Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-f46jp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T06:03:17.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fair Revaluation of Wine as an Investment*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 September 2015

Fabian Y.R.P. Bocart
Affiliation:
Institute of Statistics, Biostatistics, and Actuarial Sciences (ISBA), Université Catholique de Louvain, Voie du Roman Pays, 20, 1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium; e-mail: fabian.bocart@gmail.com.
Christian M. Hafner*
Affiliation:
Institute of Statistics, Biostatistics, and Actuarial Sciences (ISBA) and CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain, Voie du Roman Pays, 20, 1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium
*
e-mail: christian.hafner@uclouvain.be (corresponding author).
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The price of wine is a key topic among market participants interested in valuing their stock, including dealers and restaurants, and consumers who may be interested in optimizing their purchases. A closely related issue, revaluation is the need to regularly update the value of a stock. This need is especially acute in the growing industry of wine as an investment. In this case, fair-value measurement is compulsory by law. We briefly review methods available to funds and introduce a new quantitative method aimed at achieving compliance with IFRS (International Financial Reporting Standard) 13 for fair valuation. Using auction data on 26,640 lots, we apply this method to compute the current fair value of a basket of 232 different wines. (JEL Classifications: C14, C43, Z11)

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Association of Wine Economists 2015 

I. Introduction

Although most consumers generally obtain wine with the objective of drinking it, some also buy it for the purpose of investment. The recent wine economics literature has highlighted the direct benefits of wine investment and the positive diversification effects wine can introduce to a portfolio of standard assets; see, for example, Fogarty and Sadler (Reference Fogarty and Sadler2014), Sanning et al., (Reference Sanning, Shaffer and Sharratt2008), and the general overview of the wine finance literature in Storchmann (Reference Storchmann2012). Indeed, wine shares many characteristics with other storable agricultural goods considered investments, for example, an active auction market that offers market participants transparency and liquidity. Wine funds in particular have industrialized the art of speculating in wine, creating the possibility of active investment in this alternative asset.

Measuring performance of wine investment funds is necessary to properly compute performance fees of managers, assess the fair value of a share in the fund, and, more generally, provide accurate reporting to all involved stakeholders. Because of increasing access to data and automation capabilities, traditional valuation of physical assets by independent appraisers is becoming less important. For example, the econometric approach of Ashenfelter (Reference Ashenfelter2008) and Ashenfelter et al. (Reference Ashenfelter, Ashmore and Lalonde1995) to evaluate the quality of a wine tends to outperform expert opinions in terms of predicting prices at auction. Furthermore, the growing level of stocks held by wine funds makes a regular “manual” valuation by experts very difficult, if not impossible. As a consequence, the adoption of IFRS 13 (International Financial Reporting Standard 13, in effect since January 2013) by regulated wine funds requires significant changes in traditional procedures for determining fair value. Unlike stocks and bonds, a bottle of wine does not yield any coupon or dividend; and, unlike other conspicuous assets such as art that perpetually yield aesthetic dividends (Baumol, Reference Baumol1986), wine cannot be consumed without destroying its value. For the same reason, cash flows cannot be obtained from renting, or leasing, bottles of wine, so any type of net-present-value valuation cannot be applied. This research addresses the question of the valuation of wine in the context of wine funds valued in going-concern that are subject to traditional International Accounting Standards (IAS; some of which are still in use today) and IFRS regulations.

The valuation of returns on wine investments generally relates to the application of hedonic regression or the method of repeated sales. Hedonic regression was popularized by Rosen (Reference Rosen1974), who suggested that consumers pay a marginal price for each characteristic of a given good, with the sum of these implicit prices comprising the observed market price. Examples of applications of hedonic regression in the wine market are Combris et al. (Reference Combris, Lecocq and Visser1997), Fogarty (Reference Fogarty2006), Golan and Shalit (Reference Golan and Shalit1993), Nerlove (Reference Nerlove1995), Oczkowski (Reference Oczkowski1994), Priilaid and van Rensburg (Reference Priilaid and van Rensburg2012), and Yoo et al. (Reference Yoo, Florkowski and Carew2011). The method of repeated sales can be viewed as a nested case of hedonic regression and consists of computing average returns of identical goods sold over time. Examples of applications of this method in the wine market include Burton and Jacobsen (Reference Burton and Jacobsen2001), Fogarty (Reference Fogarty2010), Fogarty and Jones (Reference Fogarty and Jones2011), Jaeger (Reference Jaeger1981), Krasker (Reference Krasker1979), Masset and Henderson (Reference Masset and Henderson2010), Masset and Weisskopf (Reference Masset, Weisskopf, Giraud-Heraud and Pichery2013) and Sanning et al. (Reference Sanning, Shaffer and Sharratt2008). For a recent review of alternative methods to measure wine investment returns and benefits from risk diversification, see Fogarty and Sadler (Reference Fogarty and Sadler2014).

