Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-g4j75 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T04:40:48.224Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Modeling Grape Price Dynamics in Mendoza: Lessons for Policymakers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 October 2019

German Puga
Affiliation:
Agricultural and Resource Economics, School of Agriculture and Environment, University of Western Australia, 35 Stirling Highway, Crawley WA6009, Australia; e-mail: 22284819@student.uwa.edu.au.
James Fogarty*
Affiliation:
Agricultural and Resource Economics, School of Agriculture and Environment, University of Western Australia, 35 Stirling Highway, Crawley WA6009, Australia
Atakelty Hailu
Affiliation:
Agricultural and Resource Economics, School of Agriculture and Environment, University of Western Australia, 35 Stirling Highway, Crawley WA6009, Australia; e-mail: atakelty.hailu@uwa.edu.au.
Alejandro Gennari
Affiliation:
National University of Cuyo, Department of Economics, Policy and Rural Administration, Provincia de Mendoza, Argentina; e-mail: agennari@fca.uncu.edu.ar.
*
e-mail: james.fogarty@uwa.edu.au (corresponding author).
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Mendoza is the main wine-producing province of Argentina, and the government is currently implementing a range of policies that seek to improve grape grower profitability, including a vineyard replanting program. This study uses a dataset of all grape sales recorded in Mendoza from 2007 to 2018, totaling 90,910 observations, to investigate the determinants of grape prices. Key findings include: smaller volume transactions receive lower-average prices per kilogram sold; the discount for cash payments is higher in less-profitable regions; and the effect of wine stock levels on prices is substantial for all varieties. Long-run predicted prices are also estimated for each variety, and region; and these results suggest that policymakers should review some of the varieties currently used in the vineyard replanting program. (JEL Classifications: Q12, Q13, Q18)

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Association of Wine Economists 2019

I. Introduction

Accounting for 71% of total Argentinean grape production, Mendoza is the main wine province of Argentina. Argentina is the fifth-largest wine producer in the world (Anderson, Nelgen, and Pinilla, Reference Anderson, Nelgen and Pinilla2017; OIV, 2018). Mendoza is a wine-producing region of international importance and in 2017 the estimated value of wine grape production in Mendoza was US$576 million (Argentinean Wine Corporation, 2018).

In Mendoza, there are two current government programs where a greater understanding of the determinants of wine grape prices would be valuable. The first is a vineyard replanting program that provides interest-free credits to growers with vineyards smaller than 20 hectares to help them pull out existing vines and replant with higher-quality varieties (Government of Mendoza, 2017). The program objective is to replant 10,000 hectares, which represents 6.5% of the current area planted with grapes in Mendoza (Argentinean Secretary of Agriculture, 2017). The second program, which started in 2019, is a market intervention program that will buy grapes (to make grape juice, wine, or industrial alcohol) and wine if wine stocks are deemed too high, and sell wine if wine stocks are deemed too low. The stated program objective is to stabilize grape (and wine) prices and avoid wine imports (Government of Mendoza, 2019).

In this research, we use a combined hedonic price autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model to estimate long-run relationships for grape prices in Mendoza. The regression model outputs are directly relevant to both the existing vineyard replanting program and the new wine and grape stock level management program.

II. Literature Review on Grape Prices

The factors that influence grape prices in Mendoza have not yet been studied in detail, and a search of the literature failed to identify any research on the determinants of grape prices in Mendoza, or any other Argentinean province. Relevant studies of wine grape prices outside Argentina include: Oczkowski (Reference Oczkowski2006) for Australia; Costa-Font et al. (Reference Costa-Font, Serra, Gil and Gras2009) for Catalonia; Fuller and Alston (Reference Fuller and Alston2012) and Volpe et al. (Reference Volpe, Green, Heien and Howitt2012) for California; and Tomsik et al. (Reference Tomsik, Stojanova, Sedlo and Vajcnerova2016) for the Czech Republic. Relevant related research on table grape prices identified included: Reynolds (Reference Reynolds2009) for South Africa; Weisong et al. (Reference Weisong, Xiaoshuan, Lingxian and Zettan2010) for China; and Yilmaz and Abdikoglu (Reference Yilmaz, Abdikoglu, Arslan, Ali Içbay and Reggiero2017) for Turkey.

