Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b95js Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T08:09:48.717Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Political Economy Model: A Blue Wave Forecast For 2020

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 October 2020

Michael S. Lewis-Beck
Affiliation:
University of Iowa
Charles Tien
Affiliation:
Hunter College & The Graduate Center, CUNY
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Forecasting the 2020 US Elections
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

The Political Economy model represents one of the earliest political science forecasting models for presidential elections (Lewis-Beck and Rice Reference Lewis-Beck and Rice1982; Reference Lewis-Beck and Rice1984a). It relies on a multiple regression equation with just a few predictor variables, drawing from leading theories of vote choice, measured several months before the election (as done by Lewis-Beck and Tien previously in Reference Lewis-Beck and Tien1996 and Reference Lewis-Beck and Tien2008). The model may be simply stated: the vote share for the party in the White House is determined by presidential popularity and economic growth. Much has been said about the uniqueness of the 2020 election campaign, e.g., COVID-19, the extreme character of Trump’s rule, the dramatic economic collapse, widespread protests ignited by George Floyd’s killing, among other things. We do not deny these circumstances. However, we believe their effects are absorbed, then expressed, via the causal structure the model suggests. Here we apply the model to forecast the 2020 presidential election (popular and Electoral College votes), followed by forecasts for the House and Senate elections. We forecast a Democratic sweep.

Much has been said about the uniqueness of the 2020 election campaign, e.g., COVID-19, the extreme character of Trump’s rule, the dramatic economic collapse, widespread protests ignited by George Floyd’s killing, among other things.

PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

The presidential election model is written thusly (Lewis-Beck and Rice Reference Lewis-Beck and Rice1984a, 17):

(Eq.1) $$ \mathrm{Incumbent}\ \mathrm{Vote}=\mathrm{Presidential}\ \mathrm{Popularity}+\mathrm{Economic}\ \mathrm{Growth}, $$

where the Presidential Vote = the two-party share of the national popular vote for the president’s party, Economic Growth = the GNP growth in the first two quarters of the election year, and Presidential Popularity = Gallup’s July job approval rating for the president.

According to the model, the election represents a referendum on the performance of the president with respect to leading political and economic issues. The better the performance, the better the White House party will do. Below we show model estimates using ordinary least squares (OLS):

(Eq. 2) $$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Vote}=37.50+.26\ast \mathrm{Popularity}+1.18\ast \mathrm{Growth}\\ {}\quad (15.37)\quad (4.73)\quad (2.25)=\mathrm{t}-\mathrm{ratio}\end{array}} $$

R-squared = .76 Adj. R-squared = .73 Root Mean Squared Error = 2.75 Durbin-Watson = 2.39 N = 18 elections, 1948-2016 Figures in parentheses = t-ratios Asterisk indicates statistical significance = .05, one-tail (Tien Reference Tien2020).

This model, though parsimonious, forecast the 2016 result quite accurately. Indeed, it nailed the two-party popular vote result, forecasting a 51.0 percentage share for Clinton, who actually received 51.1% (Lewis-Beck and Tien Reference Lewis-Beck and Tien2018). This trivial amount of error gave the model first place, in an accuracy evaluation of such structural forecasting models (Campbell Reference Campbell2017). While it would be foolish optimism to expect such a degree of accuracy in 2020, it seems reasonable to believe the model will fare well with respect to the Trump-Biden contest. To forecast 2020, we insert the current values as of 8/27/20 for the predictor variables, Popularity (41) and Growth (-4.14)Footnote 1 :

(Eq.3) $$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{Vote}=37.50+.26\ (41)+1.18\ \left(-4.14\right)\\ {}\quad =43.3\%\quad \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{popular}\ \mathrm{two}-\mathrm{party}\ \mathrm{vote}\ \mathrm{for}\ \mathrm{Trump}.\end{array}} $$

