Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T12:06:21.200Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Which Public? Whose Goods? What We Know (and What We Don't) About Public Goods in Rural China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 December 2016

Sara A. Newland*
Affiliation:
Department of political science, Villanova University. Email: sara.newland@villanova.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

What have we learned from a decade of research on the provision of public goods in the Chinese countryside? This review article surveys the literature in political science, economics and Chinese area studies. It describes the three dominant types of explanations for variation in the quality of public goods: local elections, social sanctioning and economic policies. It then argues that these findings are plagued by a set of common problems. Scholars mean different things when they use the term “public goods,” making their findings difficult to compare. Furthermore, the most common measures of public goods ignore the ways in which local officials manipulate statistics to enhance their career prospects and the interconnected nature of geographic-administrative units in the Chinese state. I suggest some ways to address these problems, and make recommendations for new directions in research on the topic.

摘要

这十年来, 有关中国农村公共物品供给的研究有哪些结论? 这篇评论文章总结了政治学、经济学与中国区域研究等三个学科的研究成果。根据本文的观察, 现有的研究对于公共物品的质量不均主要有三种解释: 地方选举、社会制裁和经济政策。作者发现, 这些理论都有类似的缺点。首先, 对于“公共物品” 定义不精确, 让研究结果难以比较。此外, 常用的公共物品计量方法忽略了地方官员为了政绩操纵统计数据, 也少考虑中国各级政府间的互动与联繫。最后, 作者提出几个新的研究方向来克服上述问题, 以深化我们对于中国农村公共物品供给的认识。

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 2016 

After our first year in Sancha … Mimi and I donated one hundred dollars’ worth of cement to the village, specifying that it could be used to make any necessary repairs to the new Sancha road. The Party Secretary took the gift and paved a perfect sidewalk to her house, and now she could ride her motorcycle all the way to the front door.

Peter Hessler (Reference Hessler2010), Country Driving, 190–91

China's staggering urban growth has largely left the countryside behind.Footnote 1 First used to subsidize the urban economy during the Maoist era, then left to stagnate as decollectivization destroyed the limited rural social services that existed under Mao, rural China has long been poor – and poorly served by local governments. Yet, in the past decade a set of changes has converged to foster a sense of cautious optimism among China-watchers that the situation might improve. Investment in rural infrastructure has dramatically increased. Village elections have become increasingly competitive, even if they remain imperfect,Footnote 2 and many villagers now exercise greater control over the management of village finances through the participatory decision-making model known as “one affair, one discussion” (yi shi yi yi 一事一议).Footnote 3 Policymakers have become more sympathetic to the countryside; the Hu–Wen administration attempted to rebalance China's development strategy, implementing the “Building a new socialist countryside” (shehuizhuyi xin nongcun jianshe 社会主义新农村建设) policies for improving rural health care, modernizing agriculture and building infrastructure.

These changes – combined with the increased ease of survey research in rural China – have inspired new research questions and created new data sources with which to answer them. Has the combination of top-down pro-rural policies and bottom-up accountability mechanisms improved the quality of public goods and services in the Chinese countryside? If not, what problems have prevented greater progress? Since 2004, numerous researchers have sought to answer these questions, focusing on the effects of village elections, tax-for-fee reform, social networks, officials’ promotion incentives and other factors on public goods – although the county level, increasingly responsible for the provision of public goods, remains understudied. What have we learned from a decade of research on the provision of public goods in the Chinese countryside?Footnote 4

Several points of agreement emerge.Footnote 5 First, the direct election of village heads has increased expenditure on village-level public goods and services. Second, social ties to citizens compel village officials to expend effort and resources on the provision of public goods and services. Third, changes in China's economic policies – among them tax-for-fee reform, the 2008–2009 economic stimulus plan, an increase in the outsourcing of public services, and the recentralization of rural finances and public service provision – have affected village leaders’ ability to provide public goods and services.

At the same time, existing studies often depart from the orthodox definition of public goods, and disagree about how the provision of public goods should be measured. Furthermore, the most commonly used measures in the quantitative literature line up poorly with our qualitative knowledge of rural governance in China. As a result, it is difficult to know what to make of these findings on their own terms, and equally difficult to draw them into broader comparative conversations about authoritarianism, local governance and provision of public goods. This represents a lost opportunity. The study of local public goods provision is a growth industry in political science and economics, and the fact that China faces the same challenges as many developing countries – but addresses these challenges with a distinctive set of rural governance policies – makes China a useful comparison case. However, existing scholarship on the provision of public goods in China has largely focused on village leaders’ decisions about resource allocation, and has ignored the questions about free-riding and cooperation that are central to the study of the provision of public goods in other contexts. As a result, these literatures share a common term – public goods – but otherwise have little to say to each other.

What Are Public Goods?

Public goods have two key properties: they are non-rivalrous and non-excludable (see Table 1).Footnote 6 One person's use of a non-rivalrous good does not diminish its availability to others; the clean air that I breathe does not make the air that you breathe dirtier. Non-excludable goods benefit both those who contribute and those who do not. For example, all of a country's residents reap the rewards of national defence regardless of whether they pay taxes that contribute to that defence or not.

Table 1: Types of Goods

In combination, these two qualities mean that public goods pose particular challenges that cannot be easily solved by market mechanisms; without government intervention, they are likely to be underprovided relative to the population's demand for them. In particular, public goods are plagued by the free-rider problem. Since non-contributors and contributors can benefit equally from public goods, individuals have little incentive to pay their fair share. There is, therefore, little profit to be made from providing public goods, and while demand for them may be high, supply – if left to the market alone – will almost certainly be low.

While these problems mean that governments typically provide public goods, particular attributes of local communities may either encourage citizens to “carry their weight” or exacerbate the free-rider problem. Within close-knit communities, the fear of social sanctioning may encourage citizens to contribute even when pure self-interest would lead them to do otherwise. In rural Kenya, for instance, parents could be compelled to donate to village schools if free riders were socially sanctioned; ethnically homogenous communities were able to implement these sanctions more effectively, and had better public goods as a result.Footnote 7 Similarly, strong norms of reciprocity within cultural groups may encourage seemingly selfless contributions to public goods.Footnote 8 Finally, homogenous communities may share policy and spending preferences to a greater degree than do diverse communities. Citizens in culturally or ethnically homogenous areas may thus be willing to pay their fair share, but those in more ethnically diverse areas prefer to minimize public goods spending and instead pay privately for their preferred services.Footnote 9

What We Know About the Past

The provision of public goods has since 1949 been one of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) regime's greatest successes – and among its most notable failures. The new communist leadership bought peasants’ loyalty with public health campaigns, irrigation projects and basic medical care. Although these services were rudimentary, they represented a significant improvement in areas where such services had historically been non-existent. The provision of public goods was gradually institutionalized through the work unit in urban areas and through the collective in the countryside. The quality of rural public services ebbed and flowed with the political tides during the Maoist era. The system for providing public goods collapsed entirely during the Great Leap Forward and its tragic aftermath, then experienced a resurgence with the revival of the Cooperative Medical Scheme (hezuo yiliao zhidu 合作医疗制度) and the arrival of the “barefoot doctors” during the Cultural Revolution.Footnote 10 As Tony Saich rightly points out, it is difficult to know how to evaluate the effect of these early services, since many of their gains were wiped out by the horror of the Great Leap famine.Footnote 11 Nonetheless, during the Maoist period a widespread, if basic, infrastructure for the provision of public goods was essentially created from scratch, and brought about dramatic improvements: life expectancy rose by nearly 33 years over the course of the period, literacy rates increased dramatically, and rural infrastructure expanded.Footnote 12

“Reform and opening” destroyed many of the Maoist-era institutions that provided public goods. Decollectivization undermined the basis for rural health services and access to basic health services dropped dramatically. By 1984, only 5 per cent of villages had health care coverage via the Cooperative Medical Scheme.Footnote 13 In urban areas, state-owned enterprises struggled to adapt to the demands of the market and cut costs by slashing the services they provided. Private services emerged as a replacement, but access was limited and unequal.Footnote 14 Whereas at the start of the reform period free local health care in the countryside was nearly universal – in 1975, 85 per cent of the population had access to care – coverage had dropped to just 10 per cent by 2005.Footnote 15 This situation more or less remained the case for decades, and life expectancy rates and other measures were virtually constant for much of the reform period.

