Data, it is said, is the new oil. Treated as a raw material, once processed, once refined, data fuels the new economy. But data also differs from oil in multiple ways. Unlike oil, it is not only non-depletable, it is constantly generated and exponentially growing, which enhances its value. Moreover, unlike oil, data exhaust from transactions is not waste but recycled for further use. And unlike oil, data is non-rivalrous as it can be exploited by multiple users. Yet, despite the differences, the metaphor is powerful not only because data fuels the new economy, but also because data is extracted as raw material (in this case not only from land but from humans), and data is then refined and protected and traded through law as a form of property.Footnote 2 The value of data vastly surpasses that of oil as measured by the capitalization of the world's largest firms.Footnote 3 The only question for companies is how to gather, store, analyze, and deploy data ever more efficiently since data can significantly reduce transaction and production costs.
This article examines the social challenges posed by a data-driven economy, their implications for trade law, the current trade negotiating context, and a way forward that can both enhance trade and regulatory efficacy. The article's normative premise is that countries and the societies that they represent face different contexts and have different normative preferences, such that it is important to develop mechanisms to govern the interface of different regulatory systems and show appropriate deference toward domestic choices. At the same time, institutional mechanisms can facilitate deliberation, learning, and norm development regarding the regulatory choices at stake and their implications.
The article is divided into four sections. Section 1 sets the stage regarding law as a ‘channeling’ tool in the digital economy. Section 2 examines seven critical governance challenges posed by the data-driven economy. Section 3 presents the negotiating context in which three major powers – the United States, European Union, and China – advance different governance models. Section 4 provides a governance framework for moving forward in light of the challenges, a framework that is modest and that foregrounds the importance of building resilience and engaging in problem solving, learning, and adaptation. The proposed framework does not offer a panacea, especially given regulatory uncertainty and legitimate differences in country positions. However, it does put trade negotiations in a broader governance context, noting where commitments in trade agreements are more appropriate and where they need to be subject to regulatory flexibilities. It also notes where these issues should be addressed through other governance mechanisms involving policy frameworks beyond trade liberalization.
1. The Data-Driven Economy and Law
The data-driven economy refers to the collection, aggregation, organization, analysis, exchange, and exploitation of digital information, whether for use in production (such as in ‘smart manufacturing’ and ‘smart agriculture’), the sale of goods and services (such as through electronic commerce), the provision of services (such as through online platforms like Uber), and trade in data as such (whether for advertising, solicitation, or assessment, as for credit ratings).Footnote 4 The data-driven economy is fueled by the data generated from connected devices, which is then used to innovate, produce, operate, and sell responsive machines, goods, and services.Footnote 5 McKinsey estimates that the value of global data flows surpassed that of trade in goods as early as 2014.Footnote 6 Today, such data constitutes a fourth factor of production, in addition to the three traditional ones of land, labor, and capital.Footnote 7
Technology has been and is being developed through the exponential rise in computing power, storage, and bandwidth to exploit data. 5G wireless technology expands capacity, enhances the speed of information flows, reduces latency for near-real time communication, and transforms scalability for new services. Data-trained artificial intelligence (AI) industrializes learning, which increases productivity, reduces costs, and improves logistical services, thus facilitating trade.Footnote 8 Microchips enable powerful computers at our fingertips, generating new data to be processed. ‘Smart’ manufacturing self-automates, trumpeted in Germany as ‘Industry 4.0’ and in the United States as the ‘Industrial Internet’. Linking big data, cloud computing, wireless sensor networks, and automated analytic tools with industrial equipment makes manufacturing more efficient, more precise, and more responsive.Footnote 9 Daily life – from driverless cars to heart monitors and security locks – revolutionize through the so-called Internet of Things.Footnote 10
Many, if not most commentators on trade and technology, are technological optimists since, in basic economic theory, ‘technological progress by definition shifts out the production possibilities frontier’ and thus enhances aggregate social welfare.Footnote 11 Basic trade law and economics casebooks deploy parables that compare trade with technology with a moral that countries should embrace the social welfare benefits of trade.Footnote 12 Even Dani Rodrik, a leading critic of the trade regime for having liberalized too far, has argued that technology is more benign than trade in its distributional effects.Footnote 13
If one is a technology optimist, then our task is less daunting: law should incentivize technology's development and use. Ronald Gilson, writing from Stanford in the nerve center of Silicon Valley, famously called lawyers ‘transaction cost engineers’.Footnote 14 It is lawyers who grease the wheels and driverless cars of innovation – the creative disruptor of not just commerce but our life worlds. It is law and lawyers that construct the intangibles of the data-driven economy, such that data's potential as energy is released.Footnote 15 Because AI systems require huge quantities of updated data to ‘train’ them and to continuously learn, improve, and refine their output, the data-driven economy relies on the free flow of data across borders generated from digitized societies.Footnote 16 Predictions made through AI improve with more data, driving demand. For economic globalization, the ‘free flow of data’ becomes the ‘fifth freedom’ alongside the free movement of goods, services, capital, and labor – the ‘four freedoms’ of the European Union's internal market.Footnote 17
The great contract scholars and rule-of-law theorists stressed law's channeling function.Footnote 18 For the technological optimist, lawyers’ role is to free up data flows so as to release pent-up energy for a leap in efficiency, facilitating the making of responsive, just-in-time products adapted to individual and group desires and needs. The challenge for trade law scholars then is to combat constraints on data flows such as data localization requirements that are proliferating,Footnote 19 and new digital taxes,Footnote 20 constituting a new protectionism impeding progress in the digitalized world. The challenge is to press for inter-operative standards to ensure frictionless flow across borders and combat fragmentation. The dream is a world where small-and-medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) – the Jeffersonian democrats of the marketplace – can compete on a fair footing with the multinational behemoths.Footnote 21 The goal is a terrain where developing country entrepreneurs can better participate and compete because deficiencies of physical infrastructure matter less in a world of hand-held computers and digitalized communications and services.Footnote 22 The vision is a world of affordable products tailored for individual wants produced in an environmentally sustainable way.Footnote 23 With advances such as 3-D printing, we conceivably could live in a more localized society that would, in the words of Richard Baldwin, in his book The Globotics Upheaval, ‘make for a better society’.Footnote 24 Trade lawyers’ role, from this vantage, is to release the potential of microchips, circuits, and smart machines through the free flow of data. If only government representatives could see policy from the individual consumer's perspective and understand the utilitarian benefits of global markets, the neoclassical trade theorist posits, the world would be freer, richer, and more peaceful.
