In March 2011, international news outlets reported that internal security spending in China had, for the first time, surpassed external defence expenditure.Footnote 1 Double-digit increases in spending had pushed the domestic security budget upward at an exponential rate, as shown in Figure 1, and the internal security budget remained higher than the defence budget for several subsequent years (see Table 1).
Table 1: China's External Defence and Internal Security Spending, 2010–2013
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_tab1.gif?pub-status=live)
Sources: “Quanguo gonggong caizheng zhichu juesuan biao” (National public expenditure final account tables), published by the Ministry of Finance at: http://yss.mof.gov.cn/2010juesuan/201107/t20110720_578444.html; http://yss.mof.gov.cn/2011qgczjs/201207/t20120710_665233.html; http://yss.mof.gov.cn/2012qhczjs/201307/t20130715_966261.html; http://yss.mof.gov.cn/2013qgczjs/201407/t20140711_1111874.html.
Notes: In 2014 and 2015, the Chinese government declined to release the total amount spent on internal security. All US$ estimates adjusted based on 2013 annual average exchange rates.
Since then, domestic security has occupied a prominent place in public and academic discussions of Chinese politics and society, and the domestic security budget is a frequent point of reference.Footnote 2 But how should observers interpret this apparently astonishing growth? Journalists commonly suggest that China's leaders are raising spending in an unprecedented fashion to address heightened insecurity and as part of an increasing emphasis on “stability maintenance” (weihu wending 维护稳定, or, weiwen 维稳) in official discourse and behaviour.Footnote 3 Academic literature, however, has taken a different tack, citing spending increases as evidence of the “strong coercive capacity” of the Chinese state following a “dramatic expansion” in that capacity since the early 1990s.Footnote 4
This article demonstrates that neither of these perspectives is entirely correct, in large part because both rest on an overly simplistic idea of what “coercive capacity” means and because they selectively employ indicators that are not a good match for the concept. In the pages that follow, I seek to clarify the discussion on China's internal security spending in order to shed light on the role of coercive capacity in China's authoritarian stability. This is done in two ways: first by carefully defining coercive capacity, and then by using new theoretically derived indicators, placed in appropriate comparative perspective, to provide a re-assessment of China's coercive capacity.Footnote 5
The revised analysis of China's domestic security budget demonstrates that conventional wisdom exaggerates the exceptional and unprecedented nature of China's increases in spending on domestic security. The Chinese Communist Party (CCP) has indeed attempted to strengthen its coercive capacity, but it is probably doing so because it perceives that capacity to be inadequate for managing China's rapidly changing society. In other words, budget trends in the last two decades likely indicate the weakness and limitation of CCP coercive capacity during this period, not its strength.
This article proceeds in four sections. The second section establishes the importance of coercive capacity, outlines the current lack of clarity in its theorization and measurement, and offers a theoretically guided redefinition of the concept and some suggestions for better measurement. The third section offers a revised analysis of China's domestic security spending, based on the reconceptualization offered in section two. The fourth section concludes by discussing the implications of this analysis for current developments. It discusses how the framework proposed here may usefully illuminate China's internal security behaviour in recent years, including the reorganization of domestic security forces, the creation of new national security legislation, and the tightening of control over Chinese society under Xi Jinping's 习近平 leadership.
Assessing China's Coercive Capacity
Coercive capacity has long been recognized as a critical component of authoritarian stability.Footnote 6 Few studies, however, examine how that capacity is generated and sustained, or assess the relative importance of the budget in that process. This section asks: what is coercive capacity and how should it be measured? More specifically, it discusses how internal security expenditures are related (or not) to coercive capacity, both generally and in the China case.
