have been higher in general, not only in industries where it was economically profitable, but also in the sciences and the arts, where the benefits were not so great. Changes in attitudes should also reflect in works of fiction. In Bourgeois Equality, McCloskey (Reference McCloskey2016a) notes that whereas ancient narratives such as the Odyssey and the Aeneid tend to focus on extrinsic rewards such as fame, money, and marriage (see sect. 3.3), early modern English novels such as Robinson Crusoe (1719) show an intrinsic interest in planning, deliberation, and technical details, that is, on the kind of information that individuals pursuing a long-term strategy would like.

LHT also predicts changes outside the economic domain – in love, for example. According to LHT, individuals growing up in affluent environments are more motivated by long-term pair-bonding and show stronger attachment to their spouses (Chisholm et al. Reference Chisholm, Quinlivan, Petersen and Coall2005; Del Giudice Reference Del Giudice2009; Quinlan Reference Quinlan2003; Simpson et al. Reference Simpson, Collins and Salvatore2011). Thus, LHT predicts that higher levels of innovativeness should be associated with greater romantic attachment, which is what is observed in the Roman period and the medieval period, as well as in the early modern period with an increase of romantic works (e.g., Tristan and Iseult) during periods of affluence (Baumard et al. Reference Baumard, Huillery and Zabrocki2018). Growing empathy toward others, even without economic motives or personal gains such as in the case of slavery, is also predicted by LHT, but much less so by rational choice theory. Our work confirms this prediction, showing that facial cues associated with trust increased over the period of 1500–1900 in English portraits and that this increase was best predicted by the rise of life expectancy and GDP per capita (Safra et al. Reference Safra, Grèzes, Chevallier and Baumard2019).

Finally, LHT predicts attitude changes much less fine-grained than those that would result from standard behavioral mechanisms attuned to day-to-day changes in circumstances. For example, LHT studies have reported that many variables, such as mating, time discounting, and trust, are partly calibrated during childhood or even in utero, and that later changes in the environment cannot offset these early calibrations. Overall, LHT predicts the emergence not just of new behaviors in response to new incentives, but of a whole new mentality.

6.4. Beyond the industrial revolution: Explaining cultural revolutions in history

This article focuses on the Industrial Revolution, but in principle, LHT provides a framework not just of the origins of the Industrial Revolution but also, potentially, of the entire “civilizing process.” From an evolutionary point of view, the “civilizing process” might indeed be the “constellation of affluence” expressed at a larger scale: With growing affluence, people's psychologies changed, which allowed for more innovation and higher economic growth, but also for higher levels of social trust, explaining the strong association between affluence and democracy (Boix & Stokes Reference Boix and Stokes2003; Inglehart & Welzel Reference Inglehart and Welzel2005; Przeworski et al. Reference Przeworski, Limongi, Giner and Bagchi1995). In his pioneering work The Silent Revolution (Reference Inglehart1977), Ronald Inglehart demonstrated how the cohorts born after World War II and raised during a period of fast economic growth were much less materialistic and much more tolerant than the previous generation, in line with the LHT framework. The same logic may be at play today, with the slow and yet massive transformation of modern societies in the direction of greater respect for human rights and greater inclusion of females as well as sexual and ethnic minorities (Fariss Reference Fariss2014; Norris & Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2011; Pinker Reference Pinker2018).

To conclude, Life History Theory has the potential to explain slow and silent changes in history: changes that occur without any apparent modification of the political, religious, or institutional environment. This tool also has the potential to explain how long-term material changes can have dramatic effects on human societies. With the help of Life History Theory, we are now in a position to better understand how living conditions can modify individual preferences and eventually change the course of history.

Acknowledgments

I thank Jean-Baptiste André, Pascal Boyer, Coralie Chevallier, Anton Howes, Deirdre N. McCloskey, Hugo Mercier, Joel Mokyr, Olivier Morin, Dan Sperber, and one anonymous reviewer for their thorough reading of the manuscript and their critical comments.

