Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T16:08:01.192Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Pursuit of Non-Trade Policy Objectives in EU Trade Policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2021

Ingo Borchert
Affiliation:
University of Sussex, UK
Paola Conconi*
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles (ECARES), Bruxelles1050, Belgium CEPR, CESifo CEP, London
Mattia Di Ubaldo
Affiliation:
University of Sussex, UK
Cristina Herghelegiu
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles (ECARES), Bruxelles1050, Belgium
*
*Corresponding author: Email: pconconi@ulb.ac.be
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The European Union (EU) often conditions preferential access to its market on compliance with Non-Trade Policy Objectives (NTPOs), including human rights and labor and environmental standards. In this paper, we first systematically document the coverage of NTPOs across the main tools of EU trade policy: its (association and non-association) trade agreements and Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) programs. We then discuss the extent to which the EU can use these tools as a ‘carrot-and-stick’ mechanism to promote NTPOs in trading partners. We argue that, within trade agreements, the EU has limited scope to extend or restrict tariff preferences to ‘reward good behavior’ or ‘punish bad behavior’ on NTPOs, partly because multilateral rules require members to eliminate tariffs on substantially all trade. By contrast, GSP preferences are granted on a unilateral basis, and can thus more easily be extended or limited, depending on compliance with NTPOs. Our analysis also suggests that the commercial interests of the EU inhibit the full pursuit of NTPOs in its trade agreements and GSP programs.

Type
Original Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The European Union (EU) is one of the biggest players in world trade and often exploits its commercial power as a diplomatic tool.Footnote 1 It has been argued that preferential access to the EU market, sometimes combined with financial aid and economic cooperation, is ‘the principal instrument of foreign policy for the EU’ (Sapir, Reference Sapir1998, 726).

The EU conducts its external relations, including trade relations, with the stated purpose of promoting its values. This goal has been made official in the Treaty of Lisbon, notably Article 21 (1), which states:

The Union's action on the international scene shall be guided by the principles which have inspired its own creation, development and enlargement, and which it seeks to advance in the wider world: democracy, the rule of law, the universality and indivisibility of human rights and fundamental freedoms, respect for human dignity, the principles of equality and solidarity, and respect for the principles of the United Nations Charter and international law.

Art. 21 (3) of the Treaty on European Union (TEU) explicitly encompasses trade as part of the action of the EU ‘on the international scene’, and trade policy must consequently ‘be guided’ by EU values. For this reason, the EU often conditions preferential trade access to its market to the achievement of Non-Trade Policy Objectives (NTPOs), such as sustainable development, human rights, and good governance.Footnote 2 In response to increasing calls from the European Parliament and civil society, the new von der Leyen Commission has promised to strengthen the use of trade tools in support of such NTPOs.Footnote 3

The purpose of the paper is twofold. First, we systematically document the coverage of NTPOs across the main tools of EU preferential trade policy: trade agreements – which we distinguish between association and non-association agreements – and the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP). Second, we examine the extent to which the EU can use these trade policy instruments as a ‘carrot-and-stick’ mechanism to promote NTPOs in partner countries. It should be stressed that our goal is to examine whether the EU can potentially use conditionality in tariff preferences to promote NTPOs. We do not study outcomes, i.e., whether EU trade agreements and GSP programs actually have had any impact on such objectives.

To examine the coverage of NTPOs in trade agreements, we use data from the Design of Trade Agreements (DESTA) project. Because of differences in rationale and legal status, it is useful to group NTPOs according to their political and economic objectives. Political NTPOs include civil and political rights as well as security issues, whereas economic NTPOs encompass economic and social rights and environmental protection.Footnote 4

We show that political NTPOs related to human rights and security are more prevalent in association than in non-association agreements, and their coverage decreases with the size of the trading partner. This suggests that, when negotiating association agreements with neighboring countries, the EU is mostly driven by political motives: it offers preferential access to its market in exchange for close political co-operation (possibly towards future membership). Non-association agreements are instead more focused on economic NTPOs related to labor and environmental standards, and the coverage of these provisions increases with the size of the trading partner. This suggests that the inclusion of economic NTPOs in trade agreements is mostly driven by commercial motives and a desire by the EU to ensure a ‘level playing field’ between domestic producers and foreign competitors.

We also document the coverage of NTPOs in the GSP programs of the EU. Over the years, the EU has introduced in its GSP regulations provisions aimed at pursuing both political and economic NTPOs. These provisions make GSP eligibility conditional on respect of core principles set out in international conventions (e.g., on human rights, labor and environmental protection, fight against terrorism, and drug trafficking).

We then examine the extent to which the EU can use tariff preferences – in its trade agreements and GSP programs – as a ‘carrot-and-stick’ mechanism to incentivize trading partners and achieve NTPOs. We argue that tariff preferences offered through trade agreements are not an effective tool to promote compliance with NTPOs. The key reason for this ineffectiveness is that EU trade agreements are subject to the requirements imposed by Article XXIV of the GATT/WTO, which stipulates that member countries should eliminate tariffs and other restrictive measures on ‘substantially all the trade’. Given that tariffs must be eliminated reciprocally across the board, the EU cannot easily extend or restrict preferential access to its market to ‘reward good behavior’ or to ‘punish bad behavior’ on NTPOs.Footnote 5

In principle, the EU can trigger the ‘essential elements’ clause in case of severe NTPOs violations by a trading partner, leading to the suspension or termination of the trade agreement. However, this clause only applies to severe violations of political NTPOs (related to human rights, democracy, the rule of law, and security). Moreover, in the few cases in which the EU has activated the ‘essential elements’ clause, it has never suspended or terminated the agreement. This may partly be due to the fact that this ‘stick’ is too drastic: given the reciprocal nature of a trade agreement, its suspension or termination can be extremely costly, not only for the trading partner, but also for the EU.

When it comes to its GSP programs, we argue that the EU can more easily condition preferential access to its market to compliance with NTPOs by the trading partners. The key difference is that GSP preferences are offered on a unilateral basis, which affords more leeway in using conditionality by preference-granting countries.

The EU can reward GSP members that make progress towards NTPOs by offering lower tariffs and/or a broader product coverage (positive conditionality). For example, since 2014 the Philippines has been a beneficiary of the GSP+ program. This special incentive arrangement for Sustainable Development and Good Governance grants developing countries full removal of tariffs on two thirds of all product categories, conditional on their ratification of and compliance with core international conventions on human rights, labor, and environmental protection.Footnote 6

Conversely, in case of violations of NTPOs, the EU can punish the trading partner by suspending part or all of its GSP preferences (negative conditionality). For example, in 2010 the EU withdrew Sri Lanka from its GSP+ program. This decision was based on the findings of an investigation by the Commission that identified shortcomings in the implementation by Sri Lanka of three UN human rights conventions (the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, the Convention against Torture, and the Convention on the Rights of the Child, respectively).

Although GSP programs can in principle be an effective tool to promote NTPOs in trading partners, the EU has only punished NTPO violations on a few occasions, mostly in the case of severe violations of human rights in small developing countries. Commercial motives may explain why similar violations in larger developing countries have not been punished. We argue that monitoring and implementation of GSP conditionalities would need to be more consistent and rules-based if the new EU Commission truly wanted to use trade policy to promote NTPOs.

In line with previous studies (see, e.g., Poletti and Sicurelli, Reference Poletti and Sicurelli2018; Meissner and Mckenzie, Reference Meissner and Mckenzie2018), our analysis suggests that EU trade policies are driven by two often conflicting goals: promoting European values and pursuing the commercial interests of EU members.

The paper is structured as follows. In Sections 2 and 3, we briefly trace the evolution of NTPO provisions in EU trade agreements and GSP programs, respectively. In Section 4, we focus on conditionality clauses in EU trade agreements and GSP programs, comparing the extent to which these trade tools can be used to promote NTPOs. Section 5 concludes.

2. NTPOs in EU Trade Agreements

At present, the EU has in place the largest trade network in the world, with 42 trade agreements fully in force or provisionally applied.Footnote 7 These trade agreements are listed in Table A-1 in Appendix A.

All trade agreements covering goods are notified at the WTO under GATT Article XXIV and take the form of free trade agreements (FTAs), with the exception of the ones with Andorra, Turkey, and San Marino, which are customs unions.Footnote 8 Table A-1 also distinguishes whether these trade agreements are part of an association agreement.