The China field is divided on these questions. The dominant interpretation suggests that since 1989, China has been undergoing a long-term process of “securitization” (of which weiwen is the most recent manifestation) that has strengthened the regime's coercive capacity.Footnote 7 This explanation points to increased spending on the coercive apparatus as a major piece of evidence for its claims.Footnote 8 Even works that are normatively critical of the increased spending interpret it as an indication of rising coercive capacity.Footnote 9
A few Chinese-language studies, however, adopt a more sceptical tone, noting that the 1994 fiscal reforms exacerbated local budget problems even in the context of increased overall spending. They argue that the Ministry of Public Security's (MPS) frontline officers often have inadequate resources for the tasks they are expected to perform.Footnote 10 Articles in China's public security journals commonly discuss how to deal with the negative consequences of budgetary shortfallsFootnote 11 and how to maximize efficiency, given limited resources.Footnote 12 These complaints are not necessarily to be taken at face value – under-resourcing is, after all, a perennial complaint of bureaucrats the world over – but neither should they be dismissed out of hand. Instead, this article looks at the disjuncture between these two perspectives and asks: what is China's coercive capacity? To answer that question, it is necessary to generate theoretically appropriate measures of coercive capacity and use these to judge where China falls.
Analysing spending is attractive for many reasons, not least because it is quantifiable.Footnote 13 Rigorous assessments of domestic coercive capacity and of its financial underpinnings, however, have been hampered by three key challenges, each of which directly affects the debate over China. First is a simple lack of transparency and data. There is no comprehensive dataset for internal security spending and assets comparable to the military compendia published annually by the International Institute for Strategic Studies (IISS) and the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI). Both military and internal security budgets are sensitive subjects, but the comparative lack of external pressure to make domestic expenditures transparent, combined with the institutional heterogeneity of the internal security apparatus compared to the military, hinders rigorous interpretation.Footnote 14
Second, differentiating internal from external security is often difficult, especially when assets or personnel are fungible or dual-use. As a result, there is no consensus on how to make this demarcation; datasets on military expenditure often include organizations with a domestic focus but at the same time exclude actors that have a large international impact, without providing a justification.Footnote 15 The IISS and SIPRI, for example, include the People's Armed Police (PAP) – an organization strengthened post-1989 to take over domestic security from the PLA – in China's defence spending, but they exclude maritime law enforcement agencies that operate in disputed territorial waters (such as the South China Sea).Footnote 16 On the other hand, studies of authoritarian politics typically use military spending as a proxy for coercive capacity;Footnote 17 in China's case, this excludes the main organizations/spending tasked with responsibility for domestic security, which is nonsensical if internal security is the concept of theoretical interest.
Separating law enforcement and criminal justice from political policing is the third challenge. The extent to which normal judicial-legal institutions are used for political policing, and how exactly they are employed, varies widely across countries and across time.Footnote 18 Discussion of China's domestic security budget often treats this spending as aimed entirely at suppressing political opposition to the CCP's single-party rule, commonly citing the growth of “mass incidents” to explain budget increases. Yet, in fact, in China a single budget and organizational system –the political-legal system (zhengfa xitong 政法系统) – address both criminal and political aspects of domestic security. At the local level, censors remove both pornography and political commentary, and MPS offices handle crime control as well as protest management.Footnote 19 The “internal security budget” supports law enforcement and criminal justice functions that would still require funding even if China democratized tomorrow. Yet, discussions of China's domestic security budget seldom consider whether crime, rather than political opposition, has played any role in the recent budget increases.
The above paragraphs highlight the risk of uncritically employing budget statistics to gauge China's domestic coercive capacity. What, then, should analysts use instead? I suggest not that budget statistics should be abandoned but that they must be interpreted more carefully, in historical and cross-national comparative context, to make judgments about their importance for “coercive capacity.”Footnote 20 Specifically, drawing on recent findings in security studies, I argue that any assessment of coercive capacity must go beyond simply what a country spends to incorporate two additional factors: what that money is spent on, and what it is spent against.
It is important to consider what domestic security budgets are spent on because two countries with equivalent budgets may choose to spend that money in ways that make their expenditures more or less effective. Studies of military effectiveness (where the acquisition of hardware arguably provides better evidence of capacity than it does for internal security) have shown that the correlation between spending and performance is tenuous; they conclude that “it's not what states spend, it's what they do with what they spend” that matters.Footnote 21 Just as a military that invests primarily in tanks will find itself disadvantaged in fighting a predominantly naval war, domestic security forces that are trained and equipped for rural counter-insurgency may perform poorly in urban riot control. These studies further suggest that performance is not simply a matter of buying the right equipment or training; organizational attributes such as fragmentation, social cohesion, information management and promotion patterns all affect a country's ability to translate spending into military power.Footnote 22 Recent literature suggests that the same is true of domestic security, where autocrats face organizational trade-offs between optimizing their forces to address different types of domestic security challenges, each of which they must navigate successfully in order to stay in power.Footnote 23 To understand whether increased spending is actually increasing China's coercive capacity, then, it is important to consider whether the organizations that receive that spending are effectively employing it for the purposes of controlling Chinese society.
