Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-grxwn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-09T18:44:36.739Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Silk Road and the Iranian political economy in late antiquity: Iran, the Silk Road, and the problem of aristocratic empire

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 July 2018

Richard E. Payne*
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The Iranian Empire emerged in the third century in the interstices of the Silk Road that increasingly linked the markets of the Mediterranean and the Near East with South, Central, and East Asia. The ensuing four centuries of Iranian rule corresponded with the heyday of trans-Eurasian trade, as the demand of moneyed imperial elites across the continent for one another's high-value commodities stimulated the development of long-distance networks. Despite its position at the nexus of trans-continental and trans-oceanic commerce, accounts of Iran in late antiquity relegate trade to a marginal role in its political economy. The present article seeks to foreground the contribution of trans-continental mercantile networks to the formation of Iran and to argue that its development depended as much on the political economies of its western and eastern neighbours as on internal Near Eastern factors.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © SOAS, University of London 2018 

The Iranian Empire emerged in the third century in the interstices of the Silk Road that increasingly linked the markets of the Mediterranean and the Middle East with South, Central, and East Asia. The ensuing four centuries of Iranian rule corresponded with the heyday of trans-Eurasian trade, as the demand of moneyed imperial elites across the continent for one another's high-value commodities stimulated the development of long-distance networks. Despite its position at the nexus of trans-continental and trans-oceanic commerce, accounts of Iran in late antiquity relegate trade to a marginal role in its political economy. The Silk Road provides a backdrop to Iranian history rather than playing a determinative role in its development, a phenomenon occurring within the empire rather than a cause, among others, of its emergence and endurance.Footnote 2 The present article seeks to foreground the contribution of trans-continental mercantile networks to the formation of Iran and to argue its development depended as much on the political economies of its western and eastern neighbours as on internal Middle Eastern factors. It seeks to resolve a paradox in recent accounts of the Iranian political economy by demonstrating the potential contribution of long-distance commerce to the imperial fisc. In so doing, it illustrates some of the incipient interdependencies discernible in the various political-economic systems across Eurasia in late antiquity. The agents driving and determining the course of inter-imperial interaction – in political, economic, and cultural domains respectively – resided not in the metropoles of Rome, Iran, or China, but rather in the interstices of Central Eurasia.

As a historiographical concept, the Silk Road simultaneously obscures and reveals the ancient Central Eurasian societies usually studied within its framework. The privileging of long-distance commerce reduces societies no less complex than their East and West Asian counterparts to unidimensional corridors for transit and trade, passive passageways rather than active agents in their own histories.Footnote 3 The revival of archaeological and historical scholarship in these regions has shown that their nomadic elites developed sophisticated, trans-territorial political orders and that their economies were by no means dependent on trans-continental trade.Footnote 4 The concept of the Silk Road should therefore be retired as a historiographical framework for Central Eurasia, whether in the Bronze Age or late antiquity. It remains useful, however, as the name of a complex of institutions in operation circa 50–750 ce, when mercantile networks trafficking largely if not exclusively in silk took shape. If a wide range of South Asian commodities had long attracted Mediterranean and Middle Eastern consumers, the arrival of raw silk from East Asia in the first centuries bce and ce stimulated the massive, almost insatiable, demand of Roman elites for a commodity that could only be procured from China, or, from the third century onward, from Central Asia, until the transmission of the technology of silk production to the Iranian and Roman empires in the early sixth century.Footnote 5 The Chinese courts’ use of silk as a medium of exchange with outsiders delivered a surplus into the hands of Central Eurasian elites, who found a market for the material in a Mediterranean witnessing unparalleled rates of economic and demographic growth.Footnote 6 The compact, lightweight nature of this exceptionally high-value material made the trans-continental overland trade sufficiently efficient to become profitable.

From the first century bce onward, merchants from Sogdia and Bactria established networks linking the cities of northwestern China with the ports of the Indian Ocean via the Hindu Kush, likely under Kushan patronage.Footnote 7 In the fourth century, however, Sogdian merchants began to dominate trans-continental trade and, in a sense, to construct the Silk Road as a single Central Eurasian route with corresponding political infrastructure that would continue to function into the eighth century. The Sogdian merchants established a network whose nodal points extended from the major Chinese cities to the Indian Ocean and as far westward as the frontiers of Iran.Footnote 8 Based in Sogdian cities such as Samarkand and Paykend and organized in patrilineal houses, they transmitted silk, silver and other high-value commodities in overland caravans. Such capital-intensive enterprises enabled the Sogdians to act as bankers in Chinese cities and to facilitate long-distance financial transactions. The Sogdian network developed in tandem with the Hun and Turk empires that integrated Central Eurasia in increasingly extensive and stable political orders.Footnote 9 Nomadic political elites aimed to profit from the commerce passing through their territories, through both imposing levies on merchants and investing in their enterprises. The Hun and Turk imperial formations characteristic of Central Eurasia in late antiquity were designed, in part, to protect and support trans-continental commerce, and the Sogdian network of inter-personal mercantile relationships was transformed into urban infrastructures, as a belt of cities and smaller scale settlements with their own dynamic local agrarian economies came to extend from Sogdia into the Ili Valley towards the northwestern Chinese city of Turfan.Footnote 10 The security nomadic imperial structures afforded the Sogdian merchants minimized what practitioners of New Institutional Economics call transaction costs, the obstacles to efficient, low-risk, and profitable trade.Footnote 11 An alternative, more accurate term for the Silk Road would be “nomadic political-economic network”, a complex of political institutions nomadic elites established in order to facilitate trans-continental commerce.

The Iranian court was a beneficiary of political-economic developments occurring far beyond the frontiers of both its empire and its knowledge. The influx of high-value commodities into Iranian territory, whether destined for Middle Eastern or Mediterranean markets, gave the nascent imperial house of the Sasanians a source of revenue independent from the various aristocratic houses that maintained a high degree of political-economic autonomy over their vast patrimonial territories within the empire. The basic interpretive problem of Iranian history in late antiquity has been the emergence of an Iranian court significantly more powerful, in economic and infrastructural terms, than its Parthian predecessor that coexisted with almost equally powerful Parthian aristocratic houses.Footnote 12 Recent research has sharpened the terms of the debate. On the one hand, archaeological work has demonstrated the massive scale of the infrastructural projects the Iranian court undertook, at least in the middle and late Sasanian periods, notably in the very regions where aristocratic autonomy was most pronounced: Khurasan, the Caspian littoral, and Azerbaijan.Footnote 13 The court was able to invest in the development of infrastructures on a far grander scale than the Parthians. On the other hand, historical scholarship has documented the dependence of the court on aristocrats to fulfil its basic functions.Footnote 14 Representatives of the great houses, often of Parthian descent, possessed a virtual monopoly on the major fiscal, religious, military offices, while only expanding the extent of their autonomous patrimonial landholdings. The question then arises: whence the resources that enabled the Sasanians to become more powerful than the Parthians, if the aristocracy had preserved its powers and privileges? Zoroastrian institutions played a crucial role in the consolidation of the court's powers, but they required funds to establish and maintain. A purely cultural or religious answer to the question will prove inadequate.

The financial foundations of the early Iranian court need to be uncovered. The primary source of revenue was of course taxation on agricultural production, and commerce formed only a marginal sector within what was an overwhelmingly agrarian economy. In the absence of documentary evidence, one can do no more than make the general presumption that the early Sasanians will not have been more effective than the Parthians at extracting an agrarian surplus, as extensive aristocratic territories remained beyond the reach of the court. And yet already the first Sasanians engaged in capital-intensive infrastructural projects on a massive scale. Chief among these were the foundations of royal cities, known in the late Sasanian period as šahrestān, centrally planned urban centres named after their rulers and forming part of the royal domain. The first two Sasanians, Ardashir I and Shapur I, founded nearly a dozen such cities, often displacing pre-existing poleis that were refounded as royal centres. If the continued stability of aristocratic power makes the rapid expansion of revenues within the empire implausible, there are clear indications of the importance of extra-imperial sources, not least the foundation of šahrestān at – and often in place of – strategic emporia. To extract revenue from trans-Eurasian trade, the early Sasanians had to assert control over mercantile routes, establish infrastructures facilitating mercantile activity and its taxation, and cultivate a mercantile network operating in their service. Not only did each of these appear as overriding priorities for the earliest kings of kings, but the court also created centres of production for the reworking of raw materials into high-value commodities in demand across Eurasia. The package of institutions the Iranian court developed functioned in tandem with the Silk Road to foster the unprecedented circulation of goods between East and West Asia characteristic of late antiquity. In the process, the court secured an autonomous source of revenue that facilitated the formation of the infrastructurally robust imperial apparatus of the middle and late Sasanian periods, when the royal fisc gradually augmented its revenues from agrarian production throughout its territories as well as from the continued conduct of commerce.

The early Sasanians and trans-Eurasian corridors

The early Sasanians carefully consolidated their control of the Persian Gulf. Their native region of Fars encompassed its northern coastline, and a series of intermontane routes linked their power-bases of Istakhr, Ardashir-Xwarrah, and Bishapur with the sea. Immediately after conquering the highland core of Fars, Ardashir I turned to its coast, as far north as the southern shores of Khuzestan.Footnote 15 The Persian Gulf formed the nexus of the emerging Iranian Empire, facilitating communication and commerce between the regions of Mesopotamia, Khuzestan, and Fars where the early Sasanian court's powers were concentrated. Of the nine cities attributed to the first Sasanian, five were arrayed around the Iranian sea: Astarabad-Ardashir and Wahman-Ardashir replacing the polis of Spasinou Charax and its nearby entrepôt Forat in southern Mesopotamia; Ohrmazd-Ardashir in Khuzestan; Revardashir, the port of Fars; and another eponymous settlement, whose precise name remains unclear, in Bahrain.Footnote 16 At the same time, third-century rulers enthroned their most powerful dynasts as Mēšān-šāh in the southern Mesopotamian coastal region of Maishan (MP. Mēšān, Gr. Characene) and as Sagān-šāh in Iran's southeastern quadrant, on the northern shores of the Indian Ocean.Footnote 17 Subsequent Sasanians developed additional cities along these northern coasts. The famed medieval emporium of Siraf in southeastern Fars seems to have been established in the late fourth or early fifth century, while in the middle of the fifth century Daibul, near modern Karachi, extended the reach of the Iranian court as far as the frontiers of Guptid India.Footnote 18

The urban network the Sasanians created on the northern coast of the Persian Gulf gradually displaced Arabian mercantile centres. In the Hellenistic and Parthian periods, the eastern Arabian sites of Failaka, Mleiha, Thaj, al-Dur, and Qala'at al-Bahrain flourished as nodal points of a commercial network extending from Oman to Spasinou Charax.Footnote 19 Each of these sites, however, was either abandoned or drastically downsized in the early Sasanian period, as part of a general contraction of settlement in eastern Arabia.Footnote 20 Iranian settlements on the southwestern shores of the Gulf were modest in size and comparatively disparate, often military installations. The archaeology thus corresponds well with the literary evidence, which records military campaigns to discipline Arabian powers – notably under Ardashir I and Shapur II – with only rare references to settlements of political significance.Footnote 21 At the sites of Mleiha and al-Dur in the United Arab Emirates, the excavators have connected evidence of abandonment or destruction in the middle of the third century with historiographical accounts of the first two Sasanian interventions in the region.Footnote 22 The third century inaugurated an economic decline not only in eastern Arabia, but also in the central and southern regions of the peninsula that continued into the early seventh century.Footnote 23 The causes of such contraction were manifold. The loss of control of trans-regional trade was nevertheless a leading factor, especially in Eastern Arabia where settlements were precarious even at their peak. The early Sasanians, moreover, intervened in eastern Arabia at the very moment when its sites began to participate in long-distance trade by the Indian Ocean on a significant scale. Evidence for the importation of high-value commodities from India appears for the first time in the mid-second and early third centuries, immediately preceding the eclipse of the eastern Arabian sites, as Palmyrene merchants created an alternative to the traditional commercial route to the Mediterranean via the Red Sea.Footnote 24 Ardashir I rerouted the nascent network through the ports of the šahrestān under the control of the court.