The central government's renewed attention to providing public goods in the early 21st century represented the convergence of two sets of policy priorities. The first was an attempt to ameliorate rural–urban inequality, the second a desire to rebuild (albeit on a more limited scale) the social safety net that had existed for most of the Maoist period. Investment in rural infrastructure improved dramatically, with investment in rural roads growing from 35.8 to 124.2 billion yuan between 2001 and 2004, and infrastructure investment exploding after 2008 to offset the effects of the global financial crisis.Footnote 16 Rural health insurance, largely destroyed by decollectivization, was also revived. Whereas in 1993 only 6.6 per cent of rural residents had health coverage, in 2011 the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (xinxing nongcun hezuo yiliao zhidu 新型农村合作医疗制度) covered 832 million people.Footnote 17 The central government also invested in subsidies and fee exemptions for poor students, urban health and workplace injury insurance, and a welfare programme for the poorest citizens called the Minimum Living Standard Scheme (dibao 低保). These programmes, largely implemented by county governments, have grown at a rapid pace. For example, by 2011, the dibao covered more than 50 million people.Footnote 18 Villages, once the primary providers of rural public goods, continue to play a sizeable role in providing some public goods (the construction of local roads and irrigation projects, for instance), and funding for these projects remains limited.Footnote 19 However, the increasing centralization of rural public goods has changed both the amount and the funding structure of these goods. Overall investment in village public goods and the share of investment that comes from higher levels of government have both increased substantially (from 350 yuan per capita in 1997 to nearly 1,000 yuan in 2008). Nearly 75 per cent of these funds now come from the township level and above.Footnote 20

What We Know About the Present

Village elections and the provision of public goods

The literature on the local provision of public goods consistently finds that elected village officials provide better public goods than appointed ones, and that more democratic election procedures are associated with better provision. Two categories of explanations, which I term electoral accountability and resource mobilization, provide potential causal mechanisms linking democracy to better public goods.Footnote 21 Electoral accountability can take several forms. Villagers may be better than higher-level officials at monitoring local officials. When village heads are accountable to villagers (who may vote them out of office for poor performance), they are less likely to get away with misuse of funds because their wasteful spending is more likely to be observed. As a result, the implementation of village elections has led to greater investment in the public goods that villagers care about, such as irrigation in farming villages.Footnote 22 The increased transparency that elections create also decreases wasteful spending, an effect that is magnified when the village head shares power with other local elites.Footnote 23 Other work in this vein argues that direct election makes representatives more accountable to villagers and results in higher spending on public goods – so long as the position of village representative is relatively lucrative.Footnote 24 Positive “neighbour effects” – such that more investment in public goods in nearby locales motivates officials to provide better public goods in their own – are also induced by village democracy.Footnote 25 These effects have changed over time as rural China's economic policy environment has shifted. More democratic village governance (measured by the frequency of villagers’ meetings and the election of village cadres) had no effect on levels of expenditure on public goods before the implementation of tax-for-fee reform, but led to higher levels afterwards.Footnote 26

These studies suggest that elections induce an “electoral connection” that makes cadres understand and respond to villagers’ policy preferences.Footnote 27 A second body of work on accountability to voters treats the provision of public goods as “pork-barrel politics,” a tool for buying votes on election day. Because public goods benefit the entire community rather than just a small group of elites, they help officials to mobilize a large number of voters, as do efforts to redistribute village income towards the poor.Footnote 28 Renfu Luo et al. find that elected village officials spend more on village infrastructure than do appointed officials; the authors argue that cadres are more likely to be re-elected when they distribute “pork” – in the form of public goods – to their constituents.Footnote 29 These findings are contested, however, by research that looks at the distribution of projects across natural villages within a given administrative village. While both the village head and the village Party secretary use their positions to distribute pork to their home natural villages, they pay a price for doing so: village leaders who pander to their neighbours are less likely to be re-elected.Footnote 30

The second mechanism, resource mobilization, refers to the village head's ability to compel villagers to contribute to public goods. Unsurprisingly, wealthier villages invest more in public goods than do poor villages.Footnote 31 However, the available resources may be endogenous to the relationship between officials and villagers. In an interesting side-note to their main findings, Monica Martinez-Bravo et al. find that villagers pay more towards public goods when the village head is elected rather than appointed.Footnote 32 Resource mobilization for the provision of public goods can also be an impetus for (rather than an outcome of) village elections. China's economic liberalization means that the state can no longer fund itself by extracting monopoly rents from the command economy, and instead must rely on “taxation by consent” to pay for public goods.Footnote 33 But, villagers may be unwilling to make these contributions without a greater input into their use, resulting in the creation of elected village committees (cunmin huiyi 村民会议).

Social networks and the provision of public goods

A second set of findings concerns the relationship between social networks and the provision of public goods. Citizens use social pressure to hold officials accountable, even when democratic accountability is limited. Lily Tsai finds that groups which are “encompassing” – open to all within the village – and “embedding” (meaning that village officials participate in the group) offer higher “moral standing” to officials who provide high-quality public goods.Footnote 34 More recent work agrees but focuses narrowly on the participation of village officials in lineage groups.Footnote 35 These social ties benefit villagers, who receive better public goods, but also help the officials who provide these goods: working with social groups to “coproduce” public goods improves village officials’ perceptions of local state authority, and makes officials more optimistic about citizens’ compliance.Footnote 36

Social ties between lower- and higher-level officials also improve the provision of public goods. Village and township officials with strong ties to higher-level officials may effectively lobby their superiors for resource transfers that can be devoted to public goods projects.Footnote 37 And, social ties between provincial Party secretaries and provincial elites may shift the Party secretaries’ preferences away from those of the central government and closer to those of provincial elites, leading them to spend more on public services. Surprisingly, they do so even though they may incur a career penalty for prioritizing provincial social welfare needs over the central government's policy goals.Footnote 38

Social ties between citizens may affect the quality of local public goods as well. Consistent with much of the research described in the previous section, Gerard Padro i Miquel and his co-authors find that elections increase the expenditure on public goods using funds raised by the village, but show that this effect is smaller in religiously fragmented communities. One possible explanation is that religiously homogenous villages are better at holding officials accountable. However, religiously diverse villages may also have a lower demand for public goods, with villagers preferring to pay for goods and services that only benefit their own religious group.Footnote 39 Qin Tu and his co-authors reach a similar conclusion in their study of the reconversion of forest land to private farmland after the end of a government-funded “grain to green” programme.Footnote 40 “Kinship trust” leads farmers to prioritize private benefits for themselves and their clan members (and thus to convert forests into farmland for their private use), whereas individuals with general trust in the whole community also value public goods and are more likely to maintain reforested land. Finally, similar to both Lily Tsai and Jie Chen and Narisong Huhe, Yiqing Xu and Yang Yao find that strong lineage groups improve the provision of village public goods.Footnote 41 However, they find little evidence that these ties hold officials accountable to citizens, arguing instead that officials who belong to large clans can overcome collective action problems and compel their fellow clan members to contribute to public goods instead of free-riding.

