Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T08:43:10.404Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Parties or Portfolio? The Economic Consequences of Africa’s Big Cabinets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2015

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Does cabinet size have an impact on economic policy in Africa? The average number of ministers has increased steadily for four decades, yet we know little about the economic effects of new portfolios, despite popular complaints about costly cabinets. Comparative studies generate conflicting expectations, either blaming coalition governments for patronage or crediting them with economic restraint. Using data on 45 Sub-Saharan African countries between 1971 and 2006, our empirical analysis links parties and portfolios to budgetary policy performance. We show that cabinets with more ministries are associated with budget surpluses, but they are also slightly more likely to engage in patronage spending. Next, we find that cabinets governing through multiparty coalitions have no consistent impact on budget surpluses. However, they are strongly associated with less extractive government and lower rates of patronage spending compared with single-party cabinets. These results hold after controlling for the type of colonial legacy, economic conditions, population size, constraints on executives, level of democracy, oil income, type of party system and ethnic and religious fractionalization. We conclude that parties and portfolios are both important but they have different effects: adding portfolios to the cabinet may improve economic outcomes by enhancing specialization, but governance through multiparty cabinets generates incentives to both limit extraction and restrain patronage spending.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s). Published by Government and Opposition Limited and Cambridge University Press 2015 

Does cabinet size in Africa adversely impact economic performance? Several studies note that Africa has the largest cabinets in the world (Mwenda Reference Mwenda2011; van de Walle Reference van de Walle2001), and a large literature links institutional incentives for good policy choices to economic outcomes (Acemoglu and Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; Alence Reference Alence2004; Ndulu et al. Reference Ndulu, O’Connell, Bates, Collier and Soludo2008). Yet few studies consider the economic consequences of cabinets, even though institutional research identifies them as a critical source of variation among executives. Africans are often quite willing to create new ministries if they appear necessary to address complex problems. Nigeria created a Niger Delta portfolio in 2008 to coordinate the severe developmental challenges in its southern oil-producing region which had inspired militant rebellions. The idea of a new ministry devoted entirely to development of the northern region quickly garnered public support a few years later when a different (and even more militant rebellion) confronted the north-east (Adibe Reference Adibe2014). At the same time, citizens across the continent often complain about the financial costs of ministries. Uganda’s political parties called the cabinet formed in 2006 ‘too big’ and a ‘waste of taxpayers’ money’ (Namutebi et al. Reference Namutebi, Ariko and Nalunkuuma2006). Watchdog groups echoed these complaints in 2011 when the number of ministers grew, along with their salaries (Kaiza Reference Kaiza2011). In Kenya, when competing political parties increased the number of cabinet seats in 2008, former Member of Parliament and Nobel Prize Laureate Wangari Maathai complained that the government was ‘very expensive’ (Ogutu and Machuka Reference Ogutu and Machuka2008). Civil society groups and editorials in the press widely condemned the coalition for its cost (Bosire Reference Bosire2008). Which one of these economic narratives is more representative of the economic effects of African cabinets?

Using time-series cross-sectional data on 45 Sub-Saharan African countries between 1971 and 2006, we test the impact of two different measures of cabinet size on budgetary policy performance. When measuring cabinet size in terms of the number of ministries, statistical tests show that big cabinets are strongly associated with federal budget surpluses, and weakly correlated with increases in patronage spending. When considering cabinet size in terms of single or multiple parties, tests show that coalition governments have no systematic impact on budget surpluses, but they consistently extract less revenue and spend less on patronage. This is important since patronage is deeply entrenched in Africa’s neo-patrimonial states with strong executives (van de Walle Reference van de Walle2003), and the idea of political appointments as patronage is very much within the mainstream of the comparative literature in Africa and beyond (Arriola Reference Arriola2009; Kopecký Reference Kopecký2011). We attribute these results to the differing effects of parties and portfolios: multiparty cabinets in Africa enhance economic policy accountability by promoting horizontal monitoring across the government. Under these conditions, powerful executives have less latitude to dispense patronage and individual ministers have less leverage to demand it. Our empirical findings offer support for institutional research that highlights the benefits of coalition governments (Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012; Reynolds Reference Reynolds2011). We attribute the effects of portfolios to their role in policy specialization. The results do not mean that citizen concerns about inflated ministerial salaries are misplaced, but they do suggest that egregious examples such as Kenya and Uganda are not representative of the broader economic effects of coalition governments.

The dearth of research on African cabinets is surprising for several reasons. Cabinets are an important means of gauging how well the executive branch represents political and social diversity. Proponents of power-sharing, ‘consociationalism’, and ‘consensus government’ maintain that enhancing political representation does not adversely affect economic outcomes (Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012; Norris Reference Norris2008). This is questioned by research on post-conflict policymaking (Jarstad and Sisk Reference Jarstad and Sisk2008; Rothchild and Roeder Reference Rothchild and Roeder2005), by evidence from wealthy countries about the effects of multiparty coalition governments (Alesina et al. Reference Alesina, Roubini and Choen1997; Balassone and Giordano Reference Balassone and Giordano2001) and by costly power-sharing agreements in cases such as Kenya and Zimbabwe (Cheeseman and Tendi Reference Cheeseman and Tendi2010). Studying the consequences of cabinet size in Africa is important because it addresses these conflicting empirical findings. Moreover, as we detail below, the average number of ministries and the frequency of multiparty coalitions have increased steadily in Africa; yet it is not clear if these trends have affected economic performance.

We first review literature that identifies cabinet size as a source of critical variation among executives. Though we are interested in the consequences of cabinet size, we review existing research which attributes the growth of Africa’s cabinets to population growth, democratization, post-conflict power-sharing agreements and cultural norms of inclusion. Second, we point to conflicting evidence – mostly from wealthy countries – about the economic consequences of cabinets. Several features of African politics suggest that large cabinets will be linked to inferior economic performance, including the high transaction costs of bargaining by undisciplined parties, weak collective cabinet responsibility and strong presidential patronage systems. Third, we adopt two different measures of cabinet size and formulate predictions about how they should theoretically affect economic performance. A ‘portfolio’ hypothesis states that additional ministers will improve economic outcomes through increased policy specialization. A ‘parties’ hypothesis states that multiparty coalition governments improve economic performance through intragovernmental monitoring. Fourth, empirical tests of these hypotheses under different statistical specifications show that cabinets with more ministries are more likely to run federal budget surpluses, but they also tend to spend more on patronage. Multiparty coalition governments tell a different story: they consistently extract less revenue from citizens and they spend less money on patronage. These results remain significant even after controlling for a country’s wealth, colonial history, population size, constraints on the executive, level of democracy, oil wealth, type of party system and ethnic and religious fractionalization. Based on these results, we suggest that the numbers of parties and portfolios both influence the economic consequences of African cabinets. But since multiparty coalitions have to contend with competing interests to make policy, this increases opportunities and incentives for economic policy accountability. The conclusion points out that the results have important implications for democratization because enhancing horizontal accountability through coalition governments might chip away at the discretionary authority of dominant executives.

Executive Cabinets and African Politics

In this section we document the dramatic increase in the number of ministers in African cabinets over the last four decades and then draw upon the comparative literature to explain why parties are an essential part of understanding cabinets. Next, even though this study is focused on the effects of Africa’s growing cabinet size, we briefly review the literature examining its causes, including population growth, institutional reforms related to democratization, cultural norms of inclusion and post-conflict power-sharing agreements. All of these factors underscore the need to understand the consequences of Africa’s large cabinets.