Based on our review of the Argentinean and international literature we determined that the variables we should consider in our model of grape price formations are: variety, region, financial characteristics of the transaction, harvest volume, and stock levels. Although the literature also suggests wine imports can be important, we do not consider wine imports an important factor for grape price determination in Argentina, because for the period between 2007 and 2018, imports represented less than 1% of wine production.

III. Literature Review on Grape Prices

The dataset used for this study includes all recorded grape sales from 2007 to 2018, for the 13 most planted varieties in Mendoza. There are a total of 90,910 observations in the data set (Table 1). The information recorded for each sale includes: price, variety, region, payment type (i.e., cash or financed) and quantity sold. The Mendoza Chamber of Commerce provided grape sale data. The Argentinean Wine Observatory and the Argentinean Wine Institute provided harvest and stock level data.

Table 1 Number of Observations (i.e., Transactions) and Grape Prices (2018 US$/t) by Variety and Region

Official Argentinean inflation statistics for the period 2006 through 2015 are not reliable (Cavallo, Cruces, and Perez-Truglia, Reference Cavallo, Cruces and Perez-Truglia2016; Daniel and Lanata Briones, Reference Daniel and Lanata Briones2019; Miranda-Zanetti, Delbianco, and Tohmé, Reference Miranda-Zanetti, Delbianco and Tohmé2019). As such, we use the independently compiled price index of the Santa Fe Chamber of Commerce to convert nominal prices to real prices. All prices are expressed in 2018 values.Footnote 1

IV. Methods

We use an inverse demand ARDL/hedonic price model. Both hedonic models (Ashenfelter, Reference Ashenfelter2017; Bekkerman and Brester, Reference Bekkerman and Brester2019; Cardebat et al., Reference Cardebat, Faye, Le Fur and Storchmann2017; Cross, Plantinga, and Stavins, Reference Cross, Plantinga and Stavins2017) and distributed lag models (Cardebat and Figuet Reference Cardebat and Figuet2019; Gergaud, Livat, and Song, Reference Gergaud, Livat and Song2018; Niklas and Sadik-Zada Reference Niklas and Sadik-Zada2019) have been widely used to investigate issues in the wine market. Following a process of backwards and forwards variable selection, the final model selected is:

(1)$$\eqalign{ P_{ijkt} = & {\rm \alpha} + {\rm \sum} _i {\rm \sum} _j \beta _{ij}V_iR_j + {\rm \sum} _{l} {\rm \sum} _j {\rm \zeta} _{il}R_jT_l + {\rm \sum} _{\rm \nu} \eta _{\rm \nu} Q_{\rm \nu} + {\rm \sum} _i {\rm \sum} _j \theta _{ij}{\bar{P}}_{ijt{\rm -}1} \cr &+ {\rm \sum} _i \iota_i{V_i}{H_t} + {\rm \sum} _i {k_i}{V_i}{W_t} + {\rm \sum} _i \rho _iV_iG_t + {\rm \sum} _{i} \sigma _iV_iY_t + {\rm \sum} _i \upsilon _i{V_i}{Y_t^2} + e_{ijkt},} $$

where P ijkt denotes the log of the real per kilogram price of grape variety i sold in region j associated with transaction k, at time t; V i and R j denote variety and region dummies; T l is a dummy variable for payment type (i.e., cash or installments); Q v denote volume quartile dummies; $\bar{P}_{ijt-1}$ is the average real price per kilogram for variety i in region j at time t – 1; H t is the total quantity of grapes harvested in Mendoza in the year of the transaction; W t is the total stock of wine in Argentina at the beginning of year t; G t is the total stock of grape juice in Argentina at the beginning of the year of year t; Y t denotes the year in which the transaction took place; Greek letters denote parameters to be estimated; and e ijkt is a zero mean error term.