Provision of public goods and the local political economy

The third set of conclusions evaluates the effects of recent economic policy changes on the provision of public goods. Tax-for-fee reform eliminated a long-standing source of rural discontentment, but also diminished village resources for public goods.Footnote 42 Several sources find that tax-for-fee reform had a negative effect on village-level provision of public goods because villages could not pay for these goods themselves and funding from county governments decreased.Footnote 43 Ethan Michelson agrees that tax reform posed a serious threat to village-level provision, but argues that this was a “short-run” effect in the mid-2000s and that “longer-run trends have been, on balance, positive.”Footnote 44

If tax-for-fee reform hurt the provision of public goods by diminishing local funding sources, more recent policies that have increased available funding have enabled improvements in rural public goods. Michelson argues that the large-scale economic stimulus programme put in place to limit the effects of the global financial crisis on the Chinese economy dramatically increased spending on rural infrastructure and public goods and services.Footnote 45 This rapid inflow of new funds improved these services and ameliorated longstanding state–society tensions. Bruce Dickson sees this increased investment in public goods as part of a broader attempt to update the “China model” in the wake of the financial crisis, in the hope that increased investment in public goods will forestall demands for political reform.Footnote 46

The abolition of school fees (2006) also affected public goods provision. In a national survey, this policy change increased citizens’ preference for state-funded education. Lü Xiaobo argues that this shift in attitude was driven by citizens’ growing awareness of the policy change, not by the material benefits citizens received.Footnote 47 This increased policy awareness has had important implications for citizens’ support of the CCP regime as citizens’ trust in the central government, but not in the local government, has increased.

The fiscal relationship among different levels of the Chinese party-state also affects the quality of local public goods provision. Economic decentralization creates cross-pressures that both help and hinder: on the one hand, local leaders may understand the needs of their communities better (and feel more obligated to serve these communities) than do provincial elites; on the otherhand, decentralization leaves cash-strapped localities largely responsible for funding their own public goods and services, which can undermine public goods provision. One study finds greater evidence for the first hypothesis: the infant mortality rate is lower in provinces that grant counties greater fiscal autonomy and where county governments take on a relatively large share of total provincial expenditure.Footnote 48

Finally, non-state actors play an increasingly important role in the provision of public goods owing to a policy shift towards collaborative service delivery. The 2002 Government Procurement Law allowed local governments to contract with the private sector (including for-profit firms and non-profit organizations), and the law had an almost immediate effect. From 2002 to 2004, about one-third of government expenditures on services went to outsourced services. This change reflects the Chinese government's desire to become a regulator rather than a direct service provider.Footnote 49 It is also a response to social and demographic shifts (rural-to-urban migration and a large aging population) that have made traditional place-based state services untenable.Footnote 50 However, power remains firmly in state hands: non-governmental organizations still have little say in the policy process, local governments typically contract with firms and social organizations that already have close ties to the state, and outsourcing contributes to the state's legitimacy by “co-opting external players and stakeholders.”Footnote 51 Findings on the effects of outsourcing are mixed: some suggest that outsourced services are often low quality and poorly regulated, whereas others find that outsourcing lowers costs and improves the quality of services.Footnote 52

What Don't We Know? Limitations of the Existing Literature

These sets of findings comprise a rich scholarly conversation on the causes and consequences of rural public goods provision. However, the concept of public goods, as the term is used in the literature on rural China, has fallen victim to “conceptual stretching.”Footnote 53 Two problems have emerged as a result. First, the literature addresses fundamentally different concerns than work on the same topic in other contexts, inhibiting cross-national comparison. And second, although dozens of China scholars use the term “public goods,” they often mean quite different things.

Problems of conceptualization

To understand some of these problems, it is useful to return to the orthodox definition of public goods given above. A public good is non-rivalrous (one person's use of it does not diminish its availability to others) and non-excludable (the good is available to all, and no one can be prevented from enjoying its benefits). To what degree is the literature on the provision of public goods in China consistent with this definition? While some work is careful to focus on true public goods, much does not, or else lumps together a variety of public services and infrastructure projects with varying degrees of “public good-ness,” resulting in a substantial disconnect between the main arguments of the comparative literature on the provision of public goods and the arguments advanced by China scholars.

China does face some distinctive challenges when it comes to providing public goods. Wherever formal accountability is weak, officials may have little incentive to provide goods at all, or may use public funds for personal enrichment – an explanation for underprovision that may not apply to democracies.Footnote 54 But, this in itself does not explain the China literature's inconsistency with other work on public goods. Indeed, research on provision of public goods in other contexts illustrates that many of the same dynamics (free-riding, a reluctance to share public goods across ethnic and other identity lines, and so on) exist in autocracies and democracies alike.Footnote 55

Non-rivalrousness

A handful of studies of public goods in China have focused on goods that are truly non-rivalrous. Efforts to prevent desertification in the north-west, for instance, benefit everyone who lives in the area, as do “grain to green” reforestation programmes.Footnote 56 Many other studies include measures of true public goods – centralized village sanitation facilities or dumpsters, management of publicly owned village forests and grasslands, and potable drinking water, to name a few examples – within an index designed to measure the overall quality of public goods provision.Footnote 57 However, these measures are often lumped together with other categories of public expenditure that are not necessarily public goods. Take the example of paved village roads. As the epigraph to this article highlights, expenditures on paved roads do not necessarily benefit villagers, and how public these goods really are likely depends on which roads local governments choose to pave. This is not to say that commonly used measures like public expenditure on road construction necessarily violate the non-rivalrousness requirement. Instead, it is a call for future researchers to complement quantitative measures with qualitative inquiry into the substantive meaning of these measures on the ground, and to differentiate more clearly between public expenditures and public goods.

Furthermore, most existing work on the provision of public goods treats the administrative village as the unit of analysis, despite the fact that the non-rivalrousness condition does not hold across different natural villages within a single administrative village. Village resources are limited, and projects that benefit one natural village diminish the resources available to others. Future work would thus do well to investigate the distributional patterns of public spending within a single geographic-administrative unit; the question of who benefits may well reveal more than do the myriad studies of aggregate village spending.Footnote 58

The importance of these distributional patterns was clear in my fieldwork in Yunnan province, where local governments were often cash-strapped and the funds available for public goods and services quite limited. One county middle school, for instance, relied on donations from a local cement factory to complete new construction projects at the school. The school's principal, who was politically well-connected and skilled at using his influence to benefit the school, had succeeded in improving the school's physical infrastructure through these kinds of connections.Footnote 59 But, the resources for such public–private partnerships were finite, and schools whose leaders lacked the political acumen of this particular principal were unable to make similar improvements to their infrastructure. These distributional questions are central to the quality of rural public services but suggest that the distribution of these services is governed by quite a different logic than truly non-rivalrous goods like water and air quality.