However, if one is not a technology optimist, if one is a pragmatist who believes that there are tradeoffs, if one finds that technology may be unstoppable but there remain choices for governing it, if one is concerned about not just pathologies but pathogens that law can channel, then what channel should governments choose?Footnote 25 In a world of uncertainty, of speculation, amidst the fog of transnational distrust, insecurity, and rivalry, governments face a daunting task.
2. The Challenges Posed
Let us consider seven risks that the technological tsunami of AI could unleash that are both distinct and interrelated. They are the rise of ‘winner-take-all’ companies and social inequality; social control through public and private surveillance; social polarization and risks to democracy; premature deindustrialization implicating development; national security threats and geopolitical rivalry; cybersecurity risks; and threats to personal privacy and dignity. Although technological change offers great societal benefits, it also raises new regulatory challenges for which responses vary depending on societal contexts and preferences. There is thus reason for pause before concluding ambitious trade agreements that free data flows, at least without significant safeguards. This section examines each of these challenges before the following ones address future governance options, including through trade agreements that complement (and defer to) other governance mechanisms.
First, the data-driven economy could spur growing inequality in multiple ways, which, in turn, could trigger the risks discussed below. On the one hand, because of network effects, increasing returns of scale and scope, and the dynamic of first-mover advantage, the data-driven economy increasingly gives rise to winner-take-all – or winner-take-most – companies, such as Amazon for e-commerce, Google for search engines, and Facebook for social networking.Footnote 26 Companies proficiently using AI can serve additional customers globally at little marginal cost at the same time as they enhance quality, enabling the owner of this form of capital to capture unprecedented economic rents.Footnote 27 Unlike traditional industries, scale can be increased without the costs of ‘mass’ because data is weightless; its storage is in the cloud. It thus entails near-zero marginal production costs. From this vantage, the trumpeting of e-commerce in terms of how it will benefit SMEs could be a utopian fantasy.
A data-driven economy not only enables economic behemoths to monopolize, but also enables them to engage in price discrimination so that they price at what each individual consumer is willing to pay. One of the staple arguments for the benefit of markets in neoclassical economics – that of ‘consumer surplus’ – is thus extracted from individuals since companies have the ability to predict what exactly each consumer is willing to pay and charge that amount.Footnote 28 In addition, AI permits companies to engage in cartel-like behavior through reactive, tit-for-tat responses to coordinate prices, once more to extract rents.Footnote 29 As winner-take-most companies reap monopoly, oligopoly, and collusive rents, inequality proliferates (including between high- and low-skilled workers). The trade regime is already under considerable stress. Simply removing trade barriers to data flows could contribute to social conflict within countries unless growing inequality is addressed.
Second, companies and governments gather data through surveillance that can exploit and shape us. The algorithms they use to process our data enable them to know our future and predict what we want and when we want it better than ourselves. Our wired world creates opportunities for enhanced state control through harnessing social pressure, epitomized by the development of ‘social credit’ systems in China.Footnote 30 In parallel, it enables ‘surveillance capitalists’ to steer us toward products to maximize their profits.Footnote 31 Not just our data can be automated, but also us. When social media become constitutive of social participation, we become increasingly numb to companies and governments knowing everything about us, while we know nothing about how and what they know.Footnote 32 We as consumers are consumed. We participate in our commoditization to fuel trading in data to make the commodities that we buy. It is law that helps constitute that relationship, including through protecting company algorithms through property law.Footnote 33 Law could, for example, ban particular algorithmic practices and otherwise require disclosure and monitoring of algorithms so that they can be contested, whether for different forms of bias or for their social consequences.Footnote 34
Third, because of rising inequality within countries and the spread of disinformation that the data-driven economy facilitates, social conflict within countries could rise, undermining democratic systems. Violence looms, threatening national civic and global peace. US President Trump's references to the prospect of ‘civil war’ were he to be impeached,Footnote 35 and his subsequent spouting of disinformation and conspiracy theories and instigation of a mob that ransacked the Capitol, were symptomatic, as were the mass protests of the ‘yellow vest’ movement in France.Footnote 36 Populist leaders harness US and European workers’ lost sense of status from the shift of jobs to China and the East, harnessing nationalist and populist fervor.
As a result, the data revolution has intensified pressures on democracies. To start, the dynamic of increased economic inequality facilitates conditions for decreased social solidarity and increased social conflict, which can erode democracies. More specifically, the data revolution enables others to manipulate our views, including through the proliferation of ‘fake news’ that harnesses predictive power regarding our psychology and behavior.Footnote 37 Tech developed and harnessed by groups such as Cambridge Analytica relentlessly targets individual vulnerabilities and spurs ‘thinking fast’ tribal responses, thus manipulating behavior to win elections and embed leaders in power.Footnote 38 Foreign authoritarian powers can harness these mechanisms, creating ‘vast numbers of fake persons orchestrated by shadowy intelligence warfare units building momentum for online paranoia and conspiracy theories’.Footnote 39 In addition, entrepreneurs can profit by targeting search results from prior preferences, which divides societies into information bubbles, leading to increased social fragmentation and political polarization. While foreign governments target conspiracy theories at vulnerable groups to create social chaos, entrepreneurs do so to profit from ‘clickbait’.Footnote 40 As Larry Diamond documents, anti-democratic politics are spreading globally.Footnote 41 Democracies risk becoming a shell, unless governments, companies, and societies rise to the regulatory challenge.
