INTRODUCTION
In 2018 Nigeria enacted the Federal Competition and Consumer Protection Act (FCCPA). This act is the country's first serious attempt at comprehensive regulation of market competition. It was enacted in a bid to prohibit anti-competitive activities in the country and to advance consumer welfare in general. Before the FCCPA, competition in Nigeria was largely unregulated, save perhaps for a few sector-specific measures that were not exhaustive and were largely ineffective.Footnote 1 In effect, little was done to open Nigeria's economic space to unrestrained competition. For the most part, state owned enterprises (SOEs), which were largely inefficient and moribund, monopolized or dominated crucial sectors such as rail, telecommunications and aviation.Footnote 2 Nigeria returned to democratic governance in 1999 after almost 25 years of military ruleFootnote 3 and immediately set in motion a number of measures aimed at liberalizing its economy and privatizing some of its SOEs.Footnote 4 The FCCPA can be viewed as a culmination of a long line of initiatives targeted at economic liberalization in Nigeria. The act has had a somewhat chequered history. It is in fact the result of several bills tabled before the National Assembly dating back to 2002.Footnote 5
The FCCPA regulates anti-competitive behaviour and aims to create an environment where businesses can thrive on the basis of their capabilities and performance, without being stifled by the unsavoury practices of a few unscrupulous persons. Its provisions, which significantly penalize acts and agreements that have trade distorting consequences, elaborately reflect best practice in competition regulation. However, while conceding that the development of a free-market environment is essential for Nigeria to attain its economic goals, this article contends that it is even more imperative that a reasonable level of corporate compliance be reached for the act to achieve its objectives. Among other things, this will require the strategic imposition of individual sanctions on directors of companies and undertakings that engage in anti-competitive behaviour, as a means of inducing compliance and deterring wrongdoing. The article attempts to demonstrate that, laudable as the corporate sanctions imposed for breaching the FCCPA are, particular emphasis needs to be placed on company directors, given that the greatest commercial endeavours in Nigeria are carried out through companies. This implies that directors at the helm of companies are critical, if Nigeria is to achieve significant levels of corporate compliance with the act. Drawing lessons from other countries, with the UK as a primary case study, this article proposes that the Nigerian state should create a regime for the disqualification of directors who are complicit in the violation of competition law by the companies they manage and direct. Furthermore, disqualification of directors for competition breaches (competition disqualification) will serve to bolster the existing sanctions already contained in the act, induce compliance and deter competition breaches by directors.
The article is structured in three main sections, excluding this introduction and the conclusion. The first discusses the importance of competition regulation in general, tracing its history, rationale and the implications for economic development. The next concentrates on the Nigerian framework for competition regulation and holistically analyses the substantive provisions of the FCCPA. It contends that there is particular need to facilitate corporate compliance through the imposition of strategic sanctions that not only target corporate revenues but also impose personal liability on directors in the form of competition disqualification, so as to optimize their commitment to the ideals of the act, dissuade breaches and complement existing sanctions. This section argues that the existing framework for sanctioning directors who breach the act may not sufficiently deter directors from misbehaving due to factors such as prosecutorial challenges. Furthermore that, if Nigerian courts opt to impose fines rather than incarcerate directors who commit competition offences, the intended effect of the criminalization of competition breaches would be considerably reduced. The final section examines competition disqualification in the UK, noting that the criminalization of cartel offences there has been largely ineffective, which all the more justifies disqualifying directors who breach competition law. The conclusion offers further suggestions and recommendations.