How accurate do we expect this forecast to be? First, over the time series of elections, it correctly picked the winning party 15 out of 18 times (missing 1960, 1968, and 1976), or 83% of the time. This certainty speaks to within-sample error. To examine out-of-sample error, we ran a series of jackknife tests (see table 1). That is, taking each year in turn, we dropped it from the data, re-estimated the model, then predicted that out-of-sample year and examined the forecasting error. We found zero elections with a positive error greater than 6.7%. Since our forecast is 43.3, if it has an error greater than +6.7, we would forecast a victory for the wrong party. Taken literally, that would leave no chance that this forecast of a Democratic victory would be wrong (i.e., 0/18 = .00). We shy away from such a high level of certainty. However, we construct the following 95% confidence interval (two-tail) around our point estimate of 43.3, utilizing the RMSE=2.75 and degrees of freedom=15 : [37.41, 49.6]. This result suggests a 95% probability that Trump will lose the popular vote. Twice in the last five presidential elections, the Electoral College, and not the popular vote outcome, picked the presidential winner. Thus, we forecast the Electoral College winner by regressing the incumbent party’s percent of the Electoral College vote on its percent of the two-party popular vote. We get the following results

(Eq. 4) $$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{EC}\ \mathrm{Vote}=-199.42+4.90\ast \mathrm{PopVote}\\ {}\quad \left(-11.64\right)\quad (14.94)=\mathrm{t}-\mathrm{ratio}\\ {}\mathrm{R}2=.93\quad \mathrm{adj}\ \mathrm{R}2=.93\quad \mathrm{N}=18\quad \mathrm{R}\mathrm{MSE}=7.14\end{array}} $$

Table 1 Presidential Election Predictions with the Political Economy Model

This equation yields an Electoral College forecast of only 68 electoral votes for Trump. Interestingly, this is on par with Jimmy Carter’s defeat in 1980 with 49 electoral votes.

Interestingly, this is on par with Jimmy Carter’s defeat in 1980 with 49 electoral votes.

One may be skeptical of this dramatic forecast. However, we note that 1980 happens to be the election year in our series with the most negative GNP growth. One could argue, more generally, that times are very different now and the popular vote-electoral vote connection has broken down. However, in a statistical sense, that conclusion has clay feet. In figure 1 we see the Electoral College vote share nationwide (in percent) regressed on the two-party popular vote, for the elections from 1948 to 2016. The election results fall very close to the prediction line, with an almost perfect statistical fit (R-squared = 0.93). Further, we do not really observe a deterioration in the fit when we focus on the elections of the 2000s. (Look how close the points are to the line, with even 2016 closer than some previous elections.)

Figure 1 Electoral College Vote by Popular Vote, 1948-2016

CONGRESSIONAL ELECTIONS

Forecasts for the United States House and Senate elections have been carried out from the early 1980s (Lewis-Beck and Rice Reference Lewis-Beck and Rice1984b; Reference Lewis-Beck and Rice1985). These models rest on a core political economy model:

(Eq.5) $$ \mathrm{House}\ \mathrm{Seat}\ \mathrm{Change}=\mathrm{Presidential}\ \mathrm{Popularity}+\mathrm{Income}\ \mathrm{Growth}+\mathrm{Midterm}\ \mathrm{Status}, $$

with House Seat Change = number of seats lost or gained by the president’s party, Presidential Popularity = Gallup’s June job approval rating for the president, economic conditions = growth rate of real disposable income over the first two quarters of the election year, Midterm Status = 0 for presidential election years and = 1 for midterm election years.