Iranian mercantile ties with the wider Indian Ocean and, in particular, the emporia of the Malabar coast, continued to develop unbroken throughout late antiquity. In a comprehensive quantitative review of the ceramic evidence, Seth Priestman has demonstrated a remarkably continuous rate of long-distance exchange during the Sasanian period.Footnote 25 The ceramics, of course, do not easily divulge the contents they once conveyed. New commodities, such as Indian glass beads, were introduced during these four centuries, while others disappeared.Footnote 26 The total value of goods exchanged will therefore have varied, even if the total quantity of ceramic-based trade was consistent. The institutions the court installed from Daibul to Maishan securing the route to the Mediterranean via the Persian Gulf resulted in Iranian merchants gradually surpassing their Roman counterparts in the Indian Ocean.Footnote 27 The route through the Persian Gulf offered merchants a distinct advantage: their cargo would reach Antioch at least three months sooner than vessels docking at the Roman ports of the Red Sea.Footnote 28 Whenever the monsoon made the journey possible in the spring, merchants departing from the Persian Gulf would reach their Indian destinations faster than those based in the Red Sea. As a consequence, Iranian merchants were climatically and geographically positioned to outmanoeuvre the Romans. According to the famous report of Procopius, sixth-century Aksumite merchants – Roman intermediaries – could not access silk markets in India, as the Iranians purchased the available stock before they could arrive.Footnote 29 The emporia of South Arabia and the Red Sea yielded control of Indian Ocean networks to merchants based in the Persian Gulf in the fourth and fifth centuries, despite the sixth-century attempts of the Romans to compete with the Iranians via their Aksumite allies.Footnote 30 By the middle of the fourth century, the great bulk of commerce between the Mediterranean and the Indian Ocean passed through Iran.

Simultaneously with its interventions in the Persian Gulf, the Iranian court incorporated the western termini of the Silk Road. Ardashir I conquered not only Merv, but also Balkh, where the Sasanian is thought either to have subordinated and co-opted the previous Kushan regime or to have installed a new dynasty in its place, known in the literature as Kushano-Sasanian.Footnote 31 The conquest of the core territories of the Kushan kingdom gave the court control over the primary route for the traffic of East Asian silk and other eastern commodities to the Mediterranean in the first two centuries ce, via the passes of the Hindu Kush and the port known as Barbarikon in the lower Indus Valley.Footnote 32 Shapur I expressly asserted Iranian control over the intermontane route through the relief at Rag-e Bibi, located along one of the possible paths across the mountains between Bactria and Kapisa.Footnote 33 It is telling, moreover, that the position of the Sagān-šāh, the “king of the Sakas”, always a member of the Sasanian dynasty, played so important a role in early Sasanian politics, competing with the king of Armenia for the right to succeed the kings of kings.Footnote 34 In the two centuries preceding the Sasanian conquests, the king of “Scythia” – a Parthian sub-king – protected and regulated trade between Kushan territories and the Indian Ocean at Barbarikon.Footnote 35 Whether or not the authority of the Sagān-šāh extended to the Indus, the title indicated an aspiration to displace the Scytho-Parthian kingdom and its ports.

In the latter half of the fourth century, the Iranian court yielded Bactria, as well as even the pretence of ruling regions to the south of the Hindu Kush or in the Indus Valley, to the conquering Huns. But there is no indication of an interruption in trade with East Asia. To the contrary, the western conquests of the Huns in Central Asia appear to have intensified trans-Eurasian trade. Ruling from the Sogdian cities, the Kidarite and Hephthalite Huns – and later the Turks – sought to advance the interests of their Sogdian associates and to develop their network.Footnote 36 Crucial for the operation of the Sogdian Silk Road was access to Iranian cities, Merv in particular, or to northwest Indian ports. In either case, eastern commodities had to pass through Iranian intermediaries before reaching either Near Eastern or Mediterranean markets, for even if the Sogdians travelled via the Indus – often under Hun rule in the fifth and sixth centuries – Iranian merchants dominated the Indian Ocean.Footnote 37 As a consequence, the vast majority of the goods exchanged between East Asia, the Near East, and the Mediterranean – whether travelling westward or eastward – entered Iran and its šahrestān, that is, infrastructural arenas in which the court could impose taxes. At the Roman frontiers, the Iranian court consistently sought to restrict commerce in high-value commodities to emporia under its control, especially Nisibis, in order to guarantee that only its own dependent merchants trafficked wares to the Mediterranean.Footnote 38 In the late sixth century, the Turks sought to bypass Iran with an alternative route across the steppe to the Black Sea.Footnote 39 The attempt is suggestive of the profits that could be preserved through avoiding the customs houses of the Iranian court. It was nevertheless a temporary exception to the normal course of the Silk Road through Iran in late antiquity. The Roman court's attempts to circumvent Iranian control of its access to the Silk Road, whether under Diocletian or Justinian, were wholly unsuccessful, even if the latter's acquisition of the technology of silk production reduced Roman dependency on eastern sources.Footnote 40

Iranian mercantile networks

The Sasanians created corridors linking Roman markets with Central Asia and the Indian Ocean that were likely more efficient and more secure than preceding political arrangements, giving Iranian merchants a decisive advantage over their Roman counterparts. But the question then arises: who were “Iranian” merchants? Thus far, the term has been used in a general sense to designate merchants operating within the empire. It should also distinguish agents operating under Sasanian rule from their Parthian predecessors, for the rise of the Sasanians coincided with the disappearance of a group of merchants that had dominated the Near East and Indian Ocean in the preceding century: the Palmyrene network. In the first two centuries ce, the Parthian court had invited merchants from Palmyra to establish bases in Mesopotamia and the Persian Gulf, enabling them to create a network rivalling the route via the Red Sea that had largely supplied Roman demand for eastern goods in the first century ce.Footnote 41 The Parthians granted Palmyrene agents extensive political privileges, even installing them as their own governors, in an effort to facilitate trade and to enrich the fisc. Unlike the Greek merchants in Parthian poleis, the Palmyrenes were dependent on the kings for their privileges and therefore more likely to provide a share of their profits in customs to a court with minimal capacities for surveillance and coercion.Footnote 42 The comparatively short-lived heyday of Palmyra took place during these two centuries of Parthian–Palmyrene cooperation. The early Sasanians, however, immediately removed the Palmyrene merchants from their territories and dismantled their network. The Roman dependency conducted a war against Iran in the 260s, but failed to re-establish its mercantile communities in the East.Footnote 43 Indeed, the route to the Mediterranean from the Persian Gulf along the Euphrates went into desuetude until the sixth century.

In place of the Palmyrenes, an alternative network began to form in the third century that linked the Sasanian royal foundations with the northern Mesopotamian cities of Edessa and Nisibis via the Tigris rather than the Euphrates. Already in the early third century, the Christian author of the Acts of Thomas, writing in Syriac from an Edessene perspective, could describe the journey of a merchant to the Indus Valley as a mundane event.Footnote 44 Its tale of the conversion of a Parthian king at the hands of a merchant captured the combination of commerce and Christianity characteristic of the network of communities that took shape in late antiquity between Edessa and South India, via Mesopotamia, Khuzestan, and the Persian Gulf. It is revealing that, in the late Sasanian period, East Syrian Christians located their origins in trans-imperial mercantile communities.Footnote 45 The sixth- or early seventh-century History of Mar Mari recounted how the merchants of Khuzestan and Fars had been the first inhabitants of the Iranian world to convert to Christianity.Footnote 46 Although its projection of Christian origins into the first century was more hagiographical than historical, the account of the co-development of the religion and commerce retains plausibility.

A network of Christian merchants writing – and perhaps speaking – in Syriac, the Aramaic dialect of Edessa, and capable of crisscrossing the imperial frontiers emerged in the course of the third to fifth centuries. The early Sasanian urban foundations in Khuzestan and Fars, especially Revardashir, served as its nodal points, together with ancillary settlements in eastern Arabia. Significantly, the History of Mar Mari specified that “the merchants of Khuzestan reside in cities”, that is, the šahrestān of Ērān-Xwarrah-Shapur/Karka d-Ledan and Jundishapur/Beit Lapat.Footnote 47 They were directly subject to the authority of the court, and East Syrian agents frequently operated in its service. Christian merchants from Khuzestan, for example, supported the military campaigning in fifth-century Khurasan, facilitating transregional transfers on its behalf.Footnote 48 The Iranian court, moreover, used East Syrian bishops to regulate the mercantile activity in which their co-religionists played a leading role. There were doubtless other, largely undocumented, mercantile communities that took advantage of the opportunities the Sasanians afforded.Footnote 49 What the evidence for the East Syrian network demonstrates is that the court possessed at least one set of dependent agents capable of conducting trade along its continental and oceanic corridors.

The Iranian development of mercantile networks took place more or less in concert with the Hun and Turk development of the Sogdian network in late antiquity, at least between the late fourth and early seventh centuries. The number of political frontiers a commodity had to cross between Chang'an and Constantinople was reduced to three or four, and the interstitial Iranian, Hun, and/or Turk empires provided protection and patronage for their own mercantile networks, reducing the risks of long-distance trade. The demand for eastern goods in West Asia and western goods in East Asia, meanwhile, only increased, as silk garments became almost obligatory for Roman elites and Chinese elites adopted an ever-more exoticized habitus. The Iranian court stood at the very nexus of such trans-Eurasian trade, and merchants operating in its šahrestān possessed a virtual monopoly on the traffic in high-value commodities between Central, East, and South Asia and the Near East and Mediterranean. Iranian merchants were far more dependent on the court than their Greek or Palmyrene predecessors, who remained tied to cities with a high degree of political autonomy vis-à-vis the Parthian court. The East Syrian merchants were politically dependent on the kings of kings, even if they operated autonomously in the pursuit of their own profits.

The mutually beneficial relations between Iranian merchants and the court emerges from two historical episodes. In the first, Yazdgird I (r. 399–420) dispatched the bishop of Seleucia-Ctesiphon to investigate a case of piracy: the son of the governor of Fars, the ruler's brother, had reported that “bandits” (Ar. luṣūṣ) had stolen a ship load of “of goods and jewels brought from the lands of India and China”.Footnote 50 Comparative evidence with the early modern Persian Gulf that such violent competition, often acting on behalf of rival emporia, was characteristic of the pre-modern Indian Ocean.Footnote 51 What is important here is the effort of the court to intervene in such an interruption of trade, the surveillance and protection of commerce by a provincial governor, and the role of a bishop as a liaison with East Syrian merchants. The episode is suggestive of how the court sought to secure its trading routes and to protect its merchants through a combination of martial, administrative, and religious powers. The second episode underlines the investment, in the metaphorical and literal sense of the word, of the Iranian court in its mercantile networks. In 568–9, a Turk–Sogdian embassy appealed to the court of Husraw I to allow Sogdian merchants to sell silk within Iranian territories.Footnote 52 The king of kings responded definitively, with a dramatic flourish: he purchased the silk and burned the cargo before the eyes of the envoys, asserting the control of the court and its merchants over traffic in silk through the empire. He poisoned another Turk–Sogdian embassy, severing commercial ties with the qaghanate and provoking the Turks to develop the aforementioned alternative route across the steppe to the Black Sea. The westward transfer of the technology of silk production in the course of the fifth century emboldened Husraw I to attempt to dispense with Central Asian intermediaries altogether. What deserves to be emphasized is the court's active protection and promotion of its mercantile network.

The Iranian customs house

The involvement of the court in the conduct of commerce implies its stake in mercantile profits. The Iranian fisc, or “treasury” (Middle Persian: ganj), will have derived significant revenues from trade, even if taxation of agricultural production was always the primary source of state income.Footnote 53 In the first instance, the care exhibited for cargo likely reflected the interest of the court in its own investments. As Étienne de la Vaissière has argued for the Huns and Turks, political elites along the Silk Road provided not only protection, but also capital for trans-Eurasian merchants in exchange for a share of their profits.Footnote 54 Such investment remains merely a probability in the case of the Sasanians in the absence of evidence. A more conventional and common mechanism for an ancient state to profit from long-distance trade is the imposition of taxes on imports. Nicholas Purcell has recently underlined that the fiscal demands of ancient states were rarely more effectively asserted than at the ports which merchants were constrained to use.Footnote 55 Although neither the rate of the tax the Iranian court imposed on incoming cargoes nor the scale of importation have been documented, comparison with the Roman evidence suggests revenues from trade could have formed a significant percentage of the court's income, even rivalling revenues from agricultural production.