In a 1989 essay written just before Africa’s era of dramatic democratization, a leading Nigerian political scientist noted ‘a phenomenal increase in the size of the modern cabinet’ (Osaghae Reference Osaghae1989: 129). Africa’s cabinets have in fact grown from an average of 16.5 ministries in 1971 to nearly 26.2 in 2006. Figure 1, which includes 1,561 observations from the Arthur Banks data set, illustrates this steady growth. Uganda provides one of many examples of this trend: when Yoweri Museveni took power in 1986 there were 33 ministers in his cabinet. Two decades later this number had grown to 69 ministers as he adapted to pressures to include a broader range of regional interests and ethnic groups (Tripp Reference Tripp2010: 49). ‘The cabinet is not only large but virtually useless’, said one Ugandan scholar. ‘The intention of the cabinet is to appease the head of state. It is based on the idea that when you have a huge cabinet, it is incapable of making serious decisions’ (Kiapi Reference Kiapi2010). The chair of Uganda’s parliamentary budget committee called the cabinet ‘too big for the economy’ (Osike and Olupot Reference Osike and Olupot2002), and shrinking the cabinet has been a top priority for the opposition. ‘The size of this cabinet is too big. We think it should be smaller’, said the head of the leading opposition party. ‘They have come to waste taxpayers' money yet we do not have the money’ (Namutebi et al. Reference Namutebi, Ariko and Nalunkuuma2006).

Figure 1 Average Cabinet Size, Number of Government Seats, in Africa since 1971

Source: Banks and Wilson (Reference Banks and Wilson2014).

Scholars often analyse the number of parties alongside the number of ministers because the two are closely related. Comparative research finds that the number of ministries tends to increase with the number of parties, at least when parties seek policy change (Laver and Schofield Reference Laver and Schofield1998). According to Lijphart’s seminal study (2012), the number of parties and ministries in a cabinet is the most important indicator of how representative the government is of society, and this is a central distinction between his two contrasting models of democracy, consensus and majoritarianism, which fundamentally differ in terms of the breadth of representative participation in the executive branch. In Africa, cabinets are especially important because the composition of ministries is a common gauge of the inclusiveness of government. For example, in Nigeria, the representative quality of the ministries is a ‘cardinal principle’ of government: ‘For practical politics and peaceful coexistence of diverse elements, the composition of the cabinet should reflect the diversities in a polity’ (Osaghae Reference Osaghae1989: 131). Posner’s study of Zambia (Reference Posner2005) claims that the ethnic background of cabinet ministers informs voter choice and politicians’ electoral strategies, reflecting an ethic of inclusion. Some cross-national research goes so far as to use cabinet size as a proxy variable for inclusiveness, since cabinet size correlates closely with level of ethnic diversity (Arriola Reference Arriola2009). Cabinet composition is also often used to estimate the political salience of ethnic groups or their relative access to power (Posner Reference Posner2004; Wimmer et al. Reference Wimmer, Cederman and Min2009).

At least four demonstrable factors have driven the growth of Africa’s cabinets. First, a demographic connection follows from a strong correlation between cabinet size and population size. Africa’s cabinets have apparently grown in part because the continent has experienced rapid population growth (Arriola Reference Arriola2009). This makes sense if one considers the division of labour in government expanding alongside increasing social complexity. Second, democratization in the 1990s influenced cabinet size because the return of multiparty politics ushered in a new wave of coalition governments (Oyugi Reference Oyugi2006). This is empirically reflected by the growth of multiparty coalition governments during this period: out of the 74 per cent of governments for which we have data, in 1971 less than 3 per cent were coalition governments and less than a quarter were civilian. By 2006, 55 per cent of the governments across 44 African countries governed through multiparty coalitions, and 98 per cent of all cases had civilian rulers.

Conflict resolution strategies are a third factor contributing to the size of African cabinets. The African Union formally recommends proportional representation for conflict mitigation (Murray Reference Murray2005), an electoral arrangement which increases the number of parties and the number of ministries in government. Pacts to protect the rights of sectarian interests in order to prevent backsliding into war have increased cabinet size through post-conflict power-sharing agreements in Sierra Leone (1996), the Democratic Republic of the Congo (2002 and 2003), Côte d’Ivoire (2003) and Sudan (2004). As part of its interim government, in 2006 Somalia formed a hugely oversized cabinet (Menkhaus Reference Menkhaus2008). In 2007, Sierra Leone and Côte d’Ivoire both formed governments of national unity designed to bring in former militants. In the year following each of these power-sharing agreements, the number of cabinet ministries increased. In nations tired of violence, demand for peace creates compelling incentives to form broadly inclusive governments, even if they impose financial burdens (Jarstad and Sisk Reference Jarstad and Sisk2008).

Norms of inclusion stand out as a fourth factor arguably shaping African cabinets. In Sundiata, the epic story telling the rise of Mali’s empire in the thirteenth century, the scheming half-brother of the story’s hero is ridiculed because he selfishly declares ‘power cannot be shared’ (Niane Reference Niane1965). Africa’s nationalists later embraced this sort of rhetoric. Tanzania’s Julius Nyerere believed his ‘inclusive, participatory’ model of governance with consensus building would both deepen democracy and facilitate economic growth (Baregu Reference Baregu1994). In pre-independence Nigeria, several constitutions enshrined political inclusion through ethnic balancing of the bureaucracy and the legislature’s top positions (Ekeh and Osaghae Reference Ekeh and Osaghae1989). For over half a century, dictators and democrats alike have implemented such practices. Senegal provides another example, where the discourse of democracy emphasizes the Wolof idea of demokaraasi. In this tradition, voters value conformity because it brings social security and they seek consensus because it brings stability. Including different opinions and ‘harmonizing’ them is therefore more important than alternance – alternating political power between parties (Gellar Reference Gellar2005; Schaffer Reference Schaffer1998).

In sum, the number of ministers and the frequency of coalition governments have grown dramatically since the 1970s for a variety of reasons, according to the existing literature, including population growth and post-conflict power-sharing agreements. There is also some evidence that large cabinets reflect African cultural traditions of inclusiveness. But many citizens value majoritarian qualities that promote alternating power rather than sharing it; African satisfaction with democracy in fact increases substantially after the electoral defeat of the incumbent party leads to alternation (Bratton Reference Bratton2008). Anecdotal evidence reinforces such cynicism about large cabinets. For example, in Zimbabwe, lawyers called the national unity government unconstitutional (Dube Reference Dube2009), while a spokesperson of a major party which joined the coalition said, ‘We have serious misgivings with the size of the cabinet particularly at a time when the economy is in such a bad state’ (Nyathi Reference Nyathi2009). As noted in the introduction, similar criticism erupted following Kenya’s formation of a unity government in 2008 (LeVan Reference LeVan2011). Moreover, the constitutional referendum in 2010 essentially rejected that power-sharing agreement, endorsing a largely presidential, majoritarian model of government.

All of this suggests that the literature would benefit from an empirical examination of the impact of cabinet size, and that African citizens are demanding answers. The next section clarifies our definitions and describes some comparative findings about the economic impact of cabinet size.

Are Africa’s Cabinets Cumbersome?