The question of IAS-IFRS compliance in agricultural markets is discussed in Marsh and Fischer (Reference Marsh and Fischer2013). The authors mention that wine, as a processed product, is typically excluded from the IAS 41 standard for agriculture. Azevedo (Reference Azevedo2007) focuses precisely on the impact of IAS 41 in the viticulture industry. The author highlights that fair value can be determined based on the price of an active market when it exists but, in the case of the wine-growing industry, this exercise is difficult due to the heterogeneity of wines across regions. The author suggests valuing an agricultural stock of vines by expressing it as liters of wine. Bohusova et al. (Reference Bohusova, Svoboda and Nerudova2012) review possibilities for small and medium-size enterprises (SMEs) active in the wine-growing industry to properly implement provisions in an IFRS framework for wine as a biological asset.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the current situation and methods presently used by some wine funds. Section 3 introduces a new methodology to estimate returns of a fund using either the hedonic or repeated-sales approach. In Section IV, we illustrate the hedonic method using 266,640 lots sold at auction at Christie's and Sotheby's between February 2007 and December 2013. Section V is the conclusion.

II. Current Situation

Since 2005, compliance with IAS-IFRS standards has been compulsory for all investment vehicles quoted on European stock exchanges, including wine funds. Furthermore, the recent European directive 2011/61/EU on Alternative Investment Fund Managers (AIFM) highlights a growing interest by supranational bodies in improving transparency in the market of alternative strategies, including funds that used to be less regulated. The regulation “IFRS 13 Fair Value Measurement” took effect in January 2013. In this framework, fair value is defined as “the price that would be received to sell an asset or paid to transfer a liability in an orderly transaction between market participants at the measurement date.” For nonfinancial assets, the selected valuation method must be appropriate for the measurement, consistent with their “highest and best use.” While this notion makes sense for physical assets, such as real estate or machinery (that can be rented or exploited), the “highest and best use” of a stock held by a wine fund is limited to storing it in a well-tempered cellar or wine refrigerator. As a consequence, the fair value of a wine stock must necessarily rely on IFRS 13 (24): it should correspond to a transaction taking place in the principal market for the asset or liability or, in the absence of a principal market, in the most advantageous market for the asset or liability. Since there is no centralized, or principal, market for wine, the most advantageous market is defined as the one that maximizes the amount that would be received to sell the asset after taking into account transaction costs and transport costs (IFRS 13: A1).

Wine funds currently implement various methods to value their stocks. Table 1 presents some funds of wine as an investment and which valuation they use, if published. Most of these funds trade heavily in French wines, typically representing about 80 percent of the portfolio. Some funds, such as the Wine Investment Fund, invest almost entirely in Bordeaux.

Table 1 List of Wine Investment Funds

None of the funds appears to use a historical cost approach, in which inventories are valued at the acquisition price. On the contrary, several funds already rely on a market approach to value their stocks, even though IFRS 13 compliance is not obvious in that case. However, until 2017, auditors may sign off on a market valuation approach of a fund even where full IFRS 13 compliance has not been established. Interestingly, some funds seem to use the valuation methodology promoted by the London International Vintners Exchange (Liv-ex), an Internet and telephone transaction platform for wine professionals. The company brands itself as the “industry standard” and “the official valuer for a number of leading wine funds.”

The Liv-ex platform is organized in a similar fashion as a stock exchange: bids or offers are put on the platform by professionals. When a trade takes place, both counterparties are notified of the transaction. Within 14 days, the seller then delivers the wine to the Liv-ex warehouse, which is verified by Liv-ex. Simultaneously, the buyer sends the funds to Liv-ex, which transfers the money to the seller within three weeks, whereas the buyer can either collect the wine at the warehouse or have it delivered.