For clarity, note that in the dataset it is not possible to identify specific vineyards or growers through time. As such, $\bar{P}_{ijt-1}$ is the arithmetic mean real price for variety i in region j at time t – 1, not the specific price received previously by the grower. Also, in Argentina, during production, grape juice is sulfated to ensure fermentation does not take place, and it is illegal to de-sulfate grape juice. As such, grape juice cannot be used for making wine. For this reason we treat wine stocks and grape juice stocks separately, and grape juice stocks are defined as the sum of sulfated grape juice, and the grape juice equivalent volume of grape juice concentrate. For estimation, we drop a variety, region, quartile, and payment type category. For reporting we retrieve the relevant base information from the respective adding up constraints. For inference we use robust standard errors.

V. Results

Reported in the Appendix are complete regression results. The model R2 = Adjusted-R2 = 0.831, suggesting: (i) the model is a relatively good fit to the data; and (ii) that the model fit is not due to the inclusion of a large number of irrelevant variables. With log price as the dependent variable, and many interaction terms in the model, the raw regression coefficients are difficult to interpret directly. To aid with exposition, we present: (i) a table of long-run predicted prices by variety and region; (ii) a table documenting the price dynamics, by variety; and (iii) an in-text discussion of other key information derived from the regression results. To generate estimates of long-run predicted prices by variety and region, we assumed median levels for harvest, wine stocks, and grape juice stocks; payment by installments; quantity sold is in the first (smallest) quartile; and the year is 2018.

A. Long-Run Predicted Prices

Table 2 shows clear price differences between varieties and across regions. Within regions, in general, prices for red varieties are higher than for white varieties, which in turn are higher than for rosé varieties. The exception to this general result is for Chardonnay grapes, a high-quality white grape variety that sells at prices higher than some red varieties. Across regions, but within variety, the price premium achieved in Uco Valley and Lujan-Maipu, relative to the South and the Northeast, is most pronounced for premium varieties, and completely disappears for low-value varieties. Both Uco Valley and Lujan-Maipu are renowned for quality production, and although the price premium in these regions disappears for low-quality varieties, there are relative few transactions for low-quality varieties in these two regions (see Table 1).

Table 2 Long-Run Predicted Prices for Mendoza, Current Area Planted, and Average Revenue (2018)

For most varieties, prices are lower in the South region than in the Northeast region. These lower prices may reflect not just quality, but also logistics issues. The South region is relatively far from the other three regions. Selling grapes to a winery in another region may mean high transportation costs, which are usually paid by the grower. As such, growers in the South face a more restricted market than growers in the other three regions.

In the first phase of the government supported replanting program, Malbec was used for 40% of the area replanted; however, varieties associated with relatively low prices have also been widely used: Bonarda 20%; Tempranillo 6%; and Syrah 6% (Government of Mendoza 2017). Given the price observed for Cabernet Sauvignon grapes, it is notable that this variety, which tolerates a wide range of environmental conditions, has not been widely used for replanting.

Some varieties that have lower prices also have higher yields than premium varieties. For example, in Mendoza as a whole, for 2018, the average yield for Criolla Grande was 17 t/ha, while for Cabernet Sauvignon it was 7 t/ha. However, controlling for other relevant factors, the price differences observed are so large that some of the varieties currently used in the replanting program are unlikely to be the best option for growers seeking to maximize profit. To illustrate the issue, in the final column of Table 2, we show average revenue per ha by variety for Mendoza as a whole for 2018. Based on the detail in Table 2, it is difficult to understand the relative prominence of Bonarda in the replanting program: the relatively high yield does not compensate for the low price.

Looking forward, the high long-run equilibrium prices for Aspirant Bouchet are unlikely to be sustained. A unique feature of Aspirant Bouchet is that its color index is so high, that small quantities of the variety can be blended with generic white wine, and the resulting blend legally sold as red wine. During the study period there were no limitations on the percentage of white and rosé grapes that could be blended with a small amount of Aspirant Bouchet to create a wine that could be legally sold as red wine. However, since 2019, all red wine sold in Argentina must be made with at least 65% red grape varieties, and the red grape variety requirement will gradually increase to 80% in 2030 (Official Bulletin of Argentina, 2019). This structural change to the market is likely to impact Aspirant Bouchet prices, but as this policy change came after the study period, we have no direct evidence on the likely size of the impact.