Non-excludability

The degree to which so-called public goods in China fulfil the non-excludability criterion also varies substantially. By lumping together goods and services that can be targeted to specific recipients with those that cannot, much of the existing literature makes it difficult to assess whether the problems of non-excludability are actually relevant to rural China. Indices that combine true public goods with ones that can be limited to contributors may be useful for understanding how much local governments spend on a range of public goods and services, but they muddy our understanding of the patterns of provision and use that actually result from this spending. If the quality of so-called public goods is poor, is it because they are overused, as we would expect of non-excludable goods? Or because citizens refuse to contribute to their upkeep? By contrast, the quality of excludable goods might suffer owing to imperfect markets or factors that make it difficult for buyers to assess their value accurately. Disaggregating these different types of goods would open up new avenues of research on the distinct mechanisms that undermine (or improve) the quality of each type.

The dynamics of rural education and health service provision illustrate some of the problems with treating these services as public goods. Some of the most frequently used measures of so-called public goods – spending on teachers’ salaries, number of teachers, number of hospital beds per capita, spending on medical clinics – ignore the fact that citizens can be (and frequently are) excluded from using these services in several ways. First, citizens’ access to health services in the countryside is largely determined by their ability to pay. Although the New Cooperative Medical Scheme (NCMS) has increased access to rural health care by diminishing the cost to citizens, citizens typically pay for services in cash up front and are later reimbursed by their local health insurance office. This payment structure imposes an insuperable barrier to medical care for typically cash-strapped rural families.Footnote 60 The scheme's low reimbursement rate for catastrophic illnesses also makes it difficult for the sickest individuals to afford care. One study found that in 2007, patients with medical expenditures greater than 10,000 yuan, although promised a reimbursement rate of over 40 per cent, were in fact reimbursed just 2.18 per cent from the NCMS; another study found that inpatient stays were reimbursed at just 15 per cent.Footnote 61 In the typology of types of goods I describe above, medical care in rural China is closer to a club good than to a public good.

Education also rarely fits the classic model of a public good. The nationalization of nine years of compulsory education and the “two exemptions and one subsidy” (liang mian yi bu 两免一补) policy designed to defray school costs for poor students have increased the degree to which basic education can be considered a non-excludable good. However, the distribution of education spending across schools and across students suggests that education spending is also more similar to a club good than to a public good. One reason is the unequal resource distribution within schools. Local officials and other well-connected residents lobby to place their children in the highest-performing teachers’ classes. Nominally equal, they receive more resources and better instruction than other classes, and have fewer disruptive students.Footnote 62 Of course, this is not just a rural phenomenon: parents across China pay informal fees to get their children into the best classes and the most elite schools, with these fees reaching US$130,000 at the most desirable Beijing schools.Footnote 63

Problems of measurement

Measuring quality, or measuring graft?

It comes as no surprise to students of Chinese politics that local governments misallocate resources. Even when higher levels of government exercise relatively strict oversight, county governments are adept at inflating payrolls and fabricating budgetary shortfalls in order to maximize the grants and loans they receive.Footnote 64 It is thus puzzling that much of the literature on rural public goods provision in China takes local government expenditure as the key indicator of quality.Footnote 65 Another common measure of the provision of public goods – the number of new public projects – is vulnerable to similar problems. Officials frequently undertake wasteful projects simply to prove to their superiors that they are taking initiative, but this says little about the quality of services to citizens. Indeed, new projects may come at the expense of high-quality public services as officials invest resources in cosmetic efforts instead of improving existing services.Footnote 66

In one poor county where I conducted fieldwork in Sichuan province, for instance, the county government invested substantial resources in creating a beautifully paved and tree-lined road to impress visiting officials who came into the county from the prefectural capital. The road won a provincial award for its beauty but had little effect on citizens’ daily lives – few citizens owned cars and road travel on the county road was infrequent. The roads that were heavily used – the ones connecting the county seat to several townships within the county – were unpaved and in poor condition, but because these roads were unlikely to be used by higher-level officials, they remained neglected.Footnote 67 While expenditures or the number of kilometres of paved roads might suggest the presence of an effective and public service-oriented county government, the disconnect between the services that the government provided and the ones that citizens actually needed suggests that these measures do not provide a complete or valid picture of public service quality.

Whereas much, although certainly not all, existing research has focused on spending on public goods, future scholarship should pay greater attention to a broader range of public goods outcomes, and especially outcome measures that are relatively immune to self-serving manipulation by local officials. Local experts can provide useful guidance regarding the types of measures that are least vulnerable to manipulation by self-serving officials, and gradual improvements in data quality and access mean that a greater range of such measures are becoming available to researchers. Wherever possible, scholars should seek independent assessments of the quality of public service projects rather than rely on self-reported data from government officials. One set of scholars, for instance, hired engineers to assess the quality of new road construction in a sample of rural locations; others have used satellite imagery to assess rural electrification. Studies employing innovative measures such as these are more likely to produce valid results than those which rely on the very measures that officials are most keen to brag about.Footnote 68

Treating localities as independent units

In the “politically centralized, but economically decentralized” Chinese state, local governments spend money and implement policies but they have limited policymaking power and report to the next higher level of government. The literature on public goods provision, however, focuses on villages in isolation, ignoring the web of interconnected political units within which public goods are provided. These interconnections are important because they may inhibit the provision of public goods. One study found, for instance, that while village elections increase the share of public spending in the village budget, they hurt the quality of public goods by weakening fiscal sharing across villages – a necessity for public goods projects that require coordination across multiple villages.Footnote 69

There are clear incentives for the head of a given locality to provide public goods. But, officials do not make decisions in a vacuum. Their ability to provide public goods may be helped or hindered by their personal relationships with higher-level officials and by the spending priorities of higher levels of government. For example, when county officials decide to distribute limited monetary resources to some townships but not others, these decisions determine the options available to township officials, virtually ensuring that some townships will have better public goods. And, as village schools have been replaced by larger, centralized ones and national campaigns to modernize the countryside have brought new resources to rural areas, the assumption that each locality provides public goods in isolation has become untenable.

The Yunnan middle school principal mentioned above, for instance, was part of a strong set of social networks with county officials, many of whom had begun their careers as teachers and school administrators alongside the principal before moving into positions in the county bureaucracy. These ties meant that the principal had the ear of county officials when he needed it, and was able to lobby for resources for the school effectively in informal ways. While his efforts were partially self-serving, they also brought meaningful improvements (among them a high-quality library and computer lab) to the school.Footnote 70 But in the context of limited resources, the special attention that this school received came at a cost to other schools, including those with more pressing problems (such as the high dropout rates in some of the ethnic minority township schools). The top administrators of minority autonomous township schools in the same county had limited social or professional relationships with county-level officials – the county government was overwhelmingly Han Chinese, and social ties were organized largely along ethnic lines. This lack of social connections made it difficult for them to lobby for resources as effectively as the more successful middle school principal could.