References

Abramson, S. & Boix, C. (2014) The roots of the industrial revolution: Political institutions or (socially embedded) know-how? Unpublished typescript, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J. (2005) The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic growth. The American Economic Review 95(3):546–79.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. & Robinson, J. (2012) Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown.Google Scholar
A'Hearn, B., Baten, J. & Crayen, D. (2009) Quantifying quantitative literacy: Age heaping and the history of human capital. The Journal of Economic History 69(3):783808.Google Scholar
Akee, R., Copeland, W., Costello, E. J. & Simeonova, E. (2018) How does household income affect child personality traits and behaviors? American Economic Review 108(3):775827.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2001) The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explorations in economic history 38(4):411–47.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009a) How prosperous were the Romans? Evidence from Diocletian's Price Edict (AD 301). In: Quantifying the Roman economy: Methods and problems, ed. Bowman, A. & Wilson, A., pp. 327–45. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009b) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2017a) Real wages once more: A response to Judy Stephenson. Working Paper 20170006, New York University Abu Dhabi, Department of Social Science, revised July 2017.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C., Bassino, J.-P., Ma, D., Moll-Murata, C. & Van Zanden, J. L. (2011) Wages, prices, and living standards in China, 1738–1925: In: Comparison with Europe, Japan, and India. The Economic History Review 64(s1):838.Google Scholar
Andersen, T. B., Jensen, P. S. & Skovsgaard, C. V. (2016) The heavy plow and the agricultural revolution in Medieval Europe. Journal of Development Economics 118:133–49.Google Scholar
Andrews, C., Nettle, D., Reichert, S., Bedford, T., Monaghan, P. & Bateson, M. (2018) A marker of biological ageing predicts adult risk preference in European starlings, Sturnus vulgaris. Behavioral Ecology 29(3):589–97.Google Scholar
Bassino, J.-P., Broadberry, S. N., Fukao, K., Gupta, B. & Takashima, M. (2015) Japan and the Great Divergence, 7251874. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP10569. Available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2602806.Google Scholar
Baten, J., Ma, D., Morgan, S. & Wang, Q. (2010) Evolution of living standards and human capital in China in the 18–20th centuries: Evidences from real wages, age-heaping, and anthropometrics. Explorations in Economic History 47(3):347–59.Google Scholar
Baten, J. & Sohn, K. (2013) Back to the “normal” level of human-capital driven growth? A note on early numeracy in Korea, China, and Japan, 15501800. University of Tuebingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance 52, University of Tuebingen, Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences.Google Scholar
Baten, J. & Van Zanden, J. L. (2008) Book production and the onset of modern economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 13(3):217–35.Google Scholar
Bateson, M., Brilot, B. O., Gillespie, R., Monaghan, P. & Nettle, D. (2015) Developmental telomere attrition predicts impulsive decision-making in adult starlings. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 282(1799):20142140.Google Scholar
Baumard, N., André, J.-B. & Sperber, D. (2013) A mutualistic approach to morality: The evolution of fairness by partner choice. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 36(1):5978.Google Scholar
Baumard, N. & Chevallier, C. (2015) The nature and dynamics of world religions: A life-history approach. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 282(1818).Google Scholar
Baumard, N., Huillery, E. & Zabrocki, L. (2018) The origins of love and asceticism: How economic prosperity changed human psychology in Medieval Europe. Working paper.Google Scholar
Baumard, N., Hyafil, A., Morris, I. & Boyer, P. (2015) Increased affluence explains the emergence of ascetic wisdoms and moralizing religions. Current Biology 25(1):1015.Google Scholar
Béaur, G. (2017) Niveau de vie et révolution des objets dans la France d'Ancien Régime. Meaux et ses campagnes aux XVIIe et XVIIIe siècles. Revue dhistoire moderne contemporaine 4(64–4):2558.Google Scholar
Belsky, J., Steinberg, L., Houts, R. M. & Halpern-Felsher, B. L. (2010) The development of reproductive strategy in females: Early maternal harshness → earlier menarche → increased sexual risk taking. Developmental Psychology 46(1):120.Google Scholar
Benenson, J. F., Pascoe, J. & Radmore, N. (2007) Children's altruistic behavior in the dictator game. Evolution and Human Behavior 28(3):168–75.Google Scholar
Blaine, T. & Boyer, P. (2018) Origins of sinister rumors: A preference for threat-related material in the supply and demand of information. Evolution and Human Behavior 39(1):6775. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2017.10.001.Google Scholar
Blair, C., Granger, D. A., Willoughby, M., Mills-Koonce, R., Cox, M., Greenberg, M. T., Kivlighan, K. T., Fortunato, C. K. & FLP Investigators. (2011) Salivary cortisol mediates effects of poverty and parenting on executive functions in early childhood. Child Development 82(6):1970–84.Google Scholar
Blair, C. & Raver, C. C. (2012) Child development in the context of adversity: Experiential canalization of brain and behavior. American Psychologist 67(4):309.Google Scholar
Bloom, N., Jones, C. I., Van Reenen, J. & Webb, M. (2017) Are ideas getting harder to find? National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 23782.Google Scholar
Boehm, J. K., Chen, Y., Williams, D. R., Ryff, C. & Kubzansky, L. D. (2015) Unequally distributed psychological assets: Are there social disparities in optimism, life satisfaction, and positive affect? PLoS One 10(2):e0118066.Google Scholar
Boix, C. & Stokes, S. C. (2003) Endogenous democratization. World Politics 55(4):517–49.Google Scholar