For House forecasts, we use a simple referendum model, conditioned on whether the contest is a midterm. In the most recent House election, 2018, this model performed quite well, with a total seats change error of only nine seats, well below the median error for the series (Tien and Lewis-Beck Reference Tien and Lewis-Beck2019). Given we are in a presidential year, White House success in terms of making seat gains (or losses) boils down to how the Republicans have handled economic and non-economic issues. OLS estimates for the post-World War II elections follow:

(Eq. 6) $$ \mathrm{House}\ \mathrm{Seat}\ \mathrm{Change}=-45.53+.83\ast \mathrm{Popularity}+4.89\ast \mathrm{Income}\hbox{--} 29.1\ast \mathrm{Midterm}(-3.55)\quad (3.47)\quad (2.95)\quad (-4.81)=\mathrm{t}-\mathrm{ratio} $$

R-squared = .60 Adj. R-squared = .57 Root mean squared error = 17.85. Durbin-Watson = 1.87, N = 36 elections (1948-2018) and the other notation is as with Eq.2.

To use this equation to forecast the 2020 House elections, we plug in the appropriate values (as of 7/27/20),Footnote 2 so producing the following seat change estimate:

(Eq. 7) $$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{House}\ \mathrm{Seat}\ \mathrm{Change}=-45.53+.83\ (38)+4.89\ \left(-3.77\right)-29.1\ (0)\\ {}\quad =-32\ \mathrm{seat}\ \mathrm{loss}\ \mathrm{for}\ \mathrm{the}\ \mathrm{Republicans}.\end{array}} $$

What about seat change for the 2020 Senate elections? We hold that the political economic forces operating on the House also operate on the Senate, with the added constraint of their different electoral calendar (i.e., just one-third of the Senate seats are on the ballot, every two years). The Senate forecasting model expresses itself as:

(Eq.8) $$ \mathrm{Senate}\ \mathrm{Seat}\ \mathrm{Change}=\mathrm{Popularity}+\mathrm{Economy}+\mathrm{Midterm}+\mathrm{Seats}\ \mathrm{Exposed}, $$

with Senate Seat Change = number of seats lost or gained by the president’s party; Seats Exposed = number of seats the president’s party has up for reelection; the other variables are as defined in equation 5. Here are OLS estimates for the model, across the post-World War II elections:

(Eq. 9) $$ \mathrm{Senate}\ \mathrm{Seat}\ \mathrm{Change}=2.79+.13\ast \mathrm{Popularity}+.91\ast \mathrm{Income}\hbox{--} 2.37\ast \mathrm{Midterm}-.70\ast \mathrm{Seat}\mathrm{s}\mathrm{Up}(1.05)(3.46)(3.35)(-2.44)(-6.42)=\mathrm{t}-\mathrm{ratio} $$

R-squared = .69 Adj. R-squared = .65 Root mean squared error = 2.84 Durbin-Watson = 1.86, N = 36 elections (1948-2018) and the other notation is as with Eq.2. All independent variable coefficients are statistically significant at the 0.05 level, one-tail.

What does this mean for Senate control in 2020? Trump’s June approval rating is 38%, disposable personal income change has been strongly negative (at -3.77), and the Republicans have 23 seats exposed (using data reported as of 7/27/20). These numbers forecast a gain of 12 seats for the Democrats, giving Democrats a Senate majority.

CONCLUSIONS

The time-tested Political Economy models point to an electoral landslide in 2020 for Democrats, across the executive and legislative branches—a Blue wave. For the presidential race, we forecast a victory for Biden not seen since the landslide elections of Ronald Reagan. Congressional election forecasts also point to large Democratic gains, giving them a Senate majority of a size last seen during Obama’s first term. Along with a near filibuster proof Senate would come a House majority of 264 seats (again on par with Obama’s first term). If Joe Biden becomes president as the political economy forecast predicts, it appears that he would govern with a unified Congress.

The time-tested Political Economy models point to an electoral landslide in 2020 for Democrats, across the executive and legislative branches—a Blue wave.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Replication files are available on Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/XJVOBX.

