Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T18:56:46.895Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Money and modernization in early modern England

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 March 2019

Nuno Palma*
Affiliation:
University of Manchester and CEPR
*
N. Palma, Department of Economics, University of Manchester, Oxford Road, Manchester m13 9pl, UK; email: nuno.palma@manchester.ac.uk; and Research Affiliate, Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Classic accounts of the English industrial revolution present a long period of stagnation followed by a fast take-off. However, recent findings of slow but steady per capita economic growth suggest that this is a historically inaccurate portrait of early modern England. This growth pattern was in part driven by specialization and structural change accompanied by an increase in market participation at both the intensive and extensive levels. These, I argue, were supported by the gradual increase in money supply made possible by the importation of precious metals from America. They enabled a substantial increase in the monetization and liquidity levels of the economy, hence decreasing transaction costs, increasing market thickness, changing the relative incentive for participating in the market and allowing agglomeration economies to arise. By making trade with Asia possible, precious metals also induced demand for new desirable goods, which in turn encouraged market participation. Finally, the increased monetization and market participation made tax collection easier. This helped the government to build up fiscal capacity and as a consequence to provide for public goods. The structural change and increased market participation that ensued paved the way for modernization.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2019 

I

The modernization of early modern England was facilitated by large-scale monetary injections, which resulted from the discovery of precious metals in America. These injections interacted positively with certain characteristics of the northwestern European economies. In this article, I explain how the increased monetization and liquidity made possible by the arrival of precious metals from America buttressed early growth patterns in England.

Figure 1 illustrates the scale of the English monetary injection in aggregate terms.Footnote 1 The figure shows that prices simply failed to keep up with the enormous increase in per capita coin supply.Footnote 2 The long-run evidence for England clearly contradicts a quantity-theory interpretation of the evolution of prices over the long run. The nominal coin stock increased by a factor of 22, from about £2 million in 1550 to £44 million by 1790, but the price level failed to keep up with even such a narrow measure of the money supply, having less than tripled over the same period. Consequently, real coin supply per capita increased from £1 to £1.5 in the 1550s to nearly £5 by the early 1790s (at constant prices of 1700).

Sources: Coin supply adjusted from Palma (Reference Palma2018); the price level is the GDP deflator of Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015).

Figure 1. Coin supply and price level, 1550–1790

The increased monetization of the English economy combined with other historical developments over the early modern period to decrease the cost of participating in markets. This in turn led to more specialization through division of labor, and to labor expansion on the intensive and extensive margins. The greater ease in making and receiving payments meant that it became easier for firms to pay the wage bill and for people to work additional days – one feature of the early modern industrious revolution.Footnote 3

Why was expanding the money supply historically difficult? The early modern monetary system was a commodity money system.Footnote 4 In this system, monetary authorities had only two ways of expanding the official (legal tender) money supply, which during the early modern period was by far the most important component of high-powered money supply (M0). The first was to debase the currency.Footnote 5 This policy tool was constrained by the equilibrium responses of private agents to mint policy, as well as competition with foreign mints (Sargent and Velde Reference Sargent and Velde2002). The only remaining possibility was to have access to new sources of bullion, through either mining or trade, as this was the critical input in the production of specie.Footnote 6 Monetary policy was conducted by means of the monetary authority setting the mint price at which private agents could coin currency from bullion, after payment of a seigniorage fee. For this, precious metals needed to be available.

As the major input in the production of specie was bullion, and since the latter was offered in inelastic supply, money supply was inelastic as well. The limited availability of precious metals meant that mint policies were restricted by equilibrium in the international bullion market. Furthermore, each coin's face value was greater than the market value of its metal content, because of the extra exchange service that each coin provided. Assaying costs were also relatively higher for smaller denominations. These restrictions, together with the indivisibility problem generated by the physical properties of commodity money (discussed in Section ii), constrained the issue of low-denomination specie.

Taken together, these restrictions led to a higher bound in the effective money that could be supplied by a monetary authority at a given moment, indexed by the availability of precious metals. From the mid fifteenth century to about 1520, the exploration of the West African coast by the Portuguese brought gold to Europe at a lower cost than had been previously possible with the trans-Saharan caravan trade. This can reasonably be described as an endogenous development and it is hard to say whether or not the increase in supply through this means was offset by relative decline in the North African caravan route. These gold injections were also of moderate quantities when measured at a European level. During the early fifteenth century there was also increasing production of silver in Burgundy, Saxony and Bohemia, and associated technical change made silver available at a lower cost than had been previously possible (Cipolla Reference Cipolla1993, pp. 174–5). But during the early modern period, Europe experienced monetary injections of unprecedented magnitude.

The availability of great quantities of precious metals in America was critical in allowing the European money supply to expand as it did in the early modern period. In their counterfactual absence, forms of ‘inside’ money including fiat, bank deposits, bills of exchange or other forms of credit could not have compensated for the relative decrease in coin supply anywhere in Europe before 1790.Footnote 7 The decrease in transaction costs encouraged people who were not already involved in the formal market economy – or were only marginally so in rural areas – to become involved, both while staying in the countryside, and, importantly, by moving to cities, hence contributing to structural change and agglomeration returns.

In England about 40 per cent of households lived mainly on wages in 1524–5, a ratio which had been approximately constant since the thirteenth century (Dyer Reference Dyer2002, p. 364).Footnote 8 But by the early 1780s few people were not directly involved in the cash economy, especially in towns (Porter Reference Porter1990, p. 187). I argue that this would not have been possible without the enormous increase in money supply. In this article I document the large-scale increase in the availability of precious metals which followed from the discovery of America, and consider in detail its effects on the English economy. I discuss a variety of channels through which it affected economic growth and modernization. I also present some comparative remarks on the effects on the continental economies.

The very large monetary injections that were the result of the discovery of America, I argue, mattered a great deal in making the English industrious and industrial revolutions possible, by alleviating the restrictions imposed on money supply by the availability of precious metals. In order for my argument to be valid, two conditions were necessary: first, money (or its substitutes) would not have expanded anyway, even if precious metals in America were not available; second, modernization would not have happened anyway, had the money supply not expanded. That is, monetization must have been a causal effect of modernization.Footnote 9 I consider the first of these conditions in Section ii, and in Section iii I address the second. Then in Section iv, I show that the English economy became deeply monetized during the early modern period. Finally, in Section v, I conclude.

II

There are three reasons why money or credit would not have expanded anyway, without the injections of precious metals from America. First, there are constraints on the power of debasement policies and how small denominations can become. Second, due to credibility problems, higher forms of money (e.g. government-supplied paper) were not a feasible alternative to coin supply at that time. And third, inside money (most credit) was a complement to, not a substitute for, coin in early modern England. These reasons are discussed in turn below.

The first alternative way to expand the money supply that I consider was the use of debasements. In principle, debasements do not require access to new metal sources. However, there are multiple problems with this policy. First, debasements could be politically unpopular. Second, if the currency was too debased, people would use foreign currency, and governments' seigniorage revenue would diminish. In addition, systematic debasements could lead to a denominational problem related to the physical property of currency as an object to facilitate exchange and liquidity – namely, either the alloy with intrinsic value would become too small relative to the overall size and weight of the coin, making it difficult to verify, or small-denomination coins would become too small to be practical. Finally, additional problems with debasements were their effects on the amount of money in circulation and the price level. As Redish (Reference Redish1990, p. 795) writes:

The political unpopularity of calling down the money and the costs of reminting meant that the adjustment was most frequently made by calling up the undervalued coin. If this were done on an annual basis to correct the coin ratings, however, the currency would have a persistent tendency to depreciate – that is, for the amount of specie per unit of account to decrease.