Complaints about big cabinets appear to be common in Africa. Yet we have few empirical studies which examine the economic effects of cabinet size outside developed countries. In this section we state our definitions of who constitutes a minister and what counts as a coalition government, drawing on the comparative literature. Next, we discuss research that comes to conflicting conclusions about the economic impact of large cabinets. On the one hand, large cabinets should undermine budgetary responsibility because policy logrolls become expensive in the aggregate. On the other hand, large cabinets could improve economic performance by making the policy process more specialized and creating new incentives for intragovernmental accountability. Finally, we identify common institutional features in Africa that make portfolio allocation especially important – and individual ministers unusually weak.

Who counts as a minister? This is important not only for operational purposes, but because it sets a threshold for determining who actually has the ability to affect spending decisions. One recent study suggests that relying on function to operationalize a definition can present more complications than departing from a legal, institutional understanding (Barbieri and Vercesi Reference Barbieri and Vercesi2013). A standard approach is to count only officials with full ministerial rank, thus excluding deputy ministers, secretaries of state, regional ministers or other officials who would add even more to these numbers (van de Walle Reference van de Walle2001). To the best of our knowledge, the Banks data set follows this definition closely. As for a multiparty coalition government, the classic understanding stems from parliamentary politics, where a coalition is a set of political parties who: (1) agree to pursue common goals; (2) pool their resources in order to achieve these goals; (3) communicate and form binding commitments concerning their goals; and (4) agree on the distribution of payoffs to be received after the coalition meets its objectives (Browne and Dreijmanis Reference Browne and Dreijmanis1982). Thus the size of the coalition derives from a direct measure of the number of political parties in the cabinet rather than from a proxy. Popular accommodation rather than elite bargaining drives coalition size. On average, this means that multiparty coalitions produce cabinets with more portfolios (Laver and Schofield Reference Laver and Schofield1998).

Arguing in favour of coalition governments in general, Lijphart argues that increasing representation in government does not require sacrificing economic performance. He stops short of definitely affirming that ‘consensus governments’, which he associates with multiparty cabinets (and other features such as federalism), perform better in terms of budget deficits and other measures of economic performance. Thus his influential study of 36 countries explicitly leaves open the door for additional empirical testing, though his results tend to support multiparty governments (Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012). South Africa provides one example of how the creation of ministries as tools of inclusion need not force a ‘tradeoff’, in Friedman’s words (Reference Friedman2004), between good government performance and democratic quality. Jacob Zuma created a slew of new ministries shortly after his election to the presidency in 2009, when the economy was contracting slightly; over the next three years macroeconomy improved, growing at 3 per cent on average and deficits dropped by about one percentage point. This might seem puzzling to those familiar with the towering (though arguably declining) presence of the African National Congress. But each new ministry was ‘shadowed’ by a corresponding oversight committee in a parliament that demonstrated autonomy by challenging the executive, and that gave opposition parties a disproportional share of committee seats (Barkan Reference Barkan2009).

Zimbabwe provides an example of how multiparty cabinets (rather than simply the number of ministers) might affect the economy. Though there is ample evidence that the coalition government formed in 2008 did little to advance democratization or to limit political violence in the long run (Lebas Reference Lebas2011), it did halt the country’s economic slide. Within two years, gross domestic product (GDP) went from a 12.5 per cent contraction to 3.5 per cent growth; government revenues increased and inflation stabilized (Africa Confidential 2010). By joining the cabinet, the opposition party, with strong roots in labour and civil society, successfully advanced some constructive economic policies despite the authoritarian practices of its coalition partner. In particular, the government’s most controversial policy, seizing white-owned farms, largely stopped after the opposition party joined the government.

By contrast, other studies find that large cabinets undermine economic performance. Van de Walle (Reference van de Walle2001), for example, points to Nigeria and Côte d’Ivoire, where big cabinets engaged in reckless levels of spending during the 1990s. One classic study reports that multiparty coalition governments are much more likely to run budget deficits (Alesina et al. Reference Alesina, Roubini and Choen1997). The World Bank explains that since coalition governments require so many compromises and payoffs, ‘fiscal outcomes are often worse than when majority governments are in power’ (World Bank 2002). Consistent with these findings, Persson and Tabellini (Reference Persson and Tabellini2003) report that majoritarian (that is, single-party) governments produce smaller deficits, regardless of whether the system is parliamentary or presidential. Wehner (Reference Wehner2010) more modestly reports that single-party cabinets can mitigate but not necessarily prevent deficit spending by reducing the conditions of partisan fragmentation. Other studies focused specifically on the number of ministries, rather than the number of parties, clearly link additional portfolios to larger budget deficits (Volkerink and de Haan Reference Volkerink and de Haan2001; Woo Reference Woo2003). Almost all of the cross-national research is limited to wealthy countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

The existing literature thus arrives at conflicting conclusions, and we know very little about the economic effects of cabinets in Africa. Cabinets could indirectly have an impact on the economy in a variety of ways, shaping the political conditions for economic growth or the ability to discipline monetary policy. But cabinets have more direct effects on public finance since they debate and shape spending priorities. For this reason it makes sense to focus on budgetary policy, particularly the impacts on revenue, spending, and the joint interaction of the two.

A causal link between cabinet size and budgetary policy could manifest itself in two ways. First, an increase in cabinet size could mean more political actors demanding resources or receiving side payments. In such situations policymaking becomes a ‘logroll’ that supplies payoffs to everyone (Strøm Reference Strøm2003). This becomes financially costly in the aggregate and appears as a strain on national budgets. Popular political parlance in Africa characterizes logrolls as sharing ‘the national cake’: politicians dividing up the spoils of the state among themselves (Gana and Egwu Reference Gana and Egwu2004; Kiapi Reference Kiapi2010). Second, large cabinets could actually limit such patronage and reduce the incentives to extract resources from citizens. ‘Public welfare is enhanced when leaders depend on a large coalition to keep them in office’, argue Bueno de Mesquita et al. ‘Under these conditions, those motivated to stay in power have no choice but to promote the public’s welfare’ (Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Morrow, Siverson and Smith2001: 71). As in Lijphart’s studies, the composition and size of the cabinet is an important component of their ‘selectorate’ theory, which focuses on the size of the eligible pool of potential rulers. Small coalitions, they say, ‘promote corruption, black marketeering, and cronyism’ (Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003: 214). Comparative institutional literature claims that such inclusive policy processes are conducive to long-term economic development (Acemoglu and Robinson Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012).

However, the number of ministers and the number of parties in the cabinet could affect these two potential outcomes quite differently. Additional ministers could increase costly demands for patronage, leading to suboptimal policy performance, or it could enhance policy specialization and technocratic capacity, leading to improvements in budgetary policy performance. Additional parties could actually be the condition driving patronage demands, along the lines of the World Bank’s comments. After all, individual ministers have less leverage to make patronage demands, and they face collective action problems that parties can resolve by lowering the costs of information and coordination (Lupia and Strøm Reference Lupia and Strøm2008). Alternatively, additional parties governing in coalitions might increase horizontal monitoring, creating a government in which executives face multiple political actors with sufficient leverage to hold them accountable for economic policy. It is therefore important to test for the impact of both ministries and parties on budgetary policy.

