INTRODUCTION: THE CLOSE NEXUS BETWEEN A MODERN SECURED TRANSACTIONS LAW AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Given the important role played by credit in any economy, a tidal wave of reforms has swept through the secured transactions laws of several countries in the developed and developing world.Footnote 1 While developed countries have presumably effected the reforms to promote further access to credit,Footnote 2 it has been argued for low and middle income countries that the reforms will catalyse access to finance by the private sector in need of it.Footnote 3 Whether the reforms were inspired by nudging from international institutions,Footnote 4 or from genuine efforts to attract improvement in credit accessibility, at least there is economic justification in asserting that countries with reformed secured transaction laws perform better than their counterparts who are yet to undertake this all-important step towards a functioning and robust credit market.Footnote 5 It has been suggested that the certainty and predictability that reform brings catalyses capital inflows that benefit not only local businesses but also consumers.Footnote 6 In summary, it has been stated on the basis of empirical research that, “by increasing domestic and international capital flows, appropriate legal reforms can play a substantially more central role in the economic development process than previously thought”.Footnote 7
Nigeria, Africa's largest economy,Footnote 8 certainly has much to benefit from the reform of her personal property security laws (PPSL). Estimates of the losses resulting from the non-acceptance by Nigerian lenders of a whole range of items of personal property are particularly troubling.Footnote 9 This has contributed to the paucity of credit available to micro, small and medium enterprises (MSMEs) and a manufacturing sector in dire need of these funds as many MSMEs often do not meet the lending criteria set by commercial banks.Footnote 10 It would be unfair to begrudge lenders who demand security, as there are indeed sound economic as well as legal reasons for requiring security from borrowers.Footnote 11 Despite efforts made in 2010 by the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN) to unlock credit through the provision of liquidity for the benefit of these enterprises,Footnote 12 two years later, for inexplicable reasons, businesses were unable to access the facilities.Footnote 13 Indeed experiences of government policy interventions only reinforce the need for reform. A reformed PPSL will indubitably unlock a plethora of assets over which MSMEs may create security interests and galvanize lenders to leverage on the certainty and predictability that will be occasioned by the new regime.
Fairly recently, stakeholders in the Nigerian credit market woke up to the “glad tidings” of reform that promises to expand access to credit through the acceptance of a broad range of items of personal property as collateral.Footnote 14 The legal instrument that has ushered in this possibility is the CBN (Registration of Security Interests in Movable Property by Banks and Other Financial Institutions in Nigeria) (Regulations, No 1, 2015) (the Regulation) made by the governor of the CBN.Footnote 15 The Regulation essentially seeks to “… improve access to finance for … MSMEs while maintaining a strong prudent lending policy to promote [sic] Sound Financial System in Nigeria”.Footnote 16 This courageous step should interest researchers tracking development in secured transactions law reform in Nigeria for two reasons.
First, the approach taken by this reform bears the trappings of the functional approach to PPSL for which article 9 of the US Uniform Commercial Code (UCC article 9) is the paradigm. As global regulatory competition continues to inspire gravitation towards the functional approach / unitary system of UCC article 9,Footnote 17 this step by the CBN means that the gravitation has not been lost on Nigeria. In fact, it may be considered as delayed, compared to the reforms which have been undertaken in other common law countries.Footnote 18 However, lying at the heart of any sustainable PPSL reform in Nigeria is the important fact of the present state of Nigeria's collateral law framework, which to all intents and purposes draws from the English compartmentalized system.Footnote 19 The implication of this realization is that there is much more to the reform of Nigeria's PPSL than that which has been done through the Regulation, no matter how laudable it appears.
The second reason is that the interaction between behavioural science and policy making has led to the enactment of legal instruments that meet the requirements of practicability and legitimacy.Footnote 20 The trend in many jurisdictions that have reformed their PPSL (at least outside Africa) reflects consensus building among stakeholders, which necessarily includes academia.Footnote 21 While this is obviously not the case in Nigeria, it may well be the reason why subsidiary legislation was used to achieve a quick fix. As this article will also argue, this approach is in itself problematic.