A useful definition of coercive capacity and its importance for authoritarian rule also requires an understanding of what the budget is being spent against. In other words, how does the coercive apparatus’ ability measure up against the challenges it is expected to handle?Footnote 24 It makes little intuitive sense to claim that the coercive capacity of (for example) a 500-person police force with a $1 million budget would be the same in a city of 20,000 as it would be in a city of 2,000,000, or that it would have the same capacity to keep order in a city with extremely high crime and violence as in a city where crime rates are much lower. During the period analysed here, Chinese society changed tremendously: the population grew, both crime and incidents of political protest increased in frequency, and many of the traditional institutions of social control that characterized Maoist China were weakened or abolished. The CCP's capacity to enforce its rule and stay in power depends not just on its raw spending, or even on its absolute ability, but on its ability relative to the also changing ability of Chinese society to challenge it. Coercive capacity will only be a useful predictor of regime survival if it is relative in its conceptualization and measurement.
Theoretically, it only makes sense to equate spending with effective coercive capacity (especially if coercive capacity is then to be credited with regime survival) if how that spending is employed and the magnitude of the challenges it must address are also considered. The sections that follow show that careful analysis of China's domestic security budget, placed in historical and cross-national comparative context and assessed alongside the above criteria, undercuts the claim that increased spending has created an increase in CCP coercive capacity. Rather, the data more likely indicate weakness or limitation – a finding that may also more logically explain China's recent domestic behaviour.
Reframing China's Internal Security Spending
The following section outlines a revised interpretation of China's domestic security spending, offering several correctives to academic and conventional wisdom. First, it looks at how much China is spending in historical perspective, showing that although total spending has increased, domestic security has remained roughly constant as a proportion of national expenditure over time. Second, it examines what China spends its domestic security budget on – what categories and what regions – to show that China's spending, and the coercive capacity it buys, is not necessarily exceptional in cross-national terms and may even be fairly low. Third, it investigates what China spends its budget against, showing that the combination of rising crime and increasing levels of political protest suggests that the challenges facing the coercive apparatus may well be outstripping its supposed increases in capacity. Finally, it presents an organizational analysis, showing that efforts to raise the political power of the coercive apparatus are not the same as strengthening its ability to manage society. Cumulatively, these points suggest that increased overall spending on domestic security is likely to indicate – and be motivated by – the inadequacy of China's coercive capacity rather than its repressive strength.
What China spends on domestic security (historical perspective)
China's domestic security budget is most often described using percentage increases from the year before or in comparison to the country's defence budget. Both of these metrics give the impression that domestic security spending has recently increased on an unprecedented and dramatic (“double-digit”) scale and that this spending is consuming an increasingly large chunk of the resources of the People's Republic of China (PRC). Neither claim is accurate. China's entire budget has been rising fast, producing double-digit growth in most categories. The growth in aggregate health care expenditure is as exponential as domestic security spending; growth in social security spending has, like domestic security, outstripped growth in defence spending since the early 1990s.Footnote 25 More than that, since the 1980s, the PRC has shifted an increasing share of its budget towards education, health care, social security and housing.Footnote 26 Domestic security spending's share of total expenditure, however, has stayed relatively constant: between 5 and 7 per cent of total expenditure (Figure 2).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_fig2g.jpeg?pub-status=live)
Figure 2: Internal Security Expenditure as Proportion of Total Expenditure
The figures presented in this article draw on China's official statistical yearbooks. Adjustments have been made where necessary in order to ensure that the aggregate figures include comparable sub-categories over time. (For example, labour re-education was sometimes included in the aggregate yearbook figure, sometimes listed separately; here, it is included in totals regardless of where in the yearbook it appeared.) The percentage of national expenditure allocated to domestic security ranged from a low of 4.4 per cent in 1992 to a peak of 7.0 per cent in 2007, declining to 5.6 per cent in 2013.
