Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T21:15:58.081Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rethinking China's Coercive Capacity: An Examination of PRC Domestic Security Spending, 1992–2012

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 July 2017

Sheena Chestnut Greitens*
Affiliation:
Department of political science, University of Missouri. Email: greitenss@missouri.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Discussions of China's rising domestic security expenditure often present this spending as evidence of the Chinese Communist Party's strong coercive capacity. This article argues that a lack of theoretical clarity about domestic security has resulted in flawed conclusions about these expenditures and their implications for China's coercive capacity. Challenging the conventional wisdom, the article analyses China's domestic security spending from 1992 through 2012 and argues that it is important to consider not only the total amount that China spends but also how it spends these resources and the magnitude of the threats that this expenditure must address. It finds that China's domestic security spending is not historically unprecedented, is not expanding as a proportion of national expenditure, and is not necessarily high (or producing high coercive capacity) when compared to other countries. The article also shows that certain locations struggle more to fund their coercive capacity than others, and that these locations overlap with areas where internal security threats may be particularly acute. The challenges that the coercive apparatus must address have also grown over the same period during which domestic security spending has risen. Finally, attempts to improve the political position of China's coercive agents cannot be equated with improvements in their capacity to manage Chinese society. Cumulatively, this reassessment provides more evidence of the limitations on China's coercive capacity than of its strength.

摘要

谈到中国国内安全开支增加的时候, 分析人士经常会假设开支的增加是共产党强制能力提高的证据。这片文章的论点是, 因为理论基础不够明晰, 所以关于中国国内安全开支的结论经常有缺点。在这篇文章, 笔者用中国从 1992 年到 2012 年的国内安全开支的分析来挑战一般常识。笔者认为, 除了开支的数量以外, 中国怎么利用这样的资源以及需要应对什么样的威胁也值得注意。根据笔者的统计分析, 中国国内安全开支: 1) 并不算史无前例, 2) 在国家预算占的比例不在扩大, 3) 跟别的国家相比不算高, 而且产生的强制能力也不算大。笔者还进一步表明在征收国内安全财政收入的方面, 一部分省市会更困难, 而且这些省市平常是有更严重的国内威胁的地方。随着国内安全开支的提高, 国内安全机关面对的挑战也加剧了很多。最后, 国内安全机关政治地位的改善并不意味着他们比较容易控制中国社会。总之, 笔者认为这项分析显示的不是中国国内安全机关的实力, 而是国内安全机关的局限。

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © SOAS University of London 2017 

In March 2011, international news outlets reported that internal security spending in China had, for the first time, surpassed external defence expenditure.Footnote 1 Double-digit increases in spending had pushed the domestic security budget upward at an exponential rate, as shown in Figure 1, and the internal security budget remained higher than the defence budget for several subsequent years (see Table 1).

Sources: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013.

Figure 1: China's Total Domestic Security Expenditure, 1992–2012

Table 1: China's External Defence and Internal Security Spending, 2010–2013

Notes: In 2014 and 2015, the Chinese government declined to release the total amount spent on internal security. All US$ estimates adjusted based on 2013 annual average exchange rates.

Since then, domestic security has occupied a prominent place in public and academic discussions of Chinese politics and society, and the domestic security budget is a frequent point of reference.Footnote 2 But how should observers interpret this apparently astonishing growth? Journalists commonly suggest that China's leaders are raising spending in an unprecedented fashion to address heightened insecurity and as part of an increasing emphasis on “stability maintenance” (weihu wending 维护稳定, or, weiwen 维稳) in official discourse and behaviour.Footnote 3 Academic literature, however, has taken a different tack, citing spending increases as evidence of the “strong coercive capacity” of the Chinese state following a “dramatic expansion” in that capacity since the early 1990s.Footnote 4

This article demonstrates that neither of these perspectives is entirely correct, in large part because both rest on an overly simplistic idea of what “coercive capacity” means and because they selectively employ indicators that are not a good match for the concept. In the pages that follow, I seek to clarify the discussion on China's internal security spending in order to shed light on the role of coercive capacity in China's authoritarian stability. This is done in two ways: first by carefully defining coercive capacity, and then by using new theoretically derived indicators, placed in appropriate comparative perspective, to provide a re-assessment of China's coercive capacity.Footnote 5

The revised analysis of China's domestic security budget demonstrates that conventional wisdom exaggerates the exceptional and unprecedented nature of China's increases in spending on domestic security. The Chinese Communist Party (CCP) has indeed attempted to strengthen its coercive capacity, but it is probably doing so because it perceives that capacity to be inadequate for managing China's rapidly changing society. In other words, budget trends in the last two decades likely indicate the weakness and limitation of CCP coercive capacity during this period, not its strength.

This article proceeds in four sections. The second section establishes the importance of coercive capacity, outlines the current lack of clarity in its theorization and measurement, and offers a theoretically guided redefinition of the concept and some suggestions for better measurement. The third section offers a revised analysis of China's domestic security spending, based on the reconceptualization offered in section two. The fourth section concludes by discussing the implications of this analysis for current developments. It discusses how the framework proposed here may usefully illuminate China's internal security behaviour in recent years, including the reorganization of domestic security forces, the creation of new national security legislation, and the tightening of control over Chinese society under Xi Jinping's 习近平 leadership.

Assessing China's Coercive Capacity

Coercive capacity has long been recognized as a critical component of authoritarian stability.Footnote 6 Few studies, however, examine how that capacity is generated and sustained, or assess the relative importance of the budget in that process. This section asks: what is coercive capacity and how should it be measured? More specifically, it discusses how internal security expenditures are related (or not) to coercive capacity, both generally and in the China case.

The China field is divided on these questions. The dominant interpretation suggests that since 1989, China has been undergoing a long-term process of “securitization” (of which weiwen is the most recent manifestation) that has strengthened the regime's coercive capacity.Footnote 7 This explanation points to increased spending on the coercive apparatus as a major piece of evidence for its claims.Footnote 8 Even works that are normatively critical of the increased spending interpret it as an indication of rising coercive capacity.Footnote 9

A few Chinese-language studies, however, adopt a more sceptical tone, noting that the 1994 fiscal reforms exacerbated local budget problems even in the context of increased overall spending. They argue that the Ministry of Public Security's (MPS) frontline officers often have inadequate resources for the tasks they are expected to perform.Footnote 10 Articles in China's public security journals commonly discuss how to deal with the negative consequences of budgetary shortfallsFootnote 11 and how to maximize efficiency, given limited resources.Footnote 12 These complaints are not necessarily to be taken at face value – under-resourcing is, after all, a perennial complaint of bureaucrats the world over – but neither should they be dismissed out of hand. Instead, this article looks at the disjuncture between these two perspectives and asks: what is China's coercive capacity? To answer that question, it is necessary to generate theoretically appropriate measures of coercive capacity and use these to judge where China falls.