The authors believe that this article is the first academic effort at dissecting the 48 section Regulation on personal property security. The aim is to undertake a critical analysis of the provisions of the Regulation as a flagship legal instrument that embodies what may pass for Nigeria's PPSL. The analytical approach is two-fold. First, the article examines the Regulation against the backdrop of what are now known as the building blocks of UCC article 9.Footnote 22 Secondly the analysis examines the intrinsic values for which a bespoke PPSL for Nigeria should strive, against the backdrop of existing legislation and the workings of the institutions that to all intents and purposes reflect the compartmentalization for which English secured transactions law is known.
After this introduction, the article examines the pre-Regulation regime pertaining to secured transactions law in Nigeria and the bedraggled circumstances that called for reforms. It then sets out a diagnosis of perceived problems that are inherent in the Regulation, as well as other incompatibilities of the pre-Regulation regime that may impair the workings of the Regulation and further complicate existing problems.
THE SECURED TRANSACTIONS LAW REGIME IN NIGERIA AND THE YEARNING FOR REFORM
The features of a reformed secured transactions law: Nigeria in perspective
A reform of secured transactions law in Nigeria should be broad enough to insure against the existence of small sets of conflicting laws and rules governing various title financing and security devices.Footnote 23 Thus, a modern secured transactions law elevates substance over form, adopts a functional approach to secured transactions, and has a unified set of rules with which to deal with the creation, perfection, prioritisation and enforcement of rights stemming from every transaction that creates a security interest on a debtor's personal property or fixtures.Footnote 24
In Nigeria, due to some inhibitive features that are tightly connected to the legal enforcement of secured transactions rights,Footnote 25 plurality of security devicesFootnote 26 and the dearth of comprehensive insolvency legislation,Footnote 27 real property assets indeed form better collateral than items of personal property, at least from a lender's perspective. Thus, underlying challenges vis-à-vis an unreformed secured transactions law,Footnote 28 the outdated personal bankruptcy law,Footnote 29 the absence of bespoke corporate insolvency legislation, as well as a dawdling judicial system,Footnote 30 render otherwise good personal property assets less valuable or attractive for lending. For instance, when evaluating the degree to which his loan is indeed asset based and truly deserving of risk analysis, an astute lender would ask a basic and crucial question: “can the lender - upon a borrower's default - rapidly enforce his security interest against the assets given by the debtor as collateral, and simultaneously transmute such collateral into proceeds to satisfy the owed debts?”Footnote 31 The key principles underlying asset based financing may well be derived from this basic question. Additionally, the lender would certainly want to know whether his security interest in the debtor's personal property is superior or subordinate to other competing security interests in the same collateral and how this panoply of security interests would be prioritized in the context of the debtor's bankruptcy or insolvency.Footnote 32
Whether a law reform initiative truly encompasses secured lending principles and is economically viable is also contingent upon the quality and efficiency of the collateral registry, and the speed with which a security interest can be enforced on the debtor's collateral after his default or bankruptcy. It is self evident that the modern principles of secured transactions are currently lacking in Nigeria, such that creditors’ ability to enforce security interests against debtors’ assets is severely weak due to a slow and overburdened judicial system. This difficulty is reinforced by the lack of a developed private enforcement mechanism vis-à-vis security interests on personal property collateral; thus, the concept of repossessing collateral via self help after a debtor's default is still hotly contested.Footnote 33 Furthermore, there is no collateral registry where security interests on personal property collateral are registered, where all existing or potential creditors can go to search for encumbrances against the personal property assets of a debtor being offered by him as collateral; this no doubt precipitates and intensifies the problem of ostensible ownership in Nigeria.Footnote 34
Consequences for lack of reform: CBN Regulation (“reform”) to the rescue?