Fourth, the technological revolution can lead to ‘premature deindustrialization’ of developing countries, possibly trapping them at low-income levels in services sectors, widening the global economic divide by a ‘digital divide’.Footnote 42 Development economists worry about the consequences for development since manufacturing helped make many developing countries, particularly in Asia, richer.Footnote 43 With deindustrialization, smart manufacturing enterprises operate more like software companies, requiring employees to design, program, operate, and debug ‘smart’ machines. That know-how will more likely reside in a few leading countries, with the United States, Europe, China, and a few others vying for leadership, while opportunities for other countries to catch up through industrialization decrease. Smaller developing countries may benefit from free data flows for foreign companies serving their constituents, but they also face foreign monopolists’ economic clout.
Fifth, data and AI pose national security challenges in light of new geopolitical rivalries and conflict, in part because the refined data and technology have dual uses, giving rise to a shift in trade analysis toward geopolitics and ‘geoeconomics’.Footnote 44 This shift places traditional trade liberals, with their analysis of trade's mutual benefits, on the defensive. At the core of the US–China trade war is technology, which will determine the global leaders of tomorrow and whether those leaders are Chinese or American. As part of this competition, China competes with the United States, Europe, and Japan in creating standards for the data-driven economy, such as for 5G infrastructure and the future of manufacturing. The US contestation of China's 2025 innovation initiative, in part, is because China threatens to take the lead in ‘smart manufacturing’ at the cutting edge of technology. Yet, that technology also can be used for military purposes. Sales of Huawei 5G infrastructure, for example, become security concerns not only because they facilitate espionage, but also because a country's economy can be held hostage under the threat of a shutdown of wireless services. Technology can be ‘weaponized’ by withholding key components in a trade war or in an actual conflict.Footnote 45 More broadly, technology is now a key part of geoeconomic rivalry in which economic predominance and technological independence become part of national security. The rise of China threatens US hegemony and, possibly in turn, the stability of the international system to the extent that it depends on one country being dominant, as contended in ‘hegemonic stability theory’.Footnote 46 Given the rivalry of a rising China and a declining United States, scholars now warn of a new ‘Thucydides Trap’ in which the rising power and the incumbent heedlessly and inescapably march toward war.Footnote 47
Sixth, apart from geopolitical rivalry, the technology poses significant systemic concerns regarding risks of system vulnerability, integrity, and availability.Footnote 48 If the 5G network were to shut down without a backup, whether from a terrorist attack or an accident, social chaos could spread, giving rise to a Margaret Atwood MaddAddam dystopia.Footnote 49 Economics, ecology, engineering, and psychology – from their different vantages – all stress the importance of resilience to guard against system collapse,Footnote 50 which the risks of the COVID-19 virus exemplify. The so-called global financial crisis was not in fact global because China and Chinese banks were less ensnared in the market disintegration triggered by the US housing and mortgage-backed securities bubble. Countries could sell their products to China, enabling the global economy to staunch contagion and recover more quickly. Imagine the counterfactual if China's economy had been ‘just like us’ (i.e., US) in 2008, with free capital flows and globally integrated banks, and had crashed as well. Because it differed, there was greater resilience for the global economy, benefitting everyone. This experience holds lessons for the risks posed by a global economy dependent on single technological systems, regardless of whether geoeconomic conflict can be managed.
Seventh, and finally, there are risks to personal privacy and dignity. We have so far stressed societal risks as opposed to individual ones, as the latter have been most frequently addressed in legal scholarship.Footnote 51 Many of these societal risks build on individual ones. Yet, even if societal risks are addressed, the risks to individuals regarding their privacy, dignity, and safety, can be ruinous, whether the individual be coerced by authoritarian governments or privately, such as through social media.Footnote 52
3. The Current Negotiating Context: Three Approaches
Trade negotiations often take a mercantilist orientation where trade negotiators aim to protect domestic industries while opening foreign markets. Through the mechanism of reciprocity, these negotiations, complemented by litigation, have led to greater trade liberalization over time. For those focused on reciprocally opening markets, their starting point is thus no different for data than it is for goods and services – how to free up flows, in this case data flows that are intrinsic to the new data-driven economy. In terms of efficiencies in production, the resulting trade law can reduce transaction costs for businesses and the costs of segmented markets.Footnote 53
Many trade scholars have focused on the lack of fit of current trade rules with developments in the new digital economy.Footnote 54 The same applies to international law more generally,Footnote 55 rendering the challenges for trade law even greater. Given that WTO rules were negotiated over a quarter of a century ago before the Internet existed, scholars naturally conclude that trade rules must be updated. WTO rules still address primarily goods, a legacy of the 1948 GATT, an era where industrial manufacturing represented the commanding heights of the economy. In 1995, with the creation of the WTO and its inclusion of a General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), the trade regime partially and indirectly addressed services that are linked to the digital economy, as well as technical regulations affecting trade in goods.Footnote 56 But that too was a quarter of a century ago and technology has changed radically. Today services constitute the largest and fastest growing part of the global economy in terms of output, value added, and employment.Footnote 57 The GATS only rudimentarily addresses digital issues where the line between a ‘good’ and a ‘service’ blurs and could eventually disappear.Footnote 58 Not only are an increasing number of goods now inextricably linked with ‘services’ (the Internet of Things), but know-how and data have become the most valuable components of trade across borders.Footnote 59