Geographic context likewise affects citizens’ demand for public goods. Savvy inhabitants “vote with their feet,” challenging the assumption that different localities provide public goods independently. One county official, for instance, assumed guardianship of her nephew so that he could attend school in her county where schools were generally excellent, rather than in his county of residence.Footnote 71 A women's bureau official in a different county sent her daughter to school in the prefectural capital because of the poor quality of the local school.Footnote 72 Although using public goods and services in one's hometown may be easier than seeking out better services elsewhere, citizens react rationally to differences in service quality. They seek out access to high-quality services and avoid using poor-quality ones. Thus, the quality of public services in one locality may affect the quality of services in other, nearby localities by increasing (or decreasing) demand for these services and by changing the makeup of the population that uses the services that a given locality provides.

These patterns of interdependence, largely ignored by the existing literature on the provision of public goods in rural China, cause thorny problems for quantitative and qualitative analysis alike. Quantitatively, interference between units makes inferring causality difficult. Because most quantitative work on the provision of public goods in China does not address interdependence across geographic units, it is difficult to assess the validity of these studies’ findings. These problems can be addressed by generating and testing explicit hypotheses about the nature of the relationship between units, a useful corrective that future work in this area should embrace.Footnote 73 Qualitatively, future research should examine the distributional patterns of public goods provision across multiple geographic units within a single higher-level unit. Shifting our focus from the quality of goods within a single unit to the variation across multiple, interconnected units will open up new questions about who wins and loses when local governments invest in public goods.

Level of analysis

Most likely owing in part to the relative ease of conducting village-level research, existing work focuses almost exclusively on village-level provision of public goods. In recent years, however, counties have assumed greater responsibility for the public goods and services that were once the responsibility of villages and townships. “Soft centralization” has led counties to assume direct control over more and more township offices.Footnote 74 Fiscal recentralization, which began with the tax-for-fee reforms, has been accompanied by political recentralization which has substantially limited the autonomy of village and township officials. One survey found, for instance, that by the mid-2000s villages did not make any investments in schools.Footnote 75 This has important implications for the study of public goods, as it suggests that the existing scholarship's focus on village-level spending and public goods projects may quickly become – or may already be – irrelevant. It also means that a new set of challenges to both the provision and uptake of public goods and services is emerging. For example, while school centralization has improved school facilities and teacher quality, it also may have negative social effects as students are required to board away from their families.Footnote 76 The burden of the boarding requirement may fall more heavily on some groups than others (the head of one NGO suggested that the policy might have a differential impact on girls, for example).Footnote 77

Recommendations

Use a broader range of research methods

Our existing knowledge of public goods provision in China comes overwhelmingly from village-level surveys. As discussed above, however, the measures most often used in these surveys are vulnerable to manipulation by local officials and may tell us little about whether these goods actually benefit citizens. Complementing survey research with more qualitative work on the dynamics of public goods could help scholars to identify better measures or new questions that could improve future survey work on the topic. Efforts to identify measures of public goods provision that are not vulnerable to manipulation by officials have already begun and should be expanded. In other contexts, field experiments have shed light on the causal mechanisms that lead to poor-quality public goods; similar experiments could be useful in the Chinese context as well.Footnote 78

Move above the village level

As discussed above, county governments now fund and administer many public goods and services. The determinants of county-level public goods provision are poorly understood, and these dynamics should be explored in future research. For example, research on county and township governance has devoted significant attention to the “cadre responsibility system” and the resulting incentives for officials to generate economic growth,Footnote 79 but whether this system incentivizes the provision of public goods has not been systematically explored. Just as importantly, the motivations of county officials that are unrelated to formal career incentives have received little attention. As I describe above, research on village-level public goods provision has explored both social and careerist factors that motivate village officials. At the county level, however, existing research largely treats officials as atomized individuals striving for rapid promotion. While this may accurately depict the behaviour of a handful of upwardly mobile officials, it ignores the large group of cadres who spend their entire careers in a single county and who display little interest in promotion. My research suggests that these officials are motivated by a different set of concerns including social ties to ethnically and geographically defined groups of citizens and to co-workers, a sense of self-worth tied to their job performance, and expertise and policy preferences determined by their prior work experience (often as township officials or as teachers). In their multifaceted, often socially oriented motivations, these officials bear a closer resemblance to Michael Lipsky's “street-level bureaucrats” than to the calculating, careerist actors the existing literature often depicts.Footnote 80 Future research on the provision of public goods would do well to focus on these additional motivations that are prevalent but poorly understood.

The interconnected nature of public goods provision across nearby localities also warrants greater exploration. Geospatial (GIS) techniques, which enable scholars to study correlations across space in sophisticated ways, have not yet played a major role in research on Chinese politics,Footnote 81 and could shed light on the relationship between the provision of public goods across multiple units within the geographic/administrative hierarchy.

Disaggregate public expenditures and public goods

The existing literature's focus means that we know a great deal about government spending on public goods, services and infrastructure. We know substantially less, however, about some of the dynamics that have proven relevant to the provision of public goods outside of China. Are public goods vulnerable to the problems (overuse and insufficient provision) that plague them in other contexts? Do particular social conditions (such as ethnic or religious diversity) undermine the provision of public goods in China as they do in much of the world?Footnote 82 Environmental governance provides one promising and underexplored topic for scholars interested in rural public goods provision.Footnote 83 The severity of China's pollution problems and the growing challenge of waste disposal in the countryside – which one county Party leader characterized as one of the biggest thorns in the side of the county party-state – make environmental issues an important element of rural politics.Footnote 84 Environmental quality is a true public good: everyone benefits from clean air and water, regardless of their personal contributions to environmental quality, and the benefits of a clean environment do not diminish if they are shared across individuals. As a result, free-riding poses a key challenge to environmental quality in the countryside.

Assess how public goods are used

Qualitative evidence suggests that the dynamics of public goods in China may diverge substantially from what we would expect based on other contexts. In some parts of China, the problem may be underuse rather than overuse of public goods. In a Tibetan area with high infant mortality rates, for instance, the government invested significant resources in improving the quality of and access to maternal health services. Despite these investments, few women took advantage of the free services, and health outcomes generally failed to improve. One cause of this failure lay in cultural factors that diminished demand for these services and in citizens’ scepticism towards officials’ attempts to encourage them to use public services. Tibetan traditional birth practices made women in this area reluctant to give birth away from home, and doctors in county hospitals were reluctant to make concessions to traditional birth practices that could allay women's fears about hospital births. In addition, citizens across China are suspicious of the “advice” they receive from paternalistic local officials (fumuguan 父母官). Having been encouraged or required to participate in numerous past public projects that cost them valuable time and money and yet yielded little benefit, citizens are sceptical of officials’ attempts to convince them to use government services even when no viable alternatives exist.Footnote 85 Thus, the fundamental challenge that citizens’ behaviour poses to the provision of public goods in some areas of China is not overuse, as traditional work on the subject outside of China would lead us to expect, but rather the opposite.