COMPETITION REGULATION: PURPOSE AND RATIONALE
Competition regulation prohibits practices or arrangements that distort or restrict competition and trade. It is carried out with a view to ensuring free and fair trade in the hope that this translates into innovation and economic development.Footnote 6 It is widely believed that unrestrained anti-competitive behaviour reduces consumer choice, increases prices and generally denies consumers and other excluded producers from benefiting optimally from trade liberalization. This is particularly so in countries where the majority live in conditions of relative poverty.Footnote 7 In the absence of regulatory and institutional safeguards, anti-competitive practices may give rise to the commission of cartel offences, such as the entering into of market-sharing agreements among a few firms in a sector, price fixing, limits on production or supply, bid-rigging, and other predatory behaviours that eliminate competition, to the detriment of the economy.Footnote 8 Such activities may also result in monopolies and the abuse by firms of their dominant market positions, which may impede growth, engender the artificial scarcity of goods and services, or result in the supply of inferior goods and services. These would in turn adversely impact innovation and negatively affect the development of quality products and services.Footnote 9 The latter objective of competition law accounts for why, even where businesses merge, they are discouraged from creating monopolies that may stifle economic freedoms.Footnote 10
Proponents of competition regulation have also suggested that healthy competition is indispensable for effective market reforms, first because it is an economic catalyst, particularly for developing countries, and secondly because it invariably translates into the gradual surrender to private enterprises of government control over poorly managed SOEs.Footnote 11 Still others have claimed that liberalization, free trade and free competition tend to translate over time into meaningful increases in cross-border trade and foreign direct investment. As such, countries that are keen to attain market efficiency are “forced” to open their markets to some form of competition.Footnote 12
Competition regulation is not only fair because it allows all parties to operate on an equal footing, it also has the added advantage of strengthening economies while enabling improved service delivery in general. A case in point is the Nigerian telecoms sector, which performed woefully when it was monopolized by the government-owned Nigerian Telecommunications Limited. The sector was eventually liberalized in 2001, with licensed operators (both local and foreign) allowed to compete among themselves in a regulated environment. The phenomenal consequences of the telecoms sector liberalization in Nigeria have been the subject of several studies.Footnote 13 Suffice to say that today the Nigerian telecommunications sector is widely adjudged to be one of the fastest growing telecoms sectors in the world, with the country having over 198 million active phone lines as at July 2020, up by over 28,000 per cent from the mere 700,000 lines operational in 2001.Footnote 14
Today there are very few countries that do not have some form of competition regulation geared towards the creation of level playing fields and the fostering of free markets in a bid to promote economic development and consumer welfare.Footnote 15 This rising spread of competition regulation is underpinned by the assumption that countries that uphold standards directed at free competition, tend to perform better than their counterparts that do not prioritize economic freedoms. On this point, the USA and the European Union (EU) are held out as examples of economic blocs that have outperformed other countries or regions that did not prioritize competition regulation.Footnote 16
Keen to optimize the benefits of globalization and develop their economies, developing countries in Africa, the Andean region and Asia have accepted the concept of free trade, at least in theory. Interestingly, several countries in these regions were historically characterized by state monopolization of strategic economic sectors and the absence of strong competition regulation. All that is changing, however, as several developing countries are jettisoning their traditional resistance to free trade in favour of economic liberalization. As noted earlier, one such country is Nigeria, which demonstrated this by enacting the FCCPA. The following analysis highlights the salient provisions of this act and its expected benefits, as well as the sanctions regime put in place to encourage compliance with its provisions.