Bosker, M., Buringh, E. & van Zanden, J. L. (2013) From Baghdad to London: Unraveling urban development in Europe, the Middle East, and North Africa, 800–1800. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(4):1418–37.Google Scholar
Bowman, A. & Wilson, A., eds. (2011) Settlement, urbanization, and population. Oxford University Publication on Demand.Google Scholar
Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Boyer, P. (2001) Religion explained: The evolutionary origins of religious thought. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Briers, B., Pandelaere, M., Dewitte, S. & Warlop, L. (2006) Hungry for money: The desire for caloric resources increases the desire for financial resources and vice versa. Psychological Science 17(11):939–43.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. (2016) When and how did the great divergence begin. Presented at the Fifth Asian Historical Economics Conference, Seoul, South Korea, September 23, 2016Google Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. M. S., Klein, A., Overton, M. & van Leeuwen, B. (2015) British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. N., Guan, H. & Li, D. D. (2018) China, Europe and the Great Divergence: A study in historical national accounting, 980–1850. The Journal of Economic History 78(4):9551000.Google Scholar
Brumbach, B. H., Figueredo, A. J. & Ellis, B. J. (2009) Effects of harsh and unpredictable environments in adolescence on development of life history strategies. Human Nature 20(1):2551.Google Scholar
Buringh, E. & Van Zanden, J. L. (2009) Charting the “Rise of the West”: Manuscripts and printed books in Europe, a long-term perspective from the sixth through eighteenth centuries. The Journal of Economic History 69(2):409–45.Google Scholar
Carey, B. (2005) British abolitionism and the rhetoric of sensibility: Writing, sentiment and slavery, 1760–807. Springer.Google Scholar
Carver, C. S., Johnson, S. L., McCullough, M. E., Forster, D. E. & Joormann, J. (2014) Adulthood personality correlates of childhood adversity. Frontiers in Psychology 5:1357.Google Scholar
Cascio, E. L. & Malanima, P. (2009) GDP in pre-modern agrarian economies (1–1820 AD) A revision of the estimates. Rivista di storia economica 25(3):391.Google Scholar
Cecchi, F. & Duchoslav, J. (2018) The effect of prenatal stress on cooperation: Evidence from violent conflict in Uganda. European Economic Review 101:3556.Google Scholar
Chanda, A. & Putterman, L. (2007) Early starts, reversals and catch-up in the process of economic development. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109(2):387413.Google Scholar
Charnov, E. L. (1991) Evolution of life history variation among female mammals. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA 88(4):1134–37.Google Scholar
Chisholm, J. S., Quinlivan, J. A., Petersen, R. W. & Coall, D. A. (2005) Early stress predicts age at menarche and first birth, adult attachment, and expected lifespan. Human Nature 16(3):233–65. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-005-1009-0.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2007) A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, G. & Cummins, N. (2015) Malthus to modernity: Wealth, status, and fertility in England, 1500–1879. Journal of Population Economics 28(1):329.Google Scholar
Clark, P. (2000) British clubs and societies 1580–1800: The origins of an associational world. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, P. & Cohen, J. (1996) Life values and adolescent mental health. Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Comin, D., Easterly, W. & Gong, E. (2010) Was the wealth of nations determined in 1000 BC? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(3):6597.Google Scholar
Cronqvist, H., Previtero, A., Siegel, S. & White, R. E. (2015) The fetal origins hypothesis in finance: Prenatal environment, the gender gap, and investor behavior. The Review of Financial Studies 29(3):739–86.Google Scholar
Cummins, N. (2017) Lifespans of the European elite, 800–1800. The Journal of Economic History 77(2):406439.Google Scholar
Currie, J. & Vogl, T. (2013) Early-life health and adult circumstance in developing countries. Annual Review of Economics 5(1):136.Google Scholar
Curry, O. S., Price, M. E. & Price, J. G. (2008) Patience is a virtue: Cooperative people have lower discount rates. Personality and Individual Differences 44(3):780–85.Google Scholar
Dang, J., Xiao, S., Zhang, T., Liu, Y., Jiang, B. & Mao, L. (2016) When the poor excel: Poverty facilitates procedural learning. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology 57(4):288–91.Google Scholar
David, P. A., Johansson, S. R. & Pozzi, A. (2010) The demography of an early mortality transition: Life expectancy, survival and mortality rates for Britain's royals,1500–1799. Oxford Economic and Social History Working Papers, No. 083, University of Oxford, Department of Economics. Available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1641447.Google Scholar
Davis, D. B. (1999) The problem of slavery in the age of revolution, 1770–1823. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
de la Croix, D. & Licandro, O. (2015) The longevity of famous people from Hammurabi to Einstein. Journal of Economic Growth 20(3):263303.Google Scholar
de Pleijt, A. M. & Van Zanden, J. L. (2016) Accounting for the “Little Divergence”: What drove economic growth in pre-industrial Europe, 1300–1800? European Review of Economic History 20(4):387409.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (1994) The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution. The Journal of Economic History 54(02):249–70.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (2008) The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Del Giudice, M. (2009) Sex, attachment, and the development of reproductive strategies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 32(1):121.Google Scholar
Deng, K. & O'Brien, P. (2016) Nutritional standards of living in England and the Yangtze Delta (Jiangnan), circa 1644–circa 1840: Clarifying data for reciprocal comparisons. Journal of World History 26(2):233–67.Google Scholar
Diamond, J. M. (2011) Guns, germs, and steel. Books on Tape.Google Scholar
Dittmar, J. (2011) The welfare impact of a new good: The printed book. Department of Economics, American University.Google Scholar