Analysing spending is attractive for many reasons, not least because it is quantifiable.Footnote 13 Rigorous assessments of domestic coercive capacity and of its financial underpinnings, however, have been hampered by three key challenges, each of which directly affects the debate over China. First is a simple lack of transparency and data. There is no comprehensive dataset for internal security spending and assets comparable to the military compendia published annually by the International Institute for Strategic Studies (IISS) and the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI). Both military and internal security budgets are sensitive subjects, but the comparative lack of external pressure to make domestic expenditures transparent, combined with the institutional heterogeneity of the internal security apparatus compared to the military, hinders rigorous interpretation.Footnote 14

Second, differentiating internal from external security is often difficult, especially when assets or personnel are fungible or dual-use. As a result, there is no consensus on how to make this demarcation; datasets on military expenditure often include organizations with a domestic focus but at the same time exclude actors that have a large international impact, without providing a justification.Footnote 15 The IISS and SIPRI, for example, include the People's Armed Police (PAP) – an organization strengthened post-1989 to take over domestic security from the PLA – in China's defence spending, but they exclude maritime law enforcement agencies that operate in disputed territorial waters (such as the South China Sea).Footnote 16 On the other hand, studies of authoritarian politics typically use military spending as a proxy for coercive capacity;Footnote 17 in China's case, this excludes the main organizations/spending tasked with responsibility for domestic security, which is nonsensical if internal security is the concept of theoretical interest.

Separating law enforcement and criminal justice from political policing is the third challenge. The extent to which normal judicial-legal institutions are used for political policing, and how exactly they are employed, varies widely across countries and across time.Footnote 18 Discussion of China's domestic security budget often treats this spending as aimed entirely at suppressing political opposition to the CCP's single-party rule, commonly citing the growth of “mass incidents” to explain budget increases. Yet, in fact, in China a single budget and organizational system –the political-legal system (zhengfa xitong 政法系统) – address both criminal and political aspects of domestic security. At the local level, censors remove both pornography and political commentary, and MPS offices handle crime control as well as protest management.Footnote 19 The “internal security budget” supports law enforcement and criminal justice functions that would still require funding even if China democratized tomorrow. Yet, discussions of China's domestic security budget seldom consider whether crime, rather than political opposition, has played any role in the recent budget increases.

The above paragraphs highlight the risk of uncritically employing budget statistics to gauge China's domestic coercive capacity. What, then, should analysts use instead? I suggest not that budget statistics should be abandoned but that they must be interpreted more carefully, in historical and cross-national comparative context, to make judgments about their importance for “coercive capacity.”Footnote 20 Specifically, drawing on recent findings in security studies, I argue that any assessment of coercive capacity must go beyond simply what a country spends to incorporate two additional factors: what that money is spent on, and what it is spent against.

It is important to consider what domestic security budgets are spent on because two countries with equivalent budgets may choose to spend that money in ways that make their expenditures more or less effective. Studies of military effectiveness (where the acquisition of hardware arguably provides better evidence of capacity than it does for internal security) have shown that the correlation between spending and performance is tenuous; they conclude that “it's not what states spend, it's what they do with what they spend” that matters.Footnote 21 Just as a military that invests primarily in tanks will find itself disadvantaged in fighting a predominantly naval war, domestic security forces that are trained and equipped for rural counter-insurgency may perform poorly in urban riot control. These studies further suggest that performance is not simply a matter of buying the right equipment or training; organizational attributes such as fragmentation, social cohesion, information management and promotion patterns all affect a country's ability to translate spending into military power.Footnote 22 Recent literature suggests that the same is true of domestic security, where autocrats face organizational trade-offs between optimizing their forces to address different types of domestic security challenges, each of which they must navigate successfully in order to stay in power.Footnote 23 To understand whether increased spending is actually increasing China's coercive capacity, then, it is important to consider whether the organizations that receive that spending are effectively employing it for the purposes of controlling Chinese society.

A useful definition of coercive capacity and its importance for authoritarian rule also requires an understanding of what the budget is being spent against. In other words, how does the coercive apparatus’ ability measure up against the challenges it is expected to handle?Footnote 24 It makes little intuitive sense to claim that the coercive capacity of (for example) a 500-person police force with a $1 million budget would be the same in a city of 20,000 as it would be in a city of 2,000,000, or that it would have the same capacity to keep order in a city with extremely high crime and violence as in a city where crime rates are much lower. During the period analysed here, Chinese society changed tremendously: the population grew, both crime and incidents of political protest increased in frequency, and many of the traditional institutions of social control that characterized Maoist China were weakened or abolished. The CCP's capacity to enforce its rule and stay in power depends not just on its raw spending, or even on its absolute ability, but on its ability relative to the also changing ability of Chinese society to challenge it. Coercive capacity will only be a useful predictor of regime survival if it is relative in its conceptualization and measurement.

Theoretically, it only makes sense to equate spending with effective coercive capacity (especially if coercive capacity is then to be credited with regime survival) if how that spending is employed and the magnitude of the challenges it must address are also considered. The sections that follow show that careful analysis of China's domestic security budget, placed in historical and cross-national comparative context and assessed alongside the above criteria, undercuts the claim that increased spending has created an increase in CCP coercive capacity. Rather, the data more likely indicate weakness or limitation – a finding that may also more logically explain China's recent domestic behaviour.

Reframing China's Internal Security Spending

The following section outlines a revised interpretation of China's domestic security spending, offering several correctives to academic and conventional wisdom. First, it looks at how much China is spending in historical perspective, showing that although total spending has increased, domestic security has remained roughly constant as a proportion of national expenditure over time. Second, it examines what China spends its domestic security budget on – what categories and what regions – to show that China's spending, and the coercive capacity it buys, is not necessarily exceptional in cross-national terms and may even be fairly low. Third, it investigates what China spends its budget against, showing that the combination of rising crime and increasing levels of political protest suggests that the challenges facing the coercive apparatus may well be outstripping its supposed increases in capacity. Finally, it presents an organizational analysis, showing that efforts to raise the political power of the coercive apparatus are not the same as strengthening its ability to manage society. Cumulatively, these points suggest that increased overall spending on domestic security is likely to indicate – and be motivated by – the inadequacy of China's coercive capacity rather than its repressive strength.

What China spends on domestic security (historical perspective)

China's domestic security budget is most often described using percentage increases from the year before or in comparison to the country's defence budget. Both of these metrics give the impression that domestic security spending has recently increased on an unprecedented and dramatic (“double-digit”) scale and that this spending is consuming an increasingly large chunk of the resources of the People's Republic of China (PRC). Neither claim is accurate. China's entire budget has been rising fast, producing double-digit growth in most categories. The growth in aggregate health care expenditure is as exponential as domestic security spending; growth in social security spending has, like domestic security, outstripped growth in defence spending since the early 1990s.Footnote 25 More than that, since the 1980s, the PRC has shifted an increasing share of its budget towards education, health care, social security and housing.Footnote 26 Domestic security spending's share of total expenditure, however, has stayed relatively constant: between 5 and 7 per cent of total expenditure (Figure 2).

Sources: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013; see also Guo, Gang Reference Guo2012. Pre-1997 statistics omit prisons.