AN OVERVIEW OF THE SUBSTANTIVE PROVISIONS OF THE FCCPA
The FCCPA is largely modelled on EU competition law.Footnote 17 As mentioned earlier, it seeks to regulate actions that may impede competition and consumer rights. The act is extensive and elaborate. Its provisions are far reaching and its scope reaches all stakeholders in the country. It applies to all agents of federal, state and local government that are engaged in commercial or economic activities.Footnote 18 The scope of the act extends to the activities of Nigerian citizens and corporate bodies incorporated in Nigeria, occurring within or outside the country, as well as to the conduct of persons in relation to the supply or acquisition of goods or services within Nigeria. Lastly, the FCCPA regulates acts outside Nigeria, carried out by any person in relation to the acquisition of shares or other assets that may result in a change in control of a business, or in any assets of a business in the country.Footnote 19
The FCCPA takes precedence over all previously enacted competition or consumer protection laws in Nigeria. It repealed the Consumer Protection Council Act 1992,Footnote 20 as well as the part of the Investment and Securities Act 2007 that dealt with mergers and acquisitions.Footnote 21 Its objectives include the promotion and maintenance of competitive markets in the Nigerian economy, the furtherance of economic efficiency, and the protection and advancement of the interests and welfare of consumers, by providing them with a wider variety of quality products at competitive prices. Other stated objectives include the prevention of restrictive or unfair business practices that may impede competition or constitute an abuse of a dominant position of market power in Nigeria, as well as the attainment of sustainable economic development.Footnote 22
The FCCPA also seeks to prevent and address anti-competitive practices and to create an environment that encourages entrepreneurs to benefit from their hard work. The FCCPA has 168 sections, divided into 18 parts, with two accompanying schedules. Its scope, objectives and application are covered by part 1.Footnote 23 The act contains extensive provisions that prohibit or regulate restrictive agreements,Footnote 24 abuse of dominant position,Footnote 25 monopolies,Footnote 26 pricesFootnote 27 and mergers.Footnote 28 It also regulates industriesFootnote 29 and criminalizes specific anti-competitive activities, such as price-fixing, conspiracy, bid-rigging, obstructing the investigation of an enquiry, offences against records (refusing to produce documents or supply information when required), giving false or misleading information, and failing to attend to give evidence before the Federal Competition and Consumer Protection Commission (FCCPC).Footnote 30 The FCCPA also makes extensive provision for consumer rights,Footnote 31 imposes duties on manufacturers, importers, distributors and suppliers of goods and services,Footnote 32 and provides mechanisms for the enforcement of consumer rights.Footnote 33 However, this article focuses on the FCCPA as it relates to competition law.
Furthermore, the FCCPA criminalizes and penalizes the contravention of its provisions, presumably to secure compliance and deter wrongdoing by undertakings. The various parts of the act contain prohibitions of anticompetitive conduct, as well as sanctions that may be imposed for contraventions. For example, it is an offence under the act for an undertaking to: enter into an agreement that tends to restrict or distort competition;Footnote 34 or persist in an anticompetitive agreement or decision that contravenes a directive of the FCCPC.Footnote 35 It is also an offence under the act for an undertaking to abuse its dominant market position,Footnote 36 or to contravene the provisions with respect to price regulation,Footnote 37 or to implement a merger without obtaining the FCCPC's approval.Footnote 38 Other offences contained in the act relate to impeding the FCCPC in its work, by: failing to furnish relevant information when required; providing a false statement, knowing it to be false in any material respect; or recklessly making a statement that is false in any material way.Footnote 39 Interestingly, for the majority of these offences, conviction of an individual undertaking attracts a fine or a prison term that may range from between three to five years.Footnote 40 In addition, if it is a company, the undertaking would generally be required to pay not more than 10 per cent of its turnover in the preceding business year as a fine,Footnote 41 while each of its directors would be liable to be prosecuted as well and, on conviction, would be subjected to penalties similar to those imposed on undertakings that are natural persons who are convicted for the same offence.Footnote 42