Droomers, M., Schrijvers, C. T., Stronks, K., van de Mheen, D. & Mackenbach, J. P. (1999) Educational differences in excessive alcohol consumption: The role of psychosocial and material stressors. Preventive Medicine 29(1):110.Google Scholar
Duckworth, A. L., Kim, B. & Tsukayama, E. (2013) Life stress impairs self-control in early adolescence. Frontiers in Psychology 3:608.Google Scholar
Dutta, R., Levine, D. K., Papageorge, N. W. & Wu, L. (2018) Entertaining Malthus: Bread, circuses, and economic growth. Economic Inquiry 56(1):358–80.Google Scholar
Eisner, M. (2001) Modernization, self-control and lethal violence. The long-term dynamics of European homicide rates in theoretical perspective. British Journal of Criminology 41(4):618–38.Google Scholar
Eisner, M. (2003) Long-term historical trends in violent crime. Crime and Justice 30:83142.Google Scholar
Eisner, M. (2014) From swords to words: Does macro-level change in self-control predict long-term variation in levels of homicide? Crime and Justice 43(1):65134.Google Scholar
Elias, N. (1982) The civilizing process, vol. 2. Blackwell. Available at: http://library.mpib-berlin.mpg.de/toc/z2010_1372.pdf.Google Scholar
Ellis, B. (2004) Timing of pubertal maturation in girls: An integrated life history approach Psychological Bulletin 130(6):920Google Scholar
Ellis, B. J., Figueredo, A. J., Brumbach, B. H. & Schlomer, G. L. (2009) Fundamental dimensions of environmental risk: The impact of harsh versus unpredictable environments on the evolution and development of life history strategies. Human Nature 20:204–68.Google Scholar
Espín, A. M., Brañas-Garza, P., Herrmann, B. & Gamella, J. F. (2012) Patient and impatient punishers of free-riders. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 279(1749):4923–28.Google Scholar
Fariss, C. J. (2014) Respect for human rights has improved over time: Modeling the changing standard of accountability. American Political Science Review 108(2):297318.Google Scholar
Fessler, D. M., Pisor, A. C. & Navarrete, C. D. (2014) Negatively-biased credulity and the cultural evolution of beliefs. PLoS One 9(4):e95167.Google Scholar
Figueredo, A. J., Vásquez, G., Brumbach, B. H., Schneider, S. M., Sefcek, J. A., Tal, I. R., Hill, D., Wenner, C. J. & Jacobs, W. J. (2006) Consilience and life history theory: From genes to brain to reproductive strategy. Developmental Review 26(2):243–75.Google Scholar
Fogel, R. W. (1964) Railroads and American economic growth: Essays in econometric history. Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Forss, S. I. F., Schuppli, C., Haiden, D., Zweifel, N. & van Schaik, C. P. (2015) Contrasting responses to novelty by wild and captive orangutans. American Journal of Primatology 77(10):1109–21.Google Scholar
Frankenhuis, W. E. & de Weerth, C. (2013) Does early-life exposure to stress shape or impair cognition? Current Directions in Psychological Science 22(5):407–12.Google Scholar
Frankenhuis, W. E., Panchanathan, K. & Nettle, D. (2016) Cognition in harsh and unpredictable environments. Current Opinion in Psychology 7:7680.Google Scholar
Galor, O. (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galor, O. & Moav, O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4):1133–91.Google Scholar
Gangadharan, L., Islam, A., Ouch, C. & Wang, L. C. (2017) The long-term effects of genocide on social preferences and risk. Working paper. Available at: http://users.monash.edu/~asaduli/pub/Conflict_March2017.pdf/.Google Scholar
Gergaud, O., Laouenan, M. & Wasmer, E. (2017) A brief history of human time. Exploring a database of “notable people.” Working paper. Available at: https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01440325/.Google Scholar
Gordon, R. J. (2012) Is U.S. economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 18315. Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w18315.Google Scholar
Griskevicius, V., Ackerman, J. M., Cantú, S. M., Delton, A. W., Robertson, T. E., Simpson, J. A., Thompson, M. E. & Tybur, J. M. (2013) When the economy falters, do people spend or save? Responses to resource scarcity depend on childhood environments. Psychological Science 24(2):197205.Google Scholar
Guégan, J.-F., Thomas, F., Hochberg, M. E., de Meeûs, T. & Renaud, F. (2001) Disease diversity and human fertility. Evolution 55(7):1308–14.Google Scholar
Harris, A. C. & Madden, G. J. (2002) Delay discounting and performance on the prisoner's dilemma game. Psychological Record 52(4):429–40.Google Scholar
Haslam, M. (2013) “Captivity bias” in animal tool use and its implications for the evolution of hominin technology. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 368(1630):20120421.Google Scholar
Haushofer, J. (2013) The psychology of poverty: Evidence from 43 countries. Working paper. Available at: http://www.princeton.edu/joha/publications/Haushofer_2013.pdf.Google Scholar
Haushofer, J. & Fehr, E. (2014) On the psychology of poverty. Science 344(6186):862–67. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1232491.Google Scholar
Heinonen, K., Räikkönen, K., Matthews, K. A., Scheier, M. F., Raitakari, O. T., Pulkki, L. & Keltikangas-Järvinen, L. (2006) Socioeconomic status in childhood and adulthood: Associations with dispositional optimism and pessimism over a 21-year follow-up. Journal of Personality 74(4):1111–26.Google Scholar
Henry, L. & Houdaille, J. (1979) Célibat et âge au mariage aux XVIIIe et XIXe siècles en France. II. Âge au premier mariage. Population (French edition) 34(2):403–42.Google Scholar
Hersh, J. & Voth, H.-J. (2009) Sweet diversity: Colonial goods and the rise of European living standards after 1492. Working paper. Available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1462015.Google Scholar
Holland, J., Silva, A. S. & Mace, R. (2012) Lost letter measure of variation in altruistic behaviour in 20 neighbourhoods. PLoS One 7(8):e43294.Google Scholar
Hörl, M., Kesternich, I., Smith, J. P. & Winter, J. K. (2016) Early-life circumstances predict measures of trust among adults: Evidence from hunger episodes in post-war Germany. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics. Published early online. Available at: https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/pdf/10.1111/sjoe.12329.Google Scholar