It is to be expected that the overall consequence of this array of weaknesses arising essentially from the unreformed nature of Nigeria's secured transaction law is that only a small subset of assets, most notably real property assets, is considered ideal for lending. By this logic, the bulk of wealth locked up in corporations’ personal property (such as inventories, equipment, accounts receivable and intellectual as well as investment property) is usually cut off, and unfortunately deemed incapable of securing lending.Footnote 35 Similarly, MSMEs, which do not always have a robust collection of real property to offer as collateral, but may instead be able to offer equipment, inventories and accounts receivable, are usually not in a good position to acquire sufficient credit to start or expand businesses; sadly they play a major economic role in Nigeria's fledgling economy.Footnote 36
It was in view of these challenges, posed essentially by an unreformed secured transactions law, that the CBN recently passed the Regulation pursuant to its powers in the CBN ActFootnote 37 and the Banks and Other Financial Institutions Act.Footnote 38 The Regulation draws essentially from the tenets of UCC article 9, a paradigm law on secured transactions.Footnote 39 However, while a secured transactions law that mirrors the building blocks of UCC article 9 is a starting point, much more work lies in ensuring that the version being implemented in Nigeria is thoroughly in line with its idiosyncratic features, and generally compatible with the existing legal framework.
Looking at the Regulation, the authors argue that it will not satisfactorily solve the numerous challenges that bedevil secured transactions law in Nigeria because it lacks certain essentials and to that extent is defective. They base their arguments on these defects (discussed below) and are of the view that, absent the fixing of these missing links, the Regulation, which is improperly seated at the moment, will indeed deepen the confusion and misery that are currently panning out in the secured lending industry in Nigeria.
SOME DIAGNOSED DEFECTS OF THE REGULATION
The first defect: Creation of an enforceable security interest – no mention of “value” in the Regulation
Using UCC article 9 as a benchmark, and given that the Regulation largely draws from its principles, there are essentially four requirements that parties to a security agreement must fulfil before the agreement becomes enforceable.Footnote 40 The Regulation captures all these requirements except one; it omitted the requirement that a secured party give “value” to a debtor in exchange for encumbering his assets under a security agreement.Footnote 41 This lack will certainly yield terrible consequences, ranging from the unenforceability of a security agreement to the exploitation of debtors whose assets would be encumbered with no loan given in return. It should not come as a surprise though that each of these essential requirements for the validity of a security agreement under UCC article 9 has been the subject of extensive litigation over several decades,Footnote 42 and it has been sufficiently settled in a plethora of cases in the USA and elsewhere that the absence of value proceeding from a secured party in a security agreement renders the agreement unenforceable against a debtor's collateral.Footnote 43
Many reasons account for why “value” is indispensably important and why its absence in the Regulation will be colossal, especially to debtors. The first reason is premised on the common law principle of “consideration”, a trite principle of contract law in Nigeria. By this principle, an agreement is unenforceable against the person making a promise until some value has come from the promisee in exchange for the performance of the promise.Footnote 44 Being that a security agreement within the purview of UCC article 9 and the Regulation is a contract, the authors argue that the absence of the requirement for a secured party to give value to a debtor in exchange for encumbering his assets is fundamentally incongruous with the basic principle of the validity of contracts in Nigeria and, to that extent, the Regulation is problematic and promises to be a seedbed for litigation.Footnote 45
Secondly, in all the countriesFootnote 46 that reformed their secured transactions law following UCC article 9 of which the authors are aware, only the Regulation has restricted natural persons from being a secured party under a security agreement; under the Regulation, only banks and financial institutions can become a secured party.Footnote 47 Apart from the curious fact that this restriction prevents Nigerians in equally good positions to advance sales or loan credits from exploiting the Regulation and its collateral registry, there is also the possibility of debtors being grossly exploited by banks whose bargaining position is far stronger than a natural debtor's, especially given the fact that the Regulation has made banks natural monopolists in this regard.Footnote 48 Indeed, a bank-natural debtor relationship in the context of the Regulation is unfortunately comparable to a horse and an ass yoked together. If “value” is not required from banks as a precondition for the validity of a security agreement, the chances are high that banks whose bargaining strength is higher could successfully encumber debtors’ assets without granting them credit to start or expand their businesses, and could validly enforce such agreements. In the authors’ view, if this happens, then the essence of the Regulation, which is to make sufficient and affordable credit available to debtors, becomes grossly defeated.