China is spending more money on everything, not just on domestic security; domestic security is not getting a bigger share of the pie now than before. This suggests that to understand increased domestic security spending, it is best to start with what is driving overall budget increases – often attributed to factors like increasing personnel costs – rather than assuming that domestic security is somehow exceptional.Footnote 27 Indeed, the pattern here suggests that the causal forces responsible for spending increases are not, in fact, either unique to internal security nor particularly new, since the percentage spent on domestic security has not dramatically increased in recent years; if anything, it has declined.
One potentially complicating factor is that under the “securitization” of the Chinese state, more parts of the political system (including bureaucrats responsible for everything from labour to the environment) now share responsibility for “stability maintenance” but do not appear in the domestic security budget. Typically, however, the responsibility of these actors in terms of stability maintenance is preventive: to minimize societal and citizen grievance and forestall unrest. I focus here on a somewhat narrower definition of coercive capacity and restrict the analysis to the set of actors who exercise and implement the regime's monopoly on (physical) force rather than include all those who are responsible for the broader political imperative of reducing citizens’ grievances with the state or regime.
How China spends its domestic security budget (categories and geography)
Coverage of China's internal security spending figures seldom discloses precisely what these statistics include or how they compare to other countries. Figure 3 shows the categorical allocation of China's domestic security spending. The bulk of China's domestic security budget since 1996 has gone to the Ministry of Public Security (gong'an 公安), ranging between 58.8 per cent (2009) and 63.2 per cent (1996). Other major categories each year include the PAP (wujing 武警), national security (guojian anquan 国家安全), procuratorate (jiancha 检察), courts (fayuan 法院), Ministry of Justice (sifa 司法), prisons (jianyu 监狱), and re-education through labour (laojiao 劳教). Since 2006, the budget has also included categories for protection of state secrets (guojia baomi 国家保密), anti-smuggling police (jisijing 缉私警) and “other” (qita 其他), although each of these is fairly small. Most categories show a fair amount of stability over time; the budget percentage going to prisons and labour re-education declined the most,Footnote 28 while the biggest spending increases were on courts and the PAP.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_fig3g.gif?pub-status=live)
Figure 3: Categories of Domestic Security Spending by per Cent of Budget, 1996–2009 Excluding MPS
As noted above, this budget includes not only explicitly “political” organizations such as state security and the PAP but also institutions with broader criminal justice functions such as local police and courts. Is China's spending on this system exceptional? To construct a preliminary answer to this question, I aggregated budgets for comparable institutions in the United States and Russia – two countries that, like China, are great powers with a large territory, diverse geography, and significant internal security concerns, either criminal or political (but which, as a robust and a weak democracy, respectively, might plausibly spend less on internal security than China's fully authoritarian system).Footnote 29 Only known and measurable costs are included, making the estimates conservative. Table 2 shows this comparison for 2013.
Table 2: Comparison of US, Russia and PRC Security Spending, 2013 (US$)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_tab2.gif?pub-status=live)
Sources: DOD 2013; Cooper Reference Cooper2014. Jane's lists Russia's 2013 defence spending as $68.8 billion for 2013. Calculations based on US population of 317,000,000; Russian population of 142,355,000; PRC population of 1,355,000,000. US Census Bureau, www.census.gov/popclock/ and http://press.ihs.com/press-release/aerospace-defense-terrorism/global-defence-budgets-overall-rise-first-time-five-years. For an explanation of construction of the US spending estimate, see Appendix 1.
When roughly equivalent categories are compared, China spent less than the United States on domestic security, for a larger territory and much larger population, and that both China and Russia spent roughly comparable amounts on domestic and external security. The United States spent around $489 per capita on domestic security, while Russia spent $393; China spent approximately $92.Footnote 30 Until a full cross-national dataset on domestic security spending is available, there is no way to tell how these three countries stack up against “the average” in their budgetary allocations for internal security or even against various comparison categories that might be of theoretical interest such as great powers, authoritarian regimes, communist countries, etc. These illustrative data, however, should call into question the assumption that China is an exceptionally heavy spender on domestic security, as often implied, or that China's high spending is simply the consequence of its authoritarian system.