Houston, A. I. & McNamara, J. M. (1999) Models of adaptive behaviour: An approach based on state. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Howes, A. (2016a) The improving mentality: Innovation during the British industrial revolution, 16511851. Working paper.Google Scholar
Howes, A. (2016b) The relevance of skills to innovation during the British Industrial Revolution, 1651–851. Working paper. Available at: http://www.eh.net/eha/wp-content/uploads/2016/08/Howes.pdf.Google Scholar
Humphries, J. & Weisdorf, J. (2016) Unreal wages? A new empirical foundation for the study of living standards and economic growth in England, 1260–1860. Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy (CAGE)Google Scholar
Inglehart, R. (1977) The silent revolution: Changing. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R. & Welzel, C. (2005) Modernization, cultural change, and democracy: The human development sequence. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jacquet, P. O., Safra, L., Wyart, V., Baumard, N. & Chevallier, C. (2019) The ecological roots of human susceptibility to social influence: A pre-registered study investigating the impact of early life adversity. Royal Society Open Science 6(1):180454. Available at: https://doi.org/10.5061/dryad.k48mr0c.Google Scholar
Jedwab, R. & Vollrath, D. (2015) Urbanization without growth in historical perspective. Explorations in Economic History 58:121.Google Scholar
Jones, B. F. (2009) The burden of knowledge and the “death of the renaissance man”: Is innovation getting harder? The Review of Economic Studies 76(1):283317.Google Scholar
Kasser, T., Ryan, R. M., Couchman, C. E. & Sheldon, K. M. (2004) Materialistic values: Their causes and consequences. In: Psychology and consumer culture: The struggle for a good life in a materialistic world, ed. Kasser, T. & Kanner, A. D., pp. 1128. American Psychological Association.Google Scholar
Kasser, T., Ryan, R. M., Zax, M. & Sameroff, A. J. (1995) The relations of maternal and social environments to late adolescents’ materialistic and prosocial values. Developmental Psychology 31(6):907.Google Scholar
Kelly, M. & Ó Gráda, C. (2013) Numerare est errare: Agricultural output and food supply in England before and during the industrial revolution. The Journal of Economic History 73(4):1132–63.Google Scholar
Kelly, M. & Ó Gráda, C. (2014) Living standards and mortality since the Middle Ages. The Economic History Review 67(2):358–81.Google Scholar
Kelly, M. & Ó Gráda, C. (2016) Adam Smith, watch prices, and the industrial revolution. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(4):1727–52.Google Scholar
Kelly, M., Mokyr, J. & Ó Gráda, C. (2014) Precocious Albion: A new interpretation of the British industrial revolution. Annual Review of Economics 6(1):363–89.Google Scholar
Kenrick, D. T., Griskevicius, V., Neuberg, S. L. & Schaller, M. (2010) Renovating the pyramid of needs: Contemporary extensions built upon ancient foundations. Perspectives on Psychological Science 5(3):292314.Google Scholar
Kesternich, I., Siflinger, B., Smith, J. P. & Winter, J. K. (2015) Individual behaviour as a pathway between early-life shocks and adult health: Evidence from hunger episodes in post-war Germany. The Economic Journal 125(588):F372F393.Google Scholar
Kiecolt, K. J., Hughes, M. & Keith, V. M. (2009) Can a high sense of control and John Henryism be bad for mental health? The Sociological Quarterly 50(4):693–14.Google Scholar
King, P. (1997) Pauper inventories and the material lives of the poor in the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries. In: Chronicling poverty, ed. Hitchcock, T., King, P. & Sharpe, P., pp. 155–91. Springer.Google Scholar
Kocher, M. G., Myrseth, K. O. R., Martinsson, P. & Wollbrant, C. E. (2013, March 28) Strong, bold, and kind: Self-control and cooperation in social dilemmas. ESMT Working Paper No. 12-01 (R1). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1988286 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1988286.Google Scholar
Kortenkamp, K. V. & Moore, C. F. (2006) Time, uncertainty, and individual differences in decisions to cooperate in resource dilemmas. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 32(5):603–15.Google Scholar
Laland, K. N. & Williams, K. (1998) Social transmission of maladaptive information in the guppy. Behavioral Ecology 9(5):493–99.Google Scholar
Lawrance, E. C. (1991) Poverty and the rate of time preference: Evidence from panel data. Journal of Political Economy 99(1):5477.Google Scholar
Legleye, S., Janssen, E., Beck, F., Chau, N. & Khlat, M. (2011) Social gradient in initiation and transition to daily use of tobacco and cannabis during adolescence: A retrospective cohort study. Addiction 106(8):1520–31.Google Scholar
Li, B. & Luiten van Zanden, J. (2012) Before the great divergence? Comparing the Yangzi Delta and The Netherlands at the beginning of the nineteenth century. The Journal of Economic History 72(4):956–89.Google Scholar
Lindert, P. H. (2016) Purchasing power disparity before 1914. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 22896. Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w22896.Google Scholar
Little, L. K. (1983) Religious poverty and the profit economy in medieval Europe. Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Lundberg, J., Bobak, M., Malyutina, S., Kristenson, M. & Pikhart, H. (2007) Adverse health effects of low levels of perceived control in Swedish and Russian community samples. BMC Public Health 7(1):314.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2007) The world economy: Vol. 1: A millennial perspective, Vol. 2: Historical statistics. Academic Foundation.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2011) The long decline of a leading economy: GDP in central and northern Italy, 1300–1913. European Review of Economic History 15(2):169219.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2013) When did England overtake Italy? Medieval and early modern divergence in prices and wages. European Review of Economic History 17(1):4570.Google Scholar