It must be borne in mind that there is as yet no law in Nigeria that adequately protects consumer debtors from abuses stemming from financial contracts; hence, abuses against consumer debtors by banks and other financial institutions are often neglected for lack of a good legal framework, given that the common law doctrine of “unconscionable terms” appears to be the only defence available to exploited debtors in contractual relations.Footnote 49 Yet, where unconscionable terms are successfully pleaded by a repressed debtor, judges do not often go beyond striking out the problematic term; the Nigerian legal system seems not ready to allow for the award of punitive damages in contracts, as are obtainable in the United States.Footnote 50 Needless to say that the doctrine of freedom of contract has often been used as a counter-defence by banks against the plea of unconscionable terms.Footnote 51
Thirdly, it is argued that, by omitting the giving of value as a precondition for the validity of a security agreement in the Regulation, a secured party could, upon concluding a security agreement with a debtor, validly file a financing statement in the collateral registry to give notice of his security interest in the debtor's collateral without any monetary advance to the debtor. The negative implication of this is that a debtor stranded of cash in this situation is almost practically prevented from seeking alternative funds elsewhere using the same collateral that has already been encumbered. This is unfortunately due to the fact that the approached prospective lenders would probably search the collateral registry to discover the existing security interest of the first creditor and on this basis could refuse to grant credit to the debtor if they desire not to be second ranking with respect to the presented collateral.Footnote 52 In the context of this analysis, it cannot be overemphasized that the Regulation took sides with the stronger party whose enormous strength could cause a situational monopoly, as well as a stranglehold on the debtor; that is, he advances little or no credit at all, and his encumbering security interest wards off other potentially good creditors.
The second defect: Co-existence of floating charge with floating lien – a dilemma in receiver appointment?
The floating charge exists in the Nigerian Companies and Allied Matters Act (CAMA) as a security device that can encumber all of a debtor's present and future acquired property, while simultaneously allowing the debtor to deal with the encumbered assets in the ordinary course of business, until the occurrence of a certain event that causes the floating charge to crystallize.Footnote 53 Admittedly, doing business today, where the bulk of a company's assets is usually locked up in its inventories and other kinds of personal property assets, economic growth would be difficult to realize in the absence of a floating security device, although, in the case of Nigeria, a floating charge can only be created and enforced by corporate persons.Footnote 54 A cursory look at comparative secured transactions law reform shows that virtually all common law countries that inherited the floating charge from England, have transformed it into a floating lien in their reformed secured transactions law.Footnote 55 The reason for this general trajectory is traceable to certain diagnosed weaknesses inherent in the floating charge device.Footnote 56
For instance, attachment of a security interest in the debtor's collateral is postponed until crystallization when the floating chargee's interest becomes fixed and queues behind previously existing fixed secured creditors. Additionally, the fact that the floating charge eventually crystallizes on all of the debtor's property has the possibility of clashing with retained title financing, such as hire purchase and conditional sale transactions into which the floating chargor has entered with a third party.Footnote 57 This no doubt raises the issue of the priority of security interests in the debtor's assets in the event of conflict between the holder of a floating charge and a retained title financer. Regrettably, Nigerian law has not adequately provided mechanisms by which this kind of conflict can be settled.Footnote 58
Notwithstanding the existence of the floating charge in Nigeria, the Regulation introduces the floating lien,Footnote 59 which is basically a fixed charge that permits the debtor to use and dispose of encumbered assets in the ordinary course of business.Footnote 60 In the case of a floating lien, the security interest attaches to the debtor's collateral immediately after the preconditions are met. This means that the scope of assets being encumbered by the floating lien device is known from the beginning. It also means that there will be no interference with title financing devices. This is because all countries that have reformed their secured transactions law following UCC article 9 have adopted the functional approach to secured transaction, which eliminates the possibility of allowing the parties to develop their own agreement to govern their relationship; instead, if a security agreement creates a security interest in the debtor's personal property or fixtures, in exchange for credit, a uniform set of rules, similar to those contained in the Regulation, will apply.