Irrespective of the matters of strategic considerations related to competition with foreign mints, debasements had limits. If economic growth was taking place but the supply of precious metals was not increasing, there was only one way to keep a given denomination proportional to other denominations in relative weight of precious metal content, which was to make the smaller denominations quite small in physical size.Footnote 10 Doing so had obvious disadvantages to trade, and further made assaying harder, amplifying the uncertainty of accepting any given coin in a random and non-repeatable transaction where reputation was not relevant.Footnote 11 It also amplified the ‘big problem of small change' (Sargent and Velde Reference Sargent and Velde2002), since smaller denominations became even more liquid relative to their value.

Despite these disadvantages, the policy of introducing small change was nevertheless sometimes attempted. For instance, a quarter-guinea coin weighing 2.09 grams was launched in 1718, but failed: ‘A piece so tiny, and so readily lost, was entirely unacceptable to the British public’ (Craig Reference Craig2011, p. 21). Nevertheless, the need for credible small change to support trade was pressing enough that it led essayists in mid-eighteenth-century England to continue recommending the minting of this coin (Redish Reference Redish1990).

Constrained by the limits of debasement as a policy tool, states were obliged to find new sources of precious metals if they wished to expand money supply while maintaining convertibility.Footnote 12 The good fortune of the early modern precious metals discoveries is that they alleviated these problems.

A second reason money supply might have increased even without the appearance of precious metals is that, in principle, higher forms of money could have made specie less necessary. However, it is important not to exaggerate the relevance of inside money during the early modern period. Paper money only became prevalent in Europe in the nineteenth century.Footnote 13 In England, as late as 1790, the monetary base was composed of £44 million of commodity-based coin and only £12 million in notes (£8 million of Bank of England notes and £4 million of all other notes; Capie Reference Capie and Prados de la Escosura2004; see Table 1).

Table 1. Estimates for the components of English nominal money supply (unit: millions of £)

Sources: Mayhew (Reference Mayhew2013); Capie (Reference Capie and Prados de la Escosura2004); Cameron (Reference Cameron1967). The category ‘other means of payment’ includes Cameron's £6 m in government tallies and £2 m in inland bills in 1688 and £3.1 m in deposits in private banks in 1750.

The timing of the growth of fiat and other means of payment can be paralleled with the increase in the size of government. One of the most remarkable aspects of the evolution of the English economy since the mid seventeenth century was the persistent growth of the government sector, which accelerated during the eighteenth century, more than quadrupling between 1700 and 1790. The growth of government happened through a ratchet effect, with expansion during times of war not fully reversed when peace came along (Brewer Reference Brewer1989; O'Brien Reference O'brien1988).

This ratchet effect was absent in the case of money supply. This is true for both coin supply and higher forms of money supply, measured either by notes of the Bank of England or broader measures that include bills of exchange and notes of provincial banks (Figure 2). The fact that until the last decade of the eighteenth century government expanded in tandem with warfare, but money supply did not, is telling as to why in earlier periods the expansion of coin supply was conditional on the availability of precious metals. The Bank of England and other financial intermediaries had the capacity to expand higher forms of money, but, concerned with their reputation and solvency, chose not to do so (O'Brien and Palma Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming).

Sources: Bank of England (1967); O'Brien and Palma (Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming).

Figure 2. The ratio between Bank of England notes and coin supply, 1694–1815

All notes of the Bank of England (and of provincial banks) were fully convertible until the Act of 1797. Only after that period was it possible for the Bank of England to expand notes significantly without running into credibility problems (Figure 2; O'Brien and Palma Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming). The same is true for provincial banks: ‘the arrival of country banking, combined with the note issues of the Bank of England, was not an answer to the shortage of silver in England and Wales even by the end of the eighteenth century’ (Clancy Reference Clancy1999, p. 30).

Indeed, Redish plainly states that ‘it was not possible to establish a stable token coinage prior to the nineteenth century’ (Redish Reference Redish1990). Notes both of the Bank of England and of provincial banks enjoyed limited circulation before the last decade of the century; people did not use these for retail purchases or other regular transactions (Clancy Reference Clancy1999, pp. 28–9; Feavearyear Reference Feavearyear1944; Clapham Reference Clapham1944). According to one estimate by the Board of Stamps, as late as 1812–16 the value of country banknotes annually in circulation was under £16 million (Clancy Reference Clancy1999, p. 29). Finally, it was also the case that until 1793 the lowest denomination for a banknote was £10, and until 1797 it was £5, both of which were well above the unskilled weekly wage (Schwarz Reference Schwarz1985). Only in 1797 were £2 and £1 notes issued by the Bank, which could be used as a means of exchange at the retail level. As for other English banks, until 1797 all were prohibited from issuing bearer notes of less than £5 (Feavearyear Reference Feavearyear1944).

Finally, I argue that coin and credit were complements, not substitutes. It has long been argued that an English ‘financial revolution’ had been in operation at least since the 1660s (Dickson Reference Dickson1993). This consisted of the increased usage of credit instruments such as bills of exchange and promissory notes,Footnote 14 as well as privately issued tokens, and after 1694, banknotes of the Bank of England (O'Brien and Palma Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming) and of provincial banks (Pressnell Reference Pressnell1956).

It is true that in the second half of the seventeenth century, the expansion of the English economy was supported by an expansion of credit. But as Table 1 and Figure 3 suggest, by the late seventeenth century M2 (as defined by Palma Reference Palma2018) was still quite close to coin supply. The seventeenth century's expansion of credit was not sufficient to compensate for the economic growth which was also occurring at both the extensive (population growth) and intensive (per capita) margins. This trend was only reversed in the eighteenth century, in tandem with an increase in the availability of precious metals, due to the discovery of gold in Brazil and to the shifting of mining priorities in the Spanish empire from Peru to Mexico.

Sources: This figure is derived using the indirect method described in Palma (Reference Palma2018), which in terms of data relies on Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015), Capie (Reference Capie and Prados de la Escosura2004) and Mayhew (Reference Mayhew2013).

Figure 3. British per capita coin supply and M2 at constant prices of 1700. The area in grey can be interpreted as the approximate size of inside money in circulation and held as store of value.

Further, the conditions of the second half of the seventeenth century in England may have been special, as they corresponded to what can essentially be described as financial sector catch-up with the best practices of the continent (Coffman, Leonard and Neal Reference Coffman, Leonard and Neal2013). Hence, while credit did expand without an increase in coin in the second half of the century, this process should be seen as a delayed response.

For the better part of the early modern period, credit and coin have been complements, not substitutes. Forms of exchange based on informal credit had been developing since the sixteenth century, but were inadequate as a substitute for coin: ‘the primary hindrance was that personal credit instruments did not circulate, at least not nearly enough to make a real difference. For commerce, agriculture and manufacturing to flourish, new sources of [outside] money had to be discovered’ (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 19).Footnote 15

Hence, commodity-based coin and inside money (such as banknotes) were complements, not substitutes.Footnote 16 It is clear that ‘in the international economy of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the arrival and distribution of bullion … was enough to set in motion a series of credit transactions' (Spooner Reference Spooner1972, p. 3). That is the view that modern economic theory also suggests (Holmström and Tirole Reference Holmström and Tirole2011). Credit was, additionally, subject to usury restrictions that were binding, especially for those without exemptions or access to collateral (Temin and Voth Reference Temin and Voth2008). The perceived need for means to expand currency in order to buttress commercial expansion is reflected in several contemporaneous intellectual and political debates, which I discuss in the Appendix.