Mani, A., Mullainathan, S., Shafir, E. & Zhao, J. (2013) Poverty impedes cognitive function. Science 341(6149):976–80. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1238041.Google Scholar
Martin, A. L. (2009) Alcohol, violence, and disorder in traditional Europe, vol. 2. Truman State University Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (2006) The bourgeois virtues: Ethics for an age of commerce. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (2010) Bourgeois dignity: Why economics can't explain the modern world. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (2016a) Bourgeois equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (2016b) Bourgeois equality: Ideas, not capital, changed the world. Available at: http://reason.com/archives/2016/05/12/bourgeois-equality.Google Scholar
McCullough, M. E., Pedersen, E. J., Schroder, J. M., Tabak, B. A. & Carver, C. S. (2013) Harsh childhood environmental characteristics predict exploitation and retaliation in humans. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 280(1750):20122104.Google Scholar
Mell, H., Safra, L., Algan, Y., Baumard, N. & Chevallier, C. (2018) Childhood environmental harshness predicts coordinated health and reproductive strategies: A cross-sectional study of a nationally representative sample from France. Evolution and Human Behavior 39(1):18.Google Scholar
Mesoudi, A. (2011) Variable cultural acquisition costs constrain cumulative cultural evolution. PLoS One 6(3):e18239.Google Scholar
Milanovic, B., Lindert, P. H. & Williamson, J. G. (2011) Pre-industrial inequality. The Economic Journal 121(551):255–72.Google Scholar
Mittal, C., Griskevicius, V., Simpson, J. A., Sung, S. & Young, E. S. (2015) Cognitive adaptations to stressful environments: When childhood adversity enhances adult executive function. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 109(4):604–21.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2009a) Intellectual property rights, the industrial revolution, and the beginnings of modern economic growth. American Economic Review 99(2):349–55.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2009b) The enlightened economy: An economic history of Britain 1700–1850. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2016) A culture of growth: The origins of the modern economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Moran, N. A. (1992) The evolutionary maintenance of alternative phenotypes. The American Naturalist 139(5):971–89.Google Scholar
Morris, I. (2013) The measure of civilization: How social development decides the fate of nations. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Moya, A. (2018) Violence, psychological trauma, and risk attitudes: Evidence from victims of violence in Colombia. Journal of Development Economics 131:1527.Google Scholar
Mullainathan, S. & Shafir, E. (2013) Scarcity: Why having too little means so much. Macmillan.Google Scholar
Murray, D. R., Trudeau, R. & Schaller, M. (2011) On the origins of cultural differences in conformity: Four tests of the pathogen prevalence hypothesis. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 37(3):318–29.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2009a) An evolutionary model of low mood states. Journal of Theoretical Biology 257(1):100103.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2010a) Dying young and living fast: Variation in life history across English neighborhoods. Behavioral Ecology 21(2):387–95.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2010b) Why are there social gradients in preventative health behavior? A perspective from behavioral ecology. PLoS One 5(10):e13371.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2011) Large differences in publicly visible health behaviours across two neighbourhoods of the same city. PLoS One 6(6):e21051.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2014) What the future held: Childhood psychosocial adversity is associated with health deterioration through adulthood in a cohort of British women. Evolution and Human Behavior 35(6):519–25.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2017) Let them eat cake! In: Hanging on to the edges: Essays on science, society and the academic life. Open Book. Available at: http://books.openedition.org/obp/7743.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. (2019) State-dependent cognition and its relevance to cultural evolution. Behavioural Processes 161:101107. Available at: http://doi.org/10.1016/j.beproc.2018.01.018.Google Scholar
Nettle, D. & Bateson, M. (2012) The evolutionary origins of mood and its disorders. Current Biology 22(17):R71221.Google Scholar
Nettle, D., Colléony, A. & Cockerill, M. (2011) Variation in cooperative behaviour within a single city. PLoS One 6(10):e26922.Google Scholar
Nettle, D., Frankenhuis, W. E. & Rickard, I. J. (2013) The evolution of predictive adaptive responses in human life history. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 280(1766):20131343.Google Scholar
Nicholas, S. & Steckel, R. H. (1991) Heights and living standards of English workers during the early years of industrializations, 1770–1815. The Journal of Economic History 51(04):937–57.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. (1996) Do real-output and real-wage measures capture reality? The history of lighting suggests not. In: The economics of new goods, ed. Bresnahan, T. F. & Gordon, R. J., pp. 2770. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Norris, P. & Inglehart, R. (2011) Sacred and secular: Religion and politics worldwide. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1991) Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1):97112.Google Scholar
North, D. C. & Weingast, B. R. (1989) Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History 49(4):803–32.Google Scholar
Ober, J. (2015) The rise and fall of classical Greece. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Olsson, O. & Hibbs, D. A. Jr. (2005) Biogeography and long-run economic development. European Economic Review 49(4):909–38.Google Scholar
Pamuk, Ş. & Shatzmiller, M. (2014) Plagues, wages, and economic change in the Islamic Middle East, 700–1500. The Journal of Economic History 74(1):196229.Google Scholar