Perhaps more importantly, China's lower spending also results in a smaller coercive presence deployed on the ground. PRC domestic security spending is not lower simply because coercive capacity – for example, the cost of hiring a police officer – is cheaper in China, and Beijing is not buying more coercive capacity for a lower price. It has fewer police per capita than the US, at 1.38 officers per 1,000 residents in 2009 (the last year for which an estimate was available), compared to a US average of 2.3 and a Russian average of around 5.Footnote 31 In fact, China has a lower per capita police ratio than many other countries (see Figure 4).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20171208053938-65924-mediumThumb-S0305741017001023_fig4g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 4: Global Police per Capita Ratios
These data suggest that complaints about China's police shortfall in public security journals and Chinese media, and the recruitment of volunteers to fill those shortfalls, are not simply the result of bureaucratic dissatisfaction and posturing for publicity (although this may also be the case).Footnote 32 China is not getting more for its money; it is actually getting less coercive power as a result of lower spending.
Analysing the geographic distribution of China's domestic security spending similarly suggests that the decentralization of domestic security budgets may have weakened China's coercive capacity, particularly in areas perceived to be resistant to CCP rule. Previous analyses have noted the dominance of provincial and local spending relative to that of the central government. Figure 5 shows that this trend has deepened over time. Indeed, the percentage of internal security expenditure funded by local rather than central coffers rose significantly from 1992 (68.7 per cent) to 2012 (83.4 per cent). This trend contrasts with the defence budget, where around 85 per cent of spending is central, and the shift towards local expenditure continued even after the 2003 reforms, which were aimed at strengthening central control by increasing transfer payments (zhuyi zhifu 转移支付) to local public security departments.Footnote 33 The transferred funds are intended to prevent local departments from levying excessive and unpopular fines to cover budgetary shortfalls, but their usage is restricted to certain categories, which often leaves local government with a heavy burden. In China, where central oversight is often framed as the answer to local abuse and predation, the gradual weakening of central financial control over coercion is notable and consistent with the idea of China as a “fragmented authoritarian” polity.Footnote 34
Past studies have shown the importance of local financial capacity for determining localities’ domestic security spending: wealthier eastern provinces spend more than poorer inland ones in both gross and per capita terms.Footnote 35 Guangdong, for example, has the largest domestic security budget of any province, while Ningxia consistently has the lowest; Guangdong's spending per capita is almost three times that of Ningxia. Poorer inland provinces and regions, however, do spend a higher proportion of their revenue on domestic security and (post-2003) fund more of their budgets through central transfers.Footnote 36 In other words, provinces that can spend more on domestic security do so; those that cannot receive money from the centre to help offset perceived shortfalls. This sub-national variation in the financial foundation of coercive capacity, hidden by the more common references to annual percentage increases and defence budget comparisons, is consistent with a strain on the coercive apparatus rather than evidence of robust capacity.
Important for assessing the regime's coercive capacity relative to society, that strain is more pronounced in particular areas. Figure 6 shows that per capita spending on domestic security has increased more steeply in some regions than in others, especially in the latter half of the 2000s. The two most noticeable increases are in Beijing – unsurprising given the presence of the top leadership – and Tibet, where per capita domestic security spending started low but increased dramatically around 2006. Indeed, Figure 7 shows that Tibet is particularly ill-equipped financially to deal with challenges to CCP rule. Domestic security spending relative to GDP has always been higher in Tibet than in other provinces, but the ratio skyrocketed after 2006. Although scholars have previously noted the uniqueness of central subsidies to Tibet, even when compared to other poor areas in western China, these figures add an additional layer of meaning.Footnote 37 In the eyes of China's leadership, Tibet represents a unique intersection: high domestic security threat combined with low financial capacity to address that threat.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_fig6g.jpeg?pub-status=live)
Figure 6: Domestic Security Spending per Capita over Time by Province
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20171208053855556-0124:S0305741017001023:S0305741017001023_fig7g.jpeg?pub-status=live)
Figure 7: Domestic Security Spending over Time by Province Relative to GDP
The threats facing China: rising crime and political protest
The example of Tibet illustrates why it is useful to consider the capacity of China's coercive apparatus relative to the challenges that the apparatus must address. Systematic consideration of these challenges, combined with the budget trends outlined above, highlights the weakness of China's coercive capacity rather than its strength.