Cognisant of the need for a specialized adjudicatory process over competition and consumer related matters, the FCCPA established the Competition and Consumer Protection Tribunal (CCPT) and mandates it to hear complaints against undertakings or companies that engage in anti-competitive activities.Footnote 43 The CCPT is a quasi-court of record,Footnote 44 in which parties have a right to legal representation.Footnote 45 It adjudicates over conduct prohibited under the FCCPA, and exercises the powers and authority conferred on it under the act or any other enactment.Footnote 46 It also exercises appellate powers over the activities of the FCCPC and sector specific regulators regarding competition or consumer protection matters.Footnote 47 It may summon and enforce the attendance of any person before it and may examine a person under oath. It may also compel the discovery and production of documents, receive evidence on affidavit on anything that, in its opinion, is necessary to issue a final and reasoned decision on the merits of the matter before it.Footnote 48 The CCPT may also impose administrative penalties on undertakings that carry out a prohibited practice under the act or contravene or fail to comply with any interim order it issues.Footnote 49 That said, it may not issue an administrative penalty in excess of 10 per cent of an undertaking's combined annual turnover in Nigeria and exports from Nigeria during the preceding financial year.Footnote 50
Under section 52 of the FCCPA, the CCPT may make an order directing an undertaking to sell any portion or all of its shares, interests or assets if a practice prohibited under the act cannot adequately be remedied under any other provisions of the act, or if the practice substantially repeats conduct by that undertaking previously found by the CCPT to be a prohibited practice.Footnote 51 The CCPT's orders, rulings, awards and judgments are binding on the parties before it and may be enforced as a judgment of the Federal High Court.Footnote 52 Appeals may however lie from the CCPT's decisions to the Court of Appeal within 30 days from the delivery of the judgment.Footnote 53
The enforcement of competition law and the development of a healthy competition culture often entails the direct involvement of a competition regulator.Footnote 54 It is in view of this that the FCCPA makes extensive provision for the FCCPC,Footnote 55 established under part 2 of the act. This body took over the roles previously performed by the Securities and Exchange Commission in relation to mergers and acquisitions,Footnote 56 and replaced the Consumer Protection Council.Footnote 57 As the primary competitor regulator, the FCCPC administers and enforces the provisions of the act.Footnote 58
For a country that had never enacted comprehensive competition legislation, the FCCPA is indeed a welcome development. However, the effective enforcement of the act may be a different thing entirely. In this respect it is expedient for policymakers to be cognisant of the fact that the economic implications and ramifications of competition regulation create a strong likelihood that individuals who had operated unhindered under the corporate platform for decades, may attempt to resist the changes that the act attempts to foist on them. Some of these firms, which reigned supreme with the backing of either the government or corrupt elements, are likely to resist the fact that their activities have now been criminalized. Highly connected monopolists with deep pockets, may also attempt to frustrate the act's objectives. In order to forestall this from happening and to promote compliance, a strong sanctions enforcement mechanism needs to be in place. The creation of sufficient incentives for corporate compliance is thus indispensable for effective competition regulation. One of these incentives is the imposition of sanctions (criminal or civil) on firms that breach competition law.Footnote 59 These fines are usually levied on the basis of companies’ turnover.Footnote 60
Corporate bodies are naturally suited to large business enterprises and they may spawn subsidiaries through which they are able to dominate major economic activities in countries all over the world. This may nevertheless expose them to the temptation to abuse their position, and engage in cartel activities and other anti-competitive behaviours. It is in order to discourage companies from engaging in cartel operations or other anti-competitive activities, that companies are frequently subjected to relatively higher fines than those imposed on individuals. For example, the EU's Competition Commission responds aggressively to anti-competitive practices by imposing mammoth fines on firms that violate competition law.Footnote 61 However, the EU is not isolated in this. Countries such as South Korea, France, Brazil and the USA have also been known to hand down stiff corporate fines, where the need arises.Footnote 62
However, companies are artificial entities. They do not have hands, legs or minds. They operate through general meetings, boards of directors and an array of officers, agents and employees, who are their hands, wills and minds.Footnote 63 It is therefore reasonable that, in order to foster corporate compliance and deter wrongdoing, sanctions and consequences for corporate competition law breaches are directed not only at firms, but also at the natural persons who control them. Typically, the twin concepts of separate personality and limited liability ought to shield and protect directors, officers and employees from the liabilities and responsibilities of companies.Footnote 64 However, these protections can be severely abused by selfish and designing people. It is with the aim of forestalling these tendencies, that courts and legislators occasionally “lift the veil of incorporation” where necessary, to enable them to impose liability on unscrupulous persons who hide behind companies to perpetrate fraud or offend statutory provisions.Footnote 65