Even when citizens do demand the services that local governments provide, problems of overuse and free-riding have not occurred, even when officials have expected them to – an important contrast to research on public goods in other contexts that warrants further investigation. As the head of a public health NGO with strong government ties explained, policymakers were concerned that the NCMS would encourage individuals to overuse rural health services because they would no longer bear the full cost of their care. When the programme was piloted in a set of “test point” counties (shidian xian 试点县), however, these problems did not arise.Footnote 86 What policies or social structures help to mitigate the problems of free-riding and overuse in China? Why do these factors ameliorate the problems associated with some public goods, such as universal health insurance, but not others, like environmental degradation? In other contexts, scholars have explored the social and institutional variables that enable high-quality public goods where we might not expect them.Footnote 87 Exploring the relevance of these factors to China, or identifying different ones that ameliorate collective action problems, would help us to gain a better understanding of the true public goods dynamics in China and bring the literature on this topic into closer conversation with the comparative literatures on political economy and local governance.

Conclusion

This paper seeks to accomplish three purposes. First, it surveys the literature on public goods provision in rural China. It describes three sets of explanations for the variation in the quality of local public goods: local elections, social sanctioning and economic policies. Second, it identifies several limitations of the existing literature that inhibit assessment of these findings’ validity. Different scholars mean different things when they use the term “public goods,” a problem of “conceptual stretching.” In terms of measurement, many studies of public goods rely on easily manipulated measures of these goods and ignore the interconnected nature of geographic-administrative units in the Chinese state. I suggest that a second generation of literature on public goods in rural China could correct these weaknesses by expanding the range of methods used to study public goods, focusing on county-level public goods provision rather than almost exclusively on villages, conceptually distinguishing between public goods and public spending, and paying more attention to how public goods are used and not just to how officials provide them.

Nearly a decade has passed since the Hu–Wen administration announced its determination to “build a new socialist countryside.” Optimists see the ensuing policies transforming villages for the better, although the changes that have occurred are not nearly dramatic enough. These policy changes – and others that will surely follow under the leadership of Xi Jinping 习近平 – will provide fertile ground for a second generation of research on rural public goods, social services and infrastructure. Greater conceptual clarity about the distinctions between these categories, better measures of their quality, and increased engagement with a variety of cross-national debates will ensure that this research is useful not only to China scholars but also to students of political economy and comparative authoritarianism as well.

Acknowledgement

This project was generously funded by the National Science Foundation (Doctoral Dissertation Improvement Grant SES-1023953), the UC-Berkeley Center for Chinese Studies, and the UC-Berkeley Institute for International Studies. I am grateful for helpful feedback from Leonardo Arriola, Devin Caughey, Sarah Garding, John Chung-en Liu, Kevin O'Brien, Laura Stoker and two anonymous reviewers. All errors remain my own.

Biographical note

Sara A. Newland is an assistant professor of political science at Villanova University. She received her PhD from the University of California, Berkeley, in 2015. In 2015–2016, she was the China Public Policy Postdoctoral Fellow at the Ash Center for Democratic Governance and Innovation at Harvard's Kennedy School of Government.

Footnotes

2 O'Brien and Han Reference O'Brien and Han2009.

4 A limited set of sources has addressed public goods provision in urban China (Solinger Reference Solinger1995; Teets Reference Teets2012), but as this literature focuses on a different set of concerns, I exclusively address rural public goods here.

5 To identify the set of relevant scholarly literature, I used two search methods. First, I searched the leading scholarly database Academic Search Premier (EBSCOHost) for peer-reviewed, English-language sources published between 2004 and 2015 that contain the terms “rural” and “public goods” or “public services” in the abstract, and that use China as a geographic keyword. This yielded a total of 48 sources, of which 16 are relevant to this paper (several articles discussed China's contribution to global public goods such as collective security; others focused on urban China). Second, I searched Google Scholar for sources published between 2004 and 2015 that contained “public goods” and “China” in the title. This yielded 201 results, including duplicate citations and non-English-language sources. I manually limited the search results to English-language publications, and included unpublished working papers only if they were cited by at least one source. This ultimately produced a list of 16 relevant sources. I also thank two anonymous reviewers for drawing my attention to several additional sources that shed light on this topic without using the terminology of public goods.

7 Miguel and Gugerty Reference Miguel and Kay Gugerty2005.

9 Alesina, Baqir and Easterly Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999.

10 Duckett Reference Duckett2011.

13 Duckett Reference Duckett2011.

14 Wagstaff et al. Reference Wagstaff, Yip, Lindelow and Hsiao2009. Duckett (Reference Duckett2011) questions whether economic reform can be blamed for the dismantling of rural health services, arguing that a 1981 change in health policy was the more proximate cause. Nonetheless, the “economic reform paradigm” remains the dominant explanation for the dramatic collapse of these services.

18 Golan, Sicular and Umapathi Reference Golan, Sicular and Umapathi2014.

19 For a detailed description of village-level investment in public goods projects, see Zhang, Linxiu, et al. Reference Zhang, Luo, Liu and Rozelle2006.

21 Above the village level, career incentives also play an important role in officials’ decisions despite the absence of meaningful elections. In order to maximize their promotion prospects, officials expend effort on goals that higher levels of government regard as “hard targets” (Edin Reference Edin2003a; Reference Edin2003b; O'Brien and Li Reference O'Brien and Li1999; Rosenberg Reference Rosenberg2015), and time investment decisions to maximize their likelihood of being promoted (Guo, Gang Reference Guo2009). These incentives have important implications for the provision of public goods (as well as for the enforcement of policies for ensuring social stability, promoting economic growth, and other national priorities). Because the literature on promotion incentives focuses on rural expenditure and on policy implementation by township- and county-level officials in general, rather than on the specific topic of public goods provision, it is outside the scope of this article. Interested readers should refer to Göbel Reference Göbel2011 and Guo, Gang Reference Guo2009 for useful overviews of this literature.

23 Zhang, Xiaobo, et al. Reference Zhang, Fan, Zhang and Huang2004.

24 Kung, Cai and Sun Reference Kung, Cai and Sun2009.

25 Agostini, Brown and Zhang Reference Agostini, Brown and Zhang2010.

28 Martinez-Bravo et al. Reference Martinez-Bravo, Padró i Miquel, Qian and Yao2012; Reference Martinez-Bravo, Padró i Miquel, Qian and Yao2014. Indeed, public goods expenditures may themselves be a redistributive tool that decreases intra-village inequality (Shen and Yao Reference Shen and Yao2008).

30 Mu and Zhang Reference Mu and Zhang2011.

31 Kung, Cai and Sun Reference Kung, Cai and Sun2009.

33 Yan Reference Yan2011, 49.

35 Chen, Jie, and Huhe Reference Chen and Huhe2013.

37 Newland Reference Newland2015; Zhou, Xueguang Reference Zhou2012.

38 Persson and Zhuravskaya Reference Persson and Zhuravskaya2012.

39 Padro i Miquel, Qian and Yao Reference Padró i Miquel, Qian and Yao2012.

46 Dickson Reference Dickson2011.

48 Uchimura and Jütting Reference Uchimura and Jütting2009.

52 Simon and Teets Reference Simon and Teets2012; Zhang, Mengzhong, and Sun Reference Zhang and Sun2012.

53 Collier and Mahoney Reference Collier and Mahoney1993.

54 Xu and Yao Reference Xu and Yao2015.

55 For a discussion of public goods in another non-democracy, see Khwaja Reference Khwaja2009.

58 Mu and Zhang's Reference Mu and Zhang2011 study is, to my knowledge, the only source that looks at public spending at the level of the natural village.