A final argument supports the idea that money and credit were complements. The decision to issue credit was often based on people's anticipation of whether the debtor would have the liquidity to honor the bill, and that in turn depended on the overall availability of money (Nightingale Reference Nightingale2010). With regards to the medieval economy, peasants did use coin and were involved in market activity, to some extent, but they also faced persistent liquidity problems (Dyer Reference Dyer1997, pp. 32, 44). Credit operations in the medieval countryside involved coined money at some stage. Credit was used in lieu of coin particularly during periods of coin shortage such as the final decades of the fourteenth century along with the fifteenth, and transaction costs involved in making payments using credit networks were higher than in using coin (Mayhew Reference Mayhew and Wood2004, p. 80; Briggs Reference Briggs, Allen and Coffman2015; Spufford Reference Spufford2002, pp. 42–4).

In sum, there were only two ways by which people could issue credit, and both critically depended on reputation in the face of repeated relationships. First, richer merchants with established businesses could write bills of exchange, even internationally. Second, at the local village level, people could and did at times informally borrow small amounts from each other (Muldrew Reference Muldrew1998).Footnote 17 But this required personal and repeated relationships that necessarily limited the scope of credit – it created complications for the advancement of structural change and division of labor, which require the availability of an anonymous and liquid means of exchange for one-off transactions in cities. The lack of an easily accessible liquid means of payment meant that in medieval economies payments often had to be made on a quarterly basis or through the ‘chalking up by local tradesmen of small debts for later settlement’ (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1995, p. 239), which surely increased credit risks and transaction costs, leading to a reduced number of equilibrium transactions.

III

Why did the early modern monetary injections matter? Research has shown that in England much of the occupational migration from agriculture to industry happened during the early modern period (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell and van Leeuwen2013, p. 369; Leigh Shaw-Taylor and Wrigley Reference Shaw-Taylor, Wrigley, Floud, Humphries and Johnson2014, p. 59). The industrial and service sectors already accounted for 40 per cent of the labor force in 1381, and by 1759 agriculture's share of the labor force had shrunk to 37 per cent and industry's grown to 34 per cent (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell and van Leeuwen2013). Wallis et al. (Reference Wallis, Colson and Chilosi2018) show that by the early eighteenth century, only around 45 per cent of the male labor force was in agriculture. Structural transformation became particularly rapid in the decades surrounding the mid seventeenth century (Wallis et al. Reference Wallis, Colson and Chilosi2018, p. 29), which also witnessed the beginnings of sustained economic growth (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015; Humphries and Weisdorf Reference Humphries and Weisdorfforthcoming).

From the 1630s the gradual increase in availability of real coin supply per capita allowed cash payments to become more frequent, structural change to beginFootnote 18 and income growth to occur. Higher monetization mattered directly, by making payments easier to make and receive, decreasing transaction costs and inducing specialization. The result was thicker markets and structural change. Higher liquidity also mattered indirectly, via spillover and general equilibrium effects. I now cover each of these effects separately, although they interacted with each other.

As far as transaction costs are concerned, the evidence we have is that making and receiving payments in cash was difficult even as late as the early seventeenth century. For example, an early seventeenth-century yeoman for whom we have detailed accounting information wished to rely on wage labor rather than provide food and other in-kind payment to his servants. But he decided against it upon realizing that ‘he simply did not have access to enough ready money to pay regular cash wages' (Muldrew Reference Muldrew and Lucassen2008, p. 401).Footnote 19

A number of factors mattered for the growth of urbanization during the early modern period, such as the growth of international trade (Allen Reference Allen2009 and Palma Reference Palma2016). But it is undeniable that in-kind payment is more difficult in cities, and that the lack of ready money was a reason why so much industry was traditionally located in the countryside (Muldrew Reference Muldrew and Lucassen2008, pp. 405, 410). Once liquidity became available, agglomeration economies could take place. This in turn led to more urbanization, creating a positive feedback loop with higher specialization (division of labor), the spacial concentration of specialized human capital and further urbanization.

The provision of more liquidity also had important indirect effects. The inflow of American silver meant that new goods such as tea, porcelain and silk could be imported by the East India Company, and these are widely believed to have caused an industrious revolution. But the most important effects were dynamic. These can be separated into learning externalities, industrial expansion effects and related demand effects. The new goods from Asia induced demand towards import substitutes, which spilled over into industrial development. In England, it is hard to conceive of important porcelain centres such as Worcester or Derby appearing if the early modern Euro-Asian trade had not happened.Footnote 20 There was also additional demand for English products from first-order receivers of the silver and gold, Spain and Portugal.Footnote 21

Tax collection was made easier by a more monetized and urbanized economy collection, raising the fiscal capacity of the state (Capie Reference Capie and Prados de la Escosura2004; Desan Reference Desan2014, p. 256). In turn, higher fiscal capacity meant that investment conditions were more attractive, and England could be a provider of transport trade services as a result of the establishment of the Royal Navy – itself a result of comparatively high fiscal capacity.

Monetary injections also helped in avoiding deflation. If the price level could adjust immediately to changes in money supply, then any change of unit of account or the overall quantity of money would not matter. As it was, whether due to social norms, menu costs, or other factors, price and especially wage rigidity was a reality (Palma Reference Palma2016).Footnote 22 In early modern England, despite the price revolution which occurred prior to the eighteenth century, customary rents were normally fixed in nominal terms. Contracts often covered a number of generations, and there were substantial benefits for tenants who were able to defeat their landlords' attempts to raise rents (Holt Reference Holt and Whittle2013). Indeed, not only was price adjustment persistently absent or incomplete for long periods of time, but it was also asymmetric – in eighteenth-century France, for instance, following changes in the unit of account, upward price adjustments were much faster and less penalizing for the real economy than downward adjustments (Velde Reference Velde2009).

Several recessionary mechanisms associated with deflation can be posited. Despite the relatively small size of financial intermediation, debt-deflation might have been a serious concern in the absence of the monetary injections.Footnote 23 For a given country, as the internal price level falls, the real exchange rate will appreciate and the economy will become less competitive. Furthermore, if deflation is avoided for a group of countries as a whole, this can be beneficial for all (Eichengreen and Sachs Reference Eichengreen and Sachs1985). Expectations about continued falling prices may also lead people to delay consumption expenditures.

As I have argued, in England monetary injections mattered in part because the additional liquidity avoided persistent deflation.Footnote 24 In the Middle Ages, supply of precious metals was quasi-fixed and hence deflation was a persistent phenomenon. According to the Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015) price deflator, it took until the 1530s for the price level to recover to the pre-Black Death level. This episode of persistent deflation from the fifteenth century onwards is associated with the late medieval bullion famine (Day Reference Day1978; Spufford Reference Spufford1989, pp. 340, 343; Dyer Reference Dyer2002, pp. 266, 384). Although some elements of the original story were subsequently criticized (Sussman Reference Sussman1998), the lack of availability of precious metals was in fact at this time an important element in preventing growth (Miskimin Reference Miskimin1964; Nightingale Reference Nightingale1990, Reference Nightingale1997, Reference Nightingale2010; Desan Reference Desan2014; Le Goff Reference Le Goff2012, p. 143).