While WTO negotiations have failed to fill key regulatory gaps for digital trade, countries have negotiated bilateral and plurilateral trade agreements to instill their priorities and values into standards for the digital economy. Trade negotiations reflect competition between systems, since countries’ positions reflect their internal policies. One can broadly speak of three distinct approaches for digital governance advanced by the WTO's three most powerful members – the United States, the European Union (EU), and China.Footnote 60
The United States has trumpeted a world of free ‘data flows’ that would benefit its companies.Footnote 61 The United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA), which entered into force on 1 July 2020, illustrates the US approach.Footnote 62 Chapter 19 of the agreement is on ‘Digital Trade’, and it represents the first time that a trade agreement has a chapter with such a title. Although this change is, in part, semantic since the chapter borrows significantly from chapter 14 of the earlier Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) agreement on ‘Electronic Commerce’, the title signifies a concern broader than trade in goods, and the chapter indeed further tightens rules in favor of US technology companies. It includes provisions mandating free movement of data, a permanent moratorium on customs duties, and bans on data localization requirements, forced disclosure of source codes, and other forced technology transfers. It also includes a new provision providing that internet platforms should not be held civilly liable for their user's actions, and is modeled after section 230 of the US Communications Decency Act.Footnote 63
Although the European Union has advanced liberalization objectives, it imposes significant restraints on the free flow of data on privacy grounds. The EU's position is reflected in its General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR), together with EU judicial oversight of its negotiation of ‘adequacy decisions’ with third countries, such as through ‘safe harbors’ and ‘privacy shields’, in order for data on European citizens to leave the continent. On 16 July 2020, the European Court of Justice invalidated the US–EU Privacy Shield because it provides inadequate protection to EU citizens’ privacy from surveillance, just as the court had in October 2015 as regards the previous US–EU ‘Safe Harbor Privacy Principles’.Footnote 64 Because the European Union lacks leading digital firms, it is politically easier for it to champion such regulation.Footnote 65
China, in contrast, applies ‘data localization’ requirements on sovereignty grounds, rather than the protection of citizen rights. In this way, the Chinese state and private Chinese companies control data over China's 1.4 billion citizens, facilitating social control while creating a competitive advantage for Chinese enterprises.Footnote 66 By requiring data localization, China limited access to Chinese nationals' data to Chinese companies, which provided them with huge advantages in the winner-take-most digital economy because of the size of China's population. A result was the rise of Chinese information technology titans such as Alibaba and Tencent.
Other countries choose among these three approaches, although those ‘choices’ occur within negotiating contexts that can involve highly asymmetric power. In this way, these different approaches are adopted around the globe. Japan has adopted the US model, as reflected in the 2019 US–Japan Trade Agreement.Footnote 67 Australia and Canada have hybrid approaches that include stronger data privacy protection as under the EU model, while India, Indonesia, and Brazil, envious of Chinese internet companies’ fortunes, are enticed by China's requirements of data localization to create national champions.Footnote 68
The questions arise: will these competing systems converge and, if not, how will they interface? It is conceivable that the United States and European Union could negotiate a further compromise in which the United States adopts EU-style privacy protections, and the European Union assures free data flows. Although the European Union will periodically challenge US tech giants, it is less likely to develop its own. Nonetheless, the European Union generally favors a single market for data flows, subject to adequate privacy and consumer protection. The United States and China, however, are less likely to negotiate a compromise (unless it includes significant carve outs on national security and other public policy grounds), given the advantages for China of requiring data localization so that foreign companies do not gain access to the Chinese data trove. India will likely follow this route.Footnote 69 Economic behemoths from just a few countries could dominate the globe. From an economics perspective, the global market will not be based on perfect competition reflected in neoclassical models, but rather ‘strategic trade’ in which a few countries compete to support national champions that reap oligopolistic and monopolistic profits, potentially having positive spillover effects for their national economies.
4. Governance Framework for a Way Forward
Although the challenges are severe, if they are to be met, law must play a critical role nationally, internationally, and transnationally. This section provides a framework for addressing the challenges posed. It places trade law in a broader regulatory context that involves competing ways to frame the ‘problem’ to be addressed in a world characterized by uncertainty and rapid technological change.Footnote 70 It then briefly applies the framework to particular issues.
Addressing the challenges requires regulation. Three key issues are: (i) how should the ‘problem’ be framed; (ii) at what level should regulation occur; and (iii) what form and content should such regulation take. First, different stakeholders, policymakers, and analysts will frame a policy challenge in different ways, involving diagnostic struggles over the ‘problem’ that legal norms are to address, such as trade protectionism, national security, economic resilience, or individual privacy. Second, the ensuing regulation to address the problem can occur at multiple levels, from local and national to international levels of political organization. Third, the regulation also can take different forms, involving hard and soft law developed by public and private bodies. Moreover, regulation in any one country will have impacts on constituencies outside that country, so that countries have incentives to address these externalities. In parallel, common problems may require regulatory coordination and cooperation among countries to address them effectively. The key questions, in sum, are: (i) in which regulatory arena does the ‘problem’ predominantly lie; (ii) what regulation, if any, should occur at the international level and how should it interface with national regulation; and (iii) what forms and processes should such regulation take, and how should these forms and processes interact.