Implications for the coexistence
The authors argue that the coexistence of a floating charge and floating lien in one legal system is a misnomer that yields rather unpleasant consequences.Footnote 61 The fact that the floating charge is contained in CAMA, an act of the National Assembly, means that it supersedes the floating lien that is contained in the Regulation, based on the usual hierarchy of laws.Footnote 62 The improperness of their coexistence could further be appreciated if it is considered that only banks and financial institutions can be secured creditors in the context of the Regulation.Footnote 63 This means that, since a floating charge can be created by any incorporated entity, the possibility of a conflict of priority rights between a bank relying on a security interest arising from a floating lien in the Regulation, and another incorporated entity whose security interest arising from a floating charge has crystallized on all the debtor's property, would usually arise. Considering that a floating charge entitles the holder to appoint a receiver to oust the debtor from managing the asset, and to manage the asset basically in the interests of the appointor, banks and other financial institutions are also the underdogs of the Regulation's defects.Footnote 64
Furthermore, the existence of two, unlinked collateral registries for incorporated entities will not only increase registration and transaction costs,Footnote 65 but also engender ostensible ownership problems in respect of dubious debtors, who may give unsuspecting lenders the impression that the assets that the debtor puts forward as security are unencumbered.Footnote 66 Similarly, a debtor who is in possession of assets following a conditional sale or hire purchase transaction with a natural creditor could possibly use those assets as collateral to obtain loans from a bank. In this case, the bank would have no way of verifying if the collateral already has encumbrances, since the collateral registry is not available for non-bank creditors to register their security interests in a debtor's personal property collateral. This scenario could also apply in the case of non-bank but incorporated creditors who use the Corporate Affairs Commission registries to register charges created on a company's asset(s). In view of this impending disaster in the Nigerian lending industry, the authors argue that a collateral registry whose use is restricted to a class of creditors can only intensify the problem of ostensible ownership, considering that Nigerians still use retention of title financing.
The third defect: The Regulation introduces a one-legged self-help repossession remedy
Why self-help repossession of collateral?
In all countries that have reformed their secured transaction law in line with UCC article 9, self-help repossession of collateral following a debtor's default has always been added to aid a secured party effortlessly to realize the debt owed to him fairly quickly.Footnote 67 There are many reasons why this is commercially sensible, First, certain collateral that is perishable can only be meaningfully utilized to offset debt if it is sold as fast as possible after default, as such collateral is insufficiently durable to last until the conclusion of litigation.Footnote 68 Similarly, as we now live in a world of competing technologies in which the speed with which electronic gadgets and personal property in general is outdated and easily replaced is more heightened than ever before, the lifespan and value of personal property have become more transient. Thus, the absence of a self-help repossessing right in respect of a debtor's collateral after default would probably result in the creditor being left with very outdated and low priced collateral after any protracted litigation, and the need would arise for the creditor to sue the debtor again for any deficient sum.Footnote 69 In fact, without a self-help remedy, credit lenders would be unlikely to accept personal property as collateral due to its ephemeral nature. It goes without saying that the absence of a developed self-help enforcement mechanism has resulted in the demand for real property collateral as a preferred form of security in Nigeria.