59 Interview with middle school principal, Yunnan province, 2011.

60 Interview with health economist, Beijing, 2011.

62 Interview with middle school English teacher, Yunnan province, 2011.

64 Liu, Mingxing, et al. Reference Liu, Wang, Tao and Murphy2009.

66 There is not necessarily a trade-off between the quantity and quality of public goods; the recent expansion of rural infrastructure has led to improvements in both quality and quantity (Liu, Chengfang, et al. Reference Liu, Zhang, Luo and Rozelle2009). However, spending increases cannot be simply assumed to improve quality.

67 Interview with local NGO employee, Sichuan province, 2010.

68 Liu, Chengfang, et al. Reference Liu, Zhang, Luo and Rozelle2009; Min and Golden Reference Min and Golden2013.

69 Wang and Yao Reference Wang and Yao2007.

70 Interviews with township middle school principal and with education bureau officials, Yunnan province, 2011.

71 Interview with county official, Yunnan province, 2011.

72 Interview with county women's bureau head, Sichuan province, 2010.

73 Bowers, Fredrickson and Panagopolous Reference Bowers, Fredrickson and Panagopoulos2013.

77 Interview with head of public health NGO, Yunnan province, 2010.

81 One exception is Guo, Shili, et al. Reference Guo, Liu, Luo and Zhang2014, although it also examines public expenditure in individual villages rather than assessing connections across units.

83 Two articles that explore environmental public goods are Tu et al. Reference Tu, Mol, Zhang and Ruben2011 and Zhou, Li Reference Zhou2004, but both have received little attention from other scholars of Chinese public goods.

84 Interview with county Communist Party office employee, Yunnan province, 2011.

85 Interview, head of public health NGO.

87 Glennerster, Miguel and Rothenberg Reference Glennerster, Miguel and Rothenberg2013; Miguel Reference Miguel2004; Ostrom Reference Ostrom1990.