Before doing so, though, it is important to point out common characteristics of the institutional environment in Africa. First, executives enjoy a variety of advantages over parties. Nearly every African executive is classified as a presidential republic in which the head of state is also the head of government, or a mixed republic with a president and a prime minister; a few countries are actually monarchies or pure military states.Footnote 1 This is significant because, as Africa’s post-independence leaders noted, the collective responsibility of parliamentary government creates incentives for restraint (Hatchard et al. Reference Hatchard, Ndulo and Slinn2004: 69). Second, even in presidential systems, African executives often appoint sitting members of the legislature to the cabinet, giving them the ability to exercise tremendous power over individual ministers’ behaviour (Lindberg and Zhou Reference Lindberg and Zhou2009). Some constitutional scholars in fact argue that the level of executive discretion over cabinets corresponds with the number of ministries (Hatchard et al. Reference Hatchard, Ndulo and Slinn2004). Third, modern African political parties have very few ideological differences (Bleck and van de Walle Reference Bleck and van de Walle2011). This makes standard approaches from the American or European literature, such as the use of a left–right continuum and median voter models, less useful for understanding cabinet behaviour (and nearly impossible to estimate). In sum, given the absence of collective responsibility, the fusion of legislative and executive authority through the appointment of sitting members of the legislature, and weak ideological cleavages, African executives enjoy great latitude.

Operationalizations and Hypothesis Formulation

Whether one measures cabinet size in terms of parties or ministries, there are compelling reasons to expect either good or bad economic performance, and existing comparative research points to conflicting findings. We formulate two hypotheses to test the impact of both measures on budgetary policy performance. A ‘portfolio’ hypothesis tests to see if cabinets with more ministers improve budgetary policy performance. Confirmation of this hypothesis would suggest that additional ministries increase specialization, much like the narrative of Nigeria in the introduction suggested, whereas rejection would imply that the new portfolios are merely patronage payoffs that undermine the economy overall. A ‘parties’ hypothesis tests the record of coalitions. Support for this hypothesis would imply that multiparty governments improve budgetary policy through horizontal monitoring, as the cases from South Africa and Zimbabwe suggested. Alternatively, multiparty governments might simply engage in costly policy logrolls, similar to wealthy democracies (Alesina et al. Reference Alesina, Roubini and Choen1997; Persson and Tabellini Reference Persson and Tabellini2003). Using both measures of cabinet size is important since frustrations about cabinets in Uganda, Kenya and elsewhere are directed towards the number of ministries as a driver of economic wastefulness, while the broader comparative literature largely focused on the impact of the number of parties.

Our theory predicts that specialization through additional ministries contributes to good budgetary policy, but that cabinets also need horizontal accountability provided by multiparty coalitions to moderate the power of strong executives. Individual ministers face high transaction costs of coordination and few incentives to make demands of the executive. In coalition governments, parties help internally coordinate and articulate distinct interests. By doing so, they increase the opportunities for horizontal monitoring across government. All else being equal, multiparty coalitions should therefore have better budgetary performance overall compared with governments that simply increase the number of ministries. The capacity to conduct this monitoring, though, could be disrupted by strong executives or the absence of opposition parties. Gabon offers an example of this, where Omar Bongo ruled from 1967 to 2009. There was virtually no political party competition, and the country displayed the greatest variation in the number of ministers in our data set (fluctuating between 20 and 53 over 35 years), as portfolios served as patronage tools. In this context, neither parties nor portfolios should have much of an impact on accountability (which we will control for below). In sum, we argue that African ministers possess weak incentives and little individual capacity to demand patronage, while parties in coalition governments use their political leverage to increase accountability across government.

We measure budgetary policy performance with three different dependent variables. First, the variable budget is the federal budget surplus or deficit, expressed as a share of GDP in local currency units, similar to operationalizations adopted by Roubini and Sachs (Reference Roubini and Sachs1989a, Reference Roubini and Sachs1989b). Second, we separately test for the impact of cabinet size on revenue extraction by the central government with the variable revenue. This is also important because low government revenues could bias our variable measuring budget surpluses, and because the rate of taxation has been used in studies of Africa to link weak government capacity to state failure (Bates Reference Bates2008) or economic collapse (van de Walle Reference van de Walle2001). In a more conventional economic sense, revenue provides a test of the relationship between taxation and representation to see if more inclusive governments actually extract less revenue. Third, the variable expenditure measures government consumption as a share of GDP, which is common proxy for patronage in cross-national studies in the developing world (Arriola Reference Arriola2013). Directly measuring different categories of disaggregated spending (health, defence, and so on) would be ideal but such data are scarce in Africa, especially during the 1970s. Regardless, if cabinets allocate patronage to reward allies or buy off potential critics, this will appear in higher overall levels of spending. These three variables are from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (2012).

Control Variables

To control for different historical conditions, we include a standard dummy variable for whether a country is a former British colony. This is important because these countries tend to be associated with other political characteristics, including more majoritarian models of democracy, single-member district-plurality electoral systems and looser controls on civil society (Widner Reference Widner1994). Colonial history thus serves as an important source of variation among African political regimes (Jensen and Wantchekon Reference Jensen and Wantchekon2004). Moreover, governments moulded after the British have traditions of weaker central banks, which often affects economic planning through inflationary policies. A value of 1 on the Britcol variable indicates a former British colony.

Since a variety of studies document linkages between societal heterogeneity and suboptimal economic performance (Easterly and Levine Reference Easterly and Levine1997; Habyarimana et al. Reference Habyarimana, Humphreys, Posner and Weinstein2009), we include the variables EthnicF and ReligiousF for the level of ethnic and religious fractionalization, respectively, from Norris’ (Reference Norris2008) data set. Population size could also have an impact on economic policy bargaining. Populations in smaller countries face lower costs of ‘exit’, thus generating incentives to compromise (Teorell Reference Teorell2010). We therefore include the natural log of the population as the variable Logpop.

We also include the variable GrowthGDP, measuring the rate of economic growth in GDP per capita, from the World Development Indicators. This control is important because economic outcomes could be endogenous to the level of development. Outside Africa, poor economic conditions also tend to affect the number of ministries, increasing them (Verzichelli Reference Verzichelli2008). This variable reflects the tremendous variation in African countries: larger economies might require a more complex division of labour managed through additional ministries or broader debates among different economic interests represented by various parties. Perhaps most importantly, we include GrowthGDP because a large literature linking economic cycles to political institutions departs from the notion that the short-term nature of politicians’ self-interest interferes with the extended time horizon conducive to formulating sound macroeconomic policies – notably balanced budgets (Franzese Reference Franzese2002). Policy analyses of Europe’s recent financial crisis, however, are challenging this view, arguing that institutional constraints (such as balanced budget rules), as well as polarized political conditions that inspire ideological commitments to fiscal discipline, often create incentives for politicians to invest in the future rather than their short-term interests (Posner and Blondal Reference Posner and Blondal2012). For our purposes, patronage could be plentiful, and revenue collection might increase, under favourable economic conditions captured by this variable. We also include the variable oil rent from Jensen and Wantchekon (Reference Jensen and Wantchekon2004) to incorporate economies that benefit from natural resources; where government consumption may rise during commodity price booms, the government typically taxes citizens at lower rates. Agriculture-based economies in Africa generally have greater revenue extraction (Englebert and Dunn Reference Englebert and Dunn2013).