Recent data suggest that England suffered from persistent secular deflation from the early fourteenth century to the first decade of the 1530s (Broadberry et al. Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015).Footnote 25 Figure 4 shows the evolution of the price level from the mid sixteenth century until 1790.Footnote 26 The figure shows the observed price level and a counterfactual price level where the money supply is fixed at the 1550 level. The counterfactual evolution of the price level is calculated using the equation of exchange, MV = PY, and using the orthodox assumption that Y and V are independent of M in the long run.Footnote 27

Source: Author's calculations, using the 1550 money supply from Palma (Reference Palma2018), and for the price level, the GDP deflator of Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015).

Figure 4. Observed and counterfactual price levels

A short macroeconomic history of early modern England in relation to monetary history can hence be told as follows. The sixteenth century was a century of stagnation for England, in terms of both per capita real GDP and money supply. While silver from South America was arriving in Spain in significant quantities (and, by extension, the territories of modern Belgium and the Netherlands, as well as Italy), English nominal coin supply increased, but these increases were outweighed by increases in population and the price level. The increase in coin supply did lead to some inflation, which eventually terminated the previous status quo of stagnating nominal wages.Footnote 28 Inflation may have encouraged wage-labor share growth, and may have had other distributional consequences,Footnote 29 but it did not lead to observable per capita income growth.Footnote 30

It took until the early seventeenth century for precious metals from America to start having a significant effect on England's money supply. This effect pre-dates the very significant (for the standards of the time) growth which then occurred (Figure 5). From the Cottington Treaty of 1631 onwards, both private merchants and asentistas in Spain sent silver bullion and coin to Flanders aboard English vessels.Footnote 31 These would first stop in Dover where two-thirds of the silver would be transported to the Tower mint in London to be turned into English coinage. These agents would then ‘use the coined silver to buy bills of exchange from English merchants redeemable in Flanders' (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 37).Footnote 32

Sources: Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015); Palma (Reference Palma2018).

Figure 5. Real income and coin supply per capita

After 1639, a decisive defeat of the Spanish fleet by the Dutch Republic meant that ‘Spain became even more dependent upon English carriers than she had been previously’ (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 65). After this date, the Spanish placed ‘vital importance … on cultivating good relations with England’ (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 66). But conversely, the volume of imported Spanish silver ‘explains why parliament, which was almost totally dependent upon the City for liquid funds … was anxious to give all possible guarantees of State protection to the Spanish silver factors and their principals' (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 85).Footnote 33 The Dover entrepôt and the Cottington Treaty operated for 16 years, from 1631 to 1647. From then onward, the Dutch took over much of this carrying trade (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 90).

Figure 5 contrasts per capita coin supply and real income, focusing on the period after the Great Debasement of 1542–52. As we can see, in the second half of the sixteenth century, real per capita coin supply was essentially trendless. It then rose sharply in the period 1620–40, slightly anticipating the persistent growth in per capita output.Footnote 34 Coin supply then slowly decreased (in per capita terms), always staying well above the pre-1620s level.Footnote 35 These changes over time illustrate well the limitation of the monetary approach to the balance of payments (McCloskey and Zecher Reference McCloskey, Zecher, Frenkel and Johnson1976), because they show that geopolitical changes often mattered more for explaining net flows of silver than variation in income or productivity (for an example, see Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 72).

Stagnation in coin supply during the second half of the seventeenth century led to coin of increasingly bad quality until the Great Recoinage of 1696, but this was largely compensated for by circulation of inside money (Figure 6).Footnote 36 Finally, in the eighteenth century, there was an increased availability of gold and a rise in per capita coin supply in association with the discovery of Brazilian gold and the Methuen Treaty,Footnote 37 as well as with the Spanish Bourbon shift of the American empire towards the Mexican mines.

Sources: Palma (Reference Palma2018); and for the deflator, Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015).

Figure 6. Real income and indirect M2 per capita

IV

Several scholars claim that the early modern period was characterized by a dramatic lack of liquidity, and in particular a lack of small denominations (e.g. Muldrew Reference Muldrew and Lucassen2008).Footnote 38 But these studies present no systematic quantitative evidence that allows either a temporal or cross-sectional perspective. How can we in fact know which denominations circulated at different times?

Studying hoards is not ideal for this purpose, because people hoard at particular times, usually times of unrest – which explains why so many hoards exist for the civil war period (Besly Reference Besly2003, p. 123). Accordingly, it is not surprising that large denominations dominate hoards even for periods when petty coins may have been much more important than the hoards suggest. A better option is the study of individual (stray) finds. These are coins that appear isolated because they were lost. They may appear in urban or rural contexts, often in the middle of rural fields most likely due to having been lost on the floor of a home, swept away during cleaning and then released in the fields together with other domestic refuse which served as fertilizer (Dyer Reference Dyer1997, p. 36).

These individual coins are currently being found by metal detectors at a growing rate of several per year. In order to study denominations systematically, I rely on a UK government programme, called the Portable Antiquities Scheme, which records findings of archaeological interest by members of the public, often metal detectorists.Footnote 39 Over 16,000 post-medieval coins have been recorded on the database; for this study I consider only single-coin finds.Footnote 40

Coin periods are identified by reigns. For each reign, I have counted the number of coins of each denomination as well as their total value. Tables A1–A4 in the Appendix show the full details, and Figure 7 summarizes the results. As the figure shows, denominations of 1 penny or less become common – more than 50 per cent of finds – only from the period of Charles I onward.Footnote 41

Source: Author's calculations, using the raw data from the Portable Antiquities Scheme.

Figure 7. Distribution of denominations for different periods

Lucassen (Reference Lucassen2014, p. 74) defines deep monetization as the intersection of two conditions which are jointly sufficient for a society to be considered as such. First, denominations must exist which are equal to one hour or less of waged work. Second, these must exist in sufficiently large quantities, defined as a per capita quantity equal to five or more hours of waged work. If these conditions hold, a society can be considered to have a substantial stock of small change. He identified deep monetization as being present in the Netherlands in parts of the early modern period, as well as after 1840. Using this concept, I show here that the English economy was deeply monetized since at least 1630–60.

Figure 8 considers the first of Lucassen's conditions. We can safely choose the penny as the smallest candidate denomination because the only other denomination which appears in significant quantities, the farthing, or a quarter of a penny, would certainly not fulfill the second necessary condition – see Tables A1–A4 in the Appendix. As Figure 8 shows, the period after 1630/1660 fulfills the first deep monetization condition.Footnote 42

Sources: Wages from Clark (Reference Clark2018), and for the threshold, see text.

Figure 8. Deep monetization necessary condition 1: existence of small denominations

In turn, Figure 9 considers the second deep monetization condition. For which periods does small cash exist in sufficiently large quantities? Lucassen defines sufficiently large as a per capita quantity equal to five or more hours of waged work. Hence, I use the percentages in value equal or smaller than a penny from Tables A1–A4 in the Appendix, and I multiply this by the coin supply from Palma (Reference Palma2018).Footnote 43 This gives me a measure of small cash available per capita, which I then divide by the average hourly nominal wages from Clark (Reference Clark2018).Footnote 44 The result is shown in Figure 9; notice that I can only show this for the periods for which I have the denomination shares breakdown, hence 1509–1820.