Association agreements are a very important instrument used by the EU in its external policy, as they ‘establish a legal and institutional framework for the development of privileged relations involving close political and economic cooperation’ (Van Elsuwege and Chamon, Reference Van Elsuwege and Chamon2019, 9). The legal basis for association agreements is Article 217 TFEU. If a trade agreement is negotiated under this article, then throughout our analysis we classify it as an association agreement.Footnote 9

During recent decades, trade agreements have not only increased in number but have also become ‘deeper’. They often include provisions related to NTPOs. To describe the coverage of NTPOs in EU trade agreements, we use the dataset on their legalization constructed by Lechner (Reference Lechner2016) in the context of the Design of Trade Agreements (DESTA) project. The use of this dataset is motivated by two reasons. First, it provides nuanced measures of the coverage of NTPOs instead of simply coding whether or not they are included in an agreement. Second, the database covers a wide range of agreements, including the most recent ones.Footnote 10 While the degree of legalization is not a measure of enforcement per se, it captures variation in the degree of commitment towards NTPOs by the EU and its trading partners.

The concept of legalization, introduced by Abbott et al. (Reference Abbott, Keohane, Moravcsik, Slaughter and Snidal2000) and applied by Lechner (Reference Lechner2016) to NTPOs in trade agreements, is based on three criteria: obligation, precision, and delegation. Obligation refers to the extent to which trading partners make commitments indicating the intent to be legally bound. Precision refers to the degree to which the rules that define the conduct required, authorized, or proscribed for trading partners are unambiguous. Delegation measures to what extent third parties have been granted authority to implement, interpret, and apply the rules, to resolve disputes, and possibly make further rules. A legalization score is computed aggregating these three dimensions for each category of NTPOs. The score ranges from ‘ideal’ legalization, where the three dimensions are maximized, to the complete absence of legalization.Footnote 11

In Figure 1, we analyze the evolution of NTPOs in trade agreements negotiated by the EU over the last five decades, based on the overall legalization scores. The figure shows that NTPOs have gained prominence during the last two decades: all the agreements with the highest overall legalization scores (above 40) have all been signed after the Treaty of Lisbon (e.g. with Georgia, Moldova, Ukraine, Canada, Japan, and Vietnam).

Figure 1. Evolution of the legalization of NTPOs in EU trade agreements

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on Lechner (Reference Lechner2016).

Combining Figure 1 and Table A-1, it is apparent that the highest legalization scores correspond to association agreements with small trading partners (e.g. Georgia, Moldova, Ukraine) as well as to FTAs with larger partners (e.g. Canada, Japan, Vietnam). To further explore the driving forces behind the high scores of these agreements, in Table 1 we decompose the overall score of each trade agreement by type of NTPOs and by type of agreement (association or non-association).

Table 1. Degree of legalization of NTPOs in EU trade agreements

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on Lechner (Reference Lechner2016).

The most recent association and non-association agreements have similar overall legalization scores, yet the composition of these scores is different across the two types of agreements. In the case of association agreements, political NTPOs (civil and political rights and security issues) prevail. In the case of non-association agreements, the high overall legalization scores are mainly driven by economic NTPOs (economic and social rights and environmental protection). As discussed below, this systematic difference reflects different motives to negotiate trade agreements: the desire for close political co-operation (possibly towards future membership) is a key motive in association agreements, while market access is the primary rationale in non-association agreements.

In what follows, we provide more details about the heterogeneity in the coverage of political and economic NTPOs, respectively, in EU trade agreements.

2.1 Political NTPOs

As mentioned before, EU trade agreements cover NTPOs of a political nature, which encompass provisions related to civil and political rights (e.g., human rights, democracy, and the rule of law) and to security and peace (e.g., non-proliferation of weapons of mass destruction, combating terrorism, organized crime, and corruption).

Human rights, democracy, and the rule of law have been systematically considered as ‘essential elements’ of EU trade agreements since 1995. The non-proliferation of weapons of mass destruction (WMD) also has also constituted an ‘essential element’ of EU trade agreements since 2003, but on a less systematic basis.Footnote 12

The ‘essential elements’ clause is usually divided in two provisions. The first one presents the scope of the clause, describing the principles that the parties engage to abide by (e.g., human rights, democracy, the rule of law, non-proliferation of WMD). The second provision enables one party to take ‘appropriate measures’ in case the other party violates the ‘essential elements’ clause. The measures introduced should be proportional to the violation, and priority should be given to the ones that least disturb the normal operation of the agreement. However, in the case of a material breach – which consists of either the repudiation of the agreement not sanctioned by the general rules of international law or a particularly serious and substantial violation of an ‘essential element’ – the agreement can be terminated or suspended in whole or in part, based on Article 60 of the Vienna Convention. In certain agreements, the parties can also rely on the dispute settlement mechanism of the agreement to solve the issues that arise from the violation of the ‘essential elements’ clause.

The political nature of civil and political rights and peace and security issues is apparent from the way in which they are included in trade agreements. In the case of association agreements, where the political dialogue is joint with the trade agreement, the ‘essential elements’ clauses are usually mentioned in the general principles and/or in the political dialogue section, and apply to the whole agreement. Non-association agreements do not include the ‘essential elements’ clauses, but simply refer to the principles and values from the separate framework agreements.Footnote 13

Table 1 reveals that civil and political rights and security issues are much more important in association agreements compared to non-association agreements. The average legalization scores of civil and political rights in association agreements are more than double than those of non-association agreements (7.3 versus 3.2). The same is true for security issues, which are characterized by an average legalization of 6.9 in association agreements and 3.0 in non-association agreements.

This distinction is further elucidated in Figure 2, in which we correlate the political legalization scores of association agreements (indicated with black dots) and other EU trade agreements (indicated with white squares) with the market size (log of GDP) of the trading partner.Footnote 14 The left-hand-side panel focuses on civil and political rights, while the right-hand-side panel looks at security issues.

Figure 2. Coverage of Political NTPOs in EU Trade Agreements and the Size of EU Trading Partners

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on the legalization scores from Lechner (Reference Lechner2016) and GDP in constant 2010 US $ from the World Development Indicators dataset of the World Bank.

Both panels of Figure 2 show that legalization scores of political NTPOs are negatively correlated with market size of the agreement partner and this inverse relationship is driven by association agreements (clustered at the top left corner of each panel). This suggests that, when negotiating these agreements, the EU offers to small neighboring countries preferential access to its market in exchange for political cooperation and alignment.

2.2 Economic NTPOs

Economic NTPOs related to economic and social rights and environmental protection are usually bundled together under the umbrella of ‘trade and sustainable development’ (TSD).Footnote 15 Both association and non-association agreements concluded after the Treaty of Lisbon include TSD chapters. However, unlike political NTPOs, economic NTPOs do not currently constitute ‘essential elements’ of EU trade agreements. This may change, though, due to the increasing significance of environmental policy. Executive Vice-President Valdis Dombrovskis, EU Commissioner for Trade, has recently suggested that the ‘Commission will propose the respect of the Paris climate commitments as an essential element in our future agreements’.Footnote 16

Table 1 shows that the legalization scores of economic and social rights and environmental protection are comparable between association and non-association agreements.Footnote 17

Similar to political NTPOs, the size of the trading partner is key to explaining the heterogeneity in the coverage of economic NTPOs across trade agreements. However, in the case of economic NTPOs, the relationship is positive. This can be seen from Figure 3, in which we correlate the legalization scores of economic and social rights (left panel) and environmental protection (right panel) with the market size of the agreement partner. These results suggest that commercial motives are behind the inclusion of economic NTPOs in trade agreements: when negotiating with larger trading partners, the EU pushes for higher labor and environmental standards to ensure a ‘level playing field’ between domestic producers and their foreign competitors.

Figure 3. Coverage of Economic NTPOs in EU Trade Agreements and the Size of EU Trading Partners

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on the legalization scores from Lechner (Reference Lechner2016) and GDP in constant 2010 US$ from the World Development Indicators dataset of the World Bank.

3. NTPOs in the EU's Generalized Systems of Preferences

The Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) is an alternative policy tool through which the EU can grant preferential access to its market. In this section, we first describe briefly the evolution of EU GSP schemes before discussing in detail their coverage of NTPOs.