We also include variables to control for various political conditions. The variable xconstrain, from the Database of Political Institutions, measures checks on executive authority (Keefer and Stasavage Reference Keefer and Stasavage2003). A value of 1 indicates that the chief executive has virtually unlimited authority, while a value of 5 signals significant limitations and constraints on unilateral action. This variable controls for the possibility that non-democratic regimes with small cabinets contaminate the results by making a false case for coalition governments: dictatorships with large cabinets might perform well. This is especially relevant since some of our sample precede the democratization of the 1990s. Recent research claims that consolidation of executive authority had unclear implications for economic performance in Africa between 1960 and 2000. Whereas authoritarianism improved economic performance in some South-East Asian cases, precisely the opposite was the case in Africa, where checks on executive authority and high levels of democracy corresponded with high rates of economic growth (Ndulu et al. Reference Ndulu, O’Connell, Bates, Collier and Soludo2008). The variable also accounts for the possibility of cabinets operating without effective legislatures, as well as non-democratic regimes that operate without parties. To more explicitly control for democracy, LiberalDemocracy is based on the Freedom House 100-point scale, with a higher value indicating greater democracy. We further include a civilian dummy variable to control for the possibility that it is not simply dictatorship, but military dictatorships specifically that matter with regard to the executive (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Koonings and Kruijt Reference Koonings and Kruijt2002). Finally, to accommodate for the possibility outlined earlier in the example from Gabon, where weak parties have little bargaining power and the ruler can arbitrarily create or abolish ministries, a positive value on the variable SingleParty indicates one-party rule and minimal fragmentation in the party system.Footnote 2

Hypotheses Testing Portfolios and Parties

Our ‘portfolio’ hypothesis states that additional ministries contribute to economic performance by increasing policy specialization. If so, we would expect to see federal budget surpluses (or lower deficits) indicated by positive coefficients on the budget variable, lower rates of extraction indicated by negative coefficients on revenue, and less government consumption indicated by negative coefficients on expenditure.Footnote 3 Alternatively, if governments with more portfolios engage in policy logrolls to share the national cake, then we expect to observe budget deficits as ministers collude with each other. This is essentially what the European literature suggests. Bjørn Volkerink and Jakob de Haan (2001), for example, found that across 22 OECD countries between 1971 and 1996, one additional minister increased the budget deficit by 0.08 per cent. Fiscal indiscipline that borrows from the future would contribute to inflationary policies and higher rates of extraction (indicated by positive values on the revenue variable). This pattern of results would further imply that individual ministers have some leverage to demand patronage, which would correspond with positive coefficients on expenditure. We measure the number of portfolios using the ministries variable, illustrated earlier in Figure 1.

Our ‘parties’ hypothesis states that coalition governments enhance budgetary policy performance. These multiparty governments increase the inclusiveness of policymaking and promote horizontal accountability. This intergovernmental monitoring should enable governments to restrain spending, yielding budget surpluses without necessarily increasing extractive tax policies. Most importantly, horizontal accountability should reduce logrolled patronage spending, visible as negative coefficients on expenditure. We test this hypothesis with coalition, a dummy variable created from the Arthur Banks data set, recoded so that 1 indicates a multiparty coalition cabinet and 0 indicates a one-party government. From a research design point of view, a continuous variable directly measuring the exact number of parties would be ideal and would also enable us to interact it with the ministries variable. Unfortunately, African data on parties are limited: the best available data set has no information prior to 1989 (Lindberg Reference Lindberg2006), and our construction of a new variable using Elections in Africa (Nohlen et al. Reference Nohlen, Krennerich and Thibaut1999) yielded too many gaps and fewer data points than Banks. Until African countries have experienced more electoral democracy, and such sources have been updated, we believe a dummy variable is a reasonable alternative; majoritarian democracies (‘power concentrating’ in Lijphart’s terms) tend to govern through a single party anyway, and our current approach enabled us to include authoritarian governments in the 1970s and 1980s that included parties.

Coalition governments on average have five more ministries (25.4) than single-party governments (20.5),Footnote 4 and the t-test shows there is a statistically significant difference. This suggests an implicit interaction between the cabinet and ministries variables. Our sample includes 45 African countries between 1971 and 2006 for a total of 1,560 observations. This includes 335 instances of coalition governments. Correlation analysis (not shown) implies that cabinets with more ministries tend to run budget surpluses, extract less revenue and engage in lower levels of government consumption. Bivariate association tests for coalition governments suggest that they run smaller budget deficits, collect less revenue and spend less on government consumption compared with single-party governments.

Empirical Tests for Portfolios and Parties

We perform regression analysis to obtain OLS coefficient estimates with panel corrected standard errors for each of our dependent variables (budget, revenue and expenditure).Footnote 5 This is an appropriate technique since the data contain fewer years than cases cross-sectionally. Consistent results across different models is a standard econometric check for robustness (Greene Reference Greene2008). We first test our hypotheses on budget as the dependent variable as specified in Equation 1:

$$\eqalignno{ Budget_{{it}} = & a_{i} {\plus}\beta _{1} Ministries_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{2} Coalition_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{3} {LiberalDemocracy}{\plus}\beta _{4} Xconstrain_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{5} Britcol_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{6} GrowthGDP_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{7} Oilrent_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{8} LogPop_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{9} EthnicF_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{{10}} {\mathop{Re}\nolimits} ligiousF_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{{11}} Civilian_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{{12}} SingleParty{\plus}e_{{it}} $$

Table 1 reports regression results testing the model under different statistical specifications. The positive coefficients on the ministries variable across all models indicate that cabinets with more portfolios are more likely to run a budget surplus. One additional cabinet member implies a 0.2 to 0.3 per cent larger surplus (or a smaller deficit). The coalition variable has a significant effect on budget in one of the models, where coalition governments run deficits of about 2.2 per cent. The presence of electoral democracy in Africa reduces the budget deficit by 0.1 per cent, at a statistically significant level according to all models. Executive constraints do not have a statistically significant effect on budget. Governments in former British colonies are more likely to run a larger surplus (or smaller deficits) on average between 2 and 3.4 percentage points. The effect of overall economic conditions on the budget is positive and significant in Models 3 and 4: each percentage of GDP growth reduces the budget deficit by 0.1 per cent. In Models 2, 3 and 4, countries with oil revenue appear to run a budget surplus of about 0.1 per cent for each additional 1 per cent of oil rent per GDP increase. The significance of SingleParty suggests that party polarization has an adverse impact on budget surpluses; the same goes for ethnic but interestingly not religious fractionalization. Civilian government has no statistically significant impact. The results thus far point to statistically significant support for the portfolio hypothesis, suggesting that additional ministries enhance budgetary specialization, but they neither support nor refute the parties hypothesis, since coalition governments have a very weak effect on the budget variable.

Table 1 Dependent Variable Budget (budget surplus/deficit as share of GDP)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses. *, **, *** denote significance at the 5%, 1%, 0.1% level, respectively.