Pedersen, E. J., Forster, D. E. & McCullough, M. E. (2014) Life history, code of honor, and emotional responses to inequality in an economic game. Emotion 14(5):920.Google Scholar
Pender, J. L. (1996) Discount rates and credit markets: Theory and evidence from rural India. Journal of Development Economics 50(2):257–96.Google Scholar
Pepper, G. V. & Nettle, D. (2017) The behavioural constellation of deprivation: Causes and consequences. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 40:e314.Google Scholar
Petersen, M. B. & Aarøe, L. (2015) Birth weight and social trust in adulthood: Evidence for early calibration of social cognition. Psychological Science 26(11):1681–92.Google Scholar
Pfister, U. (2011) Economic growth in Germany, 1500–1850. Paper presented at the Conference on Quantifying Long Run Economic Development, Venice, March 2224, 2011.Google Scholar
Pinker, S. (2011a) The better angels of our nature: The decline of violence in history and its causes. Penguin.Google Scholar
Pinker, S. (2018) Enlightenment now: The case for reason, science, humanism, and progress. Penguin.Google Scholar
Pomeranz, K. (2009) The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Poortinga, W., Dunstan, F. D. & Fone, D. L. (2008) Health locus of control beliefs and socio-economic differences in self-rated health. Preventive Medicine 46(4):374–80.Google Scholar
Promislow, D. E. & Harvey, P. H. (1990) Living fast and dying young: A comparative analysis of life-history variation among mammals. Journal of Zoology 220(3):417–37.Google Scholar
Przeworski, A., Limongi, F. & Giner, S. (1995) Political regimes and economic growth. In: Democracy and development, ed. Bagchi, A. K., pp. 327. Springer.Google Scholar
Quinlan, R. J. (2003) Father absence, parental care, and female reproductive development. Evolution and Human Behavior 24(6):376–90.Google Scholar
Quinlan, R. J. (2007) Human parental effort and environmental risk. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 274(1606):121–25.Google Scholar
Quinlan, R. J. & Quinlan, M. B. (2007) Parenting and cultures of risk: A comparative analysis of infidelity, aggression, and witchcraft. American Anthropologist 109(1):164–79.Google Scholar
Ridolfi, L. (2017) The French economy in the longue durée: A study on real wages, working days and economic performance from Louis IX to the Revolution (1250–1789). European Review of Economic History 21(4):437–38.Google Scholar
Rieucau, G. & Giraldeau, L.-A. (2011) Exploring the costs and benefits of social information use: An appraisal of current experimental evidence. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 366(1567):949–57.Google Scholar
Robb, K. A., Simon, A. E. & Wardle, J. (2009) Socioeconomic disparities in optimism and pessimism. International Journal of Behavioral Medicine 16(4):331.Google Scholar
Roff, D. (1993) Evolution of life histories: Theory and analysis. Springer Science and Business Media.Google Scholar
Rudaizky, D., Basanovic, J. & MacLeod, C. (2014) Biased attentional engagement with, and disengagement from, negative information: Independent cognitive pathways to anxiety vulnerability? Cognition and Emotion 28(2):245–59.Google Scholar
Safra, L., Algan, Y., Tecu, T., Grèzes, J., Baumard, N. & Chevallier, C. (2017) Childhood harshness predicts long-lasting leader preferences. Evolution and Human Behavior 38(5):645–51.Google Scholar
Safra, L., Grèzes, J., Chevallier, C. & Baumard, N. (2019) Tracking the rise of trust in history using machine learning and paintings. Manuscript in preparation.Google Scholar
Safra, L., Tecu, T., Lambert, S., Sheskin, M., Baumard, N. & Chevallier, C. (2016) Neighborhood deprivation negatively impacts children's prosocial behavior. Frontiers in Psychology 7:1760.Google Scholar
Scheidel, W. (2010) Real wages in early economies: Evidence for living standards from 1800 BCE to 1300 CE. Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 53(3):425–62.Google Scholar
Scheidel, W. & Friesen, S. J. (2009) The size of the economy and the distribution of income in the Roman Empire. Journal of Roman Studies 99:6191.Google Scholar
Schmitt, D. P. (2008) Evolutionary perspectives on romantic attachment and culture: How ecological stressors influence dismissing orientations across genders and geographies. Cross-Cultural Research 42(3):220–47.Google Scholar
Schofield, R. S. (1973) Dimensions of illiteracy, 1750–1850. Explorations in Economic History 10(4):437–54.Google Scholar
Schroeder, K. B., Pepper, G. V. & Nettle, D. (2014) Local norms of cheating and the cultural evolution of crime and punishment: A study of two urban neighborhoods. PeerJ 2:e450.Google Scholar
Serafinelli, M. & Tabellini, G. (2017) Creativity over time and space. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP12365. Available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3053893.Google Scholar
Sheldon, K. M. & Kasser, T. (2008) Psychological threat and extrinsic goal striving. Motivation and Emotion 32(1):3745.Google Scholar
Silva, A. S. & Mace, R. (2014) Cooperation and conflict: Field experiments in Northern Ireland. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 281:20141435.Google Scholar
Silva, A. S. & Mace, R. (2015) Inter-group conflict and cooperation: Field experiments before, during and after sectarian riots in Northern Ireland. Frontiers in Psychology 6:1790.Google Scholar
Simpson, J. A., Collins, W. A. & Salvatore, J. E. (2011) The impact of early interpersonal experience on adult romantic relationship functioning: Recent findings from the Minnesota longitudinal study of risk and adaptation. Current Directions in Psychological Science 20(6):355–59.Google Scholar
Smith, G. D. & Egger, M. (1993) Socioeconomic differentials in wealth and health. British Medical Journal 307(6912):1085.Google Scholar
Sperber, D. (1996) Explaining culture: A naturalistic approach, first ed., vol. 323. Blackwell.Google Scholar
Squicciarini, M. P. & Voigtländer, N. (2015) Human capital and industrialization: Evidence from the age of enlightenment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(4):1825–83. Available at: https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjv025.Google Scholar