3.1 EU GSP Schemes

The legal basis for GSP schemes in the GATT/WTO system is the Enabling Clause of 1979.Footnote 18 This clause legalizes a positive, pro-development form of trade discrimination, as it allows donor countries to offer better than most-favored-nation (MFN) tariffs to developing countries without extending the same treatment to developed trade partners. The vague formulation of the Enabling Clause, in terms of countries and goods that should be eligible for preferences, allowed for a great deal of discretion on the side of preference-granting countries (Ornelas, Reference Ornelas2016), which often use GSP programs for their own political objectives (Grossman and Sykes, Reference Grossman and Sykes2005).

Most developed countries have set up their own GSP regimes.Footnote 19 Due to the unilateral nature of these programs, the EU and other granting countries can limit the set of beneficiary countries and/or the product coverage of their GSP schemes, respectively. For example, products such as clothing and footwear, which are considered sensitive on the part of donor countries and raise concerns among import-competing firms, are either excluded from the list of beneficiary sectors or receive lower trade preferences.

The EU's approach to its GSP scheme has evolved considerably over time, through three main reforms enacted in 1995, 2006, and 2014.Footnote 20 These reforms were aimed at rendering the scheme more predictable, stable, and targeted towards those countries most in need. As of today, the EU is operating three GSP programs, which grant different levels of access to the EU market: GSP, GSP+, and EBA. Table B-1 in the Appendix lists the current members of these programs.

The first is the standard GSP program, which is currently offered to 15 beneficiary countries, falling into the categories of low and lower-middle income countries as defined by the World Bank. Membership to the standard GSP program of the EU has changed considerably over time and is now at its lowest since the launch of the program. Countries in the standard EU GSP program benefit from lower than MFN tariff treatment or zero import duties on about 66% of the tariff lines applied by the EU.

The second program is denoted as GSP+ and allows duty free imports of the vast majority of the products covered by the standard GSP.Footnote 21 The GSP+ program was introduced in 2006 and has currently eight members that have been considered eligible on the basis of their economic vulnerability (European Union, 2012).Footnote 22 As discussed below, beneficiaries under the GSP+ are granted additional preferences relative to standard GSP members in exchange for complying with a number of international conventions protecting human rights, the environment, and good governance. Table B-2 in the Appendix provides a list of these conventions.

Finally, the Everything-but-Arms (EBA) initiative introduced in 2001 grants the most far-reaching preferential treatment as it allows for duty-free imports of all products exported by the 48 Least Developed Countries (LDCs)Footnote 23 with the exception of arms and ammunitions.Footnote 24

3.2 NTPOs in EU GSP Schemes

Over the years, the EU has introduced in its GSP regulations several provisions aimed at pursuing NTPOs, making preferential access to its market conditional on compliance with these objectives. Table 2 summarizes the main reforms of the EU's GSP schemes and the gradual expansion of NTPOs in these schemes.

Table 2. Evolution of provisions related to NTPOs in the GSP Programs of the EU

One of the earliest examples in 1991 concerned security issues (European Union, 1990). To discourage the production of narcotic drugs and to stimulate planting of substitute crops, the EU granted additional trade preferences, in form of duty-free market access, to Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru. In the following years, the EU expanded what was called the ‘drugs arrangement’ to Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua, Panama, and Venezuela, justifying the extended preferential treatment granted to these additional countries with the intention of combating not only the production but also the trafficking of drugs (European Union, 1991).

The EU used the 1995 GSP reform to add further NTPOs to its GSP regulation, through two Special Incentive Arrangements addressing labor and environmental issues.Footnote 25 The first Arrangement was comprised of a set of provisions granting an additional preferential margin to beneficiaries that could prove to have adopted and applied domestically the International Labor Organization (ILO) conventions concerning the freedom of association, the protection of the right to organize and bargain collectively, and the convention concerning the minimum age for employment.Footnote 26

The second arrangement made available additional trade preferences to countries adhering to environmental standards laid down by the International Tropic Timber Organization (ITTO) relating to the sustainable management of forests (European Union, 1994). To obtain these additional trade preferences, written applications needed to be made to the European Commission (EC), with details about the domestic legislation incorporating the conventions and the measures taken to monitor their application. The EC could then decide whether to grant the trade preferences included in the Special Incentive Arrangement to the applicant country as a whole, or only to some sectors, if it considered that the conventions were effectively applied. Applications for the labor standards arrangement were filed by Georgia, Mongolia, Russia, Ukraine, Uzbekistan, Sri Lanka, and Moldova, but only the latter two countries were granted preferences.

In 2001, the addition of Pakistan to the drugs arrangement triggered the first reaction at the WTO about the discriminatory nature (amongst developing countries) of NTPO-related provisions in the EU GSP programs. India filed a complaint, which resulted in certain aspects of the ‘drugs arrangement’ being ruled to be WTO-inconsistent in the Appellate Body EC-Tariff Preferences report (Appellate Body, 2004).Footnote 27 The response of the EU was to rearrange all the NTPO provisions related to drugs, labor, and environmental provisions into the Special Arrangement for Sustainable Development and Good Governance, also known as the GSP+, a single arrangement treating jointly all the NTPOs in the GSP, which was introduced with the 2006 GSP reform.Footnote 28

Under GSP+, the EU offers duty-free market access on virtually all GSP eligible products to eligible countries that have ratified and applied a list of 27 international conventions on sustainable development and good governance. These 27 conventions broaden and deepen the range of NTPOs addressed in earlier GSP programs of the EU. Human rights and corruption were added to the areas covered by the previous scheme, and many additional provisions were included concerning labor rights, environmental protection, and security issues.Footnote 29

In its initial (2006) formulation, the list of 27 conventions was divided in two sub-lists of core and non-core conventions. GSP+ applicants needed to have ratified all of the 15 core conventions, relating to human and labor rights, and at least seven other conventions relating to environmental protection, drug production, and trafficking. In addition, countries needed to commit to having ratified all remaining conventions by 2008. This ratification requirement was amended in the 2009 version of the GSP+, which imposed the ratification of the entire set of 27 international conventions in order for a country to be eligible for GSP+ preferences. Importantly, similarly to the Special Incentive Arrangements in force pre-2006, GSP+ applicants need to maintain implementation of the conventions and accept regular monitoring and review of the status of such implementation (European Union, 2005, 2013a).

In 2006, the GSP+ scheme was offered for three years, and it was renewed in 2009 and 2014, with the latter reform setting the rules that currently apply until 2023. From the outset, fifteen countries joined the GSP+: the eleven original members of the drugs arrangement excluding Pakistan,Footnote 30 plus Moldova, Mongolia, Sri Lanka, and Georgia. In 2009, all GSP+ members re-applied for the scheme, except Panama, which failed to apply in time,Footnote 31 and Moldova, which had left the GSP program entirely because of signing a trade agreement with the EU. In addition, Armenia, Azerbaijan, and Paraguay joined the list of beneficiaries (European Union, 2008). In 2014, Colombia, Honduras, and Nicaragua did not re-apply for the GSP+ scheme.

The 2014 GSP reform altered the eligibility criteria in the GSP+ scheme (European Union, 2012, 2014b), and also established that countries that have become part of alternative preferential trade agreements with the EU would lose their GSP benefits. For this latter reason, Costa Rica, Panama, Peru, and El Salvador were excluded from the GSP+ program in 2016 (European Union, 2014a) and Georgia in 2017 (European Union, 2015). Other countries instead joined the GSP+ scheme: Cape Verde and Pakistan in 2014, the Philippines in 2015, and Kyrgyzstan in 2016 (European Union, 2014c, 2016). Finally, Azerbaijan and Ecuador graduated from the GSP scheme altogether because they were classified as upper-middle income countries for three consecutive years by the World Bank.Footnote 32

4. Can Trade Conditionality Promote NTPOs?

As shown in previous sections, the EU has attempted over the past few decades to use its trade policy instruments to pursue various NTPOs, such as the fulfillment of social norms and the respect of environmental standards (Koch, Reference Koch2015).

In this section, we discuss whether the EU can promote NTPOs in its trading partners through positive and negative conditionality in its trade agreements and GSP schemes. According to Koch (Reference Koch2015), conditionality can be classified based on the leverage mechanism, which can be both punitive (negative) or rewarding (positive). Negative conditionality is related to the reduction, suspension, or termination of benefits when the conditions are not met within a relationship. Positive conditionality involves meeting requirements as a precondition for entering into a new relationship or granting additional benefits based upon performance or reform within an established relationship.