Sources: see text.

Figure 9. Deep monetization necessary condition 2: availability of sufficient cash

If we intersect the necessary conditions of both figures, we can then conclude that only the periods 1630–60 and again from the late 1720s to about 1760 were deeply monetized in England.Footnote 45 However, we should not be too quick to conclude that the second halves of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries were not well monetized. First, notice that a large subset of these periods, 1660–85 and 1760–95, were below, but close, to the threshold. But more importantly, the figure only refers to coin supply availability. Since outside money such as inland bills of exchange and other forms of creditFootnote 46 were also used, actual money supply was surely higher.Footnote 47 O'Brien and Palma (Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming), for instance, document how after 1797 the Bank of England issued large quantities of banknotes of denominations low enough to pay wages, but this is not represented in Figures 8 and 9. Overall, I find strong evidence against Muldrew's claim that ‘liquidity was no better in the eighteenth and early nineteenth century’ than in earlier periods (Muldrew Reference Muldrew and Lucassen2008, p. 393).

V

Noting that in the Netherlands payment in kind was of secondary importance to cash during the early modern period, De Vries and Van der Woude (Reference de Vries and van der Woude1997, pp. 81–9, 714) write that ‘[m]onetization is clearly a critical factor in the spread of the calculating, rational conduct that we associate with a modern society’. There is little I can disagree with in this statement, though the evidence for England does not support their later claim that ‘not until the nineteenth century did Europe raise up an equal in this respect’.

American precious metals permitted a dramatic increase in English monetization, which in turn generated Smithian growth, supported state-building and facilitated the transition into modern economic growth. From a comparative perspective, one important question is why this did not happen elsewhere, namely in the first-order receiving countries – Spain for the entire early modern period, and Portugal after about 1700. One possibility is that these two countries suffered from the ‘Dutch disease’ and institutional resource curses (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1970 [1934]; Drelichman Reference Drelichman2005a, Reference Drelichman2005b). But the Iberian path towards backwardnessFootnote 48 should not distract us from the possibility that those monetary injections led to positive – not only persistent, but permanent – long-run effects for England and the Netherlands.Footnote 49 This has not been emphasized in the recent literature, but it did not go unnoticed by some contemporaries:

[S]ince the discovery of the mines in America, industry has increased in all the nations of Europe, except in the possessors of those mines; and this may justly be ascribed, amongst other reasons, to the increase of gold and silver … [T]he prices of all things have only risen three, or at most, four times, since the discovery of the West Indies … But will anyone assert, that there is not much more than four times the coin in Europe, that was in the fifteenth century, and the centuries preceding it? … And no other satisfactory reason can be given, why all prices have not risen to a much more exorbitant height, except that which is derived from a change of customs and manners. Besides that more commodities are produced by additional industry, the same commodities come more to market, after men depart from their ancient simplicity of manners. (Hume Reference Hume1987 [1742], p. 33)

Appendix

Improvement to the Palma (Reference Palma2018) coin supply data

Royalist recoinage. With the return of the Stuarts to the throne in the person of Charles II, mint output temporally peaked due to the demonetization of the Commonwealth issues. This recoinage was announced in September 1661 and lasted until 1663; which leads to unusually high coin output during 1662–3 (Challis Reference Challis1992, pp. 338–9). I had not corrected for this recoinage in Palma (Reference Palma2018), but I do so here, using the figures Challis calls the lion's share: £500,000 (rounded up from £489,157+£6,496), which I divide equally among 1662–3. This correction leads to normal-looking nominal mint figures for 1662–3, considering that in 1662 there was also the minting of a large quantity of French coin received in payment for Dunkirk: £327,726 (Challis Reference Challis1992, p. 339).

Sources and methodological notes for Tables A1 to A4

The main denominations are shown out of the denominations for which at least 10 coins have been found for any of the periods. Accordingly, percentages shown in the tables do not sum to 100. Foreign coinage is generally excluded; some Scottish coins may be included, but when a denomination is known to have been exclusively Scottish (e.g. 20 pence under Charles I) it is excluded. Counterfeits are included, though rare. Guineas are assumed to be worth 20 shillings (1 pound) until George I, and 21 shillings (252 pence) from then onwards. I do not show statistics for the reign of Queen Anne because only a few coins have been found for that short reign. The source is the Portable Antiques Scheme website, last accessed September 2018.

Table A1. Main denominations issued 1509–1603

Table A2. Main denominations issued 1603–60

Table A3. Main denominations issued 1660–1702

Table A4. Main denominations issued 1714–1820

Coin and credit: intellectual and political debates

Conventionally classified under the mercantilist umbrella, contemporary intellectuals, such as Malynes, Miselden and Mun and their disciples, were unanimous that the scarcity of bullion was a problem, hence the emphasis on access to bullion under a favorable trade balance.Footnote 50 In the case of Paterson, Godfrey and Mackworth, paper money was advocated as a solution, but always making clear that the extent of expansion was indirectly constrained by access to bullion.Footnote 51

In fact, the common denominator of the mercantilist literature seems to have been the preoccupation with the capacity of money to encourage economic growth. Adam Smith was mistaken in accusing these mercantilists of confusing money with wealth, because in fact the limitations of credit expansion meant that ‘there was no other way to expand the money stock than to attract silver and gold from abroad’ (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 40).Footnote 52

Wennerlind (Reference Wennerlind2011) argues that restrictions on endogenous money creation were over once the law allowed the current holder of the debt instrument to sue the initial debtor. This is where my position differs. By itself, this would have been unable to support the subsequent eighteenth-century growth. As the end of the seventeenth century approached, the fall of the average silver content of coin to 50 per cent of the official weight meant a serious monetary crisis, in part because silver coin served as security for the notes of the Bank of England (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p.11). This suggests that, later on, the lack of gold would have presented an obstacle.Footnote 53

As contemporaries recognized, the feasibility of taking credit was all about reputation. Even though the lack of currency in the face of expanding commerce provided an incentive for the development of forms of inside money, these could only be sustained as long as merchants were convinced of the buyer's ‘Integrity and Ability for Payment’, and more generally, the ‘honourable Performance of contracts and Covenants' (Defoe Reference Defoe1709).Footnote 54 This was, in fact, representative of the position of the intellectual elite of the time. Even Wennerlind (Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 241) recognizes that David Hume, while open to the notion that under appropriate levels of trust credit could flourish, insisted that currency based on silver and gold was ‘more practical’. Adam Smith advocated a similar position. Inside money could be created, but it led to higher transaction costs. As modern theory suggests, ‘A shortage of liquidity induces the private sector to try and create more stores of value, albeit at a cost’ (Holmström and Tirole Reference Holmström and Tirole2011, p. 5).Footnote 55

Footnotes

I am thankful to Martin Allen, Edward Besly, Bruce Campbell, Rui Pedro Esteves, Regina Grafe, Nick Mayhew, Larry Neal, Judy Stephenson and Jan Luiten van Zanden for helpful discussions. Special thanks to the Financial History Review editor, Stefano Battilossi, for detailed comments which led to significant improvements. Thanks also to the participants in the FHR Fast-track workshop in Turin, and an anonymous referee for useful suggestions. Adam Brzezinski provided excellent research assistance. The usual disclaimer applies. An earlier version of this article circulated as a EUI working paper MWP 2016/11 under the title ‘Money and modernization: liquidity, specialization, and structural change in early modern England’.