The Liv-ex exploits available information on its platform to produce valuations of wines. The valuation method is the following: After the submission of a list of wines to be valued, the exchange verifies the current best offer for each wine in its own system and at other dealers. The valuer then observes the best bid on the platform and looks at the most recent transaction (within the previous 30 days). If it lies within the bid-offer spread, then this transaction is used for valuation; otherwise, the mid-price is computed as the average between the bid and the offer. The scenario becomes more complex when no offer is available. In this case, Liv-ex relies on an undisclosed list of offer prices by merchants “identified as the major stockholders of wine.” If no offer was available in the previous 30 days neither at a dealer nor on the Liv-ex, then the valuation is performed by a “valuation committee” that uses “off-market bids and offers, historical list prices and transaction data.” If no bid is available, the bid is estimated from the average spreads to “orphan offers,” defined as “an offer price where [Liv-ex has] no corresponding bid. Orphans can be both live exchange offers or merchant list prices.” The Liv-ex does not include auction prices in its calculation “due to a lack of standardization of auction lots,” which can make weekly prices “very volatile with large swings” and because “auction commissions can vary.”

Despite being an interesting approach, the method seems to fail to satisfy requirements for fair-value computation of wine as a financial asset, especially in terms of the IFRS 13. First, although it is a very successful venture with 400 members and more than 1,000 transactions per month, there is little evidence that Liv-ex is the most advantageous market for selling any type of wine that could be held by a fund. According to Liv-ex, in 2010, Bordeaux wines accounted for 95% of its exchanges, with five Premiers Crus comprising 61% of Liv-ex trades by value: Château Lafite-Rothschild (Pauillac), Château Latour (Pauillac), Château Margaux (Margaux), Château Haut-Brion (Pessac, Graves), Château Mouton-Rothschild (Pauillac).

In 2011, more than US$150 million worth of wine was traded on the Liv-ex platform, which is a considerable amount in absolute value but undeniably smaller than the yearly US$400 million worth of transactions the same year at the major auction houses Acker Merrall and Condit, Christie's International, Sotheby's, Zachys, and Hart Davis Hart Wine Co. In some cases, depending on ask prices of dealers to estimate a bid price instead of relying on auction house transactions that are publicly available seems an unreasonable choice, given the opacity of dealer prices and the relative importance of large auction houses in the secondary market for wine (according to Liv-ex, auctions account for roughly 10% of the market), especially as far as old vintages and collectible wines are concerned.

First, as stated by Jones and Storchmann (Reference Jones and Storchmann2001), wines are “traded all over the world in established wine auctions. The system guarantees, similar to a stock market, a comparatively high price transparency. Therefore, it can be assumed that auction prices indicate the relative (economic) scarcity and therefore the international esteem for those wines.” Second, unlike auctions, the Liv-ex is based on standard contracts that assume a similar quality among wines with similar features. This approach, well suited to recent vintages, prevents investors from gaining complementary information about the condition of older wines. In the case of auctions, by contrast, Ashenfelter (Reference Ashenfelter1989) highlights that, at wine auctions, “revealing information tends to remove uncertainty and make low bidders more aggressive; this puts upward pressure on the bidding of others, which is in the interest of the auctioneer.” Similarly, Muth et al. (Reference Muth, Liu, Koontz and Lawrence2008) showed that in the market for fed cattle, auction barn prices are higher than equivalent forward prices. Pagano and Röell (Reference Pagano and Röell1996) proved that “the implicit bid-ask spread in a transparent auction is tighter than in a less transparent dealer market.” For the art market, Bocart and Oosterlinck (Reference Bocart and Oosterlinck2011) showed that large auction houses act as agents, mitigating authenticity issues.

Finally, one can reasonably question the independence of an exchange that excludes its competitors (auction houses) but includes data from its clients or prospects (dealers). The inclusion of a valuation committee in the event of the absence of data makes stakeholders clueless about the methodology and data eventually used to perform a valuation. In any case, a conflict of interest is possible between an exchange that acts simultaneously as intermediary and expert and a fund whose fee, like the exchange, depends on the price level.