Indeed, a right to repossess by self-help grossly reduces the costs of litigation, especially in a slow judicial system like Nigeria's, given the fact that the amount lent or being sought from the debtor might often be less than the cost of litigating that sum. Modern commerce can hardly function well without a secured transactions law that allows the use of a well regulated self-help remedy.Footnote 70 Thus, when recovery through litigation is made only an alternative avenue to recover debts, the chances are high that secured creditors, knowing the high possibility of recovering collateral immediately after default, would give sufficient and affordable credit to debtors, since there would be less need to factor in the costs of potential litigation. This would in turn impact positively on MSMEs, who would to some appreciable extent be relieved from high lending rates. Needless to say that, in aggregate, the reduced lending rates would somehow make their way into the macro strata and be felt in the economy by way of more affordable goods in the market.
Why the Regulation got it wrong with respect to the self-help repossession remedy
According to the Regulation, a secured creditor wanting to repossess a debtor's collateral after default must first give the debtor ten days’ notice.Footnote 71 The authors argue that this is inappropriate because it destroys the element of surprise that is an essential ingredient in any successful repossession of personal property collateral. An examination of most of the countries that have reformed their secured transactions law following UCC article 9 reveals that none has provided a weak version of a self-help repossession right by withholding surprise, which would destroy the level of success in collateral repossessions. Even though the authors do not advocate for a direct transplant of any law or method without ensuring that it is first adapted to suit idiosyncratic factors in Nigeria, they do not see any good reason for the ten day notice and maintain that there are solid reasons why the ten day notice in the Regulation is a mistake and would discourage lenders from giving sufficient and affordable credit to debtors.
A debtor that has been notified about a pending repossession of collateral could easily transfer the collateral out of a court's jurisdiction within the ten day period. Alternatively, he could transfer the collateral to other states in Nigeria and sell it to unsuspecting buyers in market overt, since, according to the Sale of Goods Act, buyers purchasing in a market overt are not bound by any pre-existing security interest on the collateral.Footnote 72 If this happens, the secured party would be stranded and, even when he decides to utilize his equitable right of tracing to trace the collateral, he would incur additional costs, only to compete for title with a bona fide purchaser for value without notice, who has always been the law's “favourite child”.Footnote 73
It is not news that personal property is very difficult to trace in Nigeria; this is evident from the poor success rate of tracing and locating stolen vehicles or other personal property by trained law enforcement agents. If law enforcement agents still find it enormously difficult to trace stolen items in Nigeria due to many debilitating factors,Footnote 74 then the chances are high that secured creditors would suffer several losses in the hands of dubious debtors if the latter are notified in advance about a pending repossession.
The implications of this are glaringly obvious. After one or two bad experiences with dubious debtors, lenders would probably abandon the Regulation and revert to demanding real property collateral that can be easily monitored, and cannot be hidden or transferred out of the jurisdiction even if the debtor is given advance notice of repossession. Thus, advance notice to debtors before repossession would certainly frustrate the entire ambition of the Regulation, which is to provide sufficient and affordable credit to debtors, especially MSMEs. It is on this basis therefore, that the authors argue that the ten day notice is unnecessary and should be removed immediately from the Regulation.
The intersection of secured transactions and insolvency law in Nigeria
The strength of any security interest in property is tested upon the debtor's insolvencyFootnote 75 when various competing claims against the debtor's estate seek to be satisfied; some formula should be devised to determine priority. Thus, even though the subject matter of this article is personal property, suffice it to say that priority of security interests arising from a debtor's personal property are not all that would be determined upon its insolvency; security interests arising from real property and liens by operation of law would also be determined.Footnote 76 Determining the hierarchy of security interests arising from different property claims is not that simple, because, apart from liens arising by operation of law, priority is usually determined by the order in which security interests in property were perfected.Footnote 77 Where perfection methods of security interests differ significantly between personal and real property, the bankruptcy trustee or receiver would find it difficult to resolve priorities, even more so where there is little or no guiding framework.