Stearns, S. C. (1992) The evolution of life histories, vol. 249. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Stearns, S. C. & Koella, J. C. (1986) The evolution of phenotypic plasticity in life-history traits: Predictions of reaction norms for age and size at maturity. Evolution 40(5):893913.Google Scholar
Stephens, D. W. (1981) The logic of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Animal Behaviour 29(2):628–29.Google Scholar
Stephens, W. B. (1990) Literacy in England, Scotland, and Wales, 1500–1900. History of Education Quarterly 30(4):545–71.Google Scholar
Stephenson, J. Z. (2017) “Real” wages? Contractors, workers, and pay in London building trades, 1650–1800. The Economic History Review 71:106–32. Available at: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/ehr.12491/full.Google Scholar
Stringhini, S., Sabia, S., Shipley, M., Brunner, E., Nabi, H., Kivimaki, M. & Singh-Manoux, A. (2010) Association of socioeconomic position with health behaviors and mortality. JAMA 303(12):1159–66.Google Scholar
Sunderland, D. (2007) Social capital, trust and the industrial revolution: 1780–1880. Routledge.Google Scholar
Swift, J. (1704/2018) Battle of the books. Alma Books.Google Scholar
Thomas, K. (1971) Religion and the decline of magic: Studies in popular beliefs in sixteenth and seventeenth-century England. Penguin.Google Scholar
Twenge, J. M. & Kasser, T. (2013) Generational changes in materialism and work centrality, 1976–2007: Associations with temporal changes in societal insecurity and materialistic role modeling. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 39(7):883–97.Google Scholar
Van Neuss, L. (2015) Why did the industrial revolution start in Britain? Available at: http://orbi.ulg.be/handle/2268/188592.Google Scholar
van Schaik, C. P., Burkart, J., Damerius, L., Forss, S. I. F., Koops, K., van Noordwijk, M. A. & Schuppli, C. (2016) The reluctant innovator: Orangutans and the phylogeny of creativity. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 371(1690). Available at: https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0183.Google Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. (2009) The skill premium and the “Great Divergence.” European Review of Economic History 13(1):121–53.Google Scholar
Voth, H.-J. (2000) Time and work in England 1750–1830. Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Webb, E., Thomson, S., Nelson, A., White, C., Koren, G., Rieder, M. & Van Uum, S. (2010) Assessing individual systemic stress through cortisol analysis of archaeological hair. Journal of Archaeological Science 37(4):807–12.Google Scholar
Webster, M. M. & Hart, P. J. (2006) Subhabitat selection by foraging threespine stickleback (Gasterosteus aculeatus): Previous experience and social conformity. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 60(1):7786.Google Scholar
Weir, D. (1997) Economic welfare and physical well-being in France, 1750–1990. In: Health and welfare during industrialization, ed. Steckel, R. H. & Floud, R., pp. 161200. University of Chicago Press. Available at: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7431.pdf.Google Scholar
West, S. A., Griffin, A. S. & Gardner, A. (2007) Evolutionary explanations for cooperation. Current Biology 17(16):R66172.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, R. G. & Pickett, K. (2010) The spirit level: Why equality is better for everyone. Penguin.Google Scholar
Wootton, D. (2015) The invention of science. A new history of the scientific revolution. Allen Lane/Penguin.Google Scholar
Wrigley, E. A. (1997) English population history from family reconstitution 1580–1837. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wrigley, E. A. (2013) Energy and the English industrial revolution. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences 371(1986):20110568.Google Scholar
Wrigley, E. A. & Schofield, R. S. (1983) English population history from family reconstitution: Summary results 1600–1799. Population Studies 37(2):157–84.Google Scholar
Wu, J., Balliet, D., Tybur, J. M., Arai, S., Van Lange, P. A. & Yamagishi, T. (2017) Life history strategy and human cooperation in economic games. Evolution and Human Behavior 38(4):496505.Google Scholar
Xu, T. (2017) The production and circulation of manuscripts and printed books in China compared to Europe, ca. 5811840. Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics No. 53. Available at: http://technologygovernance.eu/files/main/2013070208164949.pdf.Google Scholar
Xu, Y., van Leeuwen, B. & van Zanden, J. L. (2015) Urbanization in China, ca. 11001900. CGEH Working Paper series, vol. 63.Google Scholar
Yesuf, M. & Bluffstone, R. (2008) Wealth and time preference in rural Ethiopia Available at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/rff/dpaper/dp-08-16-efd.html.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Fast and slow strategies. Adapted from Griskevicius (2013).

Figure 1

Figure 2. The causal role of the life history switch.

Figure 2

Figure 3. (a) Brood-size manipulation. The diagram shows the creation of a single family of four focal chicks. (b) Intertemporal choice task. One colored key (here, green) was assigned to the smaller sooner option (a 1-s delay to obtain one 45-mg pellet), and the other color (here, red) was assigned to the larger later option (a longer x-s delay to obtain five 45-mg pellets) (Bateson et al. 2015).

Figure 3

Figure 4. Welfare ratios of laborers in Europe, Asia, and the Roman Empire (Allen 2009a).

Figure 4

Figure 5. GDP per capita in 1990 international dollars. Adapted from Broadberry (2018) for China, Japan, Italy, Great Britain and the Low countries, from Pfister (2011) for Germany, and from Ridolfi (2017) for France.

Figure 5

Figure 6. Urbanization rate. Sources: Bassino et al. (2015), Bosker et al. (2013), Xu et al. (2015).

Figure 6

Figure 7. The Bourgeois Revaluation and the Republic of Letters in an LHT perspective. As indicated in the figure, increasing political liberalism and scientific advances may also have contributed to the acceleration of growth (see Acemoglu & Robinson 2012; McCloskey 2016a; Mokyr 2016).