4.1 Three Principles
To determine a framework for governance of the respective challenges, we start with three general principles. First, trade agreements should be viewed as part of a broader ecology of governance of the new data-driven economy, which creates links between different rulemaking and monitoring bodies at different levels of social organization. Second, for most of the issues raised in Section 2, there should be no single system of hierarchical rules. Rather, in a world of radical uncertainty and different preferences regarding the regulation of these issues, countries will benefit from experimentation with different regulatory approaches. A diversity of regulatory approaches provides greater resilience against the systemic risks posed when single systems fail. Trade agreements thus should ensure flexibility for countries to address the complex regulatory issues at stake. Third, given the transnational impacts of the risks, as well as of national regulation addressing (or failing to address) them, there is a need for systems of regulatory coordination over options and experiences that can facilitate trade while enhancing regulatory efficacy, learning, and adaptation. Once one turns to issues of coordination and the interface of different national regulatory systems, one is in a world of transnational legal ordering that is not just top-down but also bottom-up, horizontal, and transversal.
Elsewhere I have developed a theory of transnational legal orders with the sociologist Terence Halliday.Footnote 71 That approach focuses on how problems are framed, how hard and soft law norms develop transnationally in response to such framings, and how norms settle and unsettle as part of recursive processes of interaction between different levels of social organization, from the international to the national and local. That framework has been predominantly positivist in its approach, aimed at generating empirical research for how legal norms develop, diffuse, and change transnationally.
Such an approach, however, also has normative payoffs when combined with what has been called new governance theory regarding systems of adaptive regulation in light of uncertainty involving changing problems and regulatory contexts. New governance theory, when applied transnationally, emphasizes the need for the development of transnational institutional structures for regulation comprised of a common forum for deliberation, principles to guide discussions, an open menu of options for addressing regulatory choices, and peer review and information sharing to enhance trust and learning.Footnote 72 Through such structured processes of regulatory dialogue, both hard and soft international law norms can develop, while policy differences can be debated, justified, and transparently explained.Footnote 73 The question becomes: can trade law help to facilitate and channel these processes?
Under a new governance approach, countries jointly create regulatory goals and measures to gauge achievement and permit variation in how regulatory agencies pursue the attainment of these goals. These agencies then report to each other and participate in peer review processes regarding regulatory outcomes, aimed at continual improvement and potential reassessment of goals in light of experience.Footnote 74 This approach, in the pragmatist tradition, entails ongoing mutual scrutiny of outcomes and their effectiveness based on continuous information exchange by regulators committed to regulatory improvement and attentive to risk, including potentially catastrophic risks. Under this approach, regulators exchange information, conduct joint trials and risk assessments, monitor results, and adapt regulatory practices.Footnote 75 Transparency is central to this model through processes of information sharing, peer review, questioning, and response. Through regulatory learning, norms and practices can recursively change.
At the global level, Charles Sabel and Bernard Hoekman note the possibility of open plurilateral trade agreements that core groups of countries initially would join to develop such a regulatory approach, and which others could enter subsequently.Footnote 76 In June 2020, Chile, New Zealand, and Singapore signed a Digital Economy Partnership Agreement that aims to develop mechanisms that build trust in data flows, and which is open for other parties to join.Footnote 77 More broadly, the United States and European Union discussed the development of new transatlantic regulatory mechanisms in their negotiations to create a Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership.Footnote 78 The European Union proposed the creation of a new transatlantic body, called a Regulatory Cooperation Body, to support specific regulatory cooperation initiatives and oversee them. Hoekman noted how other institutions, including private ones, could complement it in particular regulatory domains.Footnote 79 Through ongoing interactions, national regulators eventually could recognize each other's regulations as functionally equivalent, facilitating trade. These programs could lead to the institutionalization of broader sectoral frameworks, giving rise to cooperative regulatory systems that reduce barriers to trade while enhancing regulatory responsiveness in an increased number of domains. Food safety is one area where such a system has been applied transnationally.Footnote 80 The governance challenges posed by the digital economy beckons for new institutional initiatives in this vein.
New governance theory is particularly useful in a world of radical regulatory uncertainty. Given the risks, uncertainties, and differences in values, interests, and priorities, international trade law must not foreclose experimentation and variance. Yet, given these very same risks, uncertainties, and differences, international trade law and institutions are needed to foster cooperation, deliberation, and exchange of ideas. International trade law must foster transnational engagement, while not foreclosing regulatory policy space to engage with the challenges posed. Seeking and adjusting the ‘right’ balance between coordination, harmonization, and experimentation will be an ongoing challenge. Policy harmonization should not necessarily result. Countries inevitably will have different regulatory preferences, and these preferences, when not clearly discriminatory, should be respected. Nonetheless, such processes, at a minimum, can spur greater policy transparency regarding data regulation, and require reasoned justification of policy choices. Depending on the issue area, these processes can be used as alternatives or complements to hard-law requirements and judicial review in trade agreements.Footnote 81
4.2 Electronic Commerce
Among the issues that this article addresses, it is most appropriate for a trade agreement to work to facilitate trade in goods and services through electronic means. Traditional trade law frames of trade facilitation and non-discrimination apply and can be adopted at the international level through binding rules. Nonetheless, in this area too, a WTO agreement may be most achievable if it adopts a decentralized model that accommodates regulatory flexibility in which countries of varying levels of development have different implementation periods conditioned on regulatory capacity building and technical assistance. The WTO's 2017 WTO Trade Facilitation Agreement offers a model of how this can be done.Footnote 82 The Trade Facilitation Agreement provides for flexibility in relation to a country's level of development, and it facilitates provision of technical assistance and resources for developing countries to adapt their regulatory systems.
A new digital trade agreement could have a similar structure, in this case organized to accommodate not only countries at different levels of development, but also to support the interface and interoperability of different regulatory systems that reflect varying national practices and preferences.Footnote 83 For example, it could facilitate agreement on digital norms to ensure the validity of contracts, recognition of electronic authorizations and signatures, protection against fraudulent practices, and the banning of unsolicited commercial messages. In this way, parties would commit both to foster consumer trust by protecting information and preventing fraud, and to cooperate to tackle transnational problems, such as spam generated from abroad.Footnote 84 Developing country adherence to them, however, would be subject to the receipt of technical and financial assistance, as under the Trade Facilitation Agreement.