Estimates of Roman revenues from trade depend on the evidence of the Muziris papyrus, a record of the cargo of a second-century vessel. It documents the contents, value, and tax assessment of a shipment in transit from a port in Kerala to the Red Sea: nard, ivory, and garments worth 7 million sestertii, of which 25 per cent was yielded to the Roman authorities in the form of the tetarte tax.Footnote 56 At the apex of Roman trade in the Indian Ocean in the first centuries ce, conservative estimates suggest upward of 100 such vessels arrived in the ports of the Red Sea annually. The value of the Muziris cargo is generally considered to have been typical for individual shipments.Footnote 57 If 100 vessels a year passed through the offices of Roman assessors at the ports, the state would have collected roughly 175 million sestertii in revenues on an annual basis in the Red Sea alone.Footnote 58 At between 5 and 10 per cent of the state budget, taxation on trade represented a far more significant contribution to the Roman fisc than an earlier generation of scholarship could have imagined.Footnote 59

It is unlikely that the Sasanians derived less revenue from trade, for they controlled not only the rerouted corridor through the Indian Ocean, but also the overland routes from Central Asia and across Mesopotamia to the Roman Near East. The combination of these various routes of the Silk Road under Iranian control will have enabled the court to extract a share of mercantile profits at least comparable to what the Roman state arrogated at only a handful of its ports in the Red Sea. Even if Roman demand for eastern luxuries declined in the third and fourth centuries, the increased demand of Iranian aristocrats benefitting from demographic and economic growth throughout the Sasanian period would have compensated for a Mediterranean contraction. A plausible estimate places between 100 and 200 million sesterii in the Iranian treasury through taxation on trade, roughly equivalent to between 50 and 100 million drachms. Early Islamic historiographical accounts of the late Sasanian fiscal system reckon its revenues from the wealthiest province of the empire, Southern Mesopotamia, to be between 100 and 150 million drachms and an overall revenue of approximately 300–360 million drachms.Footnote 60 Taxes on trade could have amounted to as much as a third of the court's gross revenue in the late Sasanian period, when the court's mechanisms of agricultural taxation were at their most effective. For the early Sasanian court, revenues from trade would have been far more important as a source of capital, and the rise to dominance of an Iranian mercantile network operating in šahrestān helps to explain how the third- and fourth-century court was already able to undertake infrastructural projects on a far grander scale than its Parthian predecessor. In beginning to consolidate power around the Gulf, Ardashir I recognized the importance of trade as a source of fiscal revenue.

The royal cities: production and Eurasian markets

The early Sasanians did not simply seek passively to profit from merchants operating within their territories, but also actively to generate high-value commodities in urban production centres that were marketable along the Silk Road. The establishment of royal cities in Mesopotamia and Khuzestan was characteristic of early Sasanian rule, marking a departure from the Parthian period that witnessed only a handful of such foundations. The early Sasanians described the cities they usually named after themselves as their dastgird, a Middle Persian term for the rural aristocratic estate together with its dependent labourers.Footnote 61 The application of an institution of agrarian exploitation to urban centres highlights how the kings of kings conceived of their cities, namely as sources of labour enlisted on their behalf. The labourers in early Sasanian cities were often deportees from the Roman Empire. The Iranian court engaged in deportation on a Neo-Assyrian scale, beginning with Shapur I's marching of tens of thousands of Romans from Antioch and other Syrian and Anatolian cities eastward to Iran.Footnote 62 Shapur II similarly undertook mass deportations from Roman territory, as did the sixth-century conquerors Kawad and Husraw I. If initially scattered to sites across the empire, Shapur I and Shapur II concentrated deported population at their respective urban foundations in Khuzestan, Weh-Antiyōk-Šāpur (Better [than] Antioch Shapur, more commonly known as Jundishapur) and Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpur (known today as Ivan-e Kerkha).Footnote 63 The deported populations of Roman cities included some of the most highly skilled artisanal labourers in the ancient world, and the early Sasanians acknowledged the value of the human capital in their possession. The captives resettled in Khuzestan were organized in artisanal communities under the direct management of the court that specialized in metal-working and textile manufacturing. According to the early fifth-century Martyrdom of Pusai, Shapur II regrouped artisans from across the empire in a hierarchically organized “assembly” (Syriac: knušya) located in a “house of artisanry” (Syriac: beit ‘umanuta) alongside the royal palace at Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpur.Footnote 64

What they produced became leading commodities along the Silk Road. The most important industry at Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpur was the reworking of silk and wool into the high-quality, polychrome embroidered garments, often adorned with pearls, characteristic of Iranian elite textiles.Footnote 65 Khuzestan's proximity to pastoralist sources of wool and leather in the highlands, to silk and pearls via the Persian Gulf, and to mercantile networks made the region an ideal centre for the manufacture of textiles.Footnote 66 The highest office in Shapur II's artisanal organization was invested in the manager of brocade production, an East Syrian Christian named Pusai, who was the descendent of a third-century Roman captive. The origins of the large-scale production of silk brocade known from early Islamic Khuzestan therefore reside in the early Sasanian period. The influence of Iranian textiles on Roman, Central Asian, and Chinese silk garments suggests the production of brocade took place on a massive scale in Sasanian šahrestān, for export to extra-imperial markets as well as for distribution to Iranian elites. The court gave its aristocratic office-holders garments and headgear of an otherwise unattainable extravagance that distinguished aristocrats allied with the Sasanians from their lesser peers. Well documented in texts and art, no examples have been recovered archaeologically. The deserts of Egypt and Xinjiang have, however, preserved numerous silk textiles of an Iranian style that attest to the circulation of brocade produced at court far beyond the frontiers of the empire.

At Antinoe, several silk riding coats with roundel decorations corresponding with the garments Iranian aristocrats are known to have worn reveal that even middling Roman elites had begun to adopt an Iranian sartorial style by the sixth century at the latest.Footnote 67 Surviving textiles in Central Asia and China are largely post-Sasanian in date, c. 650–750 ce, but exhibit the widespread, almost overwhelming, influence of royalty-produced Iranian brocade on the silks Hun, Turk, and Chinese elites wore.Footnote 68 Art historical evidence for the use of Iranian garments in the East, at Kizil in Xinjiang, dates to the fifth century, although a preference for Western textiles appears as early as the third.Footnote 69 It is unclear whether preserved Iranian textiles were produced in the empire or were the imitations of Roman, Central Asian, or Chinese artisans.Footnote 70 What is clear is that the Iranian-style silk robe or caftan decorated with roundels became a signal feature of the elite habitus across Eurasia, part of what Matthew Canepa calls “aristocratic common cultures”.Footnote 71 However indirectly, the textile fragments of Egypt and Xinjiang attest to the widespread export of reworked silk from Iranian reduction centres, westward to the Mediterranean and northeastward into Central and East Asia.

Iranian metal-working similarly attracted consumers across Eurasia. The object most characteristic of Iranian art is the silver vessel, either a deep bowl with a medallion portrait in the early Sasanian period, or plate displaying a portrait in the middle and late Sasanian periods.Footnote 72 Iranian silver portrays the kings of kings and their courts, almost without exception, a subset of the vessels were produced according to identical standards from the same source of silver, while exhibiting stylistic development across the Sasanian period.Footnote 73 Such vessels are therefore regarded as productions of the court. Khuzestan was likely the primary centre of production, with its concentration of dependent, centrally organized artisans, extensive sources of silver, and access to mercantile networks.Footnote 74 Silver bowls and plates circulated primarily within an aristocratic gift economy, as disbursements from the court to officeholders alongside silk garments. But the cash value so often inscribed in Middle Persian on the vessels indicates their ready convertibility into drachms on the market.Footnote 75 It was the market in Iranian silver that brought plates and bowls to the Mediterranean and Central and East Asia.Footnote 76 The majority of examples were recovered from Central Eurasian contexts, ranging from Siberian excavations to Chinese tombs. The documented influence of Iranian silver on ceramics during the Sui and Tang dynasties attests to its widespread appeal – alongside Sogdian and other Central Asian productions – among Chinese elites.Footnote 77 The cross-pollination evident in Roman and Iranian silver production suggests, moreover, that vessels crisscrossed imperial frontiers, whether as gifts or commodities.Footnote 78

The Iranian court profoundly shaped the course and the content of commercial cargo along the Silk Road. No longer merely a corridor for East Asian silk and other high-value eastern goods, Iran became a site for the reworking of raw materials, most frequently at the court's centres of production, into commodities that became features of the elite habitus within the empire and beyond, as far as the Chinese and Roman capitals. The economic effects of such proto-industrial activities are impossible to measure, even comparatively. The production of signature commodities nevertheless enhanced the political-economic power of the court in two distinct, if interrelated, ways. On the one hand, the crafting of authorizing objects unique in style and splendour gave the court a means not simply of compensating its aristocrats, but of cultivating an inter-visual culture of aristocratic competition. Privileges and titles were communicated through kulāh, robes, and silver plates only the court could provide, which definitively surpassed the pre-existing repertoire of status-conferring objects in their ability to impress and to elicit assent.Footnote 79 Aristocrats in the service of the court obtained objects that both enriched and empowered them simultaneously, as the earliest allies of the Sasanians were quick to boast.Footnote 80

The diffusion of Iranian textiles and metalwork beyond the empire, on the other hand, suggests the production of a surplus for export. If garments of the highest quality were reserved as the distinctive adornments of the Iranian aristocracy, the same centres could also simultaneously have produced the reworked silk textiles exported to the Roman Empire. Procopius reported the importation of such textiles (esthēs) on so large a scale that price increases on the Iranian side attracted the attention of the court of Justinian.Footnote 81 The Roman evidence is also suggestive of the revenue of the profits to be gained from the sale of reworked silk textiles: on account of “fabulous profits”, the mid sixth-century Roman court encharged a class of fiscal administrators, the kommerkiarioi, with oversight of the exchange production of silk.Footnote 82 The interest of emperors presiding over a fiscal system far more extensive and intensive than Iran's in the income from the sale of silk textiles attests to its potential profitability. It is more difficult to assess the scale of trade in silver, but the export of vessels – perhaps the lesser quality examples often described as “provincial” productions – would have complemented revenues from textiles. It is important to stress, moreover, that these commodities were exported to Mediterranean as well as Central Asian and East Asian markets. At the most general level of observation the evidence permits, the sale of commodities produced in the proto-industrial centres of Iranian šahrestān could have rivalled taxes on trade as a source of fiscal revenue.

Conclusion

High-value commodities formed only a fraction of the goods exchanged in Iranian markets, in what remained a fundamentally agrarian economy. As Seth Priestman has shown on the basis of a comprehensive analysis of ceramics and the Persian Gulf, the vessels of long-distance trade comprised no more than 3–5 per cent of the containers exchanged at coastal centres.Footnote 83 Even along a trans-Eurasian corridor, local and regional exchanges far outpaced trans-oceanic traffic. But high-value commodities contributed more to the political economy than to the economy as a whole, for the court could tax them more straightforwardly than agrarian production, especially in light of the challenges of a continental political geography and an aristocratic political culture. The geography of Iran posed major disadvantages to empire formation, not least the difficulty of extracting revenues from disparate, highland territories and the high costs and slow pace of transferring agrarian produce overland to imperial centres. But its predicament also represented a potential advantage: located at the nexus of the largest Eurasian markets for high-value commodities, Rome and China, the court could derive profits from the exchange of goods whose value-to-weight ratio made long-distance, overland trade profitable.

The early Sasanians deliberately took advantage of the mercantile traffic that had increased markedly in the century preceding their rise. Originating in the highlands of Fars, they were keenly aware of the fortunes accruing to Palmyrene merchants and their Parthian patrons on the coastal periphery of the Sasanian heartland, and controlling trans-Eurasian corridors and rerouting them to the court's advantage were major priorities of early Sasanian military campaigns and infrastructural projects. Combining control of mercantile routes, the construction of šahrestān, the cultivation of dependent mercantile networks, and the creation of proto-industrial centres enabled the early Sasanian court to maximize the profitability of its geographical advantage. If in the third century the Silk Road chiefly exported raw silk from China to the Mediterranean via the Near East, in the sixth its merchants trafficked silk, silk and woollen textiles, silver vessels, and other commodities in multiple directions. While silk continued to be imported from Central and East Asia, reworked Iranian-style garments were exported from Iranian production centres eastward and westward, giving rise to a pan-Eurasian pattern of elite representation that prefigured the nineteenth-century rise of the business suit. It was the more complex, multidirectional, and multidimensional commerce the Iranian court helped to generate that sustained the expansion of the Silk Road, in infrastructural and economic terms, in late antiquity. It also sustained the expansion of an Iranian court that gradually augmented its infrastructural and economic powers across four centuries without undermining the economic foundations of the aristocracy. Its investments in irrigation, for instance, brought new lands and their cultivation under the purview of the fisc, while respecting – and even reinforcing – aristocratic territorial autonomy. The political economy underpinning Iranian imperialism depended as much on political, economic, and cultural developments far beyond the Near East as on internal preconditions. Even as the Roman and Chinese states at either end of the continent fractured, novel interstitial networks generated unprecedented interconnections and interdependencies among Eurasian cultures, economies, and political orders in late antiquity.

Footnotes

An earlier version of this article has appeared in Chinese translation in Wang Qingjia and Li Longguo, Duanlie yu zhuanxing: Diguo zhi hou de Ou Ya lishi yu shixue [断裂与转型:帝国之后的欧亚历史与史学] Shanghai: Shanghai guji chubanshe, 2017). The author would like to thank Frantz Grenet, an anonymous reviewer, and audiences at Peking University, the University of Chicago Center in Beijing, and Princeton University for their critical comments and suggestions.

2 Recent overviews do not connect long-distance commerce with internal political developments: Daryaee Reference Daryaee2003; Reference Daryaee2010.