The second test of our hypotheses considers the effects of cabinet size on revenues, to see if large cabinets are more extractive. These tests also allow us to ensure that the results with the budget variable were not biased by lower revenue collection. In Equation 2, Revenue it is the government revenue of the ith country collected at the tth year:

$$\openup -1pt \eqalignno{ {\mathop{Re}\nolimits} venue_{{it}} = & a_{i} {\plus}\beta _{1} Ministries_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{2} Coalition_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{3} {LiberalDemocracy}{\plus}\beta _{4} Xconstrain_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{5} Britcol_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{6} GrowthGDP_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{7} LogPop_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{8} Oilrent{\plus}\beta _{9} EthnicF_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{{10}} {\mathop{Re}\nolimits} ligiousF_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{{11}} Civilian_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{{12}} SingleParty{\plus}e_{{it}} $$

The estimation results of Equation 2 are displayed in Table 2. The statistically insignificant values on ministries mean that cabinets with more portfolios do not extract more revenue through higher tax rates or more zealous collection. In relation to the previous tests, this means that the good performance on the budget variable is actually being underwritten by fiscal discipline, rather than extractive policies. At the same time, coalition governments systematically extract less: specifically, they collect on average 6.2 to 7.7 per cent less revenue as a share of the GDP in Models 2, 3 and 4. In terms of our controls, democracies collect on average 0.1 per cent more revenues. Stronger executive constraints are also associated with higher tax rates or better tax collection, ranging between 1 and 1.1 percentage points on revenue. These two control variables suggest an implicit relationship between democracy and taxation in Africa, whether it is measured in terms of horizontal accountability (captured by the Xconstrain variable) or electoral democracy. The control for British colonies is significant, indicating that these countries extract 1.8 to 2.6 additional percentage points more in Models 1 and 2. Countries with oil revenue appear to collect on average more budget revenues by about 0.3 and 0.4 per cent extra revenues for each additional 1 per cent of oil rent per GDP. Increased ethnic fractionalization unsurprisingly reduces the revenues collected by around 15 per cent, according to Models 3 and 4. But as in the tests with Equation 1, religious fractionalization is an insignificant factor. Civilian governments – whether dictatorships or democracies – extract on average 3.1 per cent more revenue. This time, single-party governments have no significant impact, most likely because rulers who want to avoid open multiparty competition see political risks in extracting too much from citizens. In sum, since coalition governments systematically extract less from citizens, this supports the idea that parties rather than simply portfolio promote good budgetary policy.

Table 2 Dependent Variable Revenue (government revenue, excluding grants, as a share of GDP)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses. *, **, *** denote significance at the 5%, 1%, 0.1% level, respectively.

The third test of our hypotheses considers the effects of cabinet size on government consumption as a share of GDP, which we use as a proxy for patronage. If additional ministers or parties increase the overall level of patronage, this will be visible as positive coefficients on the expenditure variable, suggesting these governments engage in policy logrolls to satisfy everyone. However, if new ministries increase specialization, or if coalition governments increase horizontal accountability as parties monitor each other, then government consumption will decline. In Equation 3, expenditure it is government expenditure of the ith country during the tth year:

$$\eqalignno{ Expenditure_{{it}} = & a_{i} {\plus}\beta _{1} Ministries_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{2} Coalition_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{3} LiberalDemocracy{\plus}\beta _{4} Xconstrain_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{5} Britcol_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{6} GrowthGDP_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{7} LogPop_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{8} Oilrent{\plus}B_{8} EthnicF_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{9} {\mathop{Re}\nolimits} ligiousF_{{it}} {\plus}\beta _{{10}} Civilian_{{it}} \cr & {\plus}\beta _{{12}} SingleParty{\plus}e_{{it}} $$

The estimation results of Equation 3 are displayed in Table 3. There is weak evidence in Model 3 that each additional ministry results in 0.2 percentage points more government expenditure as a percentage of GDP. The insignificant coefficients of ministries in the other models offer no support for the portfolio hypothesis. By contrast, multiparty coalition governments systematically have lower rates of government consumption at a statistically significant level. Specifically, coalition governments on average spent 5.4 to 6.2 per cent less as a share of the GDP in Models 2, 3 and 4. The level of democracy is not statistically significant in any of the models. Stronger executive constraints are associated with increases in patronage spending, ranging between 0.9 and 1.4 percentage points across all four models at a statistically significant level. Taken together, the results with these two controls suggest that it is specifically parties in government, rather than other mechanisms of horizontal accountability (or electoral democracy) that restrains patronage spending. The population control in Model 2 suggests that a 1 per cent population increase may increase the government spending by an 0.9 additional percentage points. Ethnic fractionalization appears to reduce government consumption spending between 6.9 and 8.2 per cent, as suggested by estimates from Models 3 and 4. On the face of it, this seems odd. However, it may suggest that in Africa’s highly heterogeneous nations, there are significant transaction costs involved in colluding across ethnic groups in order to distribute patronage. British colonial history, religious fractionalization, civilian and single-party governance have no statistically significant impact in any of the models. In sum, rather than engaging in policy logrolls through collusion, coalition governments reduce the level of patronage spending through horizontal monitoring, offering strong support for our parties hypothesis.

Table 3 Dependent Variable Expenditure (government expenditure, as a share of GDP)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses. *, **, *** denote significance at the 5%, 1%, 0.1% level, respectively.

These three sets of tests show that cabinet size affects budgetary policy in Africa, but that it is important to analyse parties alongside ministries. There is evidence that additional ministries increase policy specialization, along the lines of the example from Nigeria mentioned in the introduction, since these governments are associated with budget surpluses. But significantly, the absence of a strong relationship with the expenditure variable suggests that ministers possess neither the leverage to demand patronage for themselves, nor the resources to dispense it on a significant level. Coalition governments, though, extract less and spend less, suggesting that multiparty cabinets are both less predatory towards citizens and less likely to indulge in patronage spending. The results hold across a broad range of controls.

Based on these results, we argue that the impact of Africa’s cabinets on budgetary policy depends more on parties than portfolio. We have no trouble accepting the idea that cabinet appointments serve as important patronage tools for executives, as others claim (Arriola Reference Arriola2009; van de Walle Reference van de Walle2001). But our results show that ministers acting as individuals face significant collective action problems, and the mere presence of a multiparty system, measured by the SingleParty variable, does little to overcome these barriers. Africa’s executives seek an efficient coalition that affords them political latitude, and multiparty coalition governments can limit executive discretion by lowering the transaction costs of horizontal accountability across the government. In this way, they may serve as useful stepping stones – until political competition is more robust – to improved economic outcomes.

Conclusion

African cabinet size has been increasing since the early 1970s due to factors such as democratization, post-conflict power-sharing and population growth. Yet we have virtually no comparative research about the economic consequences of this striking empirical trend. Looking at both the number of parties and portfolios in cabinets, we found that creating new ministries improved budgetary discipline, a relationship that we attributed to increased governmental specialization. There is weak evidence that multiparty coalition cabinets contribute to budget deficits, rather than surpluses. However, these cabinets do systematically extract less and spend less. These results hold even after controlling for colonial history, economic conditions, checks on executive authority, level of democracy, population size, civilian government, oil income, type of party system and ethnic and religious divisions.

One possible implication of our findings is that until electoral competition increases in Africa, multiparty governments just might contribute to democratization by restraining executive authority in the interim. We hope to test this directly in future research with additional data on alternation of power and perhaps the internal dynamics of parties. Our findings also inform classic debates about the benefits of ‘consensus’ models of democracy associated with multiparty coalition governments and power-sharing through portfolio allocations. Sceptics have reported correlations between coalition governments and weak fiscal discipline, including budget deficits (Persson and Tabellini Reference Persson and Tabellini2003; Voigt Reference Voigt2011). By contrast, proponents of consensus democracy have argued there is no tradeoff between broad-based governments that enhance political inclusion and economic performance (Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012; Norris Reference Norris2008; Reynolds Reference Reynolds2011). Hardly any of this cross-national research has focused on Africa, though, and we find little support for sceptics of coalition governments who associate them with deficits in OECD countries. Instead, our analysis of a complex set of 45 cases over four decades suggests that the proponents of consensus government may be right.