This “disregard” for corporate personality, although traditionally situated in company law, has been extended to competition regulation in countries such as the USA, Brazil, Chile, South Korea, Japan, South Africa, the UK and Australia, particularly in relation to directors and other corporate officers. Directors are the brains of companies. They determine overall corporate policy, and executive directors are usually involved in the day to day running of companies. Directors are thus strategically positioned largely to determine whether a country attains significant corporate compliance with its competition law. This accounts for why, along with companies, they are increasingly being targeted with sanctions for corporate breaches of competition law. In fact, in several countries directorsFootnote 66 may be imprisonedFootnote 67 or fined for being complicit in corporate competition breaches.Footnote 68 Targeting directors with personal liability also induces them to formulate internal strategies geared towards competition compliance.Footnote 69 Another justification for targeting directors is that, whereas corporate fines may harm “innocent” shareholders, imposing sanctions on directors is regarded as placing the “blame” squarely where it should be: on the persons who direct those companies.Footnote 70 Furthermore, achieving a deterrent by relying on fines is difficult because of legal and practical (insolvency) constraints, and also because fines imposed on the principal (company) may not necessarily deter corporate agents (directors) from engaging in wrongdoing.Footnote 71
In a similar vein, the FCCPA imposes personal liability on directors of companies that are in breach of competition law in certain instances.Footnote 72 For instance, the directors of a company that enters into an agreement in contravention of the act, are all liable to be prosecuted and, on conviction, may be fined as much as five million naira.Footnote 73 Similarly, the directors of a company that refuses to desist from abusing its dominant market position, shall be liable on conviction to imprisonment for a term not exceeding three years or to a fine of not more than 50 million naira, or to both a fine and imprisonment.Footnote 74
While the criminalization of companies and their officers for competition breaches is widespread, some countries also disqualify directors who are complicit in corporate competition breaches.Footnote 75 As a result, competition regulators in these countries have three main strategies for enforcing or securing corporate compliance with competition law. First, they may proceed against the revenues of errant companies. Secondly, they may institute criminal or civil proceedings against the individuals behind these companies, notably their directors. Lastly, they may also seek to disqualify those directors from directing companies for a defined period.
Although of relatively recent origin, the disqualification of company directors, who by their conduct prove themselves unworthy to be at the helm of corporate concerns, is now established as part of the company law of a number of countries.Footnote 76 In the Commonwealth, directors’ disqualification was first mooted by the Cohen Committee of 1962. However, it took the Companies Directors Disqualification Act 1986 (CDDA), in adopting the recommendations of the Cork Committee of 1982, to make directors’ disqualification part of UK law.Footnote 77 Despite being originally focused on directors who were involved in wrongful or fraudulent trading in insolvency, directors’ disqualification is widening in scope and application. In fact, in the UK, New Zealand, Australia and India, a person can now be disqualified from directorship if he oversees a company that habitually contravenes company law.Footnote 78 It is also becoming increasingly possible for the disqualification of a director in one country to render him unfit to become a director in another country.Footnote 79
Generally, the disqualification sanction is aimed at protecting the public from persons who may abuse the privileges associated with limited liability.Footnote 80 It also aims to minimize the extent to which such persons may repeat their omissions or misconduct.Footnote 81 By banning unfit persons from directorship, the sanction also seeks to prevent the recurrence of their misbehaviour and, by so doing, offers some protection to the public from their misdemeanours.Footnote 82 Directors’ disqualification therefore serves to forestall corporate opportunism, while strengthening corporate governance.Footnote 83 This is possible because disqualification on the ground of unfitness comes with attendant negative publicity, which may damage a director's reputation and ability to secure future work, especially in an internet age where such measures are increasingly having transnational implications.Footnote 84 Furthermore, a disqualified director may invariably be ineligible to join in the formation, promotion or management of companies,Footnote 85 or practise as a receiver, administrator or liquidator.Footnote 86
As with the UK and most of the Commonwealth, directors’ disqualification already exists in Nigerian company law, although it has not been applied strenuously.Footnote 87 The question is whether Nigeria should adopt a competition disqualification approach as a means of inducing corporate compliance with the FCCPA, or whether the existing sanctions for competition breaches contained in the act are sufficient for that purpose. To resolve this issue, the following section draws lessons from the UK.