These norms could be negotiated and developed in conjunction with other venues as part of a broader ecology of transnational and global governance. For example, the United Nations Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL), the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), and the G20, each have ongoing programs to develop, share, assess, and provide capacity building for the adoption of e-commerce regulations.Footnote 85 Though developed elsewhere, the norms could be incorporated by reference into the trade agreement and be updated over time. In terms of the international norms’ relation to national regulation, they could constitute minimum standards, while permitting countries to deviate from them on legitimate regulatory grounds.
There is precedent for this approach in WTO and other trade agreements. Within the WTO, the Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Standards references standards developed by Codex Alimentarius and other standard-setting bodies, and the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade references international standards more generally, including those developed in the International Organization for Standardization (ISO). More directly, in the EU–Canada agreement known as CETA (Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement), the parties agree that they ‘shall take into due consideration international standards of data protection of relevant international organizations of which both Parties are members’.Footnote 86 In each case, they permit parties to apply more stringent standards for legitimate regulatory reasons.
Such an agreement also could include provisions that are standard in trade agreements. It could require non-discrimination between domestic and foreign digital products, potentially subject to negotiated product and sectoral carve outs, as well as general exceptions on regulatory policy grounds, including national security. It could incorporate basic due process commitments, including the right to be heard and to receive reasoned justifications before administrative and judicial processes.
Going further, the agreement could address (and either ban or otherwise limit) customs duties on electronic transmissions. It could likewise cover the use of digital taxes, possibly, once more, by reference to standards developed elsewhere, whether in the OECD (where discussions have been highly contentious) or otherwise.Footnote 87 It also could clarify and enhance parties’ market access commitments to services that affect digital trade, which is currently being negotiated in the form of a Trade in Services Agreement on a plurilateral basis among a subset of 23 WTO members, including the United States and European Union.Footnote 88 The agreement would need to ensure that developing countries would benefit (such as through revenue collection), as well as enterprises within them, especially given the challenges posed by deindustrialization. Many developing countries are wary of liberalization of digital trade, including the banning of customs duties on electronic transmissions, fearing they will lose revenue and competitiveness.Footnote 89 These distributional concerns need to be addressed, including through partnering with other international organizations focused on economic development to ensure that the agreement would benefit all countries, including possibly through transnational reporting requirements and revenue transfer mechanisms.
A particularly challenging issue is the regulation of ‘data localization’ requirements. On the one hand, they are analogous to export bans, which are prohibited under GATT article XI. On the other hand, they vary in terms of the policy rationale supporting them. Some policy rationales, such as data privacy protection, do not have a discriminatory intent and are legitimate. Other policy rationales take an arguably illegitimate ‘beggar-thy-neighbor’ approach, aiming to privilege domestic producers over foreign ones. However, even here, the analysis is complicated given the winner-take-all nature of digital companies, and the first-mover advantage of US multinational behemoths; thus, the regulation does not involve competitive markets (as modeled in neoclassical economics), but rather oligopolistic ones involving strategic trade concerns.
Where countries want greater constraints on data-related regulation, such as prohibiting data localization and source code transfers, they can address them in bilateral and regional agreements. There is a potential for greater convergence in this area, as even the United States, for example, wishes to retain authority to access source codes to guard against money laundering and the evasion of economic sanctions, and has become more concerned about Chinese and other foreign access to the data of US citizens.Footnote 90 China, in parallel, has agreed in the 2020 Regional Comprehensive and Economic Partnership that it will not require businesses to ‘locate computing facilities’ in its territory or restrict ‘cross-border transfer of information by electronic means’ for business purposes, but subject to national security and public policy exceptions that may not be judicially reviewed under the agreement's dispute settlement mechanism.Footnote 91 Such bilateral and plurilateral trade agreements can serve as learning laboratories for the development and application of norms.
Such an agreement also could include (or be complemented by) an ongoing new governance, soft law component addressing national regulation. It could require regulatory transparency and create a framework for regulators, standard setters, and commercial enterprises to engage with and learn from each other to address the uncertainties that new technologies pose and share information through peer-to-peer processes.Footnote 92 WTO committee and working group processes offer one means.Footnote 93 A WTO committee also could work in coordination with other international organizations and standard-setting bodies where the primary regulatory peer review could be done. That body then could report to the WTO committee.
4.3 National Security, Cybersecurity, and Resilience
To turn to the other challenges raised in Section 2, they will be more difficult since the framing of the problem involves much more than ‘trade protectionism’ and ‘trade facilitation’. For example, concerns over resilience to cybersecurity risks represent a critical reason why a very ‘ambitious’ trade agreement that does not provide for regulatory flexibility would be problematic at this stage. Governments must be free to regulate and require different standards, product controls, and even product bans, on security grounds to ensure resilience. States and companies will need to develop backup, modular, and exit systems involving redundant and diverse infrastructure that is adaptive to 5G communications and other breakdowns.Footnote 94 It is a critical question for engineering and for regulatory policy. There are always tradeoffs in product performance and costs, on the one hand, and security, on the other. But here it is not a question of simple market failure and ‘second best’ government intervention to ‘correct’ it. Rather, the risks can be catastrophic. Regulation of these concerns should thus be left predominantly at the national level, addressed primarily by security and not trade law professionals.