3 Chin (Reference Chin2013) emphasizes how the political origins of a concept that rendered Central Eurasia a mere highway to legitimate early-twentieth-century colonial-capitalist projects remain inescapable. Alternative historiographical and geographical frameworks for understanding these regions, such as those of Élisée Reclus, deserve to be recovered.

4 For overviews of the burgeoning literature on nomadic political and economic complexity, see Honeychurch Reference Honeychurch2014 and Reference Honeychurch, Amitai and Biran2015; and Brosseder Reference Brosseder, Bemmann and Schmauder2015. The greater importance of local rather than trans-regional economies in Central Eurasian societies is a major theme of Hansen Reference Hansen2012.

5 Trombert (Reference Trombert and Drège2000: 113) dates the earliest production of silk at Khotan to the late second or third centuries ce. Turfan became a major production centre by the fourth century. For westward transmission, see Zuckerman Reference Zuckerman2013, re-dating the arrival of silk technology in the Roman Empire to the 530s.

7 De la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 34–41. For the debates on Kushan involvement in trade, see Mehendale Reference Mehendale1996. Oceanic routes via Southeast Asia also continued to supply Indian ports with silk throughout late antiquity, albeit on a smaller scale: Sen Reference Sen2011: 42–6.

8 De la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 30–70; Wertmann Reference Wertmann2015: 22–5, 135–7.

9 De la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 107–10, 199–215.

10 De la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 112–7.

11 See, e.g., Bresson Reference Bresson2015.

12 On the evolving infrastructural powers of the Iranian court, see Payne Reference Payne, Ando and Richardson2017.

16 Al-Ṭabarī, Ta'rīkh al-rusul wa al-mulūk, ed. de Goeje, 820, trans. Bosworth, 16; al-Dīnawārī, Al-akhbār al-ṭiwāl, ed. al-Mun‘im ‘Āmir, 45; Ḥamza al-Iṣfahānī, Ta'rīkh sinnī mulūk al-arḍ, ed. Maskūnī, 43; Gaube Reference Gaube1973: 32–8; Hansman Reference Hansman1967: 36–53; Whitehouse and Williamson Reference Whitehouse and Williamson1973: 35–43; Gyselen Reference Gyselen1989: 55–8, 60–61, 76–7. The city in Bahrain is the most problematic foundation to localize, or to substantiate: Potts Reference Potts1990: 233–4. Kervran Reference Kervran, Curiel and Gyselen1994: 330–332; Højlund Reference Højlund2006.

17 Inscription of Shapur I on the Ka‘ba-ye Zardusht, ed. and trans. Huyse, 47; Inscription of Paikuli, ed. and trans. Humbach and Skjaervø, 29–31, 45–7. The Sasanian period on the coast of Makran remains generally uncharted: Piacentini Fiorani Reference Piacentini Fiorani2014: 12.

18 Whitehouse and Williamson Reference Whitehouse and Williamson1973: 33–5. For Sasanian strata at Banbhore and its likely identification with Daibul, see Kervran Reference Kervran, Curiel and Gyselen1994: 337–8, Ghosh Reference Ghosh, Olijdam and Spoor2008, and Piacentini Fiorani Reference Piacentini Fiorani2014: 40. A network of ancillary sites extended southward along the coast from Siraf: Carter Reference Carter2005: 167, with reference to the unpublished dissertation of Williamson.

19 Kennet Reference Kennett2007: 103–4. The Seleucids and Parthians sought to penetrate Arabia in order to derive tax revenues from trade: Martinez-Sève Reference Martinez-Sève, Feyer and Graslin2014: 374–6.

20 Kennet Reference Kennett2007: 104–6.

24 Mouton and Schiettecatte Reference Mouton and Schiettecatte2014: 109. Potts (Reference Potts and Alcock1997: 94–7) spoke of a “Characene corridor” through late Parthian eastern Arabia, in which Whitehouse (Reference Whitehouse2000: 122) locates the site of al-Dur.

25 Priestman Reference Priestman2013: 399, 415.

26 For the appearance and subsequent popularity of Indian glass beads, see Kennet Reference Kennett and Schiettecatte2009: 154.

29 Procopius, Bella, ed. and trans. Dewing, 192–3.

30 Sedov Reference Sedov1992: 127–8; Schiettecatte Reference Schiettecatte2008; Sidebotham Reference Sidebotham2011: 279–82. Cobb (Reference Cobb2015: 368, 390) suggests Romans had begun to withdraw from direct participation in the Indian Ocean already in the second century. Power (Reference Power2012: 61–86) argues for continuity in the Red Sea, demonstrating trade continued, albeit on an attenuated scale. The archaeological evidence for the reorientation of networks remains incontrovertible.

31 Grenet Reference Grenet2005: 129–30; Schindel Reference Schindel2015: 147–55; Rezakhani Reference Rezakhani2017: 72–86.

32 The site remains unidentified (Bukharin Reference Bukharin2007: 134).

33 Grenet Reference Grenet2005: 131–2.

34 See Weber and Wiesehöfer Reference Weber, Wiesehöfer, Börm and Wiesehöfer2010 for competition between these two Sasanian sub-kings in the third century.

35 Periplus of the Erythraean Sea, ed. and trans. Bukharin, 40 and 56; Seland Reference Seland2010: 50–6.

36 For the urban centres of Hun and Turk rule, see Grenet Reference Grenet and Alram2010 and Stark Reference Stark2008: 210–28.

37 For possible Sogdian competition with Iranian merchants in the Indian Ocean, see Grenet Reference Grenet1996.

38 See Winter (Reference Winter1987) for an unsurpassed survey of Roman–Iranian agreements on trade.

39 Menander the Guardsman, History, ed. and trans. Blockley, 114–7; de la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 234–7. For evidence of a Sogdian colony on the Black Sea, see de la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière and Zuckerman2006.

40 Winter Reference Winter1987: 49–50; Brandes Reference Brandes2002: 277; Zuckerman, Reference Zuckerman2013: 335–6.

42 On competition with the poleis, see Gregoratti Reference Gregoratti2012.

43 Their caravans disappeared from the east by the 260s: Millar Reference Millar1998: 131.

44 Acts of Thomas, ed. Wright, 173, and trans. Klijn, 20.

45 On the role of merchants in the diffusion of Christianity, see Jullien and Jullien Reference Jullien and Jullien2001; and Harrak Reference Harrak2002.

46 History of Mar Mari, ed. and trans. Harrak, 70–75.

47 History of Mar Mari, ed. and trans. Harrak, 74–5.

48 Łazar P‘arpec‘i, Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’, ed. Ter-Mkrtchean, 94, and trans. Thomson, 143.

49 See Pourshariati (Reference Pourshariati and Sarshar2014) for an attempt to connect the historical geography of Jewish communities with mercantile routes.

50 Chronicle of Seert, v. 1.2, ed. and trans. Scher, 324.

51 Margariti Reference Margariti2008: 573.

52 Menander the Guardsman, History, ed. and trans. Blockley, 111–5; de la Vaissière Reference de la Vaissière2005: 230–32.

53 On the treasury as an abstract administrative institution, see Gyselen Reference Daryaee2003.

55 Purcell Reference Purcell and Harris2005. Bresson (Reference Bresson, Günther and Grieb2012) demonstrates how pervasive and onerous such levies typically were in the pre-modern Mediterranean, on the basis of Ptolemaic papyrological evidence.

57 Sidebotham (Reference Sidebotham2011: 218) argues for far higher average values of incoming cargo, but see the more measured evaluation of Scheidel (Reference Scheidel and Scheidel2015: 160–1).

58 For the imposition of the tetarte at Palmyra, see De Romanis Reference de Romanis, de Romanis and Sorda2006: 62–7.

61 Inscription of Shapur I on the Ka‘ba-ye Zardusht, ed. and trans. Huyse, 42.

62 Inscription of Shapur I on the Ka‘ba-ye Zardusht, ed. and trans. Huyse, 43; Morony Reference Morony and Carile2004b. On the assimilation and acculturation of Christian Roman captives, see Payne Reference Payne2015: 64–78 and Smith Reference Smith2016: 135–45.

63 Schwaigert Reference Schwaigert1989: 23–33 108–11.

64 Martyrdom of Pusai, ed. Bedjan, 209–10. The list of signatories at a synod in Jundishapur in 544 included the heads of tin-, gold-, and silver-smiths: Synodicon Orientale, ed. and trans. Chabot, 80 and 332. Pigulevskaya Reference Pigulevskaya1963: 159–69, remains the most complete discussion of urban artisanal production.

65 Yatsenko Reference Yatsenko2006: 215.

66 The extensive development of so-called “hollow ways” around Sasanian settlements in Khuzestan indicates the regular influx of pastoralists to urban centres together with their wool, an indirect testament to the importance of textile production in the region: Casana Reference Casana2013: 263–5. For the exploitation of pearl resources in the Gulf, see Carter Reference Carter2005: 166–8. Gyselen and Gasche (Reference Gyselen and Gasche1994: 26) emphasize Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpur's access to mercantile ports.

67 For the carbon-dating of the textiles, see De Moor et al. Reference De Moor, Van Strydonck, Verhecken-Lammens, Fluck and Vogelsang-Eastwood2004: 184.

68 Verhecken-Lammens et al. Reference Verhecken-Lammens, De Moor and Overlaet2006. Iranian textiles preserved in European collections are also almost exclusively post-Sasanian (Overlaet Reference Overlaet and De Jonghe1999).

69 Gasparini Reference Gasparini2014: 145. Trombert (Reference Trombert and Drège2000: 115) describes a report in the Weishu on the arrival of “Persian” textiles at the court of the Northern Wei.

70 Calament (Reference Calament, Fluck and Vogelsang-Eastwood2004: 63–4) argues that the Antinoe garments were most likely imported from Iran. For the dynamism of Central Asian textile production, see Gasparini Reference Gasparini2014.

72 Harper Reference Harper2006: 78.

73 Grabar Reference Grabar and Sawyer1967: 45–6; Harper and Meyers Reference Harper and Meyers1981: 124–5, 157; Harper Reference Harper and Otavsky1998: 217; Harper Reference Harper2006: 82.

74 The silver was largely sourced from the Zagros, where a number of mines have been surveyed (Harper and Meyers Reference Harper and Meyers1981: 146). The mints of Khuzestan emitted high volumes of silver coinage throughout the Sasanian period (Daryaee Reference Daryaee, Gyselen and Szuppe1999: 140–1; Howard-Johnston Reference Howard-Johnston2014: 159–60). The list of signatories at a synod in Jundishapur in 544 included the heads of tin-, gold-, and silver-smiths: Synodicon Orientale, ed. and trans. Chabot, 80 and 332.

76 As was the case with silk textiles, however, many vessels of Iranian style were produced in Central Asia, where Sogdian artisans produced distinctive forms of silverplate while engaging with Iranian models (Marshak Reference Marshak1971: 38–41).

79 For the granting of robes (Armenian patmučan, Middle Persian paymōzan) together with offices, and their role in the articulation of aristocratic hierarchies, see, e.g., Buzandaran Patmut‘iwnk’, ed. Patkanean, 49, 207, and trans. Garsoïan, 99, 221–2, Kārnāmag ī Ardašīr, ed. and trans. Grenet, 58–9, Letter of Tansar, ed. Minovi, 19, and trans. Boyce, 44. Grabar (Reference Grabar and Sawyer1967: 50) suggested the specific crowns of hunters accompanying the kings of kings on silver plates corresponded with the personal crowns of the aristocrats to whom they were granted.