Figure 2: Internal Security Expenditure as Proportion of Total Expenditure

The figures presented in this article draw on China's official statistical yearbooks. Adjustments have been made where necessary in order to ensure that the aggregate figures include comparable sub-categories over time. (For example, labour re-education was sometimes included in the aggregate yearbook figure, sometimes listed separately; here, it is included in totals regardless of where in the yearbook it appeared.) The percentage of national expenditure allocated to domestic security ranged from a low of 4.4 per cent in 1992 to a peak of 7.0 per cent in 2007, declining to 5.6 per cent in 2013.

China is spending more money on everything, not just on domestic security; domestic security is not getting a bigger share of the pie now than before. This suggests that to understand increased domestic security spending, it is best to start with what is driving overall budget increases – often attributed to factors like increasing personnel costs – rather than assuming that domestic security is somehow exceptional.Footnote 27 Indeed, the pattern here suggests that the causal forces responsible for spending increases are not, in fact, either unique to internal security nor particularly new, since the percentage spent on domestic security has not dramatically increased in recent years; if anything, it has declined.

One potentially complicating factor is that under the “securitization” of the Chinese state, more parts of the political system (including bureaucrats responsible for everything from labour to the environment) now share responsibility for “stability maintenance” but do not appear in the domestic security budget. Typically, however, the responsibility of these actors in terms of stability maintenance is preventive: to minimize societal and citizen grievance and forestall unrest. I focus here on a somewhat narrower definition of coercive capacity and restrict the analysis to the set of actors who exercise and implement the regime's monopoly on (physical) force rather than include all those who are responsible for the broader political imperative of reducing citizens’ grievances with the state or regime.

How China spends its domestic security budget (categories and geography)

Coverage of China's internal security spending figures seldom discloses precisely what these statistics include or how they compare to other countries. Figure 3 shows the categorical allocation of China's domestic security spending. The bulk of China's domestic security budget since 1996 has gone to the Ministry of Public Security (gong'an 公安), ranging between 58.8 per cent (2009) and 63.2 per cent (1996). Other major categories each year include the PAP (wujing 武警), national security (guojian anquan 国家安全), procuratorate (jiancha 检察), courts (fayuan 法院), Ministry of Justice (sifa 司法), prisons (jianyu 监狱), and re-education through labour (laojiao 劳教). Since 2006, the budget has also included categories for protection of state secrets (guojia baomi 国家保密), anti-smuggling police (jisijing 缉私警) and “other” (qita 其他), although each of these is fairly small. Most categories show a fair amount of stability over time; the budget percentage going to prisons and labour re-education declined the most,Footnote 28 while the biggest spending increases were on courts and the PAP.

Sources: MOF 1996–2009. Notes: For 1996–1997, the yearbooks did not include prison and labour re-education figures in total domestic security spending (but included them in subsequent years). To make the data comparable, these sub-categories were added to the 1996–1997 totals, so the estimate of total internal security spending is higher than that in the yearbooks.

Figure 3: Categories of Domestic Security Spending by per Cent of Budget, 1996–2009 Excluding MPS

As noted above, this budget includes not only explicitly “political” organizations such as state security and the PAP but also institutions with broader criminal justice functions such as local police and courts. Is China's spending on this system exceptional? To construct a preliminary answer to this question, I aggregated budgets for comparable institutions in the United States and Russia – two countries that, like China, are great powers with a large territory, diverse geography, and significant internal security concerns, either criminal or political (but which, as a robust and a weak democracy, respectively, might plausibly spend less on internal security than China's fully authoritarian system).Footnote 29 Only known and measurable costs are included, making the estimates conservative. Table 2 shows this comparison for 2013.

Table 2: Comparison of US, Russia and PRC Security Spending, 2013 (US$)

Sources: DOD 2013; Cooper Reference Cooper2014. Jane's lists Russia's 2013 defence spending as $68.8 billion for 2013. Calculations based on US population of 317,000,000; Russian population of 142,355,000; PRC population of 1,355,000,000. US Census Bureau, www.census.gov/popclock/ and http://press.ihs.com/press-release/aerospace-defense-terrorism/global-defence-budgets-overall-rise-first-time-five-years. For an explanation of construction of the US spending estimate, see Appendix 1.

When roughly equivalent categories are compared, China spent less than the United States on domestic security, for a larger territory and much larger population, and that both China and Russia spent roughly comparable amounts on domestic and external security. The United States spent around $489 per capita on domestic security, while Russia spent $393; China spent approximately $92.Footnote 30 Until a full cross-national dataset on domestic security spending is available, there is no way to tell how these three countries stack up against “the average” in their budgetary allocations for internal security or even against various comparison categories that might be of theoretical interest such as great powers, authoritarian regimes, communist countries, etc. These illustrative data, however, should call into question the assumption that China is an exceptionally heavy spender on domestic security, as often implied, or that China's high spending is simply the consequence of its authoritarian system.

Perhaps more importantly, China's lower spending also results in a smaller coercive presence deployed on the ground. PRC domestic security spending is not lower simply because coercive capacity – for example, the cost of hiring a police officer – is cheaper in China, and Beijing is not buying more coercive capacity for a lower price. It has fewer police per capita than the US, at 1.38 officers per 1,000 residents in 2009 (the last year for which an estimate was available), compared to a US average of 2.3 and a Russian average of around 5.Footnote 31 In fact, China has a lower per capita police ratio than many other countries (see Figure 4).

Source: UN Office on Drugs and Crime. 2009. “Total police personnel,” https://data.unodc.org/?lf=1&lng=en. Multiple years were tested and comparable results found.

Figure 4: Global Police per Capita Ratios

These data suggest that complaints about China's police shortfall in public security journals and Chinese media, and the recruitment of volunteers to fill those shortfalls, are not simply the result of bureaucratic dissatisfaction and posturing for publicity (although this may also be the case).Footnote 32 China is not getting more for its money; it is actually getting less coercive power as a result of lower spending.

Analysing the geographic distribution of China's domestic security spending similarly suggests that the decentralization of domestic security budgets may have weakened China's coercive capacity, particularly in areas perceived to be resistant to CCP rule. Previous analyses have noted the dominance of provincial and local spending relative to that of the central government. Figure 5 shows that this trend has deepened over time. Indeed, the percentage of internal security expenditure funded by local rather than central coffers rose significantly from 1992 (68.7 per cent) to 2012 (83.4 per cent). This trend contrasts with the defence budget, where around 85 per cent of spending is central, and the shift towards local expenditure continued even after the 2003 reforms, which were aimed at strengthening central control by increasing transfer payments (zhuyi zhifu 转移支付) to local public security departments.Footnote 33 The transferred funds are intended to prevent local departments from levying excessive and unpopular fines to cover budgetary shortfalls, but their usage is restricted to certain categories, which often leaves local government with a heavy burden. In China, where central oversight is often framed as the answer to local abuse and predation, the gradual weakening of central financial control over coercion is notable and consistent with the idea of China as a “fragmented authoritarian” polity.Footnote 34

Source: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013.