III. New Approach to Valuation of Wine as an Investment

IFRS 13 provides three degrees of hierarchy in inputs that can be used for fair value measurement. The idea behind the hierarchy is that lower levels are preferred: Level 1 inputs are “quoted prices in active markets for identical assets or liabilities that the entity can access at the measurement date” (IFRS 13: 76). Level 2 inputs “are derived mainly from or corroborated by observable market data by correlation or other means (‘market-corroborated inputs’)” (IFRS 13: 81). Level 3 inputs are unobservable inputs used “with the best information available in the circumstances, which might include the entity's own data, taking into account all information about market participant assumptions that is reasonably available” (IFRS 13: 87–89).

In the case of wine, Level 1 inputs are not readily available, especially considering the fact that available exchanges (Hong Kong Wine Exchange, BWinex in the Bordeaux region, Vinetrade in Japan, and BBX and Liv-ex in the U.K., to name but a few) are highly specialized and do not represent the market with the greatest volume and level of activity for the asset or liability. Level 2 inputs, however, are accessible to wine funds since, first, they observe their own transactions, and, second, they observe prices reached at auction and on electronic platforms. Level 3 inputs are also significant for wine funds because they concern intrinsic qualities that generate profit. Indeed, their strategies often involve acquisition and selling tactics that best exploit their position in the market because they can benefit from significant economies of scale. Furthermore, they can act as liquidity providers and add a liquidity premium. They can best adjust their movements in a market prone to dysfunction, as mentioned by Ashenfelter (Reference Ashenfelter1989): “at the first wine auction I ever attended, I saw the repeal of the law of one price,” referring to the declining price anomaly in wine auctions provoked by non-optimal absentee bidders (Ginsburgh, Reference Ginsburgh1998). Naturally, funds' strategies differ. Some specifically focus on heavily traded Bordeaux wines and try to track the overall price levels, whereas others play in niche markets of collectibles. They trade intensively in the over-the-counter market for restaurants, dealers, and collectors. Our approach to fair valuation of a wine fund combines inputs from Levels 2 and 3.

Level 2 inputs consist of observed transactions, both those made by the fund and observable prices reached at auction, buyer's premium included, for identical wines. The auction market can be considered the most advantageous market because it is open to all and applies an English auction system, known to be the one that maximizes seller revenues among auction mechanisms (Lopomo, Reference Lopomo1998). Unfortunately, because of heterogeneity at auction, different prices for seemingly identical wines (e.g., with respect to domain, vintage, and format) are observed at different auction houses in the same month. A straightforward approach consists of averaging prices observed simultaneously, so as to obtain, over time, an evolution in the average price of a given wine.

(1) $${w_{it}} = \displaystyle{1 \over {N_{it}}} \sum \nolimits_j^{N_{it}} {\,p_{itj}},$$

where w it is the value of wine i at time t, p itj is the jth transaction of wine i sold at time t and N it is the amount of identical wines i sold at time t.

This naive methodology suffers from various drawbacks, including sensitivity to outliers. Also, as Equation (1) can be seen as a particular case of hedonic regression whose explanatory variables consist of only a single constant term and time dummies, Bocart and Hafner (Reference Bocart and Hafner2012) show that the traditional fixed effects estimator of volatility $\sqrt {\displaystyle{1 \over {{N_i} - 1}} \sum \nolimits_t {\rm }{{({w_{it}} - {{\bar w}_i})}^2}} $ overestimates the volatility of the underlying value dynamics. We suggest instead the construction of a price index based on a random effect estimator of each type of wine over time. Such an estimator is naturally more robust to outliers thanks to a smoothing effect. The model is:

(2) $${\rm log}\left({\,p_{itj}} \right) = C_i + \beta _{it} + \nu _{ijt}. $$
(3) $$\beta_{it} = \beta_{it - 1} + \xi_{it}.$$

The term C i is a constant, β it is the margil impact of time on prices of wine i, and $\nu _{ijt} \sim N\left({0,\sigma _{\nu_i} ^2} \right)$ . In Equation (3), we suppose that β it is a random walk, with $\xi _{it} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma _{\xi _i} ^2} \right)$ and which, for identification, is restricted to have a mean of zero.