80 Inscriptions of Kirdir, ed. and trans. Gignoux, 56 and 68.

81 Procopius, Anecdota, ed. and trans. Dewing, 296–7.

82 Brandes Reference Brandes2002: 274–5, 281, 394–5; Zuckerman Reference Zuckerman2013: 336, 341–4.

83 Priestman Reference Priestman2013: 404–6.

References

Bibliography

Acts of Thomas, ed. Wright, William, Apocryphal Acts of the Apostles, v. I: The Syriac Texts (London: Williams and Norgate, 1871), and trans. Klijn, Albertus F.J., The Acts of Thomas: Introduction, Text, and Commentary (Leiden: Brill, 2003).Google Scholar
Buzandaran Patmut‘iwnk’ (ed. Patkanean, Kerovbe). P‘awstosi Buzandac‘woy Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’. St. Petersburg: Akad., 1883; trans. Nina Garsoïan, The Epic Histories (Buzandaran Patmut‘iwnk’) (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1989).Google Scholar
Chronicle of Seert, ed. and trans. Scher, Addaï, Histoire nestorienne (Chronique de Séert), v. 1–2 (Paris: Firmin-Didot, 1908–19).Google Scholar
al-Dīnawarī, Kitāb al-akhbār al-ṭiwāl, ed. ʿAmir, ʿAbd al-Munʿim (Cairo: Al-Idārah al-ʿĀmmah lil-Thaqāfah, 1960).Google Scholar
Ḥamza al-Iṣfahānī, Ta'rīkh sinnī mulūk al-arḍ, ed. Ya‘qūb Maskūnī, Yūsuf (Beirut: Dār Maktaba, 1961).Google Scholar
History of Mar Mari, ed. and trans. Harrak, Amir, The Acts of Mār Māri the Apostle (Atlanta: Society of Biblical Literature, 2005).Google Scholar
Inscriptions of Kirdir, ed. and trans. Gignoux, Philippe, Les quatre inscriptions du mage Kirdir: Textes et concordances (Paris: Association pour l'Avancement des Études Iraniennes, 1991).Google Scholar
Inscription of Paikuli, ed. and trans. Humbach, H. and Skjaervø, Prods O., The Sasanian Inscription of Paikuli, Part 3.1: Restored Text and Translation (Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1983).Google Scholar
Inscription of Shapur I on the Ka‘ba-ye Zardusht, ed. and trans. Huyse, Philip, Die dreisprachige Inschrift Šābuhrs I. an der Ka‘aba-i Zardušt (ŠKZ) (London: Corpus Inscriptionum Iranicarum, 1999).Google Scholar
Kārnāmag ī Ardašīr, ed. and trans. Grenet, Frantz, La geste d'Ardashir fils de Pâbag (Die: Éditions A Die, 2003).Google Scholar
Łazar P‘arpec‘i, Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’, ed. Ter-Mkrtchean, G., Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’ (Tbilisi: Tparan Ōr.N. Aghaneani, 1904), and trans. Robert W. Thomson, The History of Łazar P‘arpec‘i (Atlanta: Scholars Press, 1991).Google Scholar
Letter of Tansar, ed. Minovi, Mojtaba, Nāmah-e Tansar bih Jushnasf (Tehran: Matbaʿah-i Majlis, 1932), and trans. Boyce, Mary, The Letter of Tansar (Rome: Instituto Italiano per il Media ed Estremo Oriente, 1968).Google Scholar
Martyrdom of Pusai, ed. Bedjan, Paul, Acta martyrum et sanctorum II (Leipzig and Paris: Otto Harrassowitz, 1897): 208232.Google Scholar
Menander the Guardsman, Historia, ed. and trans. Blockley, R.C., The History of Menander the Guardsman (Liverpool: Liverpool University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
Periplus of the Erythrean Sea, ed. and trans. Bukharin, M.D., Peripl Eritreiskovo Morya: Tekst, Perevod, Kommentarii, Issledovaniya (St. Petersburg: Aleteiya, 2007).Google Scholar
Procopius, Anecdota, ed. and trans. Dewing, H.B., The Anecdota or Secret History (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1935).Google Scholar
Procopius, Bella, ed. and trans. Dewing, H.B., History of the Wars, v. I (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1914).Google Scholar
Synodicon Orientale, ed. and trans. Chabot, J.B., Synodicon Orientale, ou recueil de synodes nestoriens (Paris: Imprimerie nationale, 1902).Google Scholar
al-Ṭabarī, Ta'rikh al-rusul wa al-mulūk, ed. De Goeje, M., Annales, quos scripsit Abu Djafar Mohammed ibn Djarir at-Tabard, v. I (Leiden: Brill, 1964–5), and trans. Bosworth, C.E., The History of al-Ṭabarī, vol. V: The Sāsānids, the Byzantines, the Lakhmids, and Yemen (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1999).Google Scholar
Alizadeh, Karim. 2014. “Borderland projects of the Sasanian empire: intersection of domestic and foreign policies”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 93115.Google Scholar
Banaji, Jairus. 2006. “Precious metal coinages and monetary expansion in Late Antiquity”, in de Romanis, Federico and Sorda, Sara (eds), Dal Denarius al Dinar: L'Orient e la Moneta Romana. Rome: Istituto Italiano di Numismatica, 265303.Google Scholar
Brandes, Wolfra. 2002. Finanzverwaltung in Krisenzeiten: Untersuchungen zur byzantinischen Administration im 6.–9. Jahrhundert. Frankfurt: Löwenklau, 2002.Google Scholar
Bresson, Alain. 2015. The Making of the Ancient Greek Economy: Institutions, Markets, and Growth in the City-States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bresson, Alain. 2012. “Wine, oil and delicacies at the Pelousian customs”, in Günther, Linda-Marie and Grieb, Volker (eds), Das imperiale Rom und der hellenistische Osten: Festschrift für Jürgen Deininger zum 75. Geburtstag. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 6988.Google Scholar
Brosseder, Ursula B. 2015. “A study on the complexity and dynamics of interaction and exchange in late Iron Age Eurasia”, in Bemmann, Jan and Schmauder, Michael (eds), Complexity of Interaction along the Eurasian Steppe Zone in the First Millennium CE. Bonn: Vor- und Frühgeschichtliche Archäologie, 199332.Google Scholar
Brunner, Christopher J. 1974. “Middle Persian inscriptions on Sasanian silverware”, Metropolitan Museum Journal 9, 109–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bukharin, M.D. 2007. Peripl Eritreiskovo Morya: Tekst, Perevod, Kommentarii, Issledovaniya. St Petersburg: Aleteiya.Google Scholar
Calament, Florence. 2004. “L'apport historique des découvertes d'Antinoé au costume dit de ‘cavalier sassanide’”, in Fluck, Cäcilia and Vogelsang-Eastwood, Gillian (eds), Riding Costume in Egypt: Origin and Appearance. Leiden: Brill, 3772.Google Scholar
Canepa, Matthew. 2010. “Distant displays of power: understanding cross-cultural interaction among the elites of Rome, Sasanian Iran, and Sui-Tang China”, Ars Orientalis 38, 121–54.Google Scholar
Canepa, Matthew. 2014. “Textiles and elite tastes between the Mediterranean, Iran and Asia at the end of antiquity”, in Nosch, Marie Louise, Feng, Zhao, and Varadarajan, Lotika (eds), Global Textile Encounters. Oxford: Oxbow Books, 114.Google Scholar
Carter, Robert. 2005. “The history and prehistory of pearling in the Persian Gulf”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 48, 139209.Google Scholar
Casana, Jesse. 2013. “Radial route systems and agro-pastoral strategies in the Fertile Crescent: new discoveries from western Syria and southwestern Iran”, Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 32, 257–73.Google Scholar
Chin, Tamara. 2013. “The invention of the Silk Road, 1877”, Critical Inquiry 40, 194219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cobb, Matthew. 2015. “The chronology of Roman trade in the Indian Ocean from Augustus to early third century CE”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 58, 362418.Google Scholar
Cuny, Julien and Mouton, Michel. 2009. “La transition vers la période sassanide dans la péninsule d'Oman: Chronologie et modes de peuplement”, in Schiettecatte, Jérémie (ed.), L'Arabie à la veille de l'Islam: Bilan clinique. Paris: De Boccard, 91133.Google Scholar
Cutler, Anthony. 2005. “Silver across the Euphrates: forms of exchange between Sasanian Persia and the late Roman empire”, Mitteilungen zur spätantiken Archäologie und Byzantinischen Kunstgeschichte 4, 937.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 1999. “Sources for the economic history of late Sāsānian Fārs”, in Gyselen, Rika and Szuppe, Maria (eds), Matériaux pour l'histoire économique du monde iranien. Paris: Association pour l'Avancement des Études Iraniennes, 131–48.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 2003. “The Persian Gulf trade in late antiquity”, Journal of World History 14, 2003, 116.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 2010. “Bazaars, merchants, and trade in late antique Iran”, Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East 30, 41409.Google Scholar
De Moor, A., Van Strydonck, M. and Verhecken-Lammens, C.. 2004. “Radiocarbon dating of two Sasanian coats and three post-Sasanian tapestries”, in Fluck, Cäcilia and Vogelsang-Eastwood, Gillian (eds), Riding Costume in Egypt: Origin and Appearance. Leiden: Brill, 181–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gasparini, Mariachiara. 2014. “A mathematical expression of art: Sino-Iranian and Uighur textile interaction and the Turfan textile collection in Berlin”, Trans-Cultural Studies 1, 134–63.Google Scholar
Gaube, Heinz. 1973. Die südpersische Provinz Arraĝān/Kūh-Gīlūyeh von der arabischen Eroberung bis zur Safavidenzeit. Vienna: Verlag der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften.Google Scholar
Ghosh, Suchandra. 2008. “The western coast of India and the Gulf: maritime trade during the 3rd to 7th centuries A.D.”, in Olijdam, Eric and Spoor, Richard H. (eds), Intercultural Relations between South and Southwest Asia: Studies in Commemoration of E.C.L. During Caspers. Oxford: Archaeopress, 367–71.Google Scholar
Grabar, Oleg. 1967. “An introduction to the art of Sasanian silver”, in Sawyer, Charles (ed.), Sasanian Silver: Late Antique and Early Medieval Arts of Luxury from Iran. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 1996. “Les marchands sogdiens dans les Mers du Sud à l'époque préislamique”, Cahiers d'Asie centrale 1–2, 6584.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 2005. “Découverte d'un relief sassanide dans le nord de l'Afghanistan”, Compte Rendus de l'Académie des Inscriptions et Belle-Lettres, 115–35.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 2010. “A view from Samarkand: the Chionite and Kidarite periods in the archaeology of Sogdians (fourth to fifth centuries A.D.)”, in Alram, Michael et al. (eds), Coins, Art and Chronology, vol. 2: The First Millennium c.e. in the Indo-Iranian Borderlands. Vienna: Verlag der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 267–81.Google Scholar
Gregoratti, Leonardo. 2011. “A Parthian port on the Persian Gulf: Characene and its trade”, Anabasis: Studia Classica et Orientalia 2, 209–29.Google Scholar
Gregoratti, Leonardo. 2012. “The importance of the mint of Seleucia on the Tigris for Arsacid history: Artabanus and the Greek Parthian cities”, Mesopotamia 47, 129–36.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika. 1989. La géographie administrative de l'empire sassanide: Les témoignages, sigillographiques. Paris: Groupe pour l’Étude de la Civilisation du Moyen-Orient.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika. 2003. “Dīwān et ‘trésorie’ Sassanides: premières attestations sigillographiques”, Studia Iranica 32, 123–6.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika and Gasche, Hermann. 1994. “Suse et Ivān-e Kerkha, capitale provinciale d’Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpūr”, Studia Iranica 23, 1935.Google Scholar
Hansen, Valerie. 2012. The Silk Road: A New History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hansman, John. 1967. “Charax and the Karkheh”, Iranica Antiqua 7, 2158.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence. 1998. “Sasanian and early Islamic silver and bronze vessels”, in Otavsky, Karl (ed.), Entlang der Seidenstraße: Frühmittelalterliche Kunst zwischen Persien und China in der Abegg-Stiftung. Riggisberg: Abegg-Stiftung, 215–38.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence. 2006. In Search of the Cultural Identity: Monuments and Artifacts of the Sasanian Near East, 3rd to 7th Century A.D. New York: Bibliotheca Persica.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence and Meyers, Pieter. 1981. Silver Vessels of the Sasanian Period, v. I: Royal Imagery. New York: Metropolitan Museum of Art.Google Scholar
Harrak, Amir. 2002. “Trade routes and the Christianization of the Near East”, Journal of the Canadian Society for Syriac Studies 2, 4661.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Højlund, Flemming. 2006. “The dating of the coastal fortress at Qala'at al-Bahrain: Sasanian or Islamic?”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 17, 238–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Honeychurch, William. 2014. “Alternative complexities: the archaeology of pastoral nomadic states”, Journal of Archaeological Research 22, 277326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Honeychurch, William. 2015. “From steppe roads to Silk Roads: Inner Asian nomads and early interregional exchange”, in Amitai, Reuven and Biran, Michal (eds), Nomads as Agents of Cultural Change: The Mongols and their Eurasian Predecessors. Honolulu: University of Hawai‘i Press, 5087.Google Scholar