LESSONS FROM THE UK
Although fines or prison sentences for cartel offences existed under the Enterprise Act 2002 (Enterprise Act),Footnote 88 since 2003 the UK has also made directors’ competition disqualification part of its sanction regime through section 9A and 9B of the CDDA as a means of stimulating corporate compliance.Footnote 89 Competition disqualification was considered the path to legitimizing individual sanctions and as being the most viable option available to the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) in sanctioning individuals who breach competition law.Footnote 90 It is to that end that section 9 of the CDDA authorizes the CMA to enforce two types of competition disqualification: competition disqualification orders (CDOs)Footnote 91 and competition disqualification undertakings (CDUs).Footnote 92
Under section 9A of the CDDA, courts may be moved by the CMA (or, in certain circumstances, any other specified regulator) to declare as unfit and to disqualify from directorship, a person who was a director of a company that contravened competition law.Footnote 93 The section provides elaborate conditions that must be satisfied before CDOs can be imposed. The first is that an undertaking of which a person is a director must have breached competition lawFootnote 94 and the court must consider that his conduct as director of that company makes him unfit to be concerned in the management of a company.Footnote 95 Subsection 4 provides further guidance on how the courts may ascertain when a company has breached competition law. Under that subsection, a company breaches competition law if it engages in conduct that infringes either chapter 1 or 2 of the Competition Act of 1988, or articles 101 or 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (EU Treaty).Footnote 96 In concluding whether or not a person is unfit to be concerned in the management of a company, subsection 9A(5) of the CDDA provides additional rules regarding to what the court must or may have regard, and to what it must not have regard. First, the court must Footnote 97 have regard to whether or not subsection 9A(6) applies to the director. This subsection in effect applies to a director whose conduct contributed to the company's breach of competition law.Footnote 98 Even where his conduct did not contribute to the breach, the court must nevertheless consider whether the director had reasonable grounds to suspect whether the conduct breached competition law, but nevertheless took no steps to prevent it.Footnote 99 Even if he did not know, it would still have to consider whether he ought to have known.Footnote 100 Secondly the court may Footnote 101 have regard to the conduct of the person as a director of a company in connection with any other breach of competition law. It must not Footnote 102 however, have regard to the matters mentioned in schedule 1.Footnote 103
In contrast to the CDO, the CDU is essentially an out-of-court procedure in which, in order to avoid litigation, a person who has breached competition law in his capacity as a director of a company agrees or undertakes not to act as a director of a company for a specified period of time.Footnote 104 CDUs are essentially an alternative to judicial proceedings, which may be costly and time-wasting, and may come with attendant loss of confidentiality and negative publicity.
In practice however, there have been relatively few competition disqualifications in the UK. Caliskan notes that the number of disqualification proceedings so far instituted by the CMA is extremely low, when compared to other actions instituted by the agency against companies for other breaches of competition law.Footnote 105 In fact he observes that only two CDOsFootnote 106 and four CDUsFootnote 107 have been made in more than 15 years since competition disqualification became part of UK law. This is in direct contrast to a total of 2,041 cases that have been instituted for other related breaches of competition law. That said, it may appear that the number of competition disqualifications in the UK is gradually increasing. This fact, which may be borne out of a recent realization that directors’ disqualification is a viable tool for competition law enforcement, perhaps explains why most of the CDUs that the CMA has received so far, actually only commenced in 2016.
The question then is, why have competition disqualifications been so few in a country that introduced the sanction as a means of complementing the criminal sanctions available against directors? Again, Caliskan identified resource challenges as well as a lack of clarity in the concept of fitness or unfitness of directors as being among the most prominent factors militating against the effectiveness of competition disqualification in the UK. On the other hand, Stephan suggests that the “immunity” enjoyed by companies through leniency programmes may also have remotely or directly been responsible for why there have been so few competition disqualifications in the UK.Footnote 108
The authors are of the view that Nigeria, like the UK, also needs a CDO regime and that the omission of competition disqualification from the FCCPA is a major drawback for a country that has grappled with monopolies and the dominance of crucial economic sectors by few players.Footnote 109 It is therefore suggested that, in order to induce further corporate compliance with the FCCPA and to deter wrongdoing, Nigeria should adopt a directors’ competition disqualification mechanism. There are some advantages to adopting a competition disqualification regime in Nigeria. First, competition disqualification will complement the criminal sanctions that already exist under the act. Secondly, because disqualification procedures are civil in nature, all that would be necessary to disqualify a director would be to establish his wrongdoing on a balance of probabilities. This means that establishing the facts to ground the disqualification of a director would be quicker and easier to establish when compared to securing a conviction for competition offences, which requires proof beyond reasonable doubt.Footnote 110 Competition disqualifications would be even faster if the FCCPC were authorized to disqualify directors, as is the case in Australia,Footnote 111 or if it were empowered to receive disqualification undertakings in a similar way to the situation in the UK.