Footnotes

1. We have adjusted the economic data as all second quarter economic numbers are extreme outliers due to COVID-19. GNP change over the first two quarters of the election year dating back to 1948 has ranged from -1.38 to 4.18. We calculated the GNP change to be three times the lowest number, yielding a data point of -4.14. While this may appear to be a reasonable adjustment for such a gross outlier it is of course not the only possible adjustment. One alternative would be to use the first quarter GNP growth only (instead of the two quarter measure the model employs). Thus, using first quarter GNP growth (advanced estimate, nonannualized) of -.36 we get a forecast of 47.74% of the two-party popular vote, which translates into an electoral vote share of 186 seats. We do not favor this alternative because it ignores the pandemic and openly violates the theoretical two-quarter model specification we have always used. Another alternative would be to simply stay with the model, and use an unadjusted two quarter estimate; for example, actual GNP growth (nonannualized, released on 8/27/2020) over the first two quarters equals a whopping -5.4; if we use this estimate as our growth number, we get a two party popular vote forecast of 41.79, translating to an electoral vote share of only 29 seats. This last forecast stretches credulity; we believe, theoretically, that the outlier status of economic growth means at some point it will give the Democrats diminishing marginal returns. Hence, we do prefer our first correction, on grounds that it accommodates our general theory, taking into account the nonlinearity the outlier induces. Certainly, one can continue to argue about what adjustment should be made. For example, The Economist model contends the economic impact amounts to The Great Recession plus 40% (Gelman and Heidmanns Reference Gelman and Heidemanns2020). That adjustment is, in some sense, arbitrary, as ours could be. However, we base our forecast on our theory, the empirical track record of the model, and our reasoned assessment of the economic reality going into this election.

2. Note that the economic measure used here is income, rather than growth. This usage pays homage to the tradition of congressional election forecasting models, with their preference for the income measure (Tien and Lewis-Beck, Reference Tien and Lewis-Beck2019). With this measure, also, COVID-19 has played havoc. Economic stimulus spending boosted disposable income in the second quarter. Therefore, we Winsorize (Tufte Reference Tufte1974, 102) the data on disposable personal income, adding 1 to the largest negative number in our dataset: -2.77-1=-3.77, in order to take into account its outlier status. Again, this adjustment follows our strategy of “backing down” to some degree the even greater losses that might be projected by employing the theoretical (fully linear) extrapolation of economic effects.

References

REFERENCES

Campbell, James E. 2017. “Introduction: A Re-cap of the 2016 Election Forecasts.” PS: Political Science & Politics 50:331–32.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew, and Heidemanns, Merlin. 2020. “Forecasting the US Elections.” The Economist. https://projects.economist.com/us-2020-forecast/president.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Rice, Tom W.. 1982. “Presidential Popularity and Presidential Vote.” Public Opinion Quarterly 46:534537.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Rice, Tom W.. 1984a. “Forecasting Presidential Elections: A Comparison of Naive Models.” Political Behavior 6:3951.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Rice, Tom W.. 1984b. “Forecasting U.S. House Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 9:475486.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Rice, Tom W.. 1985. “Are Senate Elections Predictable?PS: Political Science & Politics 18:745754.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Tien, Charles. 1996. “The Future in Forecasting: Prospective Presidential Models.” American Politics Quarterly 24:468491.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Tien, Charles. 2008. “The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for ’08?PS: Political Science & Politics 41:687690.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Tien, Charles. 2018. “Candidates and campaigns: How they alter election forecasts.” Electoral Studies 54:303308. ISSN 0261-3794. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2018.04.014.Google Scholar
Tien, Charles, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S.. 2019. “Congressional Midterm Forecasts: A Trump Economic Difference?The Forum 16 (4): 591610. https://doi:10.1515/for-2018-0039 Google Scholar
Tien, Charles. 2020. “Replication Data for: 2020 US Presidential Forecast.” Harvard Dataverse doi: 10.7910/DVN/XJVOBX Google Scholar
Tufte, Edward R. 1974. Data Analysis for Politics and Policy. Englewood Cliffs, New. Jersey: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Presidential Election Predictions with the Political Economy Model

Figure 1

Figure 1 Electoral College Vote by Popular Vote, 1948-2016

Supplementary material: Link

Lewis-Beck and Tien Dataset

Link