4.1 Conditionality in EU Trade Agreements

In this section, we discuss the extent to which the EU can use tariff preferences in trade agreements as a carrot-and-stick mechanism to promote NTPOs in its trading partners. Evidently, there is a range of other policies through which the EU can pursue NTPOs, particularly in its association agreements.Footnote 33 However, the reward offered for ‘good behavior’ and the punishment inflicted for ‘bad behavior’ do not involve trade policy (tariff preferences), but non-trade related policies (e.g., financial assistance, technical co-operation programs, prospects for EU membership), which are beyond the scope of this article.

As mentioned before, preferential trade agreements covering goods are regulated by GATT Article XXIV. All EU trade agreements are negotiated under this multilateral rule, which implies that trading partners have to ‘eliminate duties and other restrictive regulations of commerce with respect to substantially all trade in products originating in the constituents of the agreement’. As a result, positive conditionality through tariff preferences is very limited: once an agreement had entered into force and the tariffs on ‘substantially all’ trade have been eliminated, the EU cannot easily use trade preferences as a ‘carrot’ to incentivize trading partners’ respect of NTPOs. The only option is to extend preferences to cover excluded products. These products are typically those considered ‘sensitive’, so eliminating tariffs on them may be economically and politically costly for the EU.

It should be stressed that the EU could have some leverage before the entry into force of trade agreements, when it can decide not to pursue trade negotiations with countries that violate NTPOs. This could induce some countries to improve their domestic policies in order to be considered as potential partners in a trade agreement with the EU. However, the negotiation of the FTA with Singapore suggests that, when deciding whether to negotiate a trade agreement, the commercial interests of the EU may prevail over the pursuit of NTPOs. Singapore did not accept to sign an agreement that would have required a change in its position regarding the death penalty, human rights, or governance. The EU thus took a weaker stance on these issues, recognizing Singapore's human rights practices through a side letter to the agreement. Meissner and McKenzie (Reference Meissner and Mckenzie2018) argue that, in the case of the EU–Singapore agreement, the pure commercial interests of the EU prevailed over the promotion of its NTPOs. McKenzie and Meissner (Reference McKenzie and Meissner2020) point out that the case of the negotiations with Singapore ‘demonstrates the significant challenge the EU faces in fulfilling its strategic objectives and maintaining both its coherence and legitimacy as a political and trade actor as it negotiates trade agreements’ (p. 3).

Negative conditionality appears to be a more prominent feature of EU trade agreements. As previously stated, the ‘essential elements’ clause provides a mechanism through which the EU could sanction its trading partners. However, the EU has never actually used trade preferences to punish violations of NTPOs.Footnote 34

Several factors limit the ability of the EU to punish violations of NTPOs by its agreement partners. First, the ‘essential elements’ clause only covers political NTPOs (civil and political rights as well as security issues). Since the TSD provisions are not defined as ‘essential elements’, a violation of labor and/or environmental provisions could not justify the suspension or termination of the agreement in the event of a breach.Footnote 35

Second, triggering the ‘essential elements’ clause could entail significant commercial costs for the EU, particularly in the case of FTAs with large trading partners. Suspending or terminating these reciprocal trade agreements would increase both the cost of importing from and exporting to the FTA partner.

Third, since trading partners are at least formally on an equal footing, it is difficult to imagine that one of them could accept monitoring of its NTPOs from a peer. For instance, monitoring the respect of human rights does not involve habilitated organs to oversee the implementation of the various clauses (Bartels, Reference Bartels2013). Concerning the TSD chapters, monitoring involves several specialized bodies and tools that require input from civil society groups, but there are concerns regarding their engagement and power to address non-compliance with labor and environmental objectives (Marx et al., Reference Marx, Ebert, Hachez and Wouters2016).Footnote 36

Finally, if the EU did increase tariffs vis-à-vis an agreement partner, this policy may be challenged at the WTO. The EU could invoke the Vienna Convention to justify triggering the ‘essential elements’ clause of the trade agreement. However, WTO jurisprudence on GATT Article XXIV, and in particular the Appellate Body ruling in Turkey – Restrictions on Imports of Textile and Clothing Products, suggests that if the EU raised tariffs towards a partner country on the ground that it did not respect democratic principles and human rights, this policy might not be considered ‘necessary’ for the functioning of the agreement (Mavroidis, Reference Mavroidis2016).

4.2 Conditionality in the EU GSP Schemes

In this section, we examine whether EU GSP schemes can provide a ‘carrot-and-stick’ mechanism to reward ‘good behavior’ and punish ‘bad behavior’ in regard to NTPOs in developing countries. Our goal is thus to assess whether the EU's GSP system could be an effective tool to promote NTPOs in developing countries. This is different from assessing the effectiveness of its application so far, which is the focus of several earlier studies (Orbie and Tortell, Reference Orbie and Tortell2009; Beke and Hachez, Reference Beke and Hachez2015; Velluti, Reference Velluti2016).Footnote 37

Positive conditionality provisions abound in the EU's GSP schemes. Since the introduction of the first NTPO elements in its GSP regulations, the EU has always offered incentives to countries that comply with non-trade objectives, by way of a more preferential tariff treatment.

In the ‘drugs arrangement’ of 1991, the EU offered duty-free market access to compliant countries, thereby deepening the preferences that they had already obtained as GSP members. These extra trade preferences, however, were perceived as discriminatory among developing countries and as running counter to the principles established in the Enabling Clause. The WTO Appellate Body held that the ‘drugs arrangement’ was offered to a hand-picked list of beneficiaries, and did not establish any objective criteria that, if met, would have allowed other developing countries to be included as beneficiaries of the arrangement (Appellate Body, 2004).

The two ‘Special Incentive Arrangements’ introduced into the GSP regulation in 1995 also offered deeper-than-GSP trade preferences, in exchange for applying three ILO conventions on labor rights and adhering to certain environmental standards. In order to benefit from this form of conditionality, however, developing countries needed apply for it, which was unlike the ‘drugs arrangement’ whose members were selected by the EU.

The current and most complete instrument through which the EU applies positive conditionality is its GSP+ scheme. The GSP+ covers all the NTPOs jointly under the general concept of ‘sustainable development and good governance’ and offers developing countries lower tariffs in exchange for compliance with NTPOs.Footnote 38 To join the GSP+ scheme, developing countries must apply to the European Commission, which evaluates whether the applicant has ratified and applied the 27 international conventions.Footnote 39

Within the boundaries of WTO case law on non-discrimination amongst GSP beneficiaries, the EU GSP schemes thus provide ample leeway to reward developing countries that make efforts on NTPOs, which can gain better access to the EU market.

Negative conditionality is also pervasive and affects all three GSP programs (standard GSP, EBA, as well as GSP+), as the EU can withdraw GSP preferences from beneficiaries in case of violations of NTPOs.Footnote 40 A country might lose its standard GSP, GSP+, or EBA preferences for all or certain products either (i) following serious and systemic violation of the principles laid down in the ‘core conventions’ (Part A of Table B-2 in Appendix B), which are used as a basis for GSP+; or (ii) if a country exported products made by prison labor; or (iii) in case of serious shortcomings in custom controls on the export and transit of (illicit) drugs, or failures in compliance with international conventions on anti-terrorism and money-laundering.Footnote 41

With reference to point (i), recall from Section 3 that GSP+ members are required to have ratified and applied 27 international conventions when they join the program, including the core conventions related to human and labor rights. The same requirement does not apply to beneficiaries of the standard GSP and EBA programs. However, if a member of any of the three GSP programs violates the core conventions, the EU can revoke its tariff preferences.Footnote 42

If a violation is reported, the EU Commission carries out an investigation, consults the beneficiary concerned, and can eventually decide to suspend GSP preferences. Preference withdrawal is therefore a gradual process and is meant to allow the country to possibly remedy the alleged violation. If a decision about a suspension of preferences is finally made, it is initially for six months, after which the EU decides to either terminate or extend the suspension (European Union, 2012).

In addition to the aforementioned provisions, the GSP+ program has specific negative conditionality provisions. Within this program, the EU regularly monitors the status of implementation of the conventions by examining the conclusions and recommendations of the relevant monitoring bodies established under those conventions (European Union, 2012).Footnote 43 GSP+ preferences can be revoked if a country fails to ratify the necessary conventions, or to effectively implement them.