B. Price Dynamics

Table 3 presents a summary of the price dynamics, by variety. Overall, the speed of adjustment coefficients (one minus lag of price coefficients) are slowest for red varieties. For rosé varieties and the lowest-quality white variety (Pedro Gimenez), the lag price coefficients are negative, which might be seen as implying a cobweb type dynamic for this segment of the market.

Table 3 Price Dynamics Coefficients Summary (Elasticities)

Alternatively, for low-quality varieties, it could be that the model fits this segment of the market poorly. To check model fit at the individual variety level, separate least squares regressions were estimated for each variety, and across these regressions (results available on request) the R2 for the lowest-quality varieties are between two and three times lower than for the medium- and high-quality varieties. We interpret this result as suggesting that for low-price varieties there may be important elements of the market that we have not captured, and we qualify our remaining comments accordingly.

In Table 3, our primary focus is the long-run coefficients, and the values have an interpretation as elasticities. The first observation that can be made from a comparison of the long-run coefficients is that, in general, prices are most sensitive to changes in the size of the harvest, followed by changes in wine stocks, and then changes in grape juice stocks. This seems an intuitively reasonable result: harvest is the activity most directly related to the wine grape market, and grape juice production the most removed.

The wine stock elasticity information is of direct relevance to the government's proposed plan to influence grape prices through active wine stock level management. There is significant heterogeneity in the estimated variety level wine stock elasticity values, but: (i) the majority of values are above minus one; and (ii) premium varieties such as Malbec, Cabernet Sauvignon, and Chardonnay tend to have elasticity values closer to zero than other varieties. That grape prices for these premium varieties appear to be less influenced by stock levels is further evidence of the value of focusing on such varieties as part of the replanting program. Overall, the heterogeneity in elasticity values suggests that influencing grape prices through an active program of wine stock management will be difficult. However, to derive a reference point for how responsive wine grape prices will be to active wine stock level management, we combine the variety surface area information in Table 2, with the variety specific elasticity values in Table 3, and derive a share-weighted wine stock level elasticity estimate of –0.77. We suggest an elasticity of around this magnitude as an appropriate working assumption for how grape prices, on average, will respond to changes in overall wine stock levels.

For grape juice stocks, the overall pattern of effects is that the response is largest for Aspirant Bouchet, then red varieties, followed by white varieties, and finally rosé varieties. That the coefficients for rosé varieties are the lowest is surprising, as the main raw material for grape juice production is rosé grape varieties. However, for this market segment, the key grape attribute is sugar content. It may be the case that years with low harvests, and, hence, low grape juice stock levels, are correlated with factors that impact sugar content levels. As we have no information on the sugar content of the grapes sold, it is not possible to test this hypothesis, but thinking through how frosts and cold days may affect both harvest size and grape sugar content levels suggests a correlation of this type is one plausible explanation for the observed result.Footnote 2

C. Other Effects

The payment type effect is both statistically and practically significant in all regions, with the price being higher for payments by installments. An immediate cash payment may be beneficial for growers that have debts to repay, and may also help finance pruning service costs in winter, and fertilizer and pesticide costs in early spring. Immediate cash payments are also valued in countries such as Argentina that have recent experience with high rates of price inflation.

The estimated immediate cash payment discount, relative to payment by installments, was 4.4% in Uco Valley and 5.2% in Lujan-Maipu. These two values are both statistically different from zero, but not statistically different to each other. The discount was 12.1% in the Northeast region and 12.4% in the South region, and these two values are not statistically different to each other, but are statistically different to the values for Uco Valley and Lujan-Maipu. On average, the Northeast and South regions are associated with lower grower profitability (Abihagle, Aciar, and Gonzalez Luque, Reference Abihagle, Aciar and Gonzalez Luque2015; Altschuler, Reference Altschuler2012). We interpret the higher value of the discount for cash payments in the Northeast and South regions as consistent with growers in these regions facing relatively high levels of financial stress, and suggest that there could be value extending formal financial services to growers in these regions.