The model can be estimated as in Bocart and Hafner (Reference Bocart and Hafner2015). At a first stage, estimate

(4) $${\rm log}\left({\,p_{itj}}\right) = C_i + \eta_{itj} $$

using ordinary least squares (OLS), where η itj  = β it  + ν itj . At a second stage, estimate β it using a Kalman filter. A wine i's fair value w iT at time T is then estimated as

(5) $${{\tilde w}_{iT}} = \sum \nolimits_{\tau = 1}^T \sum \nolimits_{\,j = 1}^{{N_{i\tau}}} {\exp}\left({\widehat{{{\beta _{\rm \iota T}}}} - \widehat{{{\beta _{\rm \iota \tau }}}}} \right){\,p_{i\tau j}}{{\rm \lambda} _{i\tau }},$$

where N is the total number of transactions observed at auction of wine i at time τ, λ is the weight allocated to the τ-th period, allowing, for instance, more recent observations to be given more weight. The particular case ${\rm \lambda} _{i\tau} = \displaystyle{1 \over {N_{i\tau}}} \delta _{\tau _T} $ (where $\delta _{\tau _T} $ is the Kronr delta) yields the classical approach of Equation (1). Alternatively, ${\rm \lambda} _{i\tau} = \displaystyle{1 \over {TN_{i\tau}}} $ gives all past time periods equal weight in the current valuation. We use this equal weighting in our empirical example in the following section. Another direct extension of the model is aggregation of wines per domain or per vintage by including additional variables in Equation (4). Also, a predictor of future prices can be derived from the Kalman filter approach as

(6) $$\widehat{{{\log}\left( {\,p_{\iota j\left( {T + 1} \right)}} \right)}} = \widehat{{C_\iota}} + \hat \beta _{i\left( {T + 1} \right)}.$$

If predictions of the price are required, corrections such as the one proposed by Jones and Zanola (Reference Jones and Zanola2010) are straightforward to implement in order to obtain an unbiased predictor.

IV. Empirical Results

To test the suggested method, we collect data on all sales of the most popularFootnote 1 wines sold at auction at Christie's and Sotheby's between February 2007 and December 2013.Footnote 2 The database consists of 26,640 observed transactions on 232 different wines whose list is available in the online appendix. Selling prices are converted to USD/bottle. In order to mimic a wine fund's portfolio, we simulate a portfolio made up of one bottle of each of the 232 different wines available in our sample. This is purely for illustrative purposes, and clearly any other type of portfolio, for example, value weighted, could have been chosen alternatively.

Each wine is reevaluated monthly. If no observation is available for a given month, the estimated fair value of the previous month is forwarded. Annualized volatility of each wine is also computed and is 25% on average.

In the online appendix, the individual monthly valuation of each of the 232 wines is provided. As expected, the price average method resulting from Equation (1) yields an unstable valuation. At individual wine levels, unreasonable spikes can be observed. Figure 1 compares the filtered valuation of the wine with the largest number of transactions (Mouton-Rothschild 1982) with the price average over time. A clear spike is visible, due to an abnormal transaction recorded at auction, and higher volatility when the price average method is used. Such effects are smoothed in the filtered version of the valuation. If the database is cleaned for outliers by discarding, for example, the top and bottom 0.1% of observations, the spike effect diminishes, but the effect from a more volatile price average method remains.

Figure 1 Filtered Versus Classical Average Price Valuations of Mouton-Rothschild 1982

At the portfolio level, Figure 2 plots the two types of valuation for our virtual portfolio made of the cumulative value of the 232 wines over time. A dotted line indicates the classical price average methodology, whereas the plain line shows the filtered version of the valuation. The filtered version exhibits a smoother progression.

Figure 2 Filtered Versus Classical Average Price Valuations for Portfolio of All 232 Wines

Finally, a more precise estimation of returns can also show relationships and dynamics among different wines. For instance, Figure 3 illustrates a tight relationship between 1996 Bordeaux wines whose domain is located between St-Estephe and Margaux in the Médoc region. These similar patterns are in sharp contrast with those for other Bordeaux wines (see Figure 4), such as those located farther south in the Pessac-Leognan area (Haut-Brion and Mission Haut-Brion) or even farther east in the Pomerol area. These nuances are not captured by the classical estimator in Equation (1). In the context of valuing a portfolio, such an analysis can be useful, for instance, in creating peer groups with corresponding price indices.