To the best of our knowledge, there have only been five instances in which the EU has sanctioned NTPO violations by GSP recipients. These are summarized in Table 3.Footnote 44

Table 3. EU sanctions following NTPO violations by GSP beneficiaries

There have been two cases of suspension of preferences granted under the standard GSP scheme, both occurring because of violations of labor standards. These cases concern Myanmar (currently an EBA member, but a GSP member at the time the sanction occurred) and Belarus (a standard GSP member). The EU sanctioned Myanmar in 1997, because of its use of forced labor, and then re-admitted the country into the GSP program in 2013 (European Union, 2013b). The sanction for Belarus occurred in 2007, as a consequence of the country's non-compliance with the Convention on freedom of assembly and collective bargaining (European Union, 2006).Footnote 45

Among GSP+ members, in 2010 Sri Lanka and Venezuela were ‘downgraded’ from GSP+ to standard GSP preferences. Sri Lanka was suspended from 2010 to 2017, because of its failure to implement effectively some of the conventions (European Union, 2009, 2010, 2017).Footnote 46 Venezuela was excluded from GSP+ due to its failure to ratify the UN convention against corruption.

Cambodia is the only country so far that has been suspended from EBA preferences. In February 2020, the EU decided to withdraw Cambodia's tariff preferences, due to serious and systematic violations of principles laid down in the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights. At the same time, to mitigate the socio-economic impacts of the preference withdrawal, and in consideration of the development needs of the country, the EU decided to remove tariff preferences only on certain products originating from Cambodia (EU Commission, 2020a,b).

It can be argued that the EU should have applied negative conditionality on more occasions and towards more GSP recipients. Indeed, European Commission (2017) reports many instances of ‘non-compliance on the ground’, including violations of human and labor rights reported in Bangladesh, Bolivia, China, Ethiopia, India, Pakistan, and Russia, which failed to trigger the negative conditionality provisions.

The EU usually justifies its limited use of negative conditionality with its policy of refraining from measures that can be harmful to a target population (Bartels, Reference Bartels2008; EU Council, 2012). A less altruistic explanation is linked to the commercial costs of punishing NTPO violations. Indeed, the EU has only applied negative GSP conditionality on small developing countries (e.g., Sri Lanka or Cambodia). When the violations have occurred in large developing countries (e.g., Pakistan or China), it has refrained from increasing tariffs as a punishment, possibly because this would have raised the cost of sourcing inputs from these countries, or for fear of retaliation in important export markets.

5. Conclusion

The EU is a pivotal player in international trade relations and its Treaties stipulate that the EU's external actions be conducted in a way so as to promote European principles and values, such as the respect for human rights and high labor and environmental standards.

In this paper, we have documented the coverage of NTPOs in the principal tools of EU trade policy: its trade agreements (association and non-association ones) and GSP programs (standard GSP, GSP+, and EBA). We have then examined the extent to which the EU could use these tools as a carrot-and-stick mechanism to promote NTPOs in trading partners.

When examining the coverage of NTPOs across EU trade agreements, we show that political NTPOs are more prevalent in agreements with smaller countries, and this result is mostly driven by association agreements (see Figure 2). In line with previous studies (e.g., Limão, Reference Limão2007), this finding suggests that the EU enters these agreements to offer small neighboring countries preferential access to its market, in exchange for political concessions (e.g., security cooperation, respect of human rights, and the rule of law). By contrast, economic NTPOs are more prevalent in trade agreements with larger countries (see Figure 3). This suggests that, when negotiating these agreements, the EU is mostly driven by commercial motives (improving access to the foreign markets, while guaranteeing a level playing field between domestic and foreign producers).

Both political and economic NTPOs are included in the GSP programs through which the EU offers preferential access to developing countries. In these programs, the EU's approach to NTPOs is more uniform than in the case of trade agreements. This may partly be due to the fact that multilateral trade rules and WTO case law limit the ability of the EU to discriminate across GSP beneficiaries.

We then discuss the extent to which the EU can use trade policy conditionality to effectively pursue NTPOs. Various studies have examined the enforceability of international agreements and whether linking trade and non-trade policy objectives can help to achieve more cooperation overall (Conconi and Perroni, Reference Conconi and Perroni2002; Limão, Reference Limão2005). These studies rely on the idea that trade policy can be used as a carrot-and-stick mechanism to enforce commitments in other policy areas. We come to a more nuanced conclusion. We argue that, within trade agreements, the EU cannot easily use trade policy conditionality to achieve non-trade objectives. This is partly due to the fact that multilateral trade rules limit the ability of the EU to reward trading partners (through lower tariffs) or punish them (through higher tariffs), depending on their behavior in relation to NTPOs. Under GATT Article XXIV, preferential trade agreements must eliminate ‘substantially all’ trade barriers amongst the signatories. Although what constitutes ‘substantially all’ trade is not precisely defined, neither in legal texts nor in case law, this article limits by design both positive and negative conditionality. As a result, once a trade agreement is concluded, it is difficult for the EU to use trade preferences as a carrot-and-stick mechanism to promote NTPOs.

The EU can have some leverage with trading partners before the entry into force of a trade agreement, since it can decide not to pursue negotiations with countries that violate NTPOs. At this stage, there might be incentives for third countries to improve their domestic policies in order to be considered as potential partners in a trade agreement with the EU. Some form of conditionality may also be possible after the entry into force of the agreement. In case of serious violations of human rights and security provisions, the EU could trigger the ‘essential elements’ and take ‘appropriate measures’ though it is legally unclear how much freedom the EU would have to increase tariffs vis-à-vis its agreement partners. Finally, non-trade policies (e.g., financial assistance or technical cooperation), which the EU can more easily offer to and take away from partner countries, may be more effective at promoting NTPOs within trade agreements.

When it comes to trade preferences offered under GSP schemes, we argue that they are a more flexible tool through which the EU could reward or punish trading partners in relation to NTPOs. GSP preferences are granted on a unilateral basis and – except for EBA preferences – do not extend to ‘substantially all trade’. The EU can thus reward countries that fulfill conditions related to NTPOs by granting them better GSP preferences (lower tariffs, on more products). GSP benefits can also be revoked, when trading partners do not fulfill these conditions. However, we point out that, if the EU wished to rely more on trade policy conditionality to promote such objectives, GSP schemes should be administered in a more consistent and rules-based way, with beneficiary countries being regularly monitored and their trade preferences being more systematically suspended or revoked in case of non-compliance with their NTPO commitments.

The new EU Commission under President von der Leyen has promised to strengthen the use of trade tools in support of NTPOs. Our paper suggests that commercial interests may inhibit the full pursuit of NTPOs in EU trade policy. The negotiations of the agreement with Singapore illustrate that the EU is at times willing to water down key values such as democracy, fundamental rights, and the rule of law in order to strike a commercial deal. Commercial interests also seem to affect the implementation of NTPO conditionality in GSP programs: although there have been many instances of severe violations of NTPOs in GSP beneficiaries, the EU has suspended trade preferences on very few occasions in which the violations have occurred in small developing countries, exempting larger countries from similar sanctions. In line with previous studies, our analysis suggests that EU trade policies reflect a tension between two often conflicting goals: promoting the principles and values of the EU and pursuing its commercial interests.

Appendix A

EU Trade Agreements

Table A-1. List of EU trade agreements notified to the WTO

Appendix B

GSP

Table B-1. List of GSP members

Table B-2. List of conventions to be ratified to be eligible for GSP+

Footnotes

We are grateful to Lisa Lechner for providing us with the data on legalization scores. We are indebted to Petros Mavroidis, Laura Puccio, André Sapir, Alan Winters (Editor), and two anonymous referees for their very useful comments and suggestions. The project leading to this paper received funding from the European Union's Horizon 2020 research and innovation program under grant agreement No 770680 (RESPECT).

1 The EU is the world's largest exporter of manufactured goods and services and is itself the biggest export market for around 80 countries. Together, its current 28 members account for 16% of world imports and exports. See http://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/eu-position-in-world-trade.

2 In general, conditionality is defined as granting benefits to a country subject to the beneficiary meeting certain conditions (Kishore, Reference Kishore2017) or as a mechanism to bring about policy reforms or impose policies that the beneficiary country would not voluntarily choose (Morrissey, Reference Morrissey, Koeberle, Silarszky and Verheyen2005).

3 See Mission Letter of then Commission President-elect Ursula von der Leyen to Phil Hogan, Commissioner-designate for Trade as of 10 September 2019: https://ec.europa.eu/commission/sites/beta-political/files/mission-letter-phil-hogan-2019_en.pdf.

4 Civil and political rights mainly refer to the protection of human rights, democratic institutions, rule of law, good governance, and corruption problems. Security issues deal with national security, drug trafficking, and the fight against terror. Economic and social rights broadly relate to labor standards, social protection, and development. Environmental protection includes objectives such as the protection of wildlife, reduction of air pollution, waste management, and forest protection.