References

Agostini, Claudio, Brown, Philip and Zhang, Xiaobo. 2010. “Neighbor effects in the provision of public goods in a young democracy.” International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) Discussion Paper No. 01027.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Baqir, Reza and Easterly, William. 1999. “Public goods and ethnic divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(4), 1243–84.Google Scholar
Bowers, Jake, Fredrickson, Mark and Panagopoulos, Costas. 2013. “Reasoning about interference between units.” Political Analysis 21(1), 97124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jie, and Huhe, Narisong. 2013. “Informal accountability, socially embedded officials, and public goods provision in rural China.” Journal of Chinese Political Science 18, 101116.Google Scholar
Chen, Xinxin, Yi, Hongmei, Zhang, Linxiu, Mo, Di, Chu, James and Rozelle, Scott. 2011. “Do poor students benefit from China's merger program? Transfer path and educational performance.” Rural Education Action Project Working Paper No. 231, Stanford, CA.Google Scholar
Collier, David, and Mahoney, James. 1993. “Conceptual ‘stretching’ revisited.” American Political Science Review 87(4), 845855.Google Scholar
Dickson, Bruce. 2011. “Updating the China model.” The Washington Quarterly 34(4), 3958.Google Scholar
Duckett, Jane. 2011. “Challenging the economic reform paradigm: policy and politics in the early 1980s collapse of the rural cooperative medical system.” The China Quarterly 205, 8095.Google Scholar
Edin, Maria. 2003a. “State capacity and local agent control in China.” The China Quarterly 173, 3552.Google Scholar
Edin, Maria. 2003b. “Remaking the communist party-state: the cadre responsibility system at the local level in China.” China: An International Journal 1(1), 115.Google Scholar
Gao, Helen. 2014. “China's education gap,” The New York Times, 4 September.Google Scholar
Glennerster, Rachel, Miguel, Edward and Rothenberg, Alexander. 2013. “Collective action in diverse Sierra Leone communities.” The Economic Journal 123(568), 285316.Google Scholar
Göbel, Christian. 2009. “The peasant's rescue from the cadre? An institutional analysis of China's rural tax and fee reform.” In Heberer, Thomas and Schubert, Gunter (eds.), Regime Legitimacy in Contemporary China: Institutional Change and Stability. New York: Routledge, 3554.Google Scholar
Göbel, Christian. 2011. “Uneven policy implementation in rural China.” The China Journal 65, 5376.Google Scholar
Golan, Jennifer, Sicular, Terry and Umapathi, Nithin. 2014. “Any guarantees? China's rural minimum living standard guarantee program.” World Bank Social Protection and Labor Discussion Paper No. 1423.Google Scholar
Guo, Gang. 2009. “China's local political budget cycles.” American Journal of Political Science 53(3), 621632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, Shili, Liu, Shaoquan, Luo, Renfu and Zhang, Linxiu. 2014. “Determinants of public goods investment in rural communities in mountainous areas of Sichuan province, China.” Journal of Mountain Science 11(3), 816824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habyarimana, James, Humphreys, Macartan, Posner, Daniel N. and Weinstein, Jeremy M. 2007. “Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision?American Political Science Review 101(4), 709725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hessler, Peter. 2010. Country Driving. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Huang, Yanzhong. 2011. “The sick man of Asia.” Foreign Affairs 90(6), 119136.Google Scholar
Jing, Yijia. 2008. “Outsourcing in China: an exploratory assessment.” Public Administration and Development 28, 119128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jing, Yijia, and Savas, E.S.. 2009. “Managing collaborative service delivery: comparing China and the United States.” Public Administration Review 69(s1), S101S107.Google Scholar
Khwaja, Asim Ijaz. 2009. “Can good projects succeed in bad communities?Journal of Public Economics 93, 899916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kung, James, Cai, Yongshun and Sun, Xiulin. 2009. “Rural cadres and governance in China: incentive, institution and accountability.” The China Journal (62), 6177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Linda Chelan. 2008. “State and market in public service provision.” Pacific Review 21(3), 257278.Google Scholar
Liang, Xiaoyun, Guo, Hong, Jin, Chenggang, Peng, Xiaoxia and Zhang, Xiulan. 2012. “The effect of the New Cooperative Medical Scheme on health outcomes and alleviating catastrophic health expenditure in China.” PLoS ONE 7(8), e40850.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lipsky, Michael. 1980. Street-level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Services. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Liu, Chengfang, Zhang, Linxiu, Luo, Renfu and Rozelle, Scott. 2009. “Infrastructure investment in rural China: is quality being compromised during quantity expansion?The China Journal 61, 105129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Mingxing, Wang, Juan, Tao, Ran and Murphy, Rachel. 2009. “The political economy of earmarked transfers in a state-designated poor county in western China.” The China Quarterly 200, 973994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
, Xiaobo. 2014. “Social policy and regime legitimacy: the effects of education reform in China.” American Political Science Review 108(2), 423437.Google Scholar
Luo, Renfu, Zhang, Linxiu, Huang, Jikun and Rozelle, Scott. 2007. “Elections, fiscal reform and public goods provision in rural China.” Journal of Comparative Economics 35(3), 583611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, Renfu, Zhang, Linxiu, Huang, Jikun and Rozelle, Scott. 2010. “Village elections, public goods investments and pork barrel politics, Chinese-style.” Journal of Development Studies 46(4), 662684.Google Scholar
Manion, Melanie. 1996. “The electoral connection in the Chinese countryside.” American Political Science Review 90(4), 736748.Google Scholar
Martinez-Bravo, Monica, Padró i Miquel, Gerard, Qian, Nancy and Yao, Yang. 2011. “Do local elections in non-democracies increase accountability? Evidence from rural China.” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 16948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinez-Bravo, Monica, Padró i Miquel, Gerard, Qian, Nancy and Yao, Yang. 2012. “The effects of democratization on public goods and redistribution: evidence from China.” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 18101.Google Scholar
Martinez-Bravo, Monica, Padró i Miquel, Gerard, Qian, Nancy and Yao, Yang. 2014. “Political reform in China: the effect of local elections.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Michelson, Ethan. 2012. “Public goods and state–society relations: an impact study of China's rural stimulus.” In Yang, Dali (ed.), The Global Recession and China's Political Economy. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 131157.Google Scholar
Miguel, Edward. 2004. “Tribe or nation? Nation building and public goods in Kenya and Tanzania.” World Politics 56(3), 327362.Google Scholar
Miguel, Edward, and Kay Gugerty, Mary. 2005. “Ethnic diversity, social sanctions, and public goods in Kenya.” Journal of Public Economics 89(11–12), 2325–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Min, Brian, and Golden, Miriam. 2013. “Electoral cycles in electricity losses in India.” Energy Policy 65, 619625.Google Scholar
Mu, Ren, and Zhang, Xiaobo. 2011. “The role of elected and appointed village leaders in the allocation of public resources.” International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) Discussion Paper No. 01061.Google Scholar
Newland, Sara. 2015. “Diversity and Distribution: Essays on Local Governance and Public Service Provision in Multiethnic China.” PhD diss., University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin, and Han, Rongbin. 2009. “Path to democracy? Assessing village elections in China.” Journal of Contemporary China 18(60), 359378.Google Scholar
O'Brien, Kevin, and Li, Lianjiang. 1999. “Selective policy implementation in rural China.” Comparative Politics 31(2), 167186.Google Scholar
Oi, Jean C., Singer Babiarz, Kim, Zhang, Linxiu, Luo, Renfu and Rozelle, Scott. 2012. “Shifting fiscal control to limit cadre power in China's townships and villages.” The China Quarterly 211, 649675.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Padró i Miquel, Gerard, Qian, Nancy and Yao, Yang. 2012. “Fragmentation, public goods and elections: evidence from China.” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 18633.Google Scholar
Persson, Petra, and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. 2012. “Elite influence as a substitute for local democracy: evidence from backgrounds of Chinese provincial leaders.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Plafker, Ted. 2001. “China's long – but uneven – march to literacy,” The New York Times, 12 February.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Lior. 2015. “Why do local officials bet on the strong? Drawing lessons from China's village redevelopment program.” The China Journal 74, 1840.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saich, Tony. 2008. Providing Public Goods in Transitional China. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1954. “The pure theory of public expenditure.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4), 387389.Google Scholar
Sato, Hiroshi. 2008. “Public goods provision and rural governance in China.” China: An International Journal 6(2), 281298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shen, Yan, and Yao, Yang. 2008. “Does grassroots democracy reduce income inequality in China?Journal of Public Economics 92, 2182–98.Google Scholar
Sicular, Terry, Ximing, Yue, Gustafsson, Björn and Shi, Li. 2007. “The urban–rural income gap and inequality in China.” Review of Income and Wealth 53(1), 93126.Google Scholar
Simon, Karla W., and Teets, Jessica C.. 2012. “Revolutionizing social service delivery in China: the new policy of ‘contracting out’ to non-profit organizations.” International Journal of Civil Society Law, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2425349. Accessed 25 October 2016.Google Scholar
Smith, Graeme. 2010. “The hollow state: rural governance in China.” The China Quarterly 203, 601618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solinger, Dorothy. 1995. “China's urban transients in the transition from socialism and the collapse of the communist ‘urban public goods regime’.” Comparative Politics 27(2), 127146.Google Scholar
Teets, Jessica C. 2012. “Reforming service delivery in China: the emergence of a social innovation model.” Journal of Chinese Political Science 17, 1532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsai, Lily L. 2007a. Accountability without Democracy: Solidary Groups and Public Goods Provision in Rural China. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsai, Lily L. 2007b. “Solidary groups, informal accountability, and local public goods provision in rural China.” American Political Science Review 101(2), 355372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsai, Lily L. 2011. “Friends or foes? Nonstate public goods providers and local state authorities in nondemocratic and transitional systems.” Studies in Comparative International Development 46(1), 4669.Google Scholar
Tu, Qin, Mol, Arthur P.J., Zhang, Lei and Ruben, Ruerd. 2011. “How do trust and property security influence household contributions to public goods? The case of the sloping land conversion program in China.” China Economic Review 22, 499511.Google Scholar
Uchimura, Hiroko, and Jütting, Johannes. 2009. “Fiscal decentralization, Chinese style: good for health outcomes?World Development, 37(12), 1926–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagstaff, Adam, Yip, Winnie, Lindelow, Magnus and Hsiao, William C.. 2009. “China's health system and its reform.” Health Economics 18, S7S23.Google Scholar
Wang, Shuna, and Yao, Yang. 2007. “Grassroots democracy and local governance: evidence from rural China.” World Development 35(10), 1635–49.Google Scholar
Xu, Yiqing, and Yao, Yang. 2015. “Informal institutions, collective action, and public investment in rural China.” American Political Science Review 109(2), 371391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yan, Xiaojun. 2011. “The democratizing power of economic reform.” Problems of Post-Communism 58(3), 3952.Google Scholar
Yang, Dennis Tao. 1999. “Urban-biased policies and rising income inequality in China.” American Economic Review 89(2), 306310.Google Scholar
Yep, Ray. 2004. “Can ‘tax-for-fee’ reform reduce rural tension in China?The China Quarterly 177, 4270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yi, Hongmei, Zhang, Linxiu, Singer, Kim, Rozelle, Scott and Atlas, Scott. 2009. “Health insurance and catastrophic illness: a report on the new cooperative medical scheme.” Health Economics 18, S119S127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Linxiu, Luo, Renfu, Liu, Chengfang and Rozelle, Scott. 2006. “Investing in rural China: tracking China's commitment to modernization.” Chinese Economy 39(4), 5784.Google Scholar
Zhang, Linxiu, Yi, Hongmei and Rozelle, Scott. 2010. “Good and bad news from China's New Cooperative Medical Scheme.” IDS Bulletin 41(4), 95106.Google Scholar
Zhang, Mengzhong, and Sun, Jian. 2012. “Outsourcing in municipal governments: experiences from the United States and China.” Public Performance and Management Review 35(4), 696726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Xiaobo, Fan, Shenggen, Zhang, Linxiu and Huang, Jikun. 2004. “Local governance and public goods provision in rural China.” Journal of Public Economics 88(12), 2857–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Yumei, Wang, Xinxin and Chen, Kevin. 2013. “Growth and distributive effects of public infrastructure investments in China.” In Cockburn, John, Dissou, Yazid, Duclos, Jean-Yves and Tiberti, Luca (eds.), Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Asia. New York: Springer International Publishing, 87116.Google Scholar
Zhou, Li. 2004. “Public goods, environmental protection, and the development paradigm in rural China.” China & World Economy 12(6), 8697.Google Scholar
Zhou, Xueguang. 2012. “The road to collective debt in rural China.” Modern China 38(3), 271307.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Types of Goods