Howard-Johnston, James. 2014. “The Sasanian state: the evidence of coinage and military construction”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 144–81.Google Scholar
Jullien, Christelle and Jullien, Florence. 2001. “Porteurs de salut: Apôtre et marchand dans l'empire iranien”, Parole de l'Orient 26, 127–43.Google Scholar
Kennett, Derek. 2009. “Transformations in late Sasanian and early Islamic eastern Arabia: the evidence from Kush”, in Schiettecatte, Jérémie (ed.), L'Arabie à la veille de l'Islam: bilan clinique. Paris: De Boccard, 135–61.Google Scholar
Kennett, Derek. 2007. “The decline of eastern Arabia in the Sasanian period”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 18, 86122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kervran, Monique. 1994. “Fortress, entrepôts et commerce: une histoire à suivre depuis les rois sassanides jusqu'aux princes d'Ormuz”, in Curiel, Raul and Gyselen, Rika (eds), Itinéraires d'Orient: Hommages à Claude Cahen. Bures-sur-Yvette: Groupe pour l’Étude de la Civilisation du Moyen-Orient.Google Scholar
Knauer, Elfriede R. 2001. “Le vêtement des nomades eurasiatiques et sa postérité”, Comptes-Rendus de l'Académie des Inscriptions & Belles-Lettres 143, 1141–87.Google Scholar
Margariti, Roxani Eleni. 2008. “Mercantile networks, port cities, and ‘pirate’ states: conflict and competition in the Indian Ocean world trade before the sixteenth century”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 51, 543–77.Google Scholar
Marshak, Boris. 1971. Sogdiiskoe Serebro: Ocherki po Vostochnoi Torevtike. Moscow: Nauka.Google Scholar
Martinez-Sève, Laurianne. 2014. “Antiochos IV en Susiane, dans le Golfe Persique et en Élymaïde”, in Feyer, C. and Graslin, L. (ed.), Le projet politique d'Antiochos IV. Nancy: ADRA, 363–93.Google Scholar
Mehendale, Sanjyot. 1996. “Begram: along ancient Central Asian and Indian trade routes”, Cahiers d'Asie centrale 1–2, 4764.Google Scholar
Millar, Fergus. 1998. “Caravan cities: the Roman Near East and long-distance trade by land”, Bulletin of the Institute of Classical Studies 42, 119–37.Google Scholar
Morony, Michael G. 2004a. “Economic boundaries? Late antiquity and early Islam”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 47, 166–94.Google Scholar
Morony, Michael G. 2004b. “Population transfers between Sasanian Iran and the Byzantine Empire”, in Carile, Antonio (ed.), La Persia e Bisanzio. Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 161–79.Google Scholar
Mouton, Michel and Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2014. In the Desert Margins: The Settlement Process in Ancient South and East Arabia. Rome: «L'Erma» di Bretschneider.Google Scholar
Overlaet, Bruno. 1999. “Dating and iconographical commentary: Sassanian and post-Sassanian tapestries”, in De Jonghe, Daniël et al. (eds), Ancient Tapestries of the R. Pfister Collection in the Vatican Library. Vatican City: Biblioteca apostolica Vaticana, 121–75.Google Scholar
Payne, Richard E. 2015. A State of Mixture: Christians, Zoroastrians, and Iranian Political Culture in Late Antiquity. Oakland: University of California Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, Richard E. 2017. “Territorializing Iran in Late Antiquity: autocracy, aristocracy, and the infrastructure of empire”, in Ando, Clifford and Richardson, Seth (eds), Ancient States and Infrastructural Power: Europe, Asia, and America. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 179217.Google Scholar
Piacentini Fiorani, Valeria. 1985. “Ardashīr ī Pāpakān and the wars against the Arabs: working hypothesis on the Sasanian hold of the Gulf”, Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 15, 5777.Google Scholar
Piacentini Fiorani, Valeria. 2014. Beyond Ibn Hawqal's Bahr al-Fārs, 10th–13th Centuries AD: Sindh and the Kīj-u-Makrān Region, Hinge of International Network of Religious, Political, Institutional and Economic Affairs. Oxford: Archaeopress.Google Scholar
Pigulevskaya, Nina V. 1963. Les villes de l’état iranien aux époques parthe et sassanide: contribution à l'histoire sociale de la Basse Antiquité. Paris: Mouton.Google Scholar
Potts, Daniel T. 1990. The Arabian Gulf in Antiquity, v. II: From Alexander the Great to the Coming of Islam. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Potts, Daniel T. 1997. “The Roman relationship with the Persicus Sinus from the rise of Spasinou Charax (127 BC) to the reign of Shapur II (AD 309–379)”, in Alcock, Susan E. (ed.), The Early Roman Empire in the East. Oxford: Oxbow, 89107.Google Scholar
Pourshariati, Parvaneh. 2008. Decline and Fall of the Sasanian Empire: The Sasanian–Parthian Confederacy and the Arab Conquest of Iran. London: I.B. Tauris.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pourshariati, Parvaneh. 2014. “New vistas on the history of Iranian Jewry in late antiquity, part I: patterns of Jewish settlement in Iran”, in Sarshar, Houman (ed.), The Jews of Iran: The History, Religion, and Culture of a Community in the Islamic World. London: I.B. Tauris, 132.Google Scholar
Power, Timothy. 2012. The Red Sea from Byzantium to the Caliphate AD 500–1000. Cairo: The American University in Cairo Press.Google Scholar
Priestman, Seth. 2013. “A quantitative archaeological analysis of ceramic exchange in the Persian Gulf and the western Indian Ocean”. PhD thesis, University of Southampton.Google Scholar
Purcell, Nicholas. 2005. “The ancient Mediterranean: the view from the customs-house”, in Harris, William V. (ed.), Rethinking the Mediterranean. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005, 200–32.Google Scholar
Rante, Rocco and Collinet, Annabelle. 2013. Nishapur Revisited: Stratigraphy and Ceramics of the Qohandez. Oxford: Oxbow.Google Scholar
Rawson, Jessica. 1991. “Central Asian silver and its influence on Chinese ceramics”, Bulletin of the Asia Institute 5, 139–51.Google Scholar
Rezakhani, Khodadad. 2017. Reorienting the Sasanians: East Iran in Late Antiquity. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
de Romanis, Federico. 2006. “Aurei after the trade: western taxes and eastern gifts”, in de Romanis, Federico and Sorda, Sara (eds), Dal Denarius al Dinar: L'Orient e la Moneta Romana. Rome: Istituto Italiano di Numismatica, 5582.Google Scholar
Rubin, Zeev. 2000. “The Sassanid monarchy”, in Cameron, Averil et al. (eds), Cambridge Ancient History, vol. 14. Late Antiquity: Empire and Successors, a.d. 425–600. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 638–61.Google Scholar
Rubin, Zeev. 2008. “Islamic traditions on the Sasanian conquest of the Himyarite realm”, Der Islam 84, 185–99.Google Scholar
Sauer, Eberhard, Rekavandi, Hamid Omrani, Wilkinson, Tony J., Nokandeh, Jebrael et al. 2013. Persia's Imperial Power in Late Antiquity: The Great Wall of Gorgān and Frontier Landscapes of Sasanian Iran. Oxford: Oxbow Books.Google Scholar
Scheidel, Walter. 2015. “State revenue and expenditure in the Han and Roman empires”, in Scheidel, Walter (ed.), State Power in Ancient China and Rome. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 150–80.Google Scholar
Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2008. “Ports et commerce maritime dans l'Arabie du Sud préislamique”, Chroniques yéménites 15, 6590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2013. “À la veille de l'Islam: effondrement ou transformation du monde antique?”, in Robin, Christian and Schiettecatte, Jérémie (eds), Les préludes de l'Islam: Ruptures et continuités des civilisations du Proche-Orient, de l'Afrique orientale, de l'Arabie et de l'Inde à la veille de l'Islam. Paris: De Boccard, 936.Google Scholar
Schindel, Nikolaus. 2015. “Sasaniden, Kushan, Kushano-Sasaniden: Münzprägung, Propaganda und Identitäten zwischen Westiran und Ostiran”, Haller Münzblätter 8, 137–67.Google Scholar
Schwaigert, Wolfgang. 1989. Das Christentum in Hūzistān in Rahmen der frühen Kirchengeschichte Persiens bis zur Synode von Seleukia-Ktesiphon im Jahre 410. Marburg: Görich & Weiershäuser.Google Scholar
Sedov, A.V. 1992. “New archaeological and epigraphical material from Qana (South Arabia)”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 3, 110–37.Google Scholar
Seland, Eivind Heldaas. 2010. Ports and Political Power in the Periplus: Complex Societies and Maritime Trade on the Indian Ocean in the First Century AD. Oxford: Archaeopress.Google Scholar
Seland, Eivind Heldaas. 2011. “The Persian Gulf or the Red Sea? Two axes in ancient Indian Ocean trade, where to go and why”, World Archaeology 43, 398–49.Google Scholar
Sen, Tansen. 2011. “Maritime interactions between China and India: coastal India and the ascendancy of Chinese maritime power in the Indian Ocean”, Journal of Central Eurasian Studies 2, 4182.Google Scholar
Sidebotham, Steven E. 2011. Berenike and the Ancient Maritime Spice Route. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Simpson, St John. 2014. “Merv, an archaeological case study from the northeastern frontier of the Sasanian empire”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 116–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Kyle. 2016. Constantine and the Captive Christians of Persia: Martyrdom and Religious Identity in Late Antiquity. Oakland: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Stark, Sören. 2008. Die Alttürkenzeit in Mittel- und Zentralasien: Archäologische und historische Studien. Wiesbaden: Dr. Ludwig Reichert Verlag.Google Scholar
Trombert, Éric. 2000. “Textiles et tissus sur la Route de la soie: éléments pour une géographie de la production et des échanges”, in Drège, Jean-Pierre (ed.), La Sérinde, terre d’échanges: art, religion, commerce du I-er au X-e siècle. Paris: Documentation français, 107–20.Google Scholar
Ulrich, Brian. 2011. “Oman and Bahrain in late antiquity: the Sasanians’ Arabian pheriphery”, Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 41, 377–86.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2005. Sogdian Traders: A History. Leiden: Brill.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2006. “Saint André chez les Sogdiens: Aux origins de Sogdaia, en Crimée”, in Zuckerman, Constantin (ed.), La Crimée entre Byzance et le khaganat khazar. Paris: Association des Amis du Centre d'Histoire et Civilisation de Byzance, 171–80.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2014. “Trans-Asian trade, or the Silk Road deconstructed (Antiquity, Middle Ages)”, in Neal, Larry and Williamson, Jeffrey G. (eds), The Cambridge History of Capitalism, v. I: The Rise of Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 101–24.Google Scholar
Verhecken-Lammens, Chris, De Moor, Antoine and Overlaet, Bruno. 2006. “Radio-carbon dated Silk Road Samites of Katoen Natie, Antwerp”, Iranica Antiqua 41, 233301.Google Scholar
Weber, Ursula and Wiesehöfer, Josef. 2010. “König Narsehs Herrschaftsverständnis”, in Börm, Henning and Wiesehöfer, Josef (eds), Commutatio et contentio: Studies in the Late Roman, Sasanian, and Early Islamic Near East. Düsseldorf: Wellem Verlag, 89132.Google Scholar
Wertmann, Patrick. 2015. Sogdians in China: Archaeological and Art Historical Analyses of Tombs and Texts from the 3rd to the 10th Century AD. Darmstadt: Philippp von Zabern.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David. 1996. “Sasanian maritime activity”, in Reade, Julian (ed.), The Indian Ocean in Antiquity. London: Kegan Paul, 339–49.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David. 2000. “Ancient glass from ed-Dur (Umm al-Qaiwain, U.A.E.) 2. Glass excavated by the Danish expedition”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 11, 87128.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David and Williamson, Andrew. 1973. “Sasanian maritime trade”, Iran 11, 2949.Google Scholar
Widengren, Geo. 1971. “The establishment of the Sasanian dynasty in the light of new evidence”, in Cerulli, Enrico (ed.), La Persia nel Medioevo. Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 711–82.Google Scholar
Wilson, Andrew. 2015. “Red Sea trade and the state”, in De Romanis, Federico and Maiuro, Marco (eds), Across the Ocean: Nine Essays on Indo-Mediterranean Trade. Leiden: Brill, 1332.Google Scholar
Winter, Engelbert. 1987. “Handel und Wirtschaft in sāsānidisch-(ost)römischen Verträgen und Abkommen”, Münstersche Beiträge zur antiken Handelsgeschichte 6, 4674.Google Scholar