Figure 3 Monthly Price Indexes of Selected Wines from the Area Between St-Estephe and Margaux, 1996 Vintage

Figure 4 Monthly Price Indexes of Selected Wines from Outside the Area Between St-Estephe and Margaux, 1996 Vintage

Source: Map created by Ralf Powierski (www.info-graphic.de).

Figure 5 Map of the Bordeaux Region

V. Conclusion

IFRS 13–compliant revaluation of wine as an investment is an important topic for fund managers, investors, and fiscal authorities. Since the notion of the “highest and best use” for nonfinancial assets is difficult to apply to bottles of wine, a fair valuation can rely only on a market approach. Unfortunately, wines are heterogeneous goods that are not traded continuously. Furthermore, they can be traded in different places: dealers, local exchanges, and auction houses. Wine funds use independent valuation, auction, and dealer-based methodology, or the “Liv-ex” method. We argue that none of these fully satisfies the stringent requirements of IFRS 13. They either fail to justify the origin of the data (e.g., in the case of independent expertise), hence the type of input, or are calibrated on markets that are not the most important or most advantageous (e.g., the Liv-ex). We suggest estimating returns of a wine portfolio by applying Kalman filtering on price progression of individual wines. We advocate that data used to calibrate the model should be the fund's own transactions, married with data from auction houses, the latter being the biggest observable market for wine transaction, and the one that best fits the definition of “most advantageous market.” Naturally, a possible extension can further discriminate among auction houses, geographic location, and so forth. Our empirical results show better performance than the traditional average of prices, which yields distorted results and fails to properly capture the market's dynamics, including market volatility.

Supplementary Material

For supplementary material accompanying this paper visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/jwe.2015.20.

Footnotes

*

Financial support from the contract Projet d'Actions de Recherche Concertées “Stochastic Modelling of Dependence” granted by the Académie universitaire Louvain, is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Christophe Spaenjers for helpful discussions and comments. We are grateful for helpful comments from Karl Storchmann and an anonymous referee.

1 That is, wines that appeared at auction at least 50 times.

2 The data were acquired from Tutela Capital, a company that specializes in managing alternative assets (https://www.tutela.net).