Figure 5: Local Spending as Proportion of Total Internal Security Spending

Past studies have shown the importance of local financial capacity for determining localities’ domestic security spending: wealthier eastern provinces spend more than poorer inland ones in both gross and per capita terms.Footnote 35 Guangdong, for example, has the largest domestic security budget of any province, while Ningxia consistently has the lowest; Guangdong's spending per capita is almost three times that of Ningxia. Poorer inland provinces and regions, however, do spend a higher proportion of their revenue on domestic security and (post-2003) fund more of their budgets through central transfers.Footnote 36 In other words, provinces that can spend more on domestic security do so; those that cannot receive money from the centre to help offset perceived shortfalls. This sub-national variation in the financial foundation of coercive capacity, hidden by the more common references to annual percentage increases and defence budget comparisons, is consistent with a strain on the coercive apparatus rather than evidence of robust capacity.

Important for assessing the regime's coercive capacity relative to society, that strain is more pronounced in particular areas. Figure 6 shows that per capita spending on domestic security has increased more steeply in some regions than in others, especially in the latter half of the 2000s. The two most noticeable increases are in Beijing – unsurprising given the presence of the top leadership – and Tibet, where per capita domestic security spending started low but increased dramatically around 2006. Indeed, Figure 7 shows that Tibet is particularly ill-equipped financially to deal with challenges to CCP rule. Domestic security spending relative to GDP has always been higher in Tibet than in other provinces, but the ratio skyrocketed after 2006. Although scholars have previously noted the uniqueness of central subsidies to Tibet, even when compared to other poor areas in western China, these figures add an additional layer of meaning.Footnote 37 In the eyes of China's leadership, Tibet represents a unique intersection: high domestic security threat combined with low financial capacity to address that threat.

Source: Data on spending from MOF 1996–2009; GDP and population data from China Data Online.

Figure 6: Domestic Security Spending per Capita over Time by Province

Source: Data on spending from MOF 1996–2009; GDP and population data from China Data Online.

Figure 7: Domestic Security Spending over Time by Province Relative to GDP

The threats facing China: rising crime and political protest

The example of Tibet illustrates why it is useful to consider the capacity of China's coercive apparatus relative to the challenges that the apparatus must address. Systematic consideration of these challenges, combined with the budget trends outlined above, highlights the weakness of China's coercive capacity rather than its strength.

The internal security budget covers crime control and management of political unrest. Both needs have increased steadily during the period of rising domestic security expenditure.Footnote 38 According to the PRC's own statistics, the number of “mass incidents” has grown steadily: from 8,700 in 1993 to 127,000 in 2008. Lawsuits against government offices and officials similarly grew: from 11,418 in 1988 to 142,861 in 2008. Both scholarly and media analyses commonly cite the rise in “mass incidents” to explain domestic security budget increases.Footnote 39 Less frequently mentioned is the fact that during the same period crime also increased, more than doubling from 2000 (4.5 million) to 2008 (9 million). Violent crimes increased at an even steeper rate. The total number of criminal cases heard in court rose from 2 million in 1987 to nearly 7 million in 2008, and China's public security bureaus dealt with a far larger number of cases than those that actually appeared in court. At the same time, many of the institutions of social control and management that existed under Mao – the household registration (hukou 户口) and work unit (danwei 单位) systems, for example – weakened during the process of economic liberalization and the rural-to-urban migration that followed.

Given these changes in Chinese society and in the institutions that previously linked the party-state with society, it is not surprising that the PRC's formal institutions of coercion have had to boost their resources to keep up. Although these data are not conclusive evidence that the regime's efforts at compensation have failed, they do provide reason to question whether the supposed expansion of coercive capacity in China has in fact kept pace with the challenges the regime faces.

Strengthening the coercive apparatus? Political power versus coercive capacity

One explanation proffered for the increased resources devoted to internal security (and the decision to stop publishing the budget in 2014) was the rise and subsequent fall of Zhou Yongkang 周永康, who was minister of public security in 2002–2007 and a member of the Politburo Standing Committee and head of the Central Political-Legal Commission (zhengfawei 政法委) in 2007–2012.Footnote 40 Yuhua Wang and Carl Minzner identify the incorporation and elevation of public security officials within the Chinese political system under Zhou as the other main indicator (in addition to budget increases) of the strengthening of coercive capacity: since the early 2000s, political-legal committee chairs have almost always sat on provincial CCP standing committees, and police chiefs are increasingly represented on provincial Party leadership teams.Footnote 41 Indeed, after Zhou's 2002 promotion, the number of police chiefs involved in provincial Party leadership increased sharply, from ~60 per cent in 2003 to ~90 per cent by 2012.Footnote 42 Wang also notes that police funding is positively correlated with the rank of police chiefs and negatively correlated with the percentage of the labour force employed by state-owned enterprises (SOEs). He concludes that the “strong coercive capacity” of the CCP plays an overlooked role in China's authoritarian resilience.Footnote 43

I believe these conclusions to be overstated. Drawing on the previously discussed literature on the organizational dimensions of coercive capacity, I suggest that these analyses have conflated two separate factors: the political power of China's coercive agents within the regime, and those agents’ capacity relative to Chinese society. Studies in comparative authoritarianism have previously documented that intra-elite politics and societal unrest are distinct challenges to authoritarian rule, and that the tools used to deal with them are different: autocrats commonly attempt to buy the loyalty of coercive agents (either politically or economically), but these efforts are often orthogonal or even counterproductive to endowing them with the capacity to manage popular unrest.Footnote 44 The treatment of the coercive apparatus from 1992 to 2012 is evidence that the CCP elevated the internal political power of coercive agents during this time, but this cannot be equated with an improvement in coercive agents’ capacity to manage Chinese society.

In fact, the trend of increasing funding for domestic security pre-dated the practice of promoting police chiefs into the Party architecture, and the improved political position of police chiefs in provincial leadership did not produce an increase in spending on domestic security as a percentage of the overall budget after either 2002 or 2007. Thus, even if higher-ranked police chiefs were able to secure more funding for their provinces than lower-ranked counterparts, the coercive apparatus as a whole did not receive more funding: recall from Figure 2 that domestic security spending as a percentage of total expenditure actually declined from 2007 to 2012. In fact, what the relationship between Party rank, SOE employment and police funding suggests is that when faced with overall budget constraints, more politically powerful police chiefs shifted resources to areas where the party-state was losing control over the labour force – a pattern that, as with the geographic data analysed above, suggests concern with the coercive apparatus’ inadequate capacity to police Chinese society, not confidence in its strength.