The internal security budget covers crime control and management of political unrest. Both needs have increased steadily during the period of rising domestic security expenditure.Footnote 38 According to the PRC's own statistics, the number of “mass incidents” has grown steadily: from 8,700 in 1993 to 127,000 in 2008. Lawsuits against government offices and officials similarly grew: from 11,418 in 1988 to 142,861 in 2008. Both scholarly and media analyses commonly cite the rise in “mass incidents” to explain domestic security budget increases.Footnote 39 Less frequently mentioned is the fact that during the same period crime also increased, more than doubling from 2000 (4.5 million) to 2008 (9 million). Violent crimes increased at an even steeper rate. The total number of criminal cases heard in court rose from 2 million in 1987 to nearly 7 million in 2008, and China's public security bureaus dealt with a far larger number of cases than those that actually appeared in court. At the same time, many of the institutions of social control and management that existed under Mao – the household registration (hukou 户口) and work unit (danwei 单位) systems, for example – weakened during the process of economic liberalization and the rural-to-urban migration that followed.
Given these changes in Chinese society and in the institutions that previously linked the party-state with society, it is not surprising that the PRC's formal institutions of coercion have had to boost their resources to keep up. Although these data are not conclusive evidence that the regime's efforts at compensation have failed, they do provide reason to question whether the supposed expansion of coercive capacity in China has in fact kept pace with the challenges the regime faces.
Strengthening the coercive apparatus? Political power versus coercive capacity
One explanation proffered for the increased resources devoted to internal security (and the decision to stop publishing the budget in 2014) was the rise and subsequent fall of Zhou Yongkang 周永康, who was minister of public security in 2002–2007 and a member of the Politburo Standing Committee and head of the Central Political-Legal Commission (zhengfawei 政法委) in 2007–2012.Footnote 40 Yuhua Wang and Carl Minzner identify the incorporation and elevation of public security officials within the Chinese political system under Zhou as the other main indicator (in addition to budget increases) of the strengthening of coercive capacity: since the early 2000s, political-legal committee chairs have almost always sat on provincial CCP standing committees, and police chiefs are increasingly represented on provincial Party leadership teams.Footnote 41 Indeed, after Zhou's 2002 promotion, the number of police chiefs involved in provincial Party leadership increased sharply, from ~60 per cent in 2003 to ~90 per cent by 2012.Footnote 42 Wang also notes that police funding is positively correlated with the rank of police chiefs and negatively correlated with the percentage of the labour force employed by state-owned enterprises (SOEs). He concludes that the “strong coercive capacity” of the CCP plays an overlooked role in China's authoritarian resilience.Footnote 43
I believe these conclusions to be overstated. Drawing on the previously discussed literature on the organizational dimensions of coercive capacity, I suggest that these analyses have conflated two separate factors: the political power of China's coercive agents within the regime, and those agents’ capacity relative to Chinese society. Studies in comparative authoritarianism have previously documented that intra-elite politics and societal unrest are distinct challenges to authoritarian rule, and that the tools used to deal with them are different: autocrats commonly attempt to buy the loyalty of coercive agents (either politically or economically), but these efforts are often orthogonal or even counterproductive to endowing them with the capacity to manage popular unrest.Footnote 44 The treatment of the coercive apparatus from 1992 to 2012 is evidence that the CCP elevated the internal political power of coercive agents during this time, but this cannot be equated with an improvement in coercive agents’ capacity to manage Chinese society.
In fact, the trend of increasing funding for domestic security pre-dated the practice of promoting police chiefs into the Party architecture, and the improved political position of police chiefs in provincial leadership did not produce an increase in spending on domestic security as a percentage of the overall budget after either 2002 or 2007. Thus, even if higher-ranked police chiefs were able to secure more funding for their provinces than lower-ranked counterparts, the coercive apparatus as a whole did not receive more funding: recall from Figure 2 that domestic security spending as a percentage of total expenditure actually declined from 2007 to 2012. In fact, what the relationship between Party rank, SOE employment and police funding suggests is that when faced with overall budget constraints, more politically powerful police chiefs shifted resources to areas where the party-state was losing control over the labour force – a pattern that, as with the geographic data analysed above, suggests concern with the coercive apparatus’ inadequate capacity to police Chinese society, not confidence in its strength.