5 The EU may have more leeway to nudge trading partners towards compliance with its NTPOs when the agreement extends cooperation beyond trade policy. This is typically the case in association agreements, in which the EU can make financial or technical assistance conditional on NTPOs. Whether these objectives can be enforced by non-trade policy instruments is beyond the scope of this article.

6 As a result of the upgrade, the number of products which the Philippines could export at zero tariff increased from 2,442 under standard GSP to 6,274 under GSP+.

7 The European Community (EC) Treaty is excluded. The European Economic Area agreement (EEA) and the EU agreements with Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland-Liechtenstein are considered separately. Trade agreements currently under negotiation (e.g., with Mercosur, India, Australia, New Zealand) are excluded from the analysis.

8 Some agreements are both FTAs and EIAs (Economic Integration Agreements) covering not only goods, but also services. These agreements are notified at the WTO under GATT Article XXIV and GATS Article V.

9 The conclusion of association agreements was already foreseen in the first EU Treaties. According to van Elsuwege and Chamon (Reference Van Elsuwege and Chamon2019), this provision has not undergone substantial modifications, except for certain procedural amendments. The current Article 217 TFEU corresponds to the former Articles 310 and 238 TEC (Treaty establishing the European Community).

10 The World Bank also collects data on the content of trade agreements. The Deep Trade Agreements database 1.0 compiled by Hofmann et al. (Reference Hofmann, Osnago and Ruta2017) based on the methodology of Horn et al. (Reference Horn, Mavroidis and Sapir2010) only analyzes whether various NTPOs are included in the agreement or not and does not cover the most recent agreements concluded by the EU. The Deep Trade Agreements database by Mattoo et al. (Reference Mattoo, Rocha and Ruta2020) provides nuanced measures, but does not cover NTPOs related to civil and political rights and security and does not include the most recent trade agreements.

11 The method used to compute the degree of legalization for each category of NTPOs in trade agreements is detailed in Lechner (Reference Lechner2016). The maximum possible legalization score varies across the four categories of NTPOs, depending on the issues specific to each category included in the analysis: 31 for civil and political rights, 37 for economic and social rights, 33 for environmental protection, and 25 for security. Therefore, the maximum possible overall legalization score per agreement is 126.

12 For instance, the agreements with countries from the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership such as Egypt, Lebanon, and Algeria, renegotiated after 2003, do not incorporate the non-proliferation of WMD clause.

13 For example, the FTA with Korea refers to the EU–South Korea Framework Agreement, while the EU–Canada FTA is framed within a Strategic Partnership Agreement. Cotonou, the umbrella agreement for the set of economic partnership agreements (EPAs) with ACP countries, is a special case. It is commonly classified as an association agreement (its legal basis is Article 217); however, the EPAs have not been concluded with a view to association, which is why we do not list them under association agreements. Moreover, the ‘essential elements’ clause of the Cotonou agreement refers to the potential suspension of development cooperation and aid, i.e., non-trade policy sanctions. See also footnote 34 below.

14 The data on GDP of the EU's trading partners (in constant 2010 US$) are taken from the World Bank's World Development Indicators database.

15 TSD chapters include ‘substantive standards’, meaning that there are minimum requirements for both parties to implement certain multilateral obligations (Harrison et al., Reference Harrison, Barbu, Campling, Richardson and Smith2019). In the case of economic and social rights, these minimum obligations refer to the ILO core labor standards, which are already binding on the parties due to their membership of the ILO. When it comes to environmental standards, the obligation to implement multilateral environmental agreements is essentially a reaffirmation of obligations already binding on the parties under those agreements. These provisions are not new to any party (Bartels, Reference Bartels2013). Second, TSD chapters include ‘procedural commitments’, through which the parties engage in dialogue and cooperation. Moreover, they commit to transparency when introducing new standards and agree to monitor and review the impact of the agreement. The parties also agree not to undermine their existing labor and environmental standards and to seek to enhance the existing regulations (Harrison et al., Reference Harrison, Barbu, Campling, Richardson and Smith2019). Finally, the implementation of TSD chapters is managed through various ‘institutional mechanisms’ including committees of state/EU officials, as described by Harrison et al. (Reference Harrison, Barbu, Campling, Richardson and Smith2019).

17 The average legalization of economic and social rights in association agreements is 9.0 and in non-association agreements it is 8.5. The same is true for environmental protection aspects, which are characterized by an average legalization of 7.4 in association agreements and 8.2 in non-association agreements.

18 Formally, this is a decision adopted by GATT contracting parties on 28 November 1979 for the Differential and More Favorable Treatment, Reciprocity and Fuller Participation of Developing Countries. The idea of granting non-reciprocal and non-discriminatory preferential market access to developing countries through GSP programs was first introduced in the late 1960s. The broad objectives were to increase participation of developing countries in international trade, foster their export earnings, promote their industrialization, and accelerate their economic growth (UNCTAD, 1968).

19 Before the adoption of the Enabling Clause, in order to temporarily legalize GSP programs, in 1971 the GATT contracting parties agreed to grant a 10-year waiver of Article 1 – the (MFN) non-discrimination obligation, for the GSP programs.

20 These reforms were respectively introduced by regulations published in 1994 (European Union, 1994), 2005 (European Union, 2005), and 2012 (European Union, 2012).

21 The share of tariff lines eligible for the duty-free GSP+ treatment is virtually the same as that for standard GSP (66%), with the difference that about 50% of standard GSP tariffs, although lower than MFN, do not go to zero (Ornelas, Reference Ornelas2016).

22 Vulnerability of the beneficiary country is defined in terms of its size (the country's EU import share of total GSP imports must be less than 1%) and diversification of export portfolio (the share of the five largest sectors in total GSP exports must be larger than 75%). The vulnerability definition was eased in the 2014 reform: the size threshold was increased from 1% to 2% (it has further been increased to 6.5% in 2015) and diversification is now computed based on the seven largest sectors in total GSP exports.

23 The identification of LDCs follows the long-standing UN definition, which is based on the three main criteria of income, human assets, and economic vulnerability. The group of LDCs has been very stable over time, with the last country to leave the group being Samoa in 2019.

24 Only imports of fresh bananas, rice, and sugar were not fully liberalized immediately. Tariff restrictions were removed in 2006 for bananas and in 2009 for sugar and rice.

25 Although the intention of introducing the Special Incentive Arrangement concerning labor rights and environmental protection appeared for the first time in the 1995 GSP reform (European Union, 1994), these arrangements were fully developed and applied only by the 1998 GSP Regulation (European Union, 1998).

26 ILO conventions 87, 98, and 138.

27 Appellate Body Report, European Communities – Conditions for the Granting of Tariff Preferences to Developing Countries, WT/DS246/AB/R, adopted 20 April 2004, DSR 2004: III, 925.

28 The WTO legality of the GSP+ program is a widely debated topic in the international law literature. For an overview of the legal issues concerning the GSP+, see Bartels (Reference Bartels2003, Reference Bartels2007), Jayasinghe (Reference Jayasinghe2015), Kishore (Reference Kishore2017).

29 The security issues in GSP+ relate to corruption and illicit drugs.

30 Pakistan joined the GSP+ in 2014, after the GSP reform that raised the vulnerability import-share threshold to 2%.

31 Panama re-joined the GSP+ scheme at the next available date, in 2014.

32 This mechanism is known as ‘income graduation’ and applies to all the members across the three EU GSP schemes.

33 For example, the agreements with the Western Balkans countries (e.g. Serbia, Montenegro, Albania), as well as those with Eastern (e.g. Moldova, Georgia, Ukraine) and Southern (e.g. Morocco, Egypt, Jordan) neighbors contain important packages related to financial assistance and technical cooperation, which support reforms in areas of good governance, democracy, the rule of law, security, and sustainable development.

34 The ‘essential elements’ clause has been invoked very rarely, even though there have been many instances in which the EU's trading partners have blatantly violated human rights (Beke et al., Reference Beke, d'Hollander, Hachez and Pérez De Las Heras2014). This happened in the context of the Cotonou Partnership Agreement with ACP countries, following coups, flawed elections, or grave human rights violations (Hachez, Reference Hachez2015). Even in these rare occasions, the EU did not lift tariff preferences to punish the trading partners, but instead suspended technical co-operation programs.