Transactions were grouped into volume quartiles, and the range for each quartile was: less than 11.3 tonnes; 11.3 to 26.4 tonnes; 26.4 to 56.1 tonnes; and greater than 56.1 tonnes. Relative to transactions in the first quartile, transactions in the second, third, and fourth quartile attracted price premiums of 2.6%, 3.5%, and 3.0%, respectively. These price premiums are not statistically different from each other, but are all statistically different from the first quartile. The government focus on policies that promote association schemes for the smallest growers therefore seem to be well founded. The average price gain from increasing transaction size is modest, but real; and as it is only necessary to move up to the second quartile to achieve this benefit, the required increase in volumes appears achievable.

There are plausible factors influencing prices that are not included in the model. For example, changes in export demand, exchange rate effects, tax changes, trends in domestic consumption, and changes in production costs. The variety level time trends, in part, capture the effect of factors not included in the model. In general, the variety level time trends describe the same basic pattern: falling real prices through to around 2013 or 2014, followed by a slow recovery. The time trend for rosé varieties, however, shows falling prices through to 2016, and then a much slower recovery. The overall effect is that the price gap between rosé varieties and other varieties has increased over the sample period.

V. Conclusion

This study has investigated wine grape price dynamics for Mendoza, the most important grape growing region of Argentina. The estimated model provides a good explanation of the price dynamics of medium- and high-quality grapes, and the model results have several practical policy implications. First, the long-run predicted prices suggest that some of the varieties used in the current government-sponsored replanting program may not be the varieties that will improve grower profitability the most. As such, a review of the replanting strategy seems appropriate. Second, there is a quantity discount effect that negatively impacts the smallest growers. Association schemes among the smallest growers to increase the average transaction size are therefore valuable. Third, there is evidence of greater financial stress in the Northeast and South regions, relative to the Uco Valley and Lujan-Maipu regions; and so, the potential benefits from extending financial services to these two regions is likely to provide the greatest return. Finally, the estimated average long-run wine stock elasticity of –0.77 can be used by policymakers as a reference value as they start to implement a program of active wine stock level management.

Appendix

Table A1 provides estimates where Malbec is the base variety, Northeast is the base region, payment is by cash, and quantity sold is the first quartile of the distribution (i.e., less than 11.3 tonnes). Table A2 provides information on the range of interaction terms. For each variety there is first a region specific term. Then for the lag of price, harvest in Mendoza, wine stocks, grape juice stocks, and the time trend, there is a variety specific term.

Table A1 Base Case Estimates

Table A2 Additional Effects for Interaction Terms

Footnotes

The authors thank an anonymous referee and the editorial team at JWE (especially Karl Storchmann) for their comments and assistance in progressing this paper to its final version.

1 Additionally, for the regression model, we used the price index from the Province of San Luis to check our results. The results we obtain using this alternate price index series are qualitatively the same as the results based on the Santa Fe Chamber of Commerce price index.

2 We note that there may be many plausible competing hypotheses for the observed result.

Notes: *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01. Heteroskedastic robust standard errors.

Notes: *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01. Heteroskedastic robust standard errors.