Conclusion
Discussions of China's domestic security expenditure often present this spending, implicitly or explicitly, as evidence of the CCP's strong and increasing coercive capacity. This article challenges that characterization by analysing not just the amount that China spends but also how it spends those resources and the magnitude of the threats that those resources must combat. It finds that China's domestic security spending is not historically unprecedented, not growing as a proportion of national expenditure, and not necessarily producing high coercive capacity compared to other countries. It also shows that certain locations struggle more to fund their coercive capacity than others, and that these locations overlap with areas in which internal security threats may be perceived as particularly acute. These findings are notable given that the challenges that the coercive apparatus faces – in terms of both crime and political opposition – have grown over the same period during which spending has risen. The article further finds that it is theoretically incorrect to assume that policies that raise the political power of coercive agents within the party-state are also measures that strengthen their capacity relative to Chinese society; the two phenomena are theoretically and empirically distinct, and there is evidence for the former but not the latter. Cumulatively, this reassessment provides stronger evidence of the limitations on China's coercive capacity as of 2012 than of its strength.
This perspective helps to explain some of the key developments in China's domestic security policy since 2012, especially the creation of a largely domestically focused National Security Commission, the passage of new national security legislation, and an overall tightening of social control under President Xi Jinping. These developments make the most sense if the CCP in 2012 is understood as a regime deeply concerned about the inadequacy of its capacity to control and manage Chinese society rather than a regime confident in the strength of its ability to do so. The PRC's decision not to continue releasing full budget statistics on internal security after 2013 confirms the need for observers of Chinese politics to develop alternative indicators of coercive capacity and to theorize the relationship between coercive capacity and China's authoritarian resilience more carefully.
Acknowledgement
The author wishes to thank Jingkai He, Jason Kwon and Hao Wang for excellent research assistance, and Zach Barter, Zack Cooper, Joe Fewsmith, Iain Johnston, Vanya Krieckhaus, Adam Liff, Peter Lorentzen, Andy Mertha, Carl Minzner, Vipin Narang, Elizabeth Perry, Suzanne Scoggins, Caitlin Talmadge, Yuhua Wang, Xie Yue, audiences at the Association for Asian Studies, Cornell University, Harvard University's Program on Global Society and Security, Princeton University, and the George Washington University's Elliott School, for helpful comments and suggestions.
Biographical note
Sheena Chestnut Greitens is an assistant professor of political science at the University of Missouri. She is also a non-resident senior fellow at the Center for East Asian Policy at the Brookings Institution, and an associate in research at the Harvard Fairbank Center. Her book, Dictators and Their Secret Police: Coercive Institutions and State Violence, was published in 2016 by Cambridge University Press.
Appendix
Calculating US domestic security spending
Comparing domestic security spending in the US and PRC is difficult for several reasons. First, America's federal structure and decentralized policing make aggregate estimation of US expenditure difficult. (Of the ~$155 billion in domestic security spending in 2013, around one-third was federal expenditure; two-thirds was state-level prison spending and state/local police forces.) Second, an ideal analysis would separate political policing, aimed at keeping a particular regime in power and therefore specific (with gradations) to autocracy, from the law enforcement tasks that are common to both democracies and autocracies. Available data, however, simply do not allow this separation.
To reach the estimates of US spending given in this article, several federal departments (including the Department of Homeland Security and parts of the Department of Justice such as the Federal Bureau of Investigation and the Federal Bureau of Prisons) were aggregated with state and local spending on police, courts and prisons. Even here, judgments on the precise breakdowns of internal versus external security are likely to be imperfect; the Department of Justice stated in 2014 that $4.4 billion of its $27.6 billion budget went to “national security,” including “counterterrorism and counterintelligence programs … intelligence gathering and surveillance capabilities,” while the FBI has alternately described its mission as either “law enforcement” or “national security,” or both.
Certain categories that were excluded from this aggregation likely make it a low or conservative one. Estimates of state and local police spending in this article do not, for example, include sheriffs’ offices, state law enforcement agencies, or special jurisdiction agencies, which equal or exceed local police departments in number.Footnote 45 It is also possible that some portion of the ~$50 billion annual intelligence budget should be included in the total, but a breakdown of this spending is not publicly available and therefore is not included.Footnote 46