The current GATT article XXI exception on national security grounds was not drafted with cybersecurity concerns at stake and it will need to be updated to address cyber threats and the appropriate deference to be given to national policy decisions.Footnote 95 The GATT article currently refers to ‘action … taken at time of war or other emergency in international relations’. National cybersecurity precautions do not neatly fall within this text.Footnote 96 The text accordingly should be expanded to grant governments greater flexibility to define their security policies in relation to new threats (beyond immediate ‘emergencies’), while remaining subject to oversight through peer-review mechanisms and (possibly) judicial application of proportionality analysis on a deferential basis. For example, article 17.13 of the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership now includes measures ‘taken so as to protect critical public infrastructure, including communications, power, and water infrastructures’ under the list of legitimate national security concerns.Footnote 97
The bulk of such regulatory efforts must be national where regulators and politicians are most easily held to account. Nonetheless, given the externalities of one country's regulations on others and given reciprocal regulatory concerns, there is a role for transnational regulatory architectures where countries adopting different economic models, holding different preferences, and advancing different interests can cooperate. That calls, on the one hand, for the retention of policy space, including the development of ‘regulatory sandboxes’ to keep up with a rapidly changing digital world in which diverse countries may gain regulatory experience and develop alternative regulatory models.Footnote 98 On the other hand, it calls for the development of new oversight and peer-review mechanisms, together with standard-setting, possibly on a voluntary, soft-law basis. Such standard setting and oversight can be allocated between the International Organization for Standardization, the International Electrotechnical Commission, the WTO, and other organizations, catalyzing interlinked networks of institutional oversight and peer review to foster policy learning, cooperation, and coordination.
In a world of increasing geoeconomic competition and accompanying national security concerns, there are limits to what trade agreements can accomplish. Because technological shifts give rise to automated and wirelessly connected products that are vulnerable to hacking, trade in such products acquires a greater security dimension. The US blacklisting of Huawei and other Chinese companies, the banning of the use of Huawei's 5G technology for their wireless networks by Australia, Japan, New Zealand, and the United Kingdom, and continental Europe's internal debates, exemplify the concerns. In this area, the 2017 US national security plan declares, ‘economic security is national security’.Footnote 99
If the invocation of national security becomes generalized, there is a risk that trade wars and the decline of the rule of law for trade could follow.Footnote 100 In response, trade law can be structured to alleviate some of these concerns by facilitating international coordination and oversight of domestic processes. The trade agreement could require the implementation of domestic due process mechanisms, such as the requiring of a risk assessment, the giving of reasons, and an opportunity for affected parties to be heard.Footnote 101 The application of these provisions could then be subject to peer review mechanisms, possibly coupled with minimal, process-oriented judicial review.Footnote 102
Rising US concerns over national security suggest that the US position is shifting toward more expansive exceptions to free data flow commitments.Footnote 103 This shift potentially could facilitate agreement, provided the exceptions are broad enough to encompass privacy and public order interests advanced by the European Union, China, and others, while providing for some international oversight. The approach set forth in this article does not offer a panacea, but it is vastly preferable to the current situation in which trust that underpins a cooperative international trade legal order is eroding.
4.4 Data Privacy
As regards data privacy regulation, countries’ approaches again will diverge based on different preferences, and thus regulation should again predominately take place at the national level. Nonetheless, structures can be developed where countries discuss their common concerns, develop soft and hard law principles and standards, and work to free data flows so long as core concerns are met. The European Court of Justice's invalidation of the US–EU Privacy Shield, while upholding the validity of the EU's ‘standard contractual clauses’ for data transfers, illustrates the challenges posed.Footnote 104 Bilateral negotiations, complemented by the development of common international principles and standards together with ongoing judicial oversight, present a path forward.
In practice, jurisdictional conflicts, including the assertion of de facto or de jure extraterritorial jurisdictional power, must be managed continuously.Footnote 105 In these cases, a key challenge for all countries will be how to protect individual information in a world where AI increasingly can identify individuals even when data is processed to be anonymized and deemed ‘non-personal’.Footnote 106 Given the transnational implications of any policy, and given the role of companies in governing data usage, there is a need for not only governments to develop rules, but also for domestic and transnational civil society organizations to be incorporated within governance mechanisms to engage with governments and corporations.Footnote 107 The WTO traditionally has only engaged with civil society organizations through such processes as its annual Public Forums, while leaving most engagement to domestic processes. In this way, the WTO differs from other international organizations, and it potentially could do more to develop new means of interaction with the WTO secretariat and member representatives.Footnote 108 Structures can be developed outside the WTO for such engagement on privacy issues, involving information exchange, peer review, and norm development to address privacy concerns. But the WTO committee system also can be engaged in coordination with such other international bodies.