Conclusion

Discussions of China's domestic security expenditure often present this spending, implicitly or explicitly, as evidence of the CCP's strong and increasing coercive capacity. This article challenges that characterization by analysing not just the amount that China spends but also how it spends those resources and the magnitude of the threats that those resources must combat. It finds that China's domestic security spending is not historically unprecedented, not growing as a proportion of national expenditure, and not necessarily producing high coercive capacity compared to other countries. It also shows that certain locations struggle more to fund their coercive capacity than others, and that these locations overlap with areas in which internal security threats may be perceived as particularly acute. These findings are notable given that the challenges that the coercive apparatus faces – in terms of both crime and political opposition – have grown over the same period during which spending has risen. The article further finds that it is theoretically incorrect to assume that policies that raise the political power of coercive agents within the party-state are also measures that strengthen their capacity relative to Chinese society; the two phenomena are theoretically and empirically distinct, and there is evidence for the former but not the latter. Cumulatively, this reassessment provides stronger evidence of the limitations on China's coercive capacity as of 2012 than of its strength.

This perspective helps to explain some of the key developments in China's domestic security policy since 2012, especially the creation of a largely domestically focused National Security Commission, the passage of new national security legislation, and an overall tightening of social control under President Xi Jinping. These developments make the most sense if the CCP in 2012 is understood as a regime deeply concerned about the inadequacy of its capacity to control and manage Chinese society rather than a regime confident in the strength of its ability to do so. The PRC's decision not to continue releasing full budget statistics on internal security after 2013 confirms the need for observers of Chinese politics to develop alternative indicators of coercive capacity and to theorize the relationship between coercive capacity and China's authoritarian resilience more carefully.

Acknowledgement

The author wishes to thank Jingkai He, Jason Kwon and Hao Wang for excellent research assistance, and Zach Barter, Zack Cooper, Joe Fewsmith, Iain Johnston, Vanya Krieckhaus, Adam Liff, Peter Lorentzen, Andy Mertha, Carl Minzner, Vipin Narang, Elizabeth Perry, Suzanne Scoggins, Caitlin Talmadge, Yuhua Wang, Xie Yue, audiences at the Association for Asian Studies, Cornell University, Harvard University's Program on Global Society and Security, Princeton University, and the George Washington University's Elliott School, for helpful comments and suggestions.

Biographical note

Sheena Chestnut Greitens is an assistant professor of political science at the University of Missouri. She is also a non-resident senior fellow at the Center for East Asian Policy at the Brookings Institution, and an associate in research at the Harvard Fairbank Center. Her book, Dictators and Their Secret Police: Coercive Institutions and State Violence, was published in 2016 by Cambridge University Press.

Appendix

Calculating US domestic security spending

Comparing domestic security spending in the US and PRC is difficult for several reasons. First, America's federal structure and decentralized policing make aggregate estimation of US expenditure difficult. (Of the ~$155 billion in domestic security spending in 2013, around one-third was federal expenditure; two-thirds was state-level prison spending and state/local police forces.) Second, an ideal analysis would separate political policing, aimed at keeping a particular regime in power and therefore specific (with gradations) to autocracy, from the law enforcement tasks that are common to both democracies and autocracies. Available data, however, simply do not allow this separation.

To reach the estimates of US spending given in this article, several federal departments (including the Department of Homeland Security and parts of the Department of Justice such as the Federal Bureau of Investigation and the Federal Bureau of Prisons) were aggregated with state and local spending on police, courts and prisons. Even here, judgments on the precise breakdowns of internal versus external security are likely to be imperfect; the Department of Justice stated in 2014 that $4.4 billion of its $27.6 billion budget went to “national security,” including “counterterrorism and counterintelligence programs … intelligence gathering and surveillance capabilities,” while the FBI has alternately described its mission as either “law enforcement” or “national security,” or both.

Certain categories that were excluded from this aggregation likely make it a low or conservative one. Estimates of state and local police spending in this article do not, for example, include sheriffs’ offices, state law enforcement agencies, or special jurisdiction agencies, which equal or exceed local police departments in number.Footnote 45 It is also possible that some portion of the ~$50 billion annual intelligence budget should be included in the total, but a breakdown of this spending is not publicly available and therefore is not included.Footnote 46

Footnotes

2 “Everything Xi wants,” The Economist, 4 July 2015; Lampton Reference Lampton2015; Erickson and Liff Reference Erickson and Liff2016.

3 On the history and development of weiwen, see Yuen Reference Yuen2014; Kan Reference Kan2013; Qian Reference Qian2012.

5 On comparative perspective, see Reny Reference Reny2011; Johnston Reference Johnston2012; O'Brien Reference O'Brien2011. On coercive capacity, see Guo, Xuezhi Reference Guo2012; Scoggins and O'Brien Reference Scoggins and O'Brien2016; Deng, Yanhua, and O'Brien Reference Deng and O'Brien2013; Tanner and Green Reference Tanner and Green2007. On China's authoritarian resilience, see (among many others) Nathan Reference Nathan2003; Pei Reference Pei2012.

7 The term “securitization” is used in Wang and Minzner Reference Wang and Minzner2015.

8 The other is the promotion of police officials within the Party hierarchy, addressed below. Wang and Minzner Reference Wang and Minzner2015; Wang Reference Wang2014a; Reference Wang2014b.

12 Xie and Dang Reference Xie and Dang2013; Shi, Xiaochen, and Zhang Reference Shi and Zhang2015.

13 Andreas and Greenhill Reference Andreas and Greenhill2010.

14 Militaries are generally cross-nationally comparable in terms of having recognizable service branches. In domestic security, however, each country tends to create its own mix of national/local police, intelligence agencies, presidential/state security agencies, courts, etc. For a comparative approach to domestic security bureaucracies, see Greitens Reference Greitens2016. Expenses may also be funded off-budget, both generally and in the Chinese case. Analysts disagree on how large China's extrabudgetary expenses on domestic security, especially funds earmarked for weiwen (weiwen jingfei), are likely to be. I acknowledge that unobserved extrabudgetary spending may introduce downward bias on the data but believe the data is still valuable so long as appropriate caveats are provided.

15 On how this lack of consensus affects military spending estimates, see Liff and Erickson Reference Liff and Erickson2013; Forsythe Reference Forsythe2014.

16 PAP spending is included in China's statistical yearbooks as a major category under domestic security. Prior to March 2013, maritime law enforcement was handled by five agencies, all civilian; post-consolidation responsibility lies with the State Oceanic Administration (under the Ministry of Land and Natural Resources). The MPS also issued passports in 2012, reportedly without consulting the Foreign Ministry, that showed disputed islands as Chinese territory. Blasko and Corbett Reference Blasko and Corbett1998; Cheung Reference Cheung1996; Erickson and Collins Reference Erickson and Collins2013; Liff and Erickson 2013; Forsythe Reference Forsythe2014; Fravel Reference Fravel2007; Goldstein Reference Goldstein2010; Jakobson Reference Jakobson2014; Martinson Reference Martinson2014; Ruwitch Reference Ruwitch2012; Tanner Reference Tanner and Mulvenon2002; IISS 2001–2012; Wines Reference Wines2009.

19 King, Pan and Roberts Reference King, Pan and Roberts2014; Scoggins and O'Brien Reference Scoggins and O'Brien2016.

20 On the value of comparison, see Liff and Erickson Reference Liff and Erickson2013; Johnston Reference Johnston2013, 34.

