We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Joan Costa-Font, London School of Economics and Political Science,Tony Hockley, London School of Economics and Political Science,Caroline Rudisill, University of South Carolina
This chapter provides an introduction to behavioural health economics. Far from attempting to replace what we know about health economics as a discipline, behavioural health economics aims at complementing its foundations by relaxing some of its core assumptions. This implies taking a more ‘realistic depiction’ of individual motivation even though it makes it more complex work beyond simple mathematical formulation. By incorporating what are otherwise anomalies of rational decision-making (defined as purposeful decision-making), health economics can go the extra mile with this extended toolkit which we define as behavioural health economics. Our agent is constrained by the social norms of its place and suffers from status quo bias and endowment effects that introduce bias into making decision and evaluations. ‘Real individuals’ care about others and have social preferences with regard to other people’s well-being, and often suffer from self-control problems, where impulsivity and emotion translate into suffering from a specific form of short sightedness otherwise known as ‘present bias’). These problems are arguably more prominent in the health domain. Market price is not the only relevant variable guiding behaviour in health and health care, where insurance is the most common form of payment, and tangible monetary incentives are often not made salient to influence behaviour.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.