35 With respect to economic NTPOs (economic and social rights, environmental protection), the TSD chapters ‘are not primarily designed as a form of conditionality but rather as a safeguard to ensure that trade liberalization does not lead to deregulation or to the erosion of labor rights or environmental standards’ (Portela, Reference Portela2018). The resolution of issues related to sustainable development is based on non-sanction procedures. Hence, the main value added of TSD chapters is to enhance dialogue and cooperation in order to attain sustainable trade objectives. This approach to sustainable development in EU trade agreements, based on dialogue- and cooperation-based solutions in case of violations, has been considered ‘as lacking the necessary vigor’ (Marx et al., Reference Marx, Ebert, Hachez and Wouters2016, 16).

36 As discussed by Bronckers and Gruni (Reference Bronckers and Gruni2019), the European Commission launched discussions with a trading partner that had failed to respect labor standards in December 2018 in the context of the EU–Korea FTA. A panel has been requested seven years after South Korea had failed to ratify and implement four of the eight fundamental ILO Conventions. However, since labor standards are excluded from the dispute settlement procedures of the agreement, no sanctions have been applied. Bronckers and Gruni (Reference Bronckers and Gruni2019) discuss different ways through which the EU could improve the enforcement of TSD chapters in its trade agreements.

37 The assessment of whether conditionality in GSP preferences can bring about meaningful improvements in human and labor rights conditions remains difficult, and is not the focus of our analysis. A few studies have examined the impact of the sanctions imposed by the EU on GSP recipients. These studies suggest that the sanctions had limited impact on Myanmar and Belarus (Zhou and Cuyvers, Reference Zhou and Cuyvers2011; Gnutzmann and Gnutzmann-Mkrtchyan, Reference Gnutzmann and Gnutzmann-Mkrtchyan2017). Sri Lanka, by contrast, was more severely affected, since its exports to the EU were concentrated in sectors like the garment industry, which were more dependent on GSP preferences (Bandara and Naranpanawa, Reference Bandara and Naranpanawa2015). From a human and labor rights perspective, the three countries subject to EU sanctions did initially little to remedy the violations reported (Zamfir, Reference Zamfir2018). Over time, however, Myanmar and Sri Lanka underwent a regime change, which led to the re-establishment of GSP and GSP+ preferences.

38 The GSP+ scheme has been considered problematic in light of the Enabling Clause (Jayasinghe, Reference Jayasinghe2015), since it seems to go against the idea that, when offering GSP preferences, ‘developed countries do not expect reciprocity, [they] do not expect developing countries, in the course of trade negotiations, to make contributions which are inconsistent with their individual development, financial and trade needs’. However, the legality of the GSP+ program has not yet been challenged.

39 Most of the early GSP+ members had ratified all of the core conventions before the creation of GSP+ in 2006 (Azerbaijan, Ecuador, Panama, Paraguay, and Peru had ratified all of the 27 conventions by 2005), with only a few ratifications around the accession date. Countries that joined the GSP+ at a later stage had ratified all the necessary conventions long before becoming GSP+ members.

40 There are also negative conditionality provisions that are unrelated to NTPOs. For example, GSP preferences can be lost: (a) in case of fraud, serious and systematic unfair trading practices (this provision will not apply for those products which are already subject to anti-dumping or countervailing measures), irregularities or failure to comply with the rules of origin, failure to provide administrative cooperation for the implementation and control of the GSP arrangements; (b) in case of serious and systematic infringements of the objectives adopted by Regional Fishery Organizations, or any arrangements concerning the conservations and management of fishery resources.

41 The antiterrorism provision was introduced in the 2014 reform (European Union, 2012).

42 To sanction a member of the standard GSP and EBA programs, the country in question must have independently ratified the relevant convention(s) and thus be bound by their principles. For example, in 1998 the EU contemplated GSP sanctions against Pakistan for using child labor, but ultimately decided against it because Pakistan had not yet ratified the child labor conventions and was thus not bound by them (Portela and Orbie, Reference Portela and Orbie2014).

43 This monitoring activity leads to a report, presented every two years by the European Commission to the EU Parliament and the EU Council.

44 On three other occasions, the EU Commission launched an investigation, but did not withdraw the GSP preferences from the countries concerned. In 1998, the EU investigated Pakistan over its alleged use of child labor, in 2008 El Salvador was investigated over its compliance with the ILO Convention on freedom of association, and in 2012 Bolivia was investigated over the alleged failure to implement the UN Convention on Narcotic Drugs (Portela and Orbie, Reference Portela and Orbie2014; Zamfir, Reference Zamfir2018).

45 Belarus’ sanction implied a fall back on standard non-preferential tariffs, as the country is not a WTO member and therefore not even entitled to WTO MFN treatment. Currently, Belarus is no longer eligible for EU GSP preferences.

46 The International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, the Convention against Torture and other Cruel, Inhuman or Degrading Treatment or Punishment, and the Convention on the Rights of the Child.

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on the information available at: http://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicSearchByMemberResult.aspx?MemberCode=918&lang=1&redirect=1 and https://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/countries-and-regions/negotiations-and-agreements/#_in-place. Source consulted on 1 August 2020. FTA, EIA and CU stand for Free Trade Agreement, Economic Integration Agreement and Customs Union, respectively.

Notes: Vietnam will continue to obtain GSP treatment in the EU over the two-year transition period following the entry into force of the EU–Vietnam FTA. Nauru, Samoa, and Tonga will lose their GSP beneficiary status from January 2021, due to being classified upper-middle income countries by the World Bank during three consecutive years. Several countries will lose their EBA membership due to graduating from their LDC status over the next years: Equatorial Guinea in 2021; Bhutan in 2026; Sao Tome and Principe, Solomon Islands in 2027. Other countries’ graduation from the LDC group will be fixed or recommended in 2021: Bangladesh, Laos, Myanmar, Nepal, Timor-Leste, Tuvalu, and Kiribati.

Source: Authors’ elaboration on EU GSP regulations.

Notes: Authors’ elaboration based on EU GSP regulations.