22 Horowitz Reference Horowitz2010; Narang and Talmadge Reference Narang and Talmadge2017.

24 Here, my argument parallels a long-standing claim in international security that relative rather than absolute gains are what matter for inter-state conflict. Grieco Reference Grieco and Baldwin1993.

25 This holds even using high-end estimates of military spending from SIPRI/IISS. Sheen Reference Sheen2013; State Council Information Office 2012.

26 Zhu and Wang Reference Zhu and Wang2011.

27 Unfortunately, the data necessary to fully test this hypothesis do not (yet) exist. Qualitative research suggests regional disparities in police salaries are consistent with the subnational variation analysed here. For example, police in Guangdong earn 6–7 times more than police officers in many other provinces. Scoggins Reference Scoggins2016.

28 Note that these data end prior to the official abolishment of labour re-education in December 2013.

29 Polity scores range from −10 (full autocracy) to 10 (full democracy). The US Polity IV score in 2013 was 10; Russia's score was 4; China's score was −8.

30 On the use and misuse of per capita figures, see Xiao Reference Xiao2013.

32 Rising salary/personnel costs would explain both increasing expenditure and a shortfall in police personnel. Zhong Reference Zhong2009; Hu Reference Hu2009; Bureau of Justice 2013; “Zhongyang zongzhiban: quntixing shijian ji xinfang zongliang xiajiang mubiao shixian” (Central CMPS Commission: reduction targets of mass incidents and petitions realized), China Net, 6 February 2009; “Jiceng minjiang mianlin zuida de kunnan shi jingli buzu” (The biggest problem with civilian police is the shortage of police), Renmin Net, 9 March 2013; “China's police complain of manpower shortage in countryside despite crime rate falling,” Xinhua, 15 November 2006.

33 Xie Reference Xie2013a, 82–85, 90; Tanner and Green Reference Tanner and Green2007.

34 Tanner and Green Reference Tanner and Green2007; Mertha Reference Mertha2009; Lu and Landry 2014; Wallace Reference Wallace2014; Lampton Reference Lampton1987a; Reference Lampton1987b; Lieberthal and Oksenberg Reference Lieberthal and Oksenberg1988; Lieberthal and Lampton Reference Lieberthal and Lampton1992.

35 Xie Reference Xie2013a, 86.

36 Footnote Ibid. Elsewhere, however, Xie says that per capita spending in more developed, wealthier provinces is lower: e.g. Qinghai spent 368 yuan per person in 2008 on domestic security while Shandong spent 184 yuan. Xie Reference Xie2012, 24.

37 Fischer Reference Fischer2015.

38 Unless otherwise cited, data in this paragraph are drawn from Zhongguo falü nianjian 1989–2009; originally cited in Xie Reference Xie2012, 5–7.

39 Shirk Reference Shirk2007, 57.

40 Fewsmith Reference Fewsmith2016; Buckley Reference Buckley2012b; He Reference He2012; Shi, Jiangtao Reference Shi2012; Jiang Reference Jiang2015; “Tiger in the net,” The Economist, 13 December 2014.

41 Wang and Minzner Reference Wang and Minzner2015.

42 Wang Reference Wang2014a, 17.

45 BJS 2013; DOJ 2013; 2014; DHS 2013; FBI 2014; Kyckelhahn Reference Kyckelhahn2012; Hudson Reference Hudson2014; Reaves Reference Reaves2010; Reference Reaves2011.