1 I take this opportunity to make a small correction to Palma (Reference Palma2018), explained in the Appendix.

2 Using instead the retail price index of Clark (Reference Clark2018) would lead to the same conclusion.

3 My contribution to the study of the industrious revolution aims to complement the standard reasons given in the literature (e.g. demand for new goods; de Vries Reference de Vries1994, Reference de Vries2008) by pointing out that there was a complementary monetary element. Indeed, many of the new goods which led to an increased labor supply depended on the availability of precious metals imported from Asia (Palma and Silva Reference Palma and Silva2016).

4 Other assets which functioned as means of exchange (inside money) did at times develop. I argue that the two forms were complements rather than substitutes. The discussion in the present section is initially restricted to outside money, but other forms of money will be considered below.

5 Munro (Reference Munro2011) makes a helpful distinction between aggressive and defensive coinage debasements. The former were fiscally motivated. The latter were a response to the debasements of neighborhood lands, and additionally a necessary consequence of the fact that where coins circulated by tale, long-term ‘wear and tear’, clipping, sweating and counterfeiting diminished the average content of precious metals in the coinage over time.

6 Indeed, ‘British currency was convertible at fixed rates into silver and gold. It exchanged at virtually fixed rates for other currencies similarly convertible. Hence the value of money in England must have been largely determined by the supply of the precious metals, and the demand for these, in the whole group of nations linked in this way’ (Ashton Reference Ashton1972, p. 196).

7 In fact, those higher forms of money would have decreased. This is because the relationship between them and coin was analogous to a traditional multiplier effect on base or high-powered money (M0). This will be discussed in detail in Section ii.

8 The situation in the early sixteenth century corresponded to a long-term stagnation which only American precious metals would break. Indeed, ‘[in] 1300 … wage labour may have accounted for about a fifth to a quarter of the total labour expended in producing goods and services. In this respect, however, the world did not change in the direction of capitalism between 1300 and 1525’ (Britnell Reference Britnell1993, p. 364; see also Britnell Reference Britnell2009). There was also room for expansion for those only occasionally involved with cash: ‘by the fourteenth century … in the most advanced areas of Europe about half of the adult population was involved and familiar with wage labour. However, because labour was seasonal, especially in rural areas, the share of the adult population in permanent wage labour was smaller. Rural wage labour was concentrated on peaks in the agricultural cycle, such as harvest work by cottagers and land-less workers' (Persson and Sharp Reference Persson and Sharp2015, p. 97).

9 The money-growth causality went both ways. The English economy had the right conditions to grow and demanded additional means of exchange (McCloskey and Zecher Reference McCloskey, Zecher, Frenkel and Johnson1976). But my emphasis on the role of American precious metals is that they were necessary for monetization to increase, which in turn was necessary (but not sufficient) for economic growth to occur.

10 This problem is more serious for gold than for silver, yet silver suffered from the opposite problem; valued by weight, coins could become too large and cumbersome to carry (Redish Reference Redish1990, p. 792). This is what disqualified copper from serving as anything other than a token currency.

11 The relative weight of precious metals could not get too small as a percentage of the overall weight of the coin, otherwise it would become difficult to assay (and less worthwhile to pay the fixed costs of doing so).

12 Convertibility was inevitable at this time due to commitment problems exemplified by failed attempts such as that of John Law in France.

13 Scotland did use paper money more regularly than England, but under high transaction costs.

14 The Promissory Notes Act of 1704 made all debt instruments negotiable by allowing not just the initial creditor but the holder of any bill to sue the initial debtor (Richards Reference Richards2012, p. 23).

15 I added the word ‘outside’ to make it clear that it is coin that is being referred here to as money. As Wennerlind (Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 110) recognizes, William Paterson, the intellectual influence behind the creation of the Bank of England, felt that ‘Credit not founded on the Universal Species of Gold and Silver, is … impracticable’, and that a minimum reserve of 15–25 per cent was necessary to make the system secure (Paterson Reference Paterson1694); Godfrey advocated a similar position (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 112).

16 Further, the expansion of paper credit was considered by contemporaries complementary to having a positive trade balance and hence access to foreign precious metals (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 282 n. 95).

17 In Catholic countries the monasteries (or other religious institutions with charitable purposes) filled the function of monitoring borrowers. In Islamic countries, the Waqf had a similar role.

18 From Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell and van Leeuwen2013), we do not know exactly when structural change started, only that it must have been between the 1520s and 1700. From Wallis et al. (Reference Wallis, Colson and Chilosi2018), however, we know that the 1630s is a plausible decade.

19 Note that this evidence is prior to the 1630s, whereas I argue below that deep monetization started between 1630 and 1660.

20 Elsewhere on the continent important centres also appeared at Delft, Chantilly and Sèvres, yet in England the industrial effects were stronger. See Berg (Reference Berg2005).

21 ‘Through both legal and smuggled imports, effective Spanish demand, sustained by American silver, promoted the economic development of Holland, England and other European countries' (Cipolla Reference Cipolla1993).

22 Even in modern economies, labor markets often do not clear as nominal wages adjust slowly to changes in economic activity.

23 Debt-deflation is the fall in the prices of assets, goods or services that raises the real value of debt, which is written down nominally. In turn, this may lead to a negative cycle due to the fall in the value of collateral.

24 These are the reasons I emphasize in this article; others may have been at play. In particular, I have here left out associated distributional implications.

25 In England, 1300–1525 was a period of arrested development, by comparison with 1000–1300 (Britnell Reference Britnell1993, Reference Britnell2009). The latter period, when silver was still available in sufficient quantities, was characterized by increased commercialization, which included the establishment of active factor markets for labor, land and capital (Campbell Reference Campbell2009). Spufford (Reference Spufford2002, pp. 12, 59) considers the growth in the money supply a necessary precondition for the commercial revolution which Europe witnessed in the thirteenth century.

26 I stop in 1790 because the French Wars and the Bank Restriction Act (1797) led to a monetary regime beyond the scope of this article (O'Brien and Palma Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming).

27 Note that if Y (or its growth) was not independent of M (or its growth), that is, if monetary neutrality or superneutrality failed to hold, the main point that Figure 4 makes would still hold qualitatively, but there would have been both less growth and less deflation.

28 Dyer (Reference Dyer and Whittle2013, p. 22) writes that ‘The daily wage of building workers reached a plateau during the fifteenth century, which persisted until 1520, of 6d per day for a skilled craftsman and 4d for a labourer.’

29 Landes (Reference Landes2003 [1969], p. 18) suggests that the long inflation of the sixteenth century, which ‘found many peasants holding long-term leases whose burden diminished’, was strongly associated with reducing seigneurial authority and enhancing the personal and economic status of the peasantry. See also Whittle (Reference Whittle and Whittle2013, p. 12).

30 This may have been for a number of reasons: decreasing real income of landowners; increased supply of labor having a contrary effect on the equilibrium real wage; and/or the increase in the share of pasture at the expense of arable land (as suggested by the ‘sheep eating men’ metaphor in Thomas More's Utopia) decreasing agricultural labor demand, even if that was itself partly a response to initially ‘high’ real wages. It is also the case that as long as large reserves of unmonetized workers still existed, a continued increase in the wage-labor force could proceed without an increase in either real wages or per capita GDP, which by definition only measure market compensation.

31 For the Cottington Treaty, see Challis (Reference Challis1992, pp. 318–20). Whether this agreement is due to Cottington himself or not is a matter of debate (see Taylor Reference Taylor1972 for the negative view), but that is immaterial to my argument.