References

Abbott, K.W., Keohane, R.O., Moravcsik, A., Slaughter, A.-M., and Snidal, D. (2000) ‘The Concept of Legalization’, International Organization 54, 401419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
WTR (2004) ‘European Communities – Conditions for the Granting of Tariff Preferences to Developing Countries’, Appellate Body, WT/DS246/AB/R, DSR 2004: III, 925.Google Scholar
Bandara, J.S. and Naranpanawa, A. (2015) ‘Garment Industry in Sri Lanka and the Removal of GSP Plus by EU’, The World Economy 38, 14381461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, L. (2003) ‘The WTO Enabling Clause and Positive Conditionality in the European Community's GSP Program’, Journal of International Economic Law 6, 507532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, L. (2007) ‘The WTO Legality of the EU's GSP+ Arrangement’, Journal of International Economic Law 10, 869886.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, L. (2008) ‘The Application of Human Rights Conditionality in the EU's Bilateral Trade Agreements and Other Trade Arrangements with Third Countries’, In-depth analysis, European Parliament.Google Scholar
Bartels, L. (2013) ‘Human Rights and Sustainable Development Obligations in EU Free Trade Agreements’, University of Cambridge Faculty of Law Research Paper No. 24/2012.Google Scholar
Beke, L., d'Hollander, D., Hachez, N., and Pérez De Las Heras, B. (2014) ‘The Integration of Human Rights in EU Development and Trade Policies’, Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies, Leuven.Google Scholar
Beke, L. and Hachez, N. (2015) ‘The EU GSP: A Preference for Human Rights and Good Governance? The Case of Myanmar’, in Global Governance through Trade: EU Policies and Approaches. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 185213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bronckers, M. and Gruni, G. (2019) ‘Taking the Enforcement of Labour Standards in the EU's Free Trade Agreements Seriously’, Common Market Law Review 56, 15911622.Google Scholar
Conconi, P. and Perroni, C. (2002) ‘Issue Linkage and Issue Tie-In in Multilateral Negotiations’, Journal of International Economics 57, 423447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
European Commission (2017) ‘Mid-Term Evaluation of the EU's Generalised Scheme of Preferences (GSP) ’, 21 September 2017. Brussels: European Commission.Google Scholar
European Commission (2020a) ‘Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2020/550’, Official Journal of the European Union, L 127/1.Google Scholar
European Commission (2020b) ‘Joint Staff Working Document Report on EU Enhanced Engagement with Three Everything but Arms Beneficiary Countries: Bangladesh, Cambodia and Myanmar’, accompanying the document ‘Joint Report to the European Parliament and the Council Report on the Generalised Scheme of Preferences Covering the Period 2018–2019’, SWD/2020/19 final.Google Scholar
European Council. (2012) ‘Guidelines on Implementation and Evaluation of Restrictive Measures (Sanctions) in the Framework of the EU Common Foreign and Security Policy’, Doc. 11205/12.Google Scholar
European Union (1990) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 3835/90’, Official Journal of the European Union L 368/11.Google Scholar
European Union (1991) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 3900/90’, Official Journal of the European Union L370/126.Google Scholar
European Union (1994) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 3281/94’, Official Journal of the European Union L348/1.Google Scholar
European Union (1998) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 2820/98’, Official Journal of the European Union L32357/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2005) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 980/2005’, Official Journal of the European Union L169/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2006) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 1933/2006’, Official Journal of the European Union L 405/35.Google Scholar
European Union (2008) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 938/2008’, Official Journal of the European Union L334/90.Google Scholar
European Union (2009) ‘Council Decision (EC) No 2009/454’, Official Journal of the European Union L149/78.Google Scholar
European Union (2010) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 143/2010’, Official Journal of the European Union L45/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2012) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 978/2012’, Official Journal of the European Union L303/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2013a) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 155/2013’, Official Journal of the European Union L 48/5.Google Scholar
European Union (2013b) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 607/2013’, Official Journal of the European Union L 181/13.Google Scholar
European Union (2014a) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 1015/2014’, Official Journal of the European Union L 283/20.Google Scholar
European Union (2014b) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 1/2014’, Official Journal of the European Union L 1/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2014c) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 1386/2014’, Official Journal of the European Union L 369/33.Google Scholar
European Union (2015) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 2015/1979’, Official Journal of the European Union L 289/3.Google Scholar
European Union (2016) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 2016/79’, Official Journal of the European Union L 17/1.Google Scholar
European Union (2017) ‘Council Regulation (EC) No 2017/836’, Official Journal of the European Union L 125/1.Google Scholar
Gnutzmann, H. and Gnutzmann-Mkrtchyan, A.. (2017) ‘The Trade Effect of GSP Removal: Evidence from Belarus’, BEROC Working Paper No. 44.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Sykes, A.O. (2005) ‘A Preference for Development: the Law and Economics of GSP’, World Trade Review 4, 4167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hachez, N. (2015) ‘“Essential Elements” Clauses in EU Trade Agreements: Making Trade Work in a Way that Helps Human Rights?’, Working Paper No. 158.Google Scholar
Harrison, J., Barbu, M., Campling, L., Richardson, B., and Smith, A. (2019) ‘Governing Labour Standards through Free Trade Agreements: Limits of the European Union's Trade and Sustainable Development Chapters’, JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 57, 260277.Google Scholar
Hofmann, C., Osnago, A., and Ruta, M.. (2017) ‘Horizontal Depth: A New Database on the Content of Preferential Trade Agreements’, Policy Research Working Paper Series 7981, The World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horn, H., Mavroidis, P.C., and Sapir, A. (2010) ‘Beyond the WTO? An Anatomy of EU and US Preferential Trade Agreements’, The World Economy 33, 15651588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jayasinghe, V. (2015) ‘The Legality of the European Union's Special Incentive Arrangement’, Journal of International Economic Law 18, 555575.Google Scholar
Kishore, P. (2017) ‘A Critical Analysis of Conditionalities in the Generalized System of Preferences’, Canadian Yearbook of International Law/Annuaire Canadien de Droit International 54, 98133.Google Scholar
Koch, S. (2015) ‘A Typology of Political Conditionality Beyond Aid: Conceptual Horizons Based on Lessons from the European Union’, World Development 75, 97108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lechner, L. (2016) ‘The Domestic Battle Over the Design of Non-Trade Issues in Preferential Trade Agreements’, Review of International Political Economy 23, 840871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Limão, N. (2005) ‘Trade Policy, Cross-Border Externalities and Lobbies: Do Linked Agreements Enforce More Cooperative Outcomes?’, Journal of International Economics 67, 175199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Limão, N. (2007) ‘Are Preferential Trade Agreements with Non-Trade Objectives a Stumbling Block for Multilateral Liberalization?’, The Review of Economic Studies 74, 821855.Google Scholar
Marx, A., Ebert, F., Hachez, N., and Wouters, J. (2016) Dispute Settlement in the Trade and Sustainable Development Chapters of EU Trade Agreements. Leuven: Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies.Google Scholar
Mattoo, A., Rocha, N., and Ruta, M. (2020) Handbook of Deep Trade Agreements. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mavroidis, P.C. (2016) The Regulation of International Trade: GATT, Vol. 1. Cambridge, CA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
McKenzie, L. and Meissner, K.L. (2020) ‘Overlapping Negotiations, Conflicting Interests? EU–Singapore Negotiations’, EUI Working Paper RSCAS 2020/67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meissner, K.L. and Mckenzie, L. (2018) ‘The Paradox of Human Rights Conditionality in EU Trade Policy: When Strategic Interests Drive Policy Outcomes’, Journal of European Public Policy 26, 12731291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrissey, O. (2005) ‘Alternatives to Conditionality in Policy-Based Lending’, in Koeberle, S., Silarszky, P., and Verheyen, G. (eds.), Conditionality Revisited: Concepts, Experiences, and Lessons Learned. Washington, DC: World Bank, 237-247.Google Scholar
Orbie, J. and Tortell, L. (2009) ‘New GSP+ Beneficiaries: Tickling the Box or Truly Consistent with ILO Findings’, The European Foreign Affairs Review 14, 663681.Google Scholar
Ornelas, E. (2016) ‘Special and Differential Treatment for Developing Countries’, in K. Bagwell and R. Staiger (eds.), Handbook of Commercial Policy, Vol. 1. North Holland: Elsevier, 369432.Google Scholar
Poletti, A. and Sicurelli, D. (2018) The Political Economy of Normative Trade Power Europe. Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portela, C. (2018) Enforcing Respect for Labour Standards with Targeted Sanctions. Singapore: Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung.Google Scholar
Portela, C. and Orbie, J. (2014) ‘Sanctions under the EU Generalised System of Preferences and Foreign Policy: Coherence by Accident?’, Contemporary Politics 20, 6376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sapir, A. (1998) ‘The Political Economy of EC Regionalism’, European Economic Review 42, 717732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UNCTAD (1968) ‘Resolution 21(II) on Preferential or Free Entry of Exports of Manufactures and Semi-Manufactures of Developing Countries to the Developed Countries.Google Scholar
Van Elsuwege, P. and Chamon, M.. (2019) ‘The Meaning of “Association” under EU law: A Study on the Law and Practice of EU Association Agreements’, European Parliament.Google Scholar
Velluti, S. (2016) ‘The Promotion and Integration of Human Rights in EU External Trade Relations’, Utrecht Journal of International and European Law 32, 4168.Google Scholar
Zamfir, I. (2018) ‘Human Rights in EU Trade Policy: Unilateral Measures Applied by the EU’, Briefing, European Parliament Research Service.Google Scholar
Zhou, W. and Cuyvers, L. (2011) ‘Linking International Trade and Labour Standards: The Effectiveness of Sanctions under the European Union's GSP’, Journal of World Trade 45, 6385.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Evolution of the legalization of NTPOs in EU trade agreementsNotes: Authors’ elaboration based on Lechner (2016).

Figure 1

Table 1. Degree of legalization of NTPOs in EU trade agreements

Figure 2

Figure 2. Coverage of Political NTPOs in EU Trade Agreements and the Size of EU Trading PartnersNotes: Authors’ elaboration based on the legalization scores from Lechner (2016) and GDP in constant 2010 US $ from the World Development Indicators dataset of the World Bank.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Coverage of Economic NTPOs in EU Trade Agreements and the Size of EU Trading PartnersNotes: Authors’ elaboration based on the legalization scores from Lechner (2016) and GDP in constant 2010 US$ from the World Development Indicators dataset of the World Bank.

Figure 4

Table 2. Evolution of provisions related to NTPOs in the GSP Programs of the EU

Figure 5

Table 3. EU sanctions following NTPO violations by GSP beneficiaries

Figure 6

Table A-1. List of EU trade agreements notified to the WTO

Figure 7

Table B-1. List of GSP members

Figure 8

Table B-2. List of conventions to be ratified to be eligible for GSP+