46 DNI 2013; DOJ 2013.

References

Albertus, Michael, and Menaldo, Victor. 2012. “Coercive capacity and the prospects for democratization.” Comparative Politics 44(2), 151169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreas, Peter, and Greenhill, Kelly M. (eds.). 2010. Sex, Drugs, and Body Counts: The Politics of Numbers in Global Crime and Conflict. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Bellin, Eva. 2005. “Coercive institutions and coercive leaders.” In Posusney, Marsha Pripstein and Angrist, Michele Penner (eds.), Authoritarianism in the Middle East: Regimes and Resistance. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biddle, Stephen. 2006. Military Power: Explaining Victory and Defeat in Modern Battle. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Ben, and Ruwitch, John. 2013. “China hikes defense budget, to spend more on internal security,” Reuters, 5 March.Google Scholar
Blasko, Dennis, and Corbett, John F. Jr. 1998. “No more Tiananmens: the People's Armed Police and stability in China, 1997.” China Strategic Review Spring, 80103.Google Scholar
Brooks, Risa, and Stanley, Elizabeth (eds.). 2007. Creating Military Power: The Sources of Military Effectiveness. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Brownlee, Jason, Masoud, Tarek and Reynolds, Andrew. 2015. The Arab Spring: Pathways of Repression and Reform. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckley, Chris. 2011. “China internal security jumps past army budget,” Reuters, 5 March.Google Scholar
Buckley, Chris. 2012a. “China's domestic security spending rises to $111 billion,” Reuters, 5 March.Google Scholar
Buckley, Chris. 2012b. “Exclusive: China considers downgrading domestic security tsar in next line-up,” Reuters, 29 August.Google Scholar
Bureau of Justice Statistics. 2013. “Local police,” 6 May, http://bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=tp&tid=71.Google Scholar
Chen, Xi. 2013. “The rising cost of stability.” Journal of Democracy 42(1), 5764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheung, Tai Ming. 1996. “Guarding China's domestic front line: the People's Armed Police and China's stability.” The China Quarterly 146, 525547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, Julian. 2014. “The funding of the power agencies of the Russian state: an update, 2005 to 2014 and beyond.” Journal of Power Institutions in Post-Soviet Societies 16, http://pipss.revues.org/4063.Google Scholar
Deng, Xuan. 2011. “Caizheng zhichu guimo, jiegou yu chengxiang shouru bupingdeng yigeizi Zhongguo shengji mianban shujude shizheng fenxi” (Financial expenditure and rural–urban inequality: evidence from Chinese inter-province panel data analysis). Jingji pinglun 4, 6369.Google Scholar
Deng, Yanhua, and O'Brien, Kevin J.. 2013. “Relational repression in China: using social ties to demobilize protesters.” The China Quarterly 215, 533552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DHS (Department of Homeland Security). 2013. “Secretary Napolitano announces fiscal year 2014 budget request,” 10 April, http://www.dhs.gov/news/2013/04/10/secretary-napolitano-announces-fiscal-year-2014-budget-request.Google Scholar
DNI (Director of National Intelligence). 2013. “DNI releases budget figure for 2013 National Intelligence Program,” 30 October, http://www.dni.gov/index.php/newsroom/press-releases/191-press-releases-2013/957-dni-releases-budget-figure-for-2013-national-intelligence-program.Google Scholar
DOD (Department of Defense). 2013. “DoD releases fiscal year 2014 budget proposal,” 10 April, http://www.defense.gov/releases/release.aspx?releaseid=15921.Google Scholar
DOJ (Department of Justice). 2013. “Department of Justice FY2014 budget request,” 10 April, http://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/2013/April/13-ag-413.html.Google Scholar
DOJ. 2014. “US Department of Justice FY2014 budget request,” 19 January, http://www.justice.gov/jmd/2014factsheets/prisons-detention.pdf.Google Scholar
Erickson, Andrew, and Collins, Gabe. 2013. “New fleet on the block: China's coast guard comes together,” Wall Street Journal: China Real Time, 11 March, http://blogs.wsj.com/chinarealtime/2013/03/11/new-fleet-on-the-block-chinas-coast-guard-comes-together/.Google Scholar
Erickson, Andrew, and Liff, Adam. 2016. “Installing a safety on the ‘loaded gun’? China's institutional reforms, National Security Commission, and Sino-Japanese crisis (in)stability.” Journal of Contemporary China 25, 98, 197215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FBI (Federal Bureau of Investigation). 2014. “Federal Bureau of Investigation, FY 2014 budget request at a glance,” 28 January, http://www.justice.gov/jmd/2014summary/pdf/fbi.pdf.Google Scholar
Fewsmith, Joseph. 2016. “China's political ecology and the fight against corruption.” China Leadership Monitor 46, http://www.hoover.org/sites/default/files/research/docs/clm46jf.pdf.Google Scholar
Fischer, Andrew M. 2015. “Subsidizing Tibet: an interprovincial comparison of western China up to the end of the Hu–Wen era.” The China Quarterly 221, 7399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Michael. 2014. “China to ramp up military spending,” New York Times, 3 February.Google Scholar
Fravel, M. Taylor. 2007. “Securing borders: China's doctrine and force structure for frontier defense.” Journal of Strategic Studies 30(4–5), 705737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Lyle J. 2010. Five Dragons Stirring up the Sea: Challenge and Opportunity in China's Improving Maritime Enforcement Capabilities. Newport, RI: Naval War College, China Maritime Studies Institute.Google Scholar
Grauer, Ryan, and Horowitz, Michael C.. 2012. “What determines military victory? Testing the modern system.” Security Studies 21(1), 83112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greitens, Sheena Chestnut. 2016. Dictators and Their Secret Police: Coercive Institutions and State Violence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grieco, Joseph M. 1993. “Anarchy and the limits of cooperation.” In Baldwin, David A. (ed.), Neorealism and Neoliberalism. New York: Columbia University Press, 116140.Google Scholar
Guo, Gang. 2012. “Politics of local law enforcement spending in China.” Paper presented at the APSA annual meeting, New Orleans, 1 September.Google Scholar
Guo, Xuezhi. 2012. China's Security State: Philosophy, Evolution, and Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, Qinglian. 2012. “China's stability maintenance system faces financial pressure,” China Rights Forum, December, http://www.hrichina.org/en/crf/article/6415.Google Scholar
Horowitz, Michael. 2010. The Diffusion of Military Power: Causes and Consequences for International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hu, Wannian. 2009. “Jingcha xinli jiankang wenti de chengyin jiqi yingdui zhi ce” (Causes and policy regarding police mental health problems). Gong'an yanjiu 3, 5964.Google Scholar
Hudson, John. 2014. “In reversal, FBI now emphasizes role in law enforcement,” Foreign Policy, 17 January.Google Scholar
IISS (International Institute for Strategic Studies). 2001–2012. The Military Balance. London: IISS.Google Scholar
Jakobson, Linda. 2014. China's Unpredictable Maritime Security Actors. Sydney: Lowy Institute.Google Scholar
Jiang, Steven. 2015. “Zhou Yongkang: from apex of power to ‘caged tiger’ in China,” CNN, 11 June.Google Scholar
Johnston, Alastair Iain. 2012. “What (if anything) does East Asia tell us about IR theory?Annual Review of Political Science 15, 5378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Alastair Iain. 2013. “How new is China's new assertiveness?International Security 37(4), 748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kan, Karita. 2013. “Whither weiwen? Stability maintenance in the 18th Party Congress.” China Perspectives 1, 8793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Gary, Pan, Jennifer and Roberts, Margaret. 2014. “Reverse engineering censorship in China.” Science 345(6199), 17.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kyckelhahn, Tracy. 2012. “State prisons expenditures, FY 1982–2010,” Bureau of Justice Statistics, Department of Justice, NCJ239672, December, http://www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/scefy8210.pdf.Google Scholar
Lampton, David M. 1987a. “Chinese politics: the bargaining treadmill.” Issues and Studies 23(1), 1141.Google Scholar
Lampton, David M. 1987b. Policy Implementation in Post-Mao China. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lampton, David M. 2015. “Xi Jinping and the National Security Commission: policy coordination and political power.” Journal of Contemporary China 24(95), 759777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lieberthal, Kenneth G., and Lampton, David M. (eds.). 1992. Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lieberthal, Kenneth G., and Oksenberg, Michel C.. 1988. Policy Making in China: Leaders, Structures, and Processes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liff, Adam P., and Erickson, Andrew S.. 2013. “China's defence spending: less mysterious in the aggregate.” The China Quarterly 216, 805830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
, Xiaobo, and Landry, Pierre. 2014. “Show me the money: interjurisdictional political competition and fiscal extraction in China.” American Political Science Review 108(3), 706722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinson, Ryan D. 2014. “The militarization of China's coast guard,” The Diplomat, 21 November.Google Scholar
Mertha, Andrew. 2009. “Fragmented authoritarianism 2.0: political pluralization in the Chinese policy process.” The China Quarterly 200, 9951012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MOF (Ministry of Finance). 1992–2002. Zhongguo caizheng nianjian 1992–2002 (Finance Yearbook of China 1992–2002) . Beijing: China State Finance.Google Scholar
MOF. 1996–2009. Difang caizheng tongji ziliao 1996–2009 (Local Financial Statistics 1996–2009) . Beijing: China Financial and Economic Publishing.Google Scholar
Narang, Vipin, and Talmadge, Caitlin. 2017. “Civil–military pathologies and defeat in war: tests using new data.” Journal of Conflict Resolution (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nathan, Andrew J. 2003. “Authoritarian resilience.” Journal of Democracy 14(1), 617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
NBS (National Bureau of Statistics of China). 2003–2013. Zhongguo tongji nianjian 2003–2013 (Statistical Yearbook of China 2003–2013) . Beijing: China Statistics Press.Google Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin. 2011. “Studying Chinese politics in an age of specialization.” Journal of Contemporary China 20(71), 535541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pei, Minxin. 2012. “Is CCP rule fragile or resilient?Journal of Democracy 23(1), 2741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Gang. 2012. “Preserving stability,” China Media Project, 14 September, http://cmp.hku.hk/2012/09/14/27074.Google Scholar
Reaves, Brian A. 2010. “Local police departments, 2007,” Department of Justice, NCJ 231174, 2 December, http://www.bjs.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=1750.Google Scholar
Reaves, Brian A. 2011. “Census of state and local law enforcement agencies, 2008,” Department of Justice, NCJ 233982, July, http://www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/csllea08.pdf.Google Scholar
Reny, Marie-Eve. 2011. “What happened to the study of China in comparative politics?Journal of East Asian Studies 11(1), 105135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roessler, Philip. 2011. “The enemy within: personal rule, coups, and civil war in Africa.” World Politics 63(2), 300346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruwitch, John. 2012. “As China's clout grows, sea policy proves unfathomable,” Reuters, 9 December.Google Scholar
Scoggins, Suzanne. 2016. “Policing China: Struggles of Law, Order and Organization.” PhD diss., University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Scoggins, Suzanne, and O'Brien, Kevin. 2016. “China's unhappy police.” Asian Survey 56(2), 225242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
SDRG (Social Development Research Group). 2010. Yi liyi biaoda zhiduhua shixian shehui de chang-zhijiu'an (Institutionalize Interest Representation to Realize Long-Term Social Stability) . Beijing: Tsinghua University Google Scholar
Sheen, Seongho. 2013. “Northeast Asia's aging population and regional security: ‘demographic peace’?” Asian Survey 53(2), 292318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, Jiangtao. 2012. “Beijing begins big political reshuffle,” South China Morning Post, 20 November.Google Scholar
Shi, Xiaochen, and Zhang, Haibo. 2015. “Zhongguo difang zhengfu gonggong anchuan zhichu xiaolu yanjiu yijiyu DEA-Tobit de erjieduan fenxi” (Study on the efficiency of public security expenditure by China's local government: evidence from second-stage DEA-Tobit model). Dianzi keji daxue xuebao (shehui kexueban) 17(1), 1217, 22.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan. 2007. Fragile Superpower. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. States and Social Revolutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solomon, Peter H. Jr. 2007. “Courts and judges in authoritarian regimes.” World Politics 60(1), 122145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
State Council Information Office. 2012. “Medical and health services in China,” http://www.china-embassy.org/eng/zt/bps/t1001641.htm. Accessed 2 June 2017.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Talmadge, Caitlin. 2015. The Dictator's Army: Battlefield Effectiveness in Authoritarian Regimes. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Tanner, Murray Scot. 2002. “The institutional lessons of disaster: reorganizing China's People's Armed Police after Tiananmen.” In Mulvenon, James (ed.), The People's Liberation Army as Organization. Washington, DC: RAND, 587635.Google Scholar
Tanner, Murray Scot, and Green, Eric. 2007. “Principals and secret agents: central versus local control over policing and obstacles to ‘rule of law’ in China.” The China Quarterly 191, 644670.Google Scholar
Wallace, Jeremy. 2014. “Juking the stats? Authoritarian information problems in China.” British Journal of Political Science 46(1), 1129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Yuhua. 2014a. “Coercive capacity and the durability of the Chinese Communist state.” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 47(1), 1325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Yuhua. 2014b. “Empowering the police: how China manages its coercive leaders.” The China Quarterly 219, 625648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Yuhua, and Minzner, Carl. 2015. “The rise of the Chinese security state.” The China Quarterly 222, 339359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whiting, Susan. 2004. “The cadre evaluation system at the grass roots: the paradox of Party rule.” In Naughton, Barry and Yang, Dali L. (eds.), Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 101119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wines, Michael. 2009. “China approves law governing armed police force,” New York Times, 27 August.Google Scholar
Xiao, Tiefeng. 2013. “Misconceptions about China's growth in military spending,” Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 28 May, http://carnegieendowment.org/2013/05/28/misconceptions-about-china-s-growth-in-military-spending/g76a.Google Scholar
Xie, Yue. 2012. “The political logic of weiwen in contemporary China.” Issues and Studies 48(3), 141.Google Scholar
Xie, Yue. 2013a. “Rising central spending on public security and the dilemma facing grassroots officials in China.” Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 42(2), 79109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xie, Yue. 2013b. Weiwende zhengzhi luoji (Political Logic of Weiwen) . Hong Kong: Tsinghua Bookstore.Google Scholar
Xie, Yue, and Dang, Dongsheng. 2013. “‘Weiwen’ de jixiao kunjing: gonggong anquan kaizhi shijiao” (The efficiency dilemma of “weiwen”: from the perspective of public security expenditure). Tongji daxue xuebao (shehui kexueban) 6, 90100.Google Scholar
Xie, Yue, and Shan, Wei. 2013. “China struggles to maintain stability: strengthening its public security apparatus.” In Gungwu, Wang and Yongnian, Zheng (eds.), China: Development and Governance. Singapore: World Scientific, 5562.Google Scholar
Yao, Ziguo. 2004. “Shilun jianli he wanshan gong'an jingfei baozhang jizhi” (Essay on establishing and improving public security budget spending). Gong'an yanjiu 12, 7881.Google Scholar
Ye, Yongguang. 2006. “Dui gong'an jingfei baozhang biaozhunde ruogan sikao” (Thoughts on securing police budget). Gong'an yanjiu 1, 6668, 75.Google Scholar
Yuen, Wei Hai Samson. 2014. “The politics of weiwen: stability as a source of legitimacy in post-Tiananmen China.” ECPR Working Paper, https://ecpr.eu/Filestore/PaperProposal/94e6e2c5-c31a-4cd8-8759-266d21ccb81d.pdf.Google Scholar
Zhong, Lena. 2009. “Community policing in China: old wine in new bottles.” Police Practice and Research 10(2), 157169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, Qing, and Wang, Xiaohu. 2011. “Structural changes of public expenditures in China.” Journal of Public Budgeting, Accounting, and Financial Management 23(4), 569587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1: China's Total Domestic Security Expenditure, 1992–2012