4.5 Competition Law
The critical issue of competition policy for the digital economy falls outside the expertise of trade professionals, but it has serious trade implications.Footnote 109 Policymakers are reevaluating competition policy in response to digitalization and the data-driven economy.Footnote 110 Policy options include regulating property rights in data,Footnote 111 blocking oligopolists’ expansion through acquisitions that preempt competition, breaking up companies, and regulating oligopolists like utilities or fiduciaries. For example, some propose granting competitive access to data to alleviate consumer ‘switching costs’ of moving from one platform to another, which otherwise locks in consumers.Footnote 112 There is considerable debate regarding these options.Footnote 113
Winner-take-most companies profit globally through trade, raising tensions between the companies’ home countries and third countries regulating them, as in the case of the European Union investigating the practices of US data-exploiting multinational companies such as Google.Footnote 114 Countries deploying competition law to discipline foreign companies will thus continue to trigger trade conflicts,Footnote 115 creating an important role for international oversight. Given significant divisions on competition policy, especially between the United States and European Union, and given divisions in economic theory, including in relation to the diversity of social contexts that different countries face, it will be difficult to address this issue in a trade agreement. Nonetheless, the issue calls for dialogue and regulatory response at the international level, including within the International Competition Network (ICN), the OECD, and UNCTAD. Although the OECD has organized a series of sessions on these issues and the ICN spent its annual meeting in 2019 at Cartagena addressing them, much more work needs to be done regarding the competition law challenges that digitalization poses.Footnote 116 The WTO created a Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition Policy in 1996, but it became inactive in 2004. Given the importance of competition policy in the regulation of the digital economy and its implication for trade, a WTO committee or working group should follow these issues, especially since the issues are being addressed in other bilateral and plurilateral trade agreements.Footnote 117
4.6 Inequality
Not to be forgotten, societies face rising inequality that the data-driven economy exacerbates. Like trade in goods, free flow of data enhances efficiency and thus welfare gains, but also facilitates economic processes that exacerbate inequality in ways that can threaten social stability and international cooperation. Liberalization of data flows should not be addressed without complementary social policies. For conventional trade theorists, social equality and trade adjustment assistance should be left entirely to the national level. Many reference Scandinavian social welfare and job flexicurity policies to show how this can be done.Footnote 118
These commentators are right, to an extent, in that such regulatory power should reside predominantly at the national level, which is most democratically legitimate. However, trade agreements can facilitate (or impede) governments’ ability to address social inclusion policies, and thus there is an inevitable link to governance at the international level.Footnote 119 At a minimum, trade agreements should not directly or indirectly constrain governments from adopting necessary policies domestically. They must accommodate (and not foreclose) mechanisms that enable states to address social concerns implicated by the digital economy.Footnote 120 For example, agreements should address tax evasion and tax avoidance so that governments can fund social welfare and job flexicurity policies.Footnote 121 These agreements should be developed primarily outside of the WTO. However, since these policies implicate trade, trade liberalization initiatives for the digital economy could be made contingent on their conclusion. Similarly, trade agreements could explicitly recognize the ability of countries to address social dumping concerns, as most recently developed in the United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement.Footnote 122 Otherwise, the economic dynamics of trade liberalization in the digital economy could further increase inequality, undercut domestic solidarity, and, in turn, empower nativist and politically populist domestic movements that undermine international cooperation and good will, as well as national democratic systems.
5. Conclusion
The world needs international institutions to enhance international deliberation, cooperation, and exchange, but international institutions must be careful not to overreach. Normatively, there are efficiency and fairness reasons for agreements to accommodate policy space so that governments may respond effectively to different preferences and priorities. Politically, when international trade law overreaches, it can spur populist backlash so that the system unravels.
The challenges raised in section 2 will not be resolved through a traditional trade agreement alone. The data-driven economy is developing at a rapid pace for which governments lack regulatory experience. Given the risks – ranging from risks to cybersecurity, national security, democratic institutions, and personal privacy – trade negotiators should proceed with caution and humility. Most of the issues raised are not clearly protectionist, as with tariffs, but rather entail regulation addressing diverse public policy concerns. While one of the purposes of international trade agreements is for national political bodies to ‘tie themselves to the mast’ to avoid the siren call of protectionism,Footnote 123 this rationale is inapt when applied to non-discriminatory regulation. Democracies should be able to elect leaders that change orientation regarding the appropriate mix of free data flow and regulation to protect security, privacy, and other legitimate concerns. Trade agreements constraining their ability to do so curtail democracy. Because governments weigh tradeoffs regarding the balance between free data flow and other policies in different ways, each country should be free to change its mind. International trade law should not foreclose these domestic debates and choices.
At the same time, governance mechanisms are needed in an interdependent world to address common challenges and the externalities that one country's regulations pose for others. Governments should be required to provide equal treatment and due process to affected foreigners domestically, and to provide public policy justifications for the regulations they adopt before transnational peer-review and other mechanisms. Section 4 advanced a pragmatist, transnational governance architecture focused on regulatory cooperation and learning as an essential complement and alternative to WTO ‘hard’ rules backed by dispute settlement. This form of international governance can interact with national regulation in ways that both enhance trade, with its accompanying welfare benefits, and regulatory efficacy, learning, and adaptation. It is not a panacea, but it is the best way for trade law and institutions to work in combination with other governance organizations and networks to address the multiple challenges raised by the data-driven economy.
The approach set forth in this article differs significantly from the ‘grand bargains’ that characterized the creation of the WTO. It is much humbler, grounded in the uncertainty that characterizes the emerging digital world and what it means for societies and individuals. Trade agreements should approach the issues with caution, focused first on traditional matters such as bindings on tariffs and non-discriminatory behind-the-border taxes. Regulation should be left predominantly at the national level, while recognizing common standards in some areas to facilitate trade in goods and services (such as regarding electronic signatures and authorizations), coupled with structures that catalyze experimentation and exchange of knowledge and practices regarding the challenges that all societies will continue to face and to which they must respond. These processes can facilitate learning and, possibly but not necessarily, convergence over time.
There are admittedly clear limits to this approach. Commercial interests and countries will contend that there is certainty regarding ‘best’ policies and they will attempt to use leverage and persuasion to extend these policies globally. ‘Learning’ is difficult to facilitate where interests have strong incentives to think otherwise. Yet, even then, such processes will make differences more transparent, while still leaving open the possibility of learning from experience that, potentially, can lead to policy adaptation.
The future can be governed in worse ways or better. Law at the international and national levels and their transnational interaction will help constitute that world. In the face of uncertainty, there is a critical need for agonistic deliberation, debate, and policy experimentation. Karl Polanyi in his book The Great Transformation described what occurred when governments lost control of unleashed markets in the first half of the last century.Footnote 124 We know how that ended. With the data revolution and the rise of AI, the risks are high. The choices societies make today will shape which science fiction remains fiction. It is a brave new world. A future will arrive that we have yet to imagine, but that (hopefully) we can muddle through.