References

Abihagle, C. E., Aciar, A., and Gonzalez Luque, L. (2015). Distribución de la renta vitivinícola: Análisis y propuestas para mejorar y estabilizar la participación del sector primario. Mendoza.Google Scholar
Altschuler, B. (2012). Social boundaries and asymmetries in today's winemaking in Mendoza. Cuadernos de Desarrollo Rural, 9(68), 151175.Google Scholar
Anderson, K., Nelgen, S., and Pinilla, V. (2017). Global Wine Markets, 1860 to 2016: A Statistical compendium. Adelaide: University of Adelaide.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argentinean Secretary of Agriculture (2017). Avanza el plan de reconversion vitivinicola en Mendoza. Buenos Aires: Ministerio de Agroindustria de la Nación.Google Scholar
Argentinean Wine Corporation (2018). Impacto de la Vitivinicultura en la Economía Argentina. Mendoza: Corporación Vivinícola Argentina.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O. (2017). The hedonic approach to vineyard site selection: Adaptation to climate change and grape growing in emerging markets. Journal of Wine Economics, 12(1), 315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bekkerman, A., and Brester, G. W. (2019). Don't judge a wine by its closure: Price premiums for corks in the US wine market. Journal of Wine Economics, 14(1), 325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardebat, J. M., Faye, B., Le Fur, E., and Storchmann, K. (2017). The law of one price? Price dispersion on the auction market for fine wine. Journal of Wine Economics, 12(3), 302331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardebat, J. M., and Figuet, J. M. (2019). The impact of exchange rates on French wine exports. Journal of Wine Economics, 14(1), 7189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cavallo, A., Cruces, G., and Perez-Truglia, R. (2016). Learning from potentially biased statistics. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2016, 59108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa-Font, M., Serra, T., Gil, M., and Gras, A. (2009). Explaining low farm-gate prices in the Catalan wine sector. International Journal of Wine Business Research, 21, 169184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, R., Plantinga, A. J., and Stavins, R. N. (2017). Terroir in the New World: Hedonic estimation of vineyard sale prices in California. Journal of Wine Economics, 12(3), 282301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daniel, C. J., and Lanata Briones, C. T. (2019). Battles over numbers: The case of the Argentine consumer price index (2007–2015). Economy and Society, 48, 127151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuller, K. B., and Alston, J. M. (2012). The demand for California wine grapes. Journal of Wine Economics, 7(2), 192212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gergaud, O., Livat, F., and Song, H. (2018). Terrorism and wine tourism: The case of museum attendance. Journal of Wine Economics, 13(4), 375383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Government of Mendoza (2017). Kerchner anuncio la extension del plan de reconversion vitivinicola de la zona Sur y Lavalle. Mendoza: Ministerio de Agroindustria de la Nación.Google Scholar
Goverment of Mendoza (2019). El Gobierno Reglamento el Fondo Anticiclico Vitivinicola. Mendoza: Mendoza: Ministerio de Agroindustria de la Nación.Google Scholar
Miranda-Zanetti, M., Delbianco, F., and Tohmé, F. (2019). Tampering with inflation data: A Benford law-based analysis of national statistics in Argentina. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 525, 761770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niklas, B., and Sadik-Zada, E. R. (2019). Income inequality and status symbols: The case of fine wine imports. Journal of Wine Economics: Selected Proceedings, 14(4). doi: 10.1017/jwe.2019.33.Google Scholar
Oczkowski, E. (2006). Modeling winegrape prices in disequilibrium. Agricultural Economics, 34(1), 97107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Official Bulletin of Argentina (2019). Resolucion 3/2019. Available at www.boletinoficial.gob.ar/.Google Scholar
OIV (2018). OIV 2018 report on the world vitivinicultural situation. Available at http://www.oiv.int/en/oiv-life/oiv-2018-report-on-the-world-vitivinicultural-situation.Google Scholar
Reynolds, S. (2009). Analysing the South African table grape industry within a partial equilibrium framework. Agrekon, 48, 124145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomsik, P., Stojanova, H., Sedlo, J., and Vajcnerova, I. (2016). Factors of profitability of the grapes production. Agricultural Economics (Zemědělská ekonomika), 62, 292297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volpe, R., Green, R., Heien, D., and Howitt, R. (2012). Estimating the supply elasticity of California wine grapes using regional systems of equations. Journal of Wine Economics, 5(2), 219235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisong, M., Xiaoshuan, Z., Lingxian, Z., and Zettan, F. (2010). A structural model for analysis of fruit supply and demand applied to grapes in China. New Zealand Journal of Agricultural Research, 50, 13591365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yilmaz, F., and Abdikoglu, D. I. (2017). Econometric analysis of the production and price of grapes in Turkey. In Arslan, H., Ali Içbay, M., and Reggiero, C. (eds.), Research on Humanities and Social Sciences: Communication, Social Sciences, Arts, 223230. Pieterlen and Bern, Switzerland: Peter Lang AG.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Number of Observations (i.e., Transactions) and Grape Prices (2018 US$/t) by Variety and Region

Figure 1

Table 2 Long-Run Predicted Prices for Mendoza, Current Area Planted, and Average Revenue (2018)

Figure 2

Table 3 Price Dynamics Coefficients Summary (Elasticities)

Figure 3

Table A1 Base Case Estimates

Figure 4

Table A2 Additional Effects for Interaction Terms