Yatsenko, S.A. 2006. Kostyum Drevnei Evrazii. Moscow: Vostochnaya Literatura RAN.Google Scholar
Zuckerman, Constantin. 2013. “Silk ‘Made in Byzantium’: a study of economic policies of Emperor Justinian”, Travaux et Mémoires 17, 323–50.Google Scholar
Acts of Thomas, ed. Wright, William, Apocryphal Acts of the Apostles, v. I: The Syriac Texts (London: Williams and Norgate, 1871), and trans. Klijn, Albertus F.J., The Acts of Thomas: Introduction, Text, and Commentary (Leiden: Brill, 2003).Google Scholar
Buzandaran Patmut‘iwnk’ (ed. Patkanean, Kerovbe). P‘awstosi Buzandac‘woy Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’. St. Petersburg: Akad., 1883; trans. Nina Garsoïan, The Epic Histories (Buzandaran Patmut‘iwnk’) (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1989).Google Scholar
Chronicle of Seert, ed. and trans. Scher, Addaï, Histoire nestorienne (Chronique de Séert), v. 1–2 (Paris: Firmin-Didot, 1908–19).Google Scholar
al-Dīnawarī, Kitāb al-akhbār al-ṭiwāl, ed. ʿAmir, ʿAbd al-Munʿim (Cairo: Al-Idārah al-ʿĀmmah lil-Thaqāfah, 1960).Google Scholar
Ḥamza al-Iṣfahānī, Ta'rīkh sinnī mulūk al-arḍ, ed. Ya‘qūb Maskūnī, Yūsuf (Beirut: Dār Maktaba, 1961).Google Scholar
History of Mar Mari, ed. and trans. Harrak, Amir, The Acts of Mār Māri the Apostle (Atlanta: Society of Biblical Literature, 2005).Google Scholar
Inscriptions of Kirdir, ed. and trans. Gignoux, Philippe, Les quatre inscriptions du mage Kirdir: Textes et concordances (Paris: Association pour l'Avancement des Études Iraniennes, 1991).Google Scholar
Inscription of Paikuli, ed. and trans. Humbach, H. and Skjaervø, Prods O., The Sasanian Inscription of Paikuli, Part 3.1: Restored Text and Translation (Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1983).Google Scholar
Inscription of Shapur I on the Ka‘ba-ye Zardusht, ed. and trans. Huyse, Philip, Die dreisprachige Inschrift Šābuhrs I. an der Ka‘aba-i Zardušt (ŠKZ) (London: Corpus Inscriptionum Iranicarum, 1999).Google Scholar
Kārnāmag ī Ardašīr, ed. and trans. Grenet, Frantz, La geste d'Ardashir fils de Pâbag (Die: Éditions A Die, 2003).Google Scholar
Łazar P‘arpec‘i, Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’, ed. Ter-Mkrtchean, G., Patmut‘iwn Hayoc’ (Tbilisi: Tparan Ōr.N. Aghaneani, 1904), and trans. Robert W. Thomson, The History of Łazar P‘arpec‘i (Atlanta: Scholars Press, 1991).Google Scholar
Letter of Tansar, ed. Minovi, Mojtaba, Nāmah-e Tansar bih Jushnasf (Tehran: Matbaʿah-i Majlis, 1932), and trans. Boyce, Mary, The Letter of Tansar (Rome: Instituto Italiano per il Media ed Estremo Oriente, 1968).Google Scholar
Martyrdom of Pusai, ed. Bedjan, Paul, Acta martyrum et sanctorum II (Leipzig and Paris: Otto Harrassowitz, 1897): 208232.Google Scholar
Menander the Guardsman, Historia, ed. and trans. Blockley, R.C., The History of Menander the Guardsman (Liverpool: Liverpool University Press, 1985).Google Scholar
Periplus of the Erythrean Sea, ed. and trans. Bukharin, M.D., Peripl Eritreiskovo Morya: Tekst, Perevod, Kommentarii, Issledovaniya (St. Petersburg: Aleteiya, 2007).Google Scholar
Procopius, Anecdota, ed. and trans. Dewing, H.B., The Anecdota or Secret History (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1935).Google Scholar
Procopius, Bella, ed. and trans. Dewing, H.B., History of the Wars, v. I (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1914).Google Scholar
Synodicon Orientale, ed. and trans. Chabot, J.B., Synodicon Orientale, ou recueil de synodes nestoriens (Paris: Imprimerie nationale, 1902).Google Scholar
al-Ṭabarī, Ta'rikh al-rusul wa al-mulūk, ed. De Goeje, M., Annales, quos scripsit Abu Djafar Mohammed ibn Djarir at-Tabard, v. I (Leiden: Brill, 1964–5), and trans. Bosworth, C.E., The History of al-Ṭabarī, vol. V: The Sāsānids, the Byzantines, the Lakhmids, and Yemen (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1999).Google Scholar
Alizadeh, Karim. 2014. “Borderland projects of the Sasanian empire: intersection of domestic and foreign policies”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 93115.Google Scholar
Banaji, Jairus. 2006. “Precious metal coinages and monetary expansion in Late Antiquity”, in de Romanis, Federico and Sorda, Sara (eds), Dal Denarius al Dinar: L'Orient e la Moneta Romana. Rome: Istituto Italiano di Numismatica, 265303.Google Scholar
Brandes, Wolfra. 2002. Finanzverwaltung in Krisenzeiten: Untersuchungen zur byzantinischen Administration im 6.–9. Jahrhundert. Frankfurt: Löwenklau, 2002.Google Scholar
Bresson, Alain. 2015. The Making of the Ancient Greek Economy: Institutions, Markets, and Growth in the City-States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bresson, Alain. 2012. “Wine, oil and delicacies at the Pelousian customs”, in Günther, Linda-Marie and Grieb, Volker (eds), Das imperiale Rom und der hellenistische Osten: Festschrift für Jürgen Deininger zum 75. Geburtstag. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 6988.Google Scholar
Brosseder, Ursula B. 2015. “A study on the complexity and dynamics of interaction and exchange in late Iron Age Eurasia”, in Bemmann, Jan and Schmauder, Michael (eds), Complexity of Interaction along the Eurasian Steppe Zone in the First Millennium CE. Bonn: Vor- und Frühgeschichtliche Archäologie, 199332.Google Scholar
Brunner, Christopher J. 1974. “Middle Persian inscriptions on Sasanian silverware”, Metropolitan Museum Journal 9, 109–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bukharin, M.D. 2007. Peripl Eritreiskovo Morya: Tekst, Perevod, Kommentarii, Issledovaniya. St Petersburg: Aleteiya.Google Scholar
Calament, Florence. 2004. “L'apport historique des découvertes d'Antinoé au costume dit de ‘cavalier sassanide’”, in Fluck, Cäcilia and Vogelsang-Eastwood, Gillian (eds), Riding Costume in Egypt: Origin and Appearance. Leiden: Brill, 3772.Google Scholar
Canepa, Matthew. 2010. “Distant displays of power: understanding cross-cultural interaction among the elites of Rome, Sasanian Iran, and Sui-Tang China”, Ars Orientalis 38, 121–54.Google Scholar
Canepa, Matthew. 2014. “Textiles and elite tastes between the Mediterranean, Iran and Asia at the end of antiquity”, in Nosch, Marie Louise, Feng, Zhao, and Varadarajan, Lotika (eds), Global Textile Encounters. Oxford: Oxbow Books, 114.Google Scholar
Carter, Robert. 2005. “The history and prehistory of pearling in the Persian Gulf”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 48, 139209.Google Scholar
Casana, Jesse. 2013. “Radial route systems and agro-pastoral strategies in the Fertile Crescent: new discoveries from western Syria and southwestern Iran”, Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 32, 257–73.Google Scholar
Chin, Tamara. 2013. “The invention of the Silk Road, 1877”, Critical Inquiry 40, 194219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cobb, Matthew. 2015. “The chronology of Roman trade in the Indian Ocean from Augustus to early third century CE”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 58, 362418.Google Scholar
Cuny, Julien and Mouton, Michel. 2009. “La transition vers la période sassanide dans la péninsule d'Oman: Chronologie et modes de peuplement”, in Schiettecatte, Jérémie (ed.), L'Arabie à la veille de l'Islam: Bilan clinique. Paris: De Boccard, 91133.Google Scholar
Cutler, Anthony. 2005. “Silver across the Euphrates: forms of exchange between Sasanian Persia and the late Roman empire”, Mitteilungen zur spätantiken Archäologie und Byzantinischen Kunstgeschichte 4, 937.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 1999. “Sources for the economic history of late Sāsānian Fārs”, in Gyselen, Rika and Szuppe, Maria (eds), Matériaux pour l'histoire économique du monde iranien. Paris: Association pour l'Avancement des Études Iraniennes, 131–48.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 2003. “The Persian Gulf trade in late antiquity”, Journal of World History 14, 2003, 116.Google Scholar
Daryaee, Touraj. 2010. “Bazaars, merchants, and trade in late antique Iran”, Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East 30, 41409.Google Scholar
De Moor, A., Van Strydonck, M. and Verhecken-Lammens, C.. 2004. “Radiocarbon dating of two Sasanian coats and three post-Sasanian tapestries”, in Fluck, Cäcilia and Vogelsang-Eastwood, Gillian (eds), Riding Costume in Egypt: Origin and Appearance. Leiden: Brill, 181–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gasparini, Mariachiara. 2014. “A mathematical expression of art: Sino-Iranian and Uighur textile interaction and the Turfan textile collection in Berlin”, Trans-Cultural Studies 1, 134–63.Google Scholar
Gaube, Heinz. 1973. Die südpersische Provinz Arraĝān/Kūh-Gīlūyeh von der arabischen Eroberung bis zur Safavidenzeit. Vienna: Verlag der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften.Google Scholar
Ghosh, Suchandra. 2008. “The western coast of India and the Gulf: maritime trade during the 3rd to 7th centuries A.D.”, in Olijdam, Eric and Spoor, Richard H. (eds), Intercultural Relations between South and Southwest Asia: Studies in Commemoration of E.C.L. During Caspers. Oxford: Archaeopress, 367–71.Google Scholar
Grabar, Oleg. 1967. “An introduction to the art of Sasanian silver”, in Sawyer, Charles (ed.), Sasanian Silver: Late Antique and Early Medieval Arts of Luxury from Iran. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 1996. “Les marchands sogdiens dans les Mers du Sud à l'époque préislamique”, Cahiers d'Asie centrale 1–2, 6584.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 2005. “Découverte d'un relief sassanide dans le nord de l'Afghanistan”, Compte Rendus de l'Académie des Inscriptions et Belle-Lettres, 115–35.Google Scholar
Grenet, Frantz. 2010. “A view from Samarkand: the Chionite and Kidarite periods in the archaeology of Sogdians (fourth to fifth centuries A.D.)”, in Alram, Michael et al. (eds), Coins, Art and Chronology, vol. 2: The First Millennium c.e. in the Indo-Iranian Borderlands. Vienna: Verlag der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 267–81.Google Scholar
Gregoratti, Leonardo. 2011. “A Parthian port on the Persian Gulf: Characene and its trade”, Anabasis: Studia Classica et Orientalia 2, 209–29.Google Scholar
Gregoratti, Leonardo. 2012. “The importance of the mint of Seleucia on the Tigris for Arsacid history: Artabanus and the Greek Parthian cities”, Mesopotamia 47, 129–36.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika. 1989. La géographie administrative de l'empire sassanide: Les témoignages, sigillographiques. Paris: Groupe pour l’Étude de la Civilisation du Moyen-Orient.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika. 2003. “Dīwān et ‘trésorie’ Sassanides: premières attestations sigillographiques”, Studia Iranica 32, 123–6.Google Scholar
Gyselen, Rika and Gasche, Hermann. 1994. “Suse et Ivān-e Kerkha, capitale provinciale d’Ērān-Xwarrah-Šāpūr”, Studia Iranica 23, 1935.Google Scholar
Hansen, Valerie. 2012. The Silk Road: A New History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hansman, John. 1967. “Charax and the Karkheh”, Iranica Antiqua 7, 2158.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence. 1998. “Sasanian and early Islamic silver and bronze vessels”, in Otavsky, Karl (ed.), Entlang der Seidenstraße: Frühmittelalterliche Kunst zwischen Persien und China in der Abegg-Stiftung. Riggisberg: Abegg-Stiftung, 215–38.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence. 2006. In Search of the Cultural Identity: Monuments and Artifacts of the Sasanian Near East, 3rd to 7th Century A.D. New York: Bibliotheca Persica.Google Scholar
Harper, Prudence and Meyers, Pieter. 1981. Silver Vessels of the Sasanian Period, v. I: Royal Imagery. New York: Metropolitan Museum of Art.Google Scholar
Harrak, Amir. 2002. “Trade routes and the Christianization of the Near East”, Journal of the Canadian Society for Syriac Studies 2, 4661.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Højlund, Flemming. 2006. “The dating of the coastal fortress at Qala'at al-Bahrain: Sasanian or Islamic?”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 17, 238–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Honeychurch, William. 2014. “Alternative complexities: the archaeology of pastoral nomadic states”, Journal of Archaeological Research 22, 277326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Honeychurch, William. 2015. “From steppe roads to Silk Roads: Inner Asian nomads and early interregional exchange”, in Amitai, Reuven and Biran, Michal (eds), Nomads as Agents of Cultural Change: The Mongols and their Eurasian Predecessors. Honolulu: University of Hawai‘i Press, 5087.Google Scholar