32 By 1632, ‘Strict surveillance was to be maintained to assure that a full two-thirds of arrivals went to the Mint’ (Taylor Reference Taylor1972, p. 246). By 1638, ‘neither the provision of Flanders nor Spain's heavy dependence on imports could be supplied without recourse to English shipping’ (Taylor Reference Taylor1972, p. 246). The rule was changed to only one-third minimum in the mid 1630s, by which time ‘the English as masters of the Channel were also masters of Spanish trade and … Brussels protested from a position of dependence’ (Taylor Reference Taylor1972, pp. 247–8).

33 It is likely that the reason why England never created a West India Company was the fear that ‘English attacks upon homebound Spanish silver fleets might have greatly reduced or ended silver exports to Dover and London’ (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 86). Access to bullion imports was seen as a first strategic priority by the Commons. A dearth of new coin would have been seen as provoking a liquidity crisis in the City money market (Kepler Reference Kepler1976, p. 87).

34 Notice, however, that the 1600–43 growth in money supply is conditional on the relatively high figure of £10 for 1643, which is based on a relatively uncertain guesstimate based on civil war coin hoards (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1995). If the 1643 figure was lower (see Palma Reference Palma2018 for details), the rise in per capita money supply would be more contemporaneous to that of per capita GDP.

35 The period of extraordinarily high mint output of the 1630s and early 1640s ‘stretched the capacity of the Tower Mint’ (Besly Reference Besly2003, p. 41), and ‘The Commonwealth (1649–60) is marked by coinage of a somewhat plain, utilitarian nature’ (Besly Reference Besly2003, p. 123). Note also that the 1630s explosion was not caused by technical change: ‘traditional methods were still in use as late as 1639–40 and there is no discernible change in technique for the rest of the reign or in the mainstream issues of the Commonwealth. The atrocious appearance of much Tower silver of the period can be explained as the result of the pressure of coining up to £1 million of Spanish silver a year by manual methods' (Besly Reference Besly2003, p. 124).

36 A caveat to the intrepretation of the temporal correlation in Figure 6 is that the ‘M2’ measure which I use there is in part derived by the income data, so there is some endogeneity by construction. Nevertheless, it is well known that various forms of credit developed over the second half of the seventeenth century (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011), so the expansion of inside money there is a well-established historical fact.

37 The 1703 Methuen Treaty signed with Portugal was a military and commercial treaty which granted preferential custom treatment for Portuguese wines (diversifying away from French wines), in exchange for English manufactures. The differential value was paid in gold, and the timing of this treaty was determined by Portugal's finding of large quantities of gold in Brazil from the 1690s onwards. As a consequence, two-thirds of Brazilian gold ended up in England: ‘Almost all our gold, it is said, comes from Portugal’ (Smith Reference Smith2003 [1776]). The resulting monetary injection into the English economy was significant: about $40 million for the period 1700–70 alone. Accordingly, Conduitt, the successor to Newton as master of the mint, claimed in 1730 that ‘nine parts of ten, or more, of all payments in England are now made in gold’ (Challis Reference Challis1992, p. 431).

38 Selgin (Reference Selgin2008) argues along similar lines, placing special emphasis on the eighteenth century.

39 The Portable Antiquities Scheme is available at https://finds.org.uk/

40 Metal detectorists do not report early modern coins as often as medieval coins. They do not need as much expert help with later coins because the inscriptions are more legible. Despite these caveats, the finds are the best indication we have of the denominations struck. Furthermore, to the extent that for later periods higher denominations are more likely to be reported – because the coins themselves appear more valuable – the resulting sample is biased against my argument. The same direction of bias happens because: ‘The Portable Antiquities Scheme regularly records all coins issued up to the end of the Commonwealth in 1660, although we have to be more selective thereafter owing to the numbers of coins found’, as reported in https://finds.org.uk/postmedievalcoins .

41 Notice that the period of Henry VIII also looks comparatively well monetized, but this was a period of enormous monetary disruption due to the Great Debasements.

42 Whether 1630 or 1660 is chosen as the best starting date depends on whether one selects 8 or 10 hours worked per day as a baseline; and, of course, skilled workers would have hit this condition earlier than the unskilled (earnings in the graph are Clark's Reference Clark2018 average).

43 I include the royalist recoinage adjustment which I explain in the Appendix.

44 Hourly earnings are obtained directly from the nominal day earnings of Clark (Reference Clark2018).

45 Notice that Lucassen (Reference Lucassen2014) finds that in the Netherlands only some periods between 1500 and 1800 were deeply monetized according to his own definition.

46 Notice that some historical works take a very narrow view of what money is, and hence define credit as something separate from money, instead only considering coin as money. This is at odds with modern economics. Both coin and credit are money; the relevant distinction is that of outside vs inside money (Holmström and Tirole Reference Holmström and Tirole2011).

47 Why not use M2 from Palma (Reference Palma2018) then? There are three reasons. First, such a measure as built in that paper is by construction endogenous to income. Second, the denomination structure from Tables A1–A4 would no longer apply, so I would be unable to determine which part was composed of small denominations. Third, and relatedly, most inside money (e.g. inland bills) was of higher denominations.

48 Documented by Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (Reference Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura2013) and by Palma and Reis (Reference Palma and Reisforthcoming).

49 For instance, during most of the seventeenth century, millions of pesos per year flowed from Spain to the Netherlands, where among other things they funded the operations of the Bank of Amsterdam.

50 The state indeed often took action: legislation prohibited the export of bullion. In the non-cooperative world of medieval and early modern Europe, perhaps there was some rationale to these policies which were castigated by Adam Smith and other classical writers. Indeed, it is noticeable that ‘such bullionist legislation was a constant feature of the work of late medieval parliaments' (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974, p. 62)

51 Other writers such as Hugh Chamberlen and John Briscoe advocated a national land bank, which would expand money based on the security of land, not bullion. The utter failure of the Land Bank United, launched in 1696, to attract capital (in sharp contrast to the Bank of England's oversubscribed issue two years earlier) suggests that this foundation was not possible. Only around the time of the Restriction Act (1797) was it really possible to have monetary expansion independent of bullion (O'Brien and Palma Reference O'brien and Palmaforthcoming), and as the establishment of the gold standard in 1821 suggests, even those measures were, for the time being, temporary.

52 With regard to the issue of trade competiveness in connection with deflation, it is noticeable that, at times, it was explicitly recognized that in order for trade to remain completive, the right amount of money was needed to maintain the price level (Wennerlind Reference Wennerlind2011, p. 40).

53 Furthermore, the Reformation created a huge concentration of wealth in England and hindered the development of a credit sector. That is why money may have been a greater bottleneck in England than in southern Europe, and not only in Italy. In other Protestant countries such as the Netherlands, Italian banking and urban institutions were at times used to finance the gap. Thanks to Regina Grafe for help in clarifying this point.

54 In an attempt to popularize the notion of credit (and defend his increasingly pro-Tory political position), Defoe used the rhetorical figure of ‘Lady credit’, the younger sister of money, who could take her sister's role in trade, but only as long as ‘her Sister constantly and punctually relieves her’ (Defoe Reference Defoe1706). For a recent review of Defoe's role in popularizing the polices of Harley, see Wennerlind (Reference Wennerlind2011, pp. 181–9).