One of two courses of action is therefore recommended for Nigeria. The first, similar to strict tort liability, is for the CCPT to be authorized automatically to disqualify directors of companies that breach the FCCPA, unless there is proof that those directors were not directly involved in carrying out the actions that amounted to the breach in question or were justifiably absent from meetings where decisions relating to the breach was taken, or that they did all that could reasonably be done to avoid the breach. This means that, when it is established that a company is in breach of competition law, all its directors should be rendered liable to be disqualified from managing companies, unless they can prove that they were not complicit in the breach. Such a measure would place the burden for securing corporate compliance with competition law on corporate management. It would thus incentivize all directors, executive and non-executive, to play more active roles in monitoring the affairs of companies and in seeing that internal self-regulating mechanisms are put in place to prevent competition breaches. The disadvantage in this approach is that it may dissuade some competent persons from agreeing to act as directors of companies, since doing so may expose them to the risk of being automatically disqualified if the companies they manage are convicted of contravening competition law. Their position would be more precarious, since directors may not always have direct control over what their delegates do and, even where they take measures to promote internal compliance, they cannot guarantee that persons working under them would comply with such measures.
In the light of the challenges with the “automatic disqualification approach” highlighted above, a second and better suggestion is that Nigeria should adopt an approach similar to that of the UK as contained in section 9A of the CDDA. It should thus authorize the CCPT to disqualify directors of companies that breach competition law by abusing their dominant position, entering into restrictive agreements, rigging bids or being involved in cartels, once it is established that their conduct renders them unfit to be concerned in the management of a company. In this respect, the CCPT, in determining unfitness, should be guided by rules aimed at ensuring that only culpable persons are disqualified. In this respect, it is proposed that Nigeria should emulate and apply rules similar to those provided for under section 9A of the CDDA, as discussed earlier in this section. In effect, the CCPT should have to consider whether the conduct of a director contributed to corporate competition contraventions, and, even where it did not, whether, on having reasonable grounds to suspect that the conduct of the entity in question amounted to a breach, the director did not take adequate steps to prevent it from occurring. Lastly, even where a director was unaware that a company was acting contrary to the FCCPA, the CCPT should still be able to determine whether or not he ought to have known that particular conduct breached the act. From the perspective of the directors, the advantage of this approach is that it avails directors of the opportunity to establish their innocence on any case instituted against them before the CCPT. It will also curtail regulatory or judicial arbitrariness by offering clear guidance to the FCCPC and the CCPT on the steps to take when companies infringe competition law.
As it stands, the FCCPA does not authorize the CCPT to adjudicate over matters instituted against directors, rather it provides for the institution of criminal prosecutions against them, presumably before the Federal High Court.Footnote 112 What this means is that the CCPT may only issue administrative sanctions against undertakings under section 51 of the FCCPA, but cannot disqualify directors. In this respect, it is suggested that the FCCPA be amended in order to authorize and empower the CCPT, at the instance of the FCCPC or a specified regulator, to impose CDOs on directors who are found to have been complicit in corporate contraventions of the act. Authorizing the CCPT rather than the Federal High Court to have oversight over the imposition of CDOs has two advantages. First, being a specialized adjudicator over a highly technical area of law, the members of the panel who are experts in competition and consumer matters,Footnote 113 would be more versed and experienced in competition law than the regular judge who, while having general knowledge of competition law, may not be an expert in that field. Secondly, disqualification matters would be more quickly attended to if handled by the CCPT rather than regular courts, where litigants often face undue delays due to the fact that most courts are overburdened with unusually large numbers of cases.Footnote 114
A contrary argument to competition disqualifications in Nigeria may be that the FCCPA already imposes sufficient criminal sanctions on directors and so introducing competition disqualification may be stretching directors’ personal liability beyond what is necessary to incentivize them to steer their companies towards compliance with the act. In theory, the authors might agree with this line of thinking since the prospect of imprisonment for any length of time ought to be sufficient to dissuade directors from involvement in cartel offences and other breaches of competition law.Footnote 115 Adding disqualification may amount to overregulation, which may at least in theory also discourage some capable persons from agreeing to “serve” as company directors. While there may be some merit in this line of argument, in practice the experience of several countries has demonstrated that criminalization of competition breaches alone has done little to discourage corporate wrongdoing. This is because criminalizing competition breaches will only deter wrongdoing if attendant sanctions are diligently enforced. However, securing competition convictions is not very easy, due to the highly technical nature of competition law and to the fact that guilt must be proved beyond reasonable doubt.