No insolvency statute in Nigeria to settle priority conflicts of security interests arising from various sources of law
With the coming into force of the Regulation, Nigeria faces a much more complicated situation in the event of the bankruptcy or winding up of a debtor. First, apart from the winding up procedures in CAMA,Footnote 78 there is no robust legal framework like the US Bankruptcy Code of 1978Footnote 79 or the English Insolvency Act of 1986Footnote 80 that exist to deal sufficiently with priority issues of secured claims arising from an insolvent debtor's estate. Secondly, it is interesting to point out that, in the realm of real property transactions in Nigeria, mortgage law is within the competence of both the state and federal governments.Footnote 81 Thus, the Conveyancing Act, 1881Footnote 82 and the various state mortgage lawsFootnote 83 deal with mortgage transactions in Nigeria depending on where the real property is located. Security interests arising from real property mortgage transactions are perfected in the land registry of the state where the real property is located; the various land registries are unlinked, although that poses no problem of ostensible ownership due to the immovable nature of real property.
However, note that, under Nigerian law, a state law is subservient to a federal law in matters of concurrent jurisdictions.Footnote 84 In the absence of a regulating insolvency statute, this poses two problematic questions. First, should security interests arising from the Conveyancing Act trump those from state mortgage laws even if the security interests arising from the latter were perfected first in time? Or should priority be determined among security interests solely on the first to perfect basis, regardless of the source of law from which the security interest arose? While in the US these dilemmas have to a large extent been solved by the Butner principle,Footnote 85 Nigerian law does not currently provide any equivalent or adequate answers. Similarly, the existence of the Regulation poses the same kind of question: where will a secured party whose security interest stems from the Regulation be placed in the hierarchy of security interests? Put more succinctly, how will the security interests arising from these different sources of law with unequal hierarchies be determined in the absence of an insolvency statute that provides a well defined structure of priorities? Certainly, following the hierarchy of laws in Nigeria, the Regulation is subservient to both federal and state laws, and the issue of priority should therefore worry banks and other financial institutions whose security interests would stem from it.
The authors further argue that reform of secured transactions law cannot be achieved in a piecemeal fashion as Nigeria has currently done. Instead, reform should be comprehensive; in other words, a certain harmony must be reached between secured transactions law and insolvency law, given that it is in the latter that priority for all security interests against a debtor's estate is determined.
CONCLUSION
This article has examined the importance of credit in any given economy and the role of secured transactions law in ensuring access to credit. These advantages are not limited to developing economies, as developed economies have undertaken or are at the threshold of undertaking reforms to their secured transaction laws. The article has also shown that the availability of credit to MSMEs in Nigeria has been hampered, not for want of items which may otherwise serve as collateral, but essentially because of the absence of badly needed reforms to her law relating to personal property. Hence the article has not only identified the problems which presently impair the decision to lend, but also highlighted the changes which reform of Nigeria's secured transactions law should embody.
Granted that reform is apropos, the article identifies key problems posed by the choice instrument of “reform” and how it has failed to deal with the existing problems and may even complicate them still further. For the purpose of creating a security interest, the Regulation ignores the requirement that value has to pass from the lender, which lays the borrower open to the danger of a creditor filing a statement when indeed the counterparty has received no credit from the creditor. This is even made worse as the Regulation countenances only banks and financial institutions as the creditors that enjoy its protection. The article also identifies the complications that will arise when the floating lien created by the Regulation is placed side by side with a system that still recognizes and in fact uses the floating charge device. The result of the analysis is that a floating lienee of the Regulation may well be at the mercy of a floating chargee. Furthermore, the article also points to the uncertain judicial attitude to self-help repossession and the notice requirement under the Regulation as combining to make an otherwise important enforcement device a “toothless bulldog”. Finally, it is argued that an insolvency statute which settles priority questions will necessarily be relevant to enable creditors know their fate in insolvency from the outset.
To be clear, the foregoing does not in any way serve to discredit the rather noble intentions that gave rise to this regulatory intervention by the CBN. Rather, it is meant to show that more needs to be done. Going forward, it is hoped that a more robust and holistic reform will be undertaken to provide a PPSL that takes all the foregoing and more into account.