55 In the American colonies, in particular in Virginia and Barbados, and even in Scotland, paper money was often used, but it only had the ability to circulate locally and under high transaction costs. Finally, one additional reason that the change to a fiat system did not happen earlier may have been related to the limited political influence of the groups that would gain from inconvertibility and depreciation (Eichengreen Reference Eichengreen1992).

References

Allen, R. C. (2001). The Great Divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explorations in Economic History, 38, pp. 411–47.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009). The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Álvarez-Nogal, C. and Prados de la Escosura, L. (2013). The rise and fall of Spain (1270–1850). Economic History Review, 66 (1), pp. 137.Google Scholar
Ashton, T. H. (1972). Economic History of England: The Eighteenth Century. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Ashton, T. H. (1997 [1948]). The Industrial Revolution, 1760–1830. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Attman, A. (1986). American Bullion in the European World Trade: 1600–1800. Gothenburg: Kungl. Vetenskaps- och Vitterhets Samhället.Google Scholar
BANK OF ENGLAND (1967). Bank of England liabilities and assets: 1696 to 1966. Quarterly Bulletin, June.Google Scholar
Barret, W. (1990). World bullion flows, 1450–1800. In Tracy, J. D. (ed.), The Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-Distance Trade in the Early Modern World 1350–1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Berg, M. (2005). Luxury and Pleasure in Eighteenth-Century Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Besly, E. (2003). The coinage of the Stuarts. British Numismatic Journal, 73, pp. 120–7.Google Scholar
Braudel, F. P. and Spooner, F. (1967). Prices in Europe from 1450 to 1750. In Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe from the Decline of the Roman Empire, vol. 4. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brewer, J. (1989). The Sinews of Power. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Briggs, C. (2015). Money and rural credit in the later Middle Ages revisited. In Allen, M. and Coffman, D. (eds.), Money, Prices and Wages: Essays in Honour of Professor Nicholas Mayhew. London and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Britnell, R. (1993). Commerce and capitalism in late Medieval England: problems of description and theory. Journal of Historical Sociology, 6 (4), pp. 359–76.Google Scholar
Britnell, R. (2009). The Commercialisation of English Society 1000–1500. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (reprint of the 1993 edition).Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. (2013). Accounting for the great divergence. LSE Economic History Working Papers, 184/13.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B., Klein, A., Overton, M. and van Leeuwen, B. (2015). British Economic Growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. and van Leeuwen, B. (2013). When did Britain industrialise? The sectoral distribution of the labour force and labour productivity in Britain, 1381–1851. Explorations in Economic History, 50, pp. 1627.Google Scholar
Cameron, R. (1967). England, 1750–1844. In R. Cameron (ed.), Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, B. M. (2009). Factor markets in England before the Black Death. Continuity and Change, 24(1), 79106.Google Scholar
Capie, F. (2004). Money and economic development in England. In Prados de la Escosura, L. (ed.), Exceptionalim and Industrialization: Britain and Its European Rivals 1688–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Challis, C. E. (1992). A New History of the Royal Mint. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cipolla, C. M. (1993). Before the Industrial Revolution: European Society and Economy 1000–1700. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2018). Average earnings and retail prices, UK, 1209–2017. www.measuringworth.com/datasets/ukearncpi/ (accessed September 2018).Google Scholar
Clancy, K. (1999). The recoinage and exchange of 1816–17. PhD thesis, University of Leeds.Google Scholar
Clapham, J. (1944) The Bank of England: A History, 2 vols, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Coffman, D., Leonard, L. and Neal, L. (eds.) (2013). Questioning Credible Commitment. Perspectives on the Rise of Financial Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Craig, J. (2011 [1953]). The Mint: A History of the London Mint from A.D. 287 to 1948. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Day, J. (1978). The great bullion famine of the fifteenth century. Past & Present, 79, pp. 354.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (1994). The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution. Journal of Economic History, 54 (2), pp. 249–70.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (2008). The Industrious Revolution: Consumer Behavior and the Household Economy, 1650 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. and van der Woude, A. (1997). The First Modern Economy: Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Defoe, D. (1706). Review of the State of the British Nation, 10 January.Google Scholar
Defoe, D. (1709). Review of the State of the British Nation, 14 June.Google Scholar
Desan, C. (2014). Making Money: Coin, Currency, and the Coming of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dickson, P. (1993 [1967]). The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 1688–1756. London and New York: Routledge (first published by Macmillan and Co.).Google Scholar
Drelichman, M. (2005a). The curse of Moctezuma: American silver and the Dutch disease. Explorations in Economic History, 42 (3), pp. 349–80.Google Scholar
Drelichman, M. (2005b). All that glitters: precious metals, rent seeking and the decline of Spain. European Review of Economic History, 9 (3), pp. 313–36.Google Scholar
Dyer, C. (1997). Peasants and coins: the uses of money in the Middle Ages. British Numismatic Journal, 67, pp. 3047.Google Scholar
Dyer, C. (2002). Making a Living in the Middle Ages: The People of Britain, 850–1520. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dyer, C. (2013). The agrarian problem, 1440–1520. In Whittle, J. (ed.), Landlords and Tenants in Britain, 1440–1660: Tawney's Agrarian Problem Revisited. Woodbridge: Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. and Sachs, J. (1985). Exchange rates and economic recovery in the 1930s. Journal of Economic History, 45 (4), pp. 925–46.Google Scholar
Feavearyear, A. E. (1944). The Pound Sterling. A History of English Money. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gould, J. (1964). The price revolution reconsidered. Economic History Review, 17, pp. 249–66.Google Scholar
Hamilton, E. J. (1970). American Treasure and the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. New York: Octagon Books (originally published in 1934 by Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Holmström, B. and Tirole, J. (2011). Inside and Outside Liquidity. Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Holt, J. (2013). The financial rewards of winning the battle for secure customary tenure. In Whittle, J. (ed.), Landlords and Tenants in Britain, 1440–1660: Tawney's Agrarian Problem Revisited. Woodbridge: Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1987 [1742]). Essays, Moral, Political, and Literary. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc. Liberty Fund. Downloaded from www.econlib.org/library/LFBooks/Hume/hmMPL26.html (accessed May 2014)Google Scholar
Humphries, J. and Weisdorf, J. (forthcoming). Unreal wages? Real income and economic growth in England, 1260–1850. Economic Journal.Google Scholar
Kepler, J. S. (1976). The Exchange of Christendom: The International Entrepôt at Dover 1622–1651. Leicester: Leicester University Press.Google Scholar
Landes, D. (2003/1969). The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Le Goff, J. (2012). Money and the Middle Ages: An Essay in Historical Anthropology. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Lucassen, J. (2014). Deep monetisation: the case of the Netherlands 1200–1940. Tijdschrift voor Sociale en Economische Geschiedenis, 11 (3), pp. 73121.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. and Zecher, J. R. (1976). How the Gold Standard worked, 1880–1913. In Frenkel, J. A. and Johnson, H. G. (eds.), The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mayhew, N. J. (1974). The monetary background to the Yorkist Recoinage of 1464–1471. British Numismatic Journal, 44, pp. 6283.Google Scholar
Mayhew, N. J. (1995). Population, money supply, and the velocity of circulation in England 1300–1700. Economic History Review, 48 (2), pp. 238–57.Google Scholar
Mayhew, N. J. (2004). Coinage and money in England, 1086–c.1500. In Wood, D. (ed.), Medieval Money