Sources: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013.
Figure 1

Table 1: China's External Defence and Internal Security Spending, 2010–2013

Figure 2

Figure 2: Internal Security Expenditure as Proportion of Total Expenditure

Sources: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013; see also Guo, Gang 2012. Pre-1997 statistics omit prisons.
Figure 3

Figure 3: Categories of Domestic Security Spending by per Cent of Budget, 1996–2009 Excluding MPS

Sources: MOF 1996–2009.Notes: For 1996–1997, the yearbooks did not include prison and labour re-education figures in total domestic security spending (but included them in subsequent years). To make the data comparable, these sub-categories were added to the 1996–1997 totals, so the estimate of total internal security spending is higher than that in the yearbooks.
Figure 4

Table 2: Comparison of US, Russia and PRC Security Spending, 2013 (US$)

Figure 5

Figure 4: Global Police per Capita Ratios

Source: UN Office on Drugs and Crime. 2009. “Total police personnel,” https://data.unodc.org/?lf=1&lng=en. Multiple years were tested and comparable results found.
Figure 6

Figure 5: Local Spending as Proportion of Total Internal Security Spending

Source: MOF 1992–2002; NBS 2003–2013.
Figure 7

Figure 6: Domestic Security Spending per Capita over Time by Province

Source: Data on spending from MOF 1996–2009; GDP and population data from China Data Online.
Figure 8

Figure 7: Domestic Security Spending over Time by Province Relative to GDP

Source: Data on spending from MOF 1996–2009; GDP and population data from China Data Online.