Howard-Johnston, James. 2014. “The Sasanian state: the evidence of coinage and military construction”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 144–81.Google Scholar
Jullien, Christelle and Jullien, Florence. 2001. “Porteurs de salut: Apôtre et marchand dans l'empire iranien”, Parole de l'Orient 26, 127–43.Google Scholar
Kennett, Derek. 2009. “Transformations in late Sasanian and early Islamic eastern Arabia: the evidence from Kush”, in Schiettecatte, Jérémie (ed.), L'Arabie à la veille de l'Islam: bilan clinique. Paris: De Boccard, 135–61.Google Scholar
Kennett, Derek. 2007. “The decline of eastern Arabia in the Sasanian period”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 18, 86122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kervran, Monique. 1994. “Fortress, entrepôts et commerce: une histoire à suivre depuis les rois sassanides jusqu'aux princes d'Ormuz”, in Curiel, Raul and Gyselen, Rika (eds), Itinéraires d'Orient: Hommages à Claude Cahen. Bures-sur-Yvette: Groupe pour l’Étude de la Civilisation du Moyen-Orient.Google Scholar
Knauer, Elfriede R. 2001. “Le vêtement des nomades eurasiatiques et sa postérité”, Comptes-Rendus de l'Académie des Inscriptions & Belles-Lettres 143, 1141–87.Google Scholar
Margariti, Roxani Eleni. 2008. “Mercantile networks, port cities, and ‘pirate’ states: conflict and competition in the Indian Ocean world trade before the sixteenth century”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 51, 543–77.Google Scholar
Marshak, Boris. 1971. Sogdiiskoe Serebro: Ocherki po Vostochnoi Torevtike. Moscow: Nauka.Google Scholar
Martinez-Sève, Laurianne. 2014. “Antiochos IV en Susiane, dans le Golfe Persique et en Élymaïde”, in Feyer, C. and Graslin, L. (ed.), Le projet politique d'Antiochos IV. Nancy: ADRA, 363–93.Google Scholar
Mehendale, Sanjyot. 1996. “Begram: along ancient Central Asian and Indian trade routes”, Cahiers d'Asie centrale 1–2, 4764.Google Scholar
Millar, Fergus. 1998. “Caravan cities: the Roman Near East and long-distance trade by land”, Bulletin of the Institute of Classical Studies 42, 119–37.Google Scholar
Morony, Michael G. 2004a. “Economic boundaries? Late antiquity and early Islam”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 47, 166–94.Google Scholar
Morony, Michael G. 2004b. “Population transfers between Sasanian Iran and the Byzantine Empire”, in Carile, Antonio (ed.), La Persia e Bisanzio. Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 161–79.Google Scholar
Mouton, Michel and Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2014. In the Desert Margins: The Settlement Process in Ancient South and East Arabia. Rome: «L'Erma» di Bretschneider.Google Scholar
Overlaet, Bruno. 1999. “Dating and iconographical commentary: Sassanian and post-Sassanian tapestries”, in De Jonghe, Daniël et al. (eds), Ancient Tapestries of the R. Pfister Collection in the Vatican Library. Vatican City: Biblioteca apostolica Vaticana, 121–75.Google Scholar
Payne, Richard E. 2015. A State of Mixture: Christians, Zoroastrians, and Iranian Political Culture in Late Antiquity. Oakland: University of California Press, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, Richard E. 2017. “Territorializing Iran in Late Antiquity: autocracy, aristocracy, and the infrastructure of empire”, in Ando, Clifford and Richardson, Seth (eds), Ancient States and Infrastructural Power: Europe, Asia, and America. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 179217.Google Scholar
Piacentini Fiorani, Valeria. 1985. “Ardashīr ī Pāpakān and the wars against the Arabs: working hypothesis on the Sasanian hold of the Gulf”, Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 15, 5777.Google Scholar
Piacentini Fiorani, Valeria. 2014. Beyond Ibn Hawqal's Bahr al-Fārs, 10th–13th Centuries AD: Sindh and the Kīj-u-Makrān Region, Hinge of International Network of Religious, Political, Institutional and Economic Affairs. Oxford: Archaeopress.Google Scholar
Pigulevskaya, Nina V. 1963. Les villes de l’état iranien aux époques parthe et sassanide: contribution à l'histoire sociale de la Basse Antiquité. Paris: Mouton.Google Scholar
Potts, Daniel T. 1990. The Arabian Gulf in Antiquity, v. II: From Alexander the Great to the Coming of Islam. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Potts, Daniel T. 1997. “The Roman relationship with the Persicus Sinus from the rise of Spasinou Charax (127 BC) to the reign of Shapur II (AD 309–379)”, in Alcock, Susan E. (ed.), The Early Roman Empire in the East. Oxford: Oxbow, 89107.Google Scholar
Pourshariati, Parvaneh. 2008. Decline and Fall of the Sasanian Empire: The Sasanian–Parthian Confederacy and the Arab Conquest of Iran. London: I.B. Tauris.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pourshariati, Parvaneh. 2014. “New vistas on the history of Iranian Jewry in late antiquity, part I: patterns of Jewish settlement in Iran”, in Sarshar, Houman (ed.), The Jews of Iran: The History, Religion, and Culture of a Community in the Islamic World. London: I.B. Tauris, 132.Google Scholar
Power, Timothy. 2012. The Red Sea from Byzantium to the Caliphate AD 500–1000. Cairo: The American University in Cairo Press.Google Scholar
Priestman, Seth. 2013. “A quantitative archaeological analysis of ceramic exchange in the Persian Gulf and the western Indian Ocean”. PhD thesis, University of Southampton.Google Scholar
Purcell, Nicholas. 2005. “The ancient Mediterranean: the view from the customs-house”, in Harris, William V. (ed.), Rethinking the Mediterranean. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005, 200–32.Google Scholar
Rante, Rocco and Collinet, Annabelle. 2013. Nishapur Revisited: Stratigraphy and Ceramics of the Qohandez. Oxford: Oxbow.Google Scholar
Rawson, Jessica. 1991. “Central Asian silver and its influence on Chinese ceramics”, Bulletin of the Asia Institute 5, 139–51.Google Scholar
Rezakhani, Khodadad. 2017. Reorienting the Sasanians: East Iran in Late Antiquity. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
de Romanis, Federico. 2006. “Aurei after the trade: western taxes and eastern gifts”, in de Romanis, Federico and Sorda, Sara (eds), Dal Denarius al Dinar: L'Orient e la Moneta Romana. Rome: Istituto Italiano di Numismatica, 5582.Google Scholar
Rubin, Zeev. 2000. “The Sassanid monarchy”, in Cameron, Averil et al. (eds), Cambridge Ancient History, vol. 14. Late Antiquity: Empire and Successors, a.d. 425–600. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 638–61.Google Scholar
Rubin, Zeev. 2008. “Islamic traditions on the Sasanian conquest of the Himyarite realm”, Der Islam 84, 185–99.Google Scholar
Sauer, Eberhard, Rekavandi, Hamid Omrani, Wilkinson, Tony J., Nokandeh, Jebrael et al. 2013. Persia's Imperial Power in Late Antiquity: The Great Wall of Gorgān and Frontier Landscapes of Sasanian Iran. Oxford: Oxbow Books.Google Scholar
Scheidel, Walter. 2015. “State revenue and expenditure in the Han and Roman empires”, in Scheidel, Walter (ed.), State Power in Ancient China and Rome. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 150–80.Google Scholar
Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2008. “Ports et commerce maritime dans l'Arabie du Sud préislamique”, Chroniques yéménites 15, 6590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiettecatte, Jérémie. 2013. “À la veille de l'Islam: effondrement ou transformation du monde antique?”, in Robin, Christian and Schiettecatte, Jérémie (eds), Les préludes de l'Islam: Ruptures et continuités des civilisations du Proche-Orient, de l'Afrique orientale, de l'Arabie et de l'Inde à la veille de l'Islam. Paris: De Boccard, 936.Google Scholar
Schindel, Nikolaus. 2015. “Sasaniden, Kushan, Kushano-Sasaniden: Münzprägung, Propaganda und Identitäten zwischen Westiran und Ostiran”, Haller Münzblätter 8, 137–67.Google Scholar
Schwaigert, Wolfgang. 1989. Das Christentum in Hūzistān in Rahmen der frühen Kirchengeschichte Persiens bis zur Synode von Seleukia-Ktesiphon im Jahre 410. Marburg: Görich & Weiershäuser.Google Scholar
Sedov, A.V. 1992. “New archaeological and epigraphical material from Qana (South Arabia)”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 3, 110–37.Google Scholar
Seland, Eivind Heldaas. 2010. Ports and Political Power in the Periplus: Complex Societies and Maritime Trade on the Indian Ocean in the First Century AD. Oxford: Archaeopress.Google Scholar
Seland, Eivind Heldaas. 2011. “The Persian Gulf or the Red Sea? Two axes in ancient Indian Ocean trade, where to go and why”, World Archaeology 43, 398–49.Google Scholar
Sen, Tansen. 2011. “Maritime interactions between China and India: coastal India and the ascendancy of Chinese maritime power in the Indian Ocean”, Journal of Central Eurasian Studies 2, 4182.Google Scholar
Sidebotham, Steven E. 2011. Berenike and the Ancient Maritime Spice Route. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Simpson, St John. 2014. “Merv, an archaeological case study from the northeastern frontier of the Sasanian empire”, Journal of Ancient History 2, 116–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Kyle. 2016. Constantine and the Captive Christians of Persia: Martyrdom and Religious Identity in Late Antiquity. Oakland: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Stark, Sören. 2008. Die Alttürkenzeit in Mittel- und Zentralasien: Archäologische und historische Studien. Wiesbaden: Dr. Ludwig Reichert Verlag.Google Scholar
Trombert, Éric. 2000. “Textiles et tissus sur la Route de la soie: éléments pour une géographie de la production et des échanges”, in Drège, Jean-Pierre (ed.), La Sérinde, terre d’échanges: art, religion, commerce du I-er au X-e siècle. Paris: Documentation français, 107–20.Google Scholar
Ulrich, Brian. 2011. “Oman and Bahrain in late antiquity: the Sasanians’ Arabian pheriphery”, Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies 41, 377–86.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2005. Sogdian Traders: A History. Leiden: Brill.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2006. “Saint André chez les Sogdiens: Aux origins de Sogdaia, en Crimée”, in Zuckerman, Constantin (ed.), La Crimée entre Byzance et le khaganat khazar. Paris: Association des Amis du Centre d'Histoire et Civilisation de Byzance, 171–80.Google Scholar
de la Vaissière, Étienne. 2014. “Trans-Asian trade, or the Silk Road deconstructed (Antiquity, Middle Ages)”, in Neal, Larry and Williamson, Jeffrey G. (eds), The Cambridge History of Capitalism, v. I: The Rise of Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 101–24.Google Scholar
Verhecken-Lammens, Chris, De Moor, Antoine and Overlaet, Bruno. 2006. “Radio-carbon dated Silk Road Samites of Katoen Natie, Antwerp”, Iranica Antiqua 41, 233301.Google Scholar
Weber, Ursula and Wiesehöfer, Josef. 2010. “König Narsehs Herrschaftsverständnis”, in Börm, Henning and Wiesehöfer, Josef (eds), Commutatio et contentio: Studies in the Late Roman, Sasanian, and Early Islamic Near East. Düsseldorf: Wellem Verlag, 89132.Google Scholar
Wertmann, Patrick. 2015. Sogdians in China: Archaeological and Art Historical Analyses of Tombs and Texts from the 3rd to the 10th Century AD. Darmstadt: Philippp von Zabern.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David. 1996. “Sasanian maritime activity”, in Reade, Julian (ed.), The Indian Ocean in Antiquity. London: Kegan Paul, 339–49.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David. 2000. “Ancient glass from ed-Dur (Umm al-Qaiwain, U.A.E.) 2. Glass excavated by the Danish expedition”, Arabian Archaeology and Epigraphy 11, 87128.Google Scholar
Whitehouse, David and Williamson, Andrew. 1973. “Sasanian maritime trade”, Iran 11, 2949.Google Scholar
Widengren, Geo. 1971. “The establishment of the Sasanian dynasty in the light of new evidence”, in Cerulli, Enrico (ed.), La Persia nel Medioevo. Rome: Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 711–82.Google Scholar
Wilson, Andrew. 2015. “Red Sea trade and the state”, in De Romanis, Federico and Maiuro, Marco (eds), Across the Ocean: Nine Essays on Indo-Mediterranean Trade. Leiden: Brill, 1332.Google Scholar
Winter, Engelbert. 1987. “Handel und Wirtschaft in sāsānidisch-(ost)römischen Verträgen und Abkommen”, Münstersche Beiträge zur antiken Handelsgeschichte 6, 4674.Google Scholar
Yatsenko, S.A. 2006. Kostyum Drevnei Evrazii. Moscow: Vostochnaya Literatura RAN.Google Scholar
Zuckerman, Constantin. 2013. “Silk ‘Made in Byzantium’: a study of economic policies of Emperor Justinian”, Travaux et Mémoires 17, 323–50.Google Scholar