Even where convictions are secured, courts tend to hand down fines rather than incarcerate directors,Footnote 116 which would normally have a stronger deterrent effect.Footnote 117 This option of settling for fines is due to a general perception that competition offences are “white collar” crimes for which incarceration may be harsh for what may not be unambiguously and inherently seen to be criminal.Footnote 118 This milder view of competition offences is widespread, despite the fact that the very foundations of competition regulation were rooted not in civil, but in criminal law.Footnote 119 In fact, perhaps with the exception of the USA and Canada, very few countries consistently incarcerate directors for breaching competition law.Footnote 120 The UK for example, which criminalized cartel offences in the hope of reproducing the successes recorded by the USA in its long history of enforcing the Sherman Act 1890 and other relevant laws,Footnote 121 has only successfully prosecuted five persons in over 15 years since it criminalized cartel behaviour.Footnote 122 The UK is not alone in this respect. Evidence from a study suggests that, as of 2016, there were an average of only two cartel prosecutions annually in France in the first two decades after the offence was introduced by article L420-6 of the French Commercial Code.Footnote 123 Germany on the other hand, only criminalizes “bid rigging”, with other related competition breaches sanctioned under administrative law.Footnote 124 One take away from the experiences of the UK, France and Germany is that reliance on criminal prosecution alone may not sufficiently dissuade directors from breaching competition law.Footnote 125
CONCLUSION
The long-term effect of prolonging the existence of unregulated markets or having inadequate competition protection is that “a deep-rooted business culture of non-regulation is fixed in the minds of the general public, generation after generation, ranging from the educated and uneducated small consumers to the businessman and even, notably, the lawmaker”.Footnote 126 This has been the experience in Nigeria, which, in seeking to overturn such a situation and open up its markets, enacted the FCCPA. In so doing however, Nigeria's legislators perhaps did not go far enough because they ignored the fact that other countries, such as the UK and Australia, have adopted competition disqualification strategies aimed at deterring directorial wrongdoing and spurring corporate compliance. As such, the thesis of this article has been that Nigeria should promote corporate compliance with the FCCPA by disqualifying directors, whose conduct contributes to corporate competition breaches, from being concerned in the management of companies. This call is further justified on the basis that the country may not have the necessary regulatory capacity to enforce the penalties contained in the FCCPA effectively, although prosecutorial capacity may be developed over time. Another issue is that, even if directors are successfully prosecuted, they will rarely be incarcerated if the experience of other countries is a guide. In effect, as long as the alternative of a “fine” remains available to Nigerian courts, directors will rarely be imprisoned for competition offences; competition disqualification by the CCPT will therefore complement the criminalization of competition offences, or serve as an alternative.
In adopting a competition disqualification framework, however, it is necessary for the law to be properly drafted and for its scope to be sufficiently broad to limit the possibility for technical loopholes. For example, directors who are subjected to competition disqualification should equally be barred from acting as shadow directors and from dominating firms, either in their capacity as majority shareholders or as advisers. To that end, disqualified persons should also be banned from being involved in the management of any company directly or indirectly, during the period of their disqualification.Footnote 127 Furthermore, the consequences for breaching disqualification orders or undertakings should be stringent so as to discourage misbehaviour not only by disqualified directors but by other directors as well. Competition disqualifications should also be publicized to protect the public further. Furthermore, persons who are subjected to competition disqualification outside Nigeria should also be prohibited from directing companies in Nigeria, provided there is evidence that they were justifiably disqualified in those countries.
CONFLICTS OF INTEREST
None