At least three important caveats are in order. First, anecdotal evidence suggests that cabinets with a large number of ministries are wasteful, and there is no denying this in egregious cases such as Uganda, Kenya and Gabon. Our results are hardly an endorsement for big salaries or new unnecessary ministries and instead make a subtle case for a combination of expertise and horizontal accountability. In addition, although cases such as Zimbabwe and Gabon provide some details about how cabinet size has an impact on bargaining, we appreciate that much richer qualitative research is needed to clarify the causal mechanisms we identified inductively. As the third wave of democratization turns 25 years old in Africa, new cohorts of former politicians are waiting to tell their stories to field researchers. Third, though government consumption is a valid – and common – measure of patronage, we hope to have access to different categories of government spending for future research. This would enable a study of how competing preferences within cabinets affect budgetary policy priorities – for example, by shifting spending from sectors such as defence to social sector programmes that are more popular to aspiring political candidates. In conclusion, given the importance of parties for understanding the impact of portfolio, we hope our findings contribute to new research about these critical African institutions: their internal dynamics, their potential to either promote or restrain patronage, and their bargaining behaviour across a broad range of regimes.

Acknowledgement

The authors would like to thank the US Agency for International Development and American University’s Africa Council for funding and inspiring this article’s initial draft, presented at a workshop on ‘The Consequences of Political Inclusion in Africa’. Subsequent drafts were presented at the Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meeting 2010, the African Studies Association Annual Meeting 2013, and at the Centre for Democracy and Development in Abuja. We are especially grateful for comments from Leonardo Arriola, Nic van de Walle, Cullen Hendrix, Staffan Lindberg, Ian Spears, Peter Lewis, Kaare Strøm, Ben Nyblade, and two anonymous reviewers for this journal. Katie Mattern, Yoonbin Ha and Martina Hanulova diligently assisted with research.

Footnotes

*

A. Carl LeVan is Assistant Professor in the School of International Service at American University, Washington, DC. Contact email: levan@american.edu; Twitter: @Dev4Security.

Assen Assenov is Associate Director for Research Support at American University, Washington, DC. Contact email: assenov@american.edu.

1 Cross-Polity Time-Series Database, State University of New York-Binghamton, www.databanks.sitehosting.net.

2 A table displaying summary statistics is available at http://carllevan.com.

3 More nuanced measures of expenditure, such as military spending or public investment, are not available consistently across countries and years.

4 This is consistent with Laver and Schofield’s (Reference Laver and Schofield1998) comparative research in Europe that demonstrates a growth in ministries as the number of parties in government increases.