References

Ashenfelter, O. (1989). How auctions work for wine and art. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(3), 2336.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O. (2008). Predicting the prices and quality of Bordeaux wines. Economic Journal, 118, 4053.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, O., Ashmore, D., and Lalonde, R. (1995). Bordeaux wine vintage quality and the weather. Chance, 8(4), 714.Google Scholar
Azevedo, G. (2007). The impact of International Accounting Standard 41 “Agriculture” in the wine industry. Working Paper. Available at SSRN 975508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W.J. (1986). Unnatural value: Or art investment as floating crap game. American Economic Review, 76, 1014.Google Scholar
Bocart, F.Y., and Hafner, C.M. (2012). Econometric analysis of volatile art markets. Computational Statistics and Data Analysis, 56, 30913104.Google Scholar
Bocart, F.Y., and Hafner, C.M. (2015). Volatility of price indices for heterogenous goods with applications to the fine art market. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 30, 291312.Google Scholar
Bocart, F., and Oosterlinck, K. (2011). Discoveries of fakes: Their impact on the art market. Economics Letters, 113(2), 124126.Google Scholar
Bohusova, H., Svoboda, P., and Nerudova, D. (2012). Biological assets reporting: Is the increase in value caused by the biological transformation revenue? Agricultural Economics–Czech (Zemedelská Ekonomika), 58(11), 520532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burton, J., and Jacobsen, J.P. (2001). The rate of return on wine investment. Economic Inquiry, 39(3), 337350.Google Scholar
Combris, P., Lecocq, S., and Visser, M. (1997). Estimation of a hedonic price equation for Bordeaux wine: Does quality matter? Economic Journal, 107(441), 390402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IFRS, European Commission. (2012). Commission Regulation (EU) No. 1255/2012 of 11 December 2012 amending Regulation (EC) No. 1126/2008 Official Journal of the European Union.Google Scholar
Fogarty, J.J. (2010). Wine investment and portfolio diversification gains. Journal of Wine Economics, 5(1), 119131.Google Scholar
Fogarty, J.J. (2006). The return to Australian fine wine. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 33(4), 542561.Google Scholar
Fogarty, J.J., and Jones, C. (2011). Return to wine: A comparison of the hedonic, repeat sales, and hybrid approaches. Australian Economic Papers, 50(4), 147156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fogarty, J.J., and Sadler, R. (2014). To save or savor: A review of approaches for measuring wine as an investment. Journal of Wine Economics, 9(3), 225248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ginsburgh, V. (1998). Absentee bidders and the declining price anomaly in wine auctions. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 13021319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golan, A., and Shalit, H. (1993). Wine quality differentials in hedonic grape pricing. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 44(2), 311321.Google Scholar
Jaeger, E. (1981). To save or savor: The rate of return to storing wine: Comment. Journal of Political Economy, 89(3), 584592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, A.M., and Zanola, R. (2010). Retransformation bias in the adjacent price index. POLIS Working Papers no. 178.Google Scholar
Jones, G.V., and Storchmann, K.H. (2001). Wine market prices and investment under uncertainty: an econometric model for Bordeaux Crus Classés. Agricultural Economics, 26(2), 115133.Google Scholar
Krasker, W.S. (1979). The rate of return to storing wine. Journal of Political Economy, 87(6), 13631367.Google Scholar
Lopomo, G. (1998). The English auction is optimal among simple sequential auctions. Journal of Economic Theory, 82(1), 144166.Google Scholar
Marsh, T., and Fischer, M. (2013). Accounting for agricultural products: U.S. versus IFRS GAAP. Journal of Business and Economics Research, 11(2), 7988.Google Scholar
Masset, P., and Henderson, C. (2010). Wine as an alternative asset class. Journal of Wine Economics, 5(1), 87118.Google Scholar
Masset, P., and Weisskopf, J. (2013). Wine as an alternative asset class. In Giraud-Heraud, E. and Pichery, M., ed., Wine Economics: Quantitative Studies and Empirical Applications. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, Ch. 9.Google Scholar
Muth, M.K, Liu, Y., Koontz, S.R., and Lawrence, J.D. (2008). Differences in prices and price risk across alternative marketing arrangements used in the fed cattle industry. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 33(1), 118135.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. (1995). Hedonic price functions and the measurement of preferences: The case of Swedish wine consumers. European Economic Review, 39(9), 16971716.Google Scholar
Oczkowski, E. (1994). A hedonic price function for Australian premium table wine. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 38(1), 93110.Google Scholar
Pagano, M., and Röell, A. (1996). Transparency and liquidity: A comparison of auction and dealer markets with informed trading. Journal of Finance, 51(2), 579611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priilaid, D.A., and van Rensburg, P. (2012). Nonlinear hedonic pricing: A confirmatory study of South African wines. International Journal of Wine Research, 4, 113.Google Scholar
Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82(1), 3455.Google Scholar
Sanning, L., Shaffer, S., and Sharratt, J.M. (2008). Bordeaux wine as a financial investment. Journal of Wine Economics, 3(1), 5171.Google Scholar
Storchmann, K. (2012). Wine economics. Journal of Wine Economics, 7(1), 133.Google Scholar
Yoo, V., Florkowski, W.J., and Carew, R. (2011). Pricing attributes of wines from emerging suppliers on the British Columbia market. Paper presented at the Agricultural & Applied Economics Association, AAEA & NAREA Joint Annual Meeting, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, July 24–26.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 List of Wine Investment Funds

Figure 1

Figure 1 Filtered Versus Classical Average Price Valuations of Mouton-Rothschild 1982

Figure 2

Figure 2 Filtered Versus Classical Average Price Valuations for Portfolio of All 232 Wines

Figure 3

Figure 3 Monthly Price Indexes of Selected Wines from the Area Between St-Estephe and Margaux, 1996 Vintage

Figure 4

Figure 4 Monthly Price Indexes of Selected Wines from Outside the Area Between St-Estephe and Margaux, 1996 Vintage

Figure 5

Figure 5 Map of the Bordeaux Region

Source: Map created by Ralf Powierski (www.info-graphic.de).
Supplementary material: File

Bocart and Hafner supplementary material

Bocart and Hafner supplementary material 1

Download Bocart and Hafner supplementary material(File)
File 335.1 KB