5 Our data have more cross-unit (countries) relative to the time periods and panel generalized least square (GLS) estimates are not feasible (N<T is required for feasibility of GLS estimates); see Beck and Katz (Reference Beck and Katz1995). We used Stata xtpcse command to produce robust estimates with standard errors that are robust to disturbances being correcting for heteroscedasticity, contemporaneously cross-sectionally correlated and autocorrelated of type AR(1). In addition, in order to eliminate the impact of outliers, we eliminated the extreme values of the dependent variables. In particular, we excluded observations with the values of expenditure or revenue share of GDP higher than 0.7 and observation with the annual inflation rate higher than 100 per cent.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (New York: Random House).Google Scholar
Adibe, J. (2014), ‘Boko Haram in Nigeria: The Way Forward’, Africa in Focus, www.brookings.edu/blogs/africa-in-focus/posts/2014/05/14-boko-haram-nigeria-adibe.Google Scholar
Africa Confidential (2010), ‘Zimbabwe: Economic Clouds, Platinum Lining’, Africa Confidential, 51(3): 2.Google Scholar
Alence, R. (2004), ‘Political Institutions and Developmental Governance in Africa’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 42(2): 163187.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Roubini, N. and Choen, G.D. (1997), Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Arriola, L. (2009), ‘Patronage and Political Stability in Africa’, Comparative Political Studies, 42(10): 13391362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriola, L. (2013), Multi-ethnic Coalitions in Africa: Business Financing of Opposition Election Campaigns (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Banks, A.S. and Wilson, K.A. (2014), Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive (Jerusalem: Databanks International), www.databanksinternational.com.Google Scholar
Balassone, F. and Giordano, R. (2001), ‘Budget Deficits and Coalition Governments’, Public Choice, 106: 327349.Google Scholar
Barbieri, C. and Vercesi, M. (2013), ‘The Cabinet: A Viable Definition and its Composition in View of a Comparative Analysis’, Government and Opposition, 48(3): 526547.Google Scholar
Baregu, M. (1994), ‘The Rise and Fall of the One-Party State in Tanzania’, in J.A. Widner (ed.), Economic Change and Political Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press): 158181.Google Scholar
Barkan, J.D. (2009), ‘South Africa: Emerging Legislature or Rubber Stamp?’, in J.D. Barkan (ed.), Legislative Power in Emerging African Democracies (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner): 205229.Google Scholar
Bates, R.H. (2008), When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Africa (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Beck, N. and Katz, J.N. (1995), ‘What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Sectional Data’, American Political Science Review, 89: 634647.Google Scholar
Bleck, J. and van de Walle, N. (2011), ‘Parties and Issues in Francophone West Africa: Towards a Theory of Non-mobilization’, Democratization, 18(5): 11251145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bosire, B. (2008), ‘Kenyans Say Jumbo Coalition Cabinet a Colossal Waste’, Agence France Presse, 4 April 2008.Google Scholar
Bratton, M. (2008), ‘The “Alternation Effect” in Africa’, in L. Diamond and M.F. Plattner (eds), How People View Democracy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press): 117128.Google Scholar
Browne, E.C. and Dreijmanis, J. (1982) (eds), Government Coalitions in Western Democracies (New York: Longman).Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R. and Smith, A. (2001), ‘Political Competition and Economic Growth’, Journal of Democracy, 12(1): 5772.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R.M. and Morrow, J.D. (2003), The Logic of Political Survival (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheeseman, N. and Tendi, B.-M. (2010), ‘Power-Sharing in Comparative Perspective: The Dynamics of “Unity Government” in Kenya and Zimbabwe’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 48(2): 203229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dube, L. (2009), ‘Appointment of Additional Ministers Unconstitutional’, Zimbabwe Independent, 6 March 2009.Google Scholar
Easterly, W. and Levine, R. (1997), ‘Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 12031250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekeh, P.P. and Osaghae, E. (1989) (eds), Federal Character and Federalism in Nigeria (Ibadan: Heinemann Educational).Google Scholar
Englebert, P. and Dunn, K.C. (2013), Inside African Politics (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner).Google Scholar
Franzese, R.J. (2002), ‘Economic and Partisan Cycles in Economic Policies and Outcomes’, Annual Review of Political Science, 5: 369421.Google Scholar
Friedman, S. (2004), ‘South Africa: Building Democracy after Apartheid’, in E. Gymiah-Boadi (ed.), Democratic Reform in Africa: The Quality of Progress (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner): 235261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gana, A.T. and Egwu, S.G. (2004) (eds), Federalism in Africa: The Imperative of Democratic Development (Trenton, NJ: Africa World Press).Google Scholar
Gandhi, J. (2008), Political Institutions under Dictatorship (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Gellar, S. (2005), Democracy in Senegal: Tocquevillian Analytics in Africa (New York: Palgrave Macmillan).Google Scholar
Greene, W.H. (2008), Econometric Analysis (New York: Prentice Hall).Google Scholar
Habyarimana, J., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. and Weinstein, J.M. (2009), Coethnicity: Diversity and the Dilemmas of Collective Action (New York: Russell Sage Foundation).Google Scholar
Hatchard, J., Ndulo, M. and Slinn, P. (2004), Comparative Constitutionalism and Good Governance in the Commonwealth: An Eastern and Southern African Perspective (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Jarstad, A. and Sisk, T. (2008) (eds), From War to Democracy: Dilemmas of Peacebuilding (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Jensen, N. and Wantchekon, L. (2004), ‘Resource Wealth and Political Regimes in Africa’, Comparative Political Studies, 37(7): 816841.Google Scholar
Kaiza, D. (2011), ‘Uganda: Steep Price of Democracy: How its Politics is Ruining Uganda’s Economy’, East African, 7 March 2011.Google Scholar
Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2003), ‘The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy’, American Political Science Review, 97(3): 407420.Google Scholar
Kiapi, E.M. (2010), ‘Uganda: Sharing the National Cake’, Inter-Press News Service, 22 January 2010.Google Scholar
Koonings, K. and Kruijt, D. (2002) (eds), Political Armies: The Military and Nation Building in the Age of Democracy (London: Zed Books).Google Scholar
Kopecký, P. (2011), ‘Political Competition and Party Patronage: Public Appointments in Ghana and South Africa’, Political Studies, 59(3): 713732.Google Scholar
Laver, M.J. and Schofield, N. (1998), Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Lebas, A. (2011), From Protest to Parties: Party-Building and Democratization in Africa (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
LeVan, A.C. (2011), ‘Power Sharing and Inclusive Politics in Africa’s Uncertain Democracies’, Governance: A Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions, 24(1): 3153.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (2012), Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (New Haven: Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Lindberg, S.I. (2006) (ed.), Democracy and Elections in Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Lindberg, S.I. and Zhou, Y. (2009), ‘Co-optation Despite Democratization in Ghana’, in J. Barkan (ed.), Legislative Power in Emerging African Democracies (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner): 147175.Google Scholar
Lupia, A. and Strøm, K. (2008), ‘Bargaining, Transaction Costs, and Coalition Governance’, in K. Strøm, W. Muller and T. Bergman (eds), Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe (Oxford: Oxford University Press): 85122.Google Scholar
Menkhaus, K. (2008), ‘Somalia: Governance vs. Statebuilding’, in C. Call (ed.), Building States to Build Peace (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner): 187215.Google Scholar
Murray, R. (2005), Human Rights in Africa: From the OAU to the AU (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Mwenda, A. (2011), ‘Uganda Has 3rd Largest Cabinet in the World’, The Independent, 19 January 2011.Google Scholar
Namutebi, J., Ariko, C. and Nalunkuuma, M. (2006), ‘Opposition Slams Big Cabinet’, New Vision, 2 June 2006.Google Scholar
Ndulu, B.J., O’Connell, S.A., Bates, R.H., Collier, P. and Soludo, C. (2008) (eds), The Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960–2000 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Niane, D.T. (1965), Sundiata: An Epic of Old Mali (New York: Pearson Longman).Google Scholar
Nohlen, D., Krennerich, M. and Thibaut, B. (1999), Elections in Africa: A Data Handbook (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Norris, P. (2008), Driving Democracy: Do Power-Sharing Institutions Work? (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyathi, K. (2009), ‘Outrage Over 71 Ministers’, The Standard, 22 February 2009.Google Scholar
Ogutu, E. and Machuka, M. (2008), ‘New Cabinet a Burden, Say Accountants’, The Standard, 4 April 2008.Google Scholar
Osaghae, E.E. (1989), ‘The Federal Cabinet, 1951–1984’, in P. Ekeh and E. Osaghae (eds), Federal Character and Federalism in Nigeria (Ibadan: Heinemann Educational): 128163.Google Scholar
Osike, F. and Olupot, M. (2002), ‘Uganda: MPs Want Cabinet Cut’, New Vision, 17 July 2002.Google Scholar
Oyugi, W. (2006), ‘Coalition Politics and Governments in Africa’, Journal of Contemporary African Studies, 24(1): 5379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2003), The Economic Effects of Constitutions (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, D. (2004), ‘Measuring Ethnic Fractionalization in Africa’, American Journal of Political Science, 48(4): 849863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, D. (2005), Institutions and Ethnic Politics in Africa (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, P. and Blondal, J. (2012), ‘Democracies and Deficits: Prospects for Fiscal Responsibility in Democratic Nations’, Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions, 25(1): 1134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, A. (2011), Designing Democracy in a Dangerous World (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Rothchild, D. and Roeder, P. (2005), ‘Dilemmas of State-Building in Divided Societies’, in P. Roeder and D. Rothchild (eds), Sustainable Peace: Power and Democracy after Civil Wars (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press): 126.Google Scholar
Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989a), ‘Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries’, Economic Policy, 8: 99132.Google Scholar
Roubini, N. and Sachs, J. (1989b), ‘Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Economies’, European Economic Review, 33: 903938.Google Scholar
Schaffer, F.C. (1998), Democracy in Translation: Understanding Politics in an Unfamiliar Culture (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Strøm, K. (2003), ‘Parliamentary Democracy and Delegation’, in K. Strøm, W.C. Müller and T. Bergman (eds), Delegation and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracies (Oxford: Oxford University Press): 55108.Google Scholar
Teorell, J. (2010), Determinants of Democratization: Explaining Regime Change in the World, 1972–2006 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Tripp, A.M. (2010), Museveni’s Uganda: Paradoxes of Power in a Hybrid Regime (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner).Google Scholar
van de Walle, N. (2001), African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979–1999 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van de Walle, N. (2003), ‘Presidentialism and Clientelism in Africa’s Emerging Party Systems’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 41(2): 297321.Google Scholar
Verzichelli, L. (2008), ‘Porfolio Allocation’, in K. Strom, W.C. Muller and T. Bergman (eds), Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe (Oxford: Oxford University Press): 237268.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (2011), ‘Empirical Constitutional Economics: Onward and Upward?’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 80(2): 319330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volkerink, B. and de Haan, J. (2001), ‘Fragmented Government Effects on Fiscal Policy: New Evidence’, Public Choice, 109(3–4): 221242.Google Scholar
Wehner, J. (2010), ‘Cabinet Structure and Fiscal Policy Outcomes’, European Journal of Political Research, 49: 631653.Google Scholar
Widner, J.A. (ed.) (1994), Economic Change and Political Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Wimmer, A., Cederman, L.-E. and Min, B. (2009), ‘Ethnic Politics and Armed Conflict: A Configurational Analysis of a New Global Data Set’, American Sociological Review, 74: 316337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woo, J. (2003), ‘Economic, Political, and Institutional Determinants of Public Deficits’, Journal of Public Economics, 87: 387426.Google Scholar
World Bank (2002), World Development Report 2002: Building Institutions for Markets (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
World Bank (2012), World Development Indicators (Washington, DC: World Bank).Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Average Cabinet Size, Number of Government Seats, in Africa since 1971Source: Banks and Wilson (2014).

Figure 1

Table 1 Dependent Variable Budget (budget surplus/deficit as share of GDP)

Figure 2

Table 2 Dependent Variable Revenue (government revenue, excluding grants, as a share of GDP)

Figure 3

Table 3 Dependent Variable Expenditure (government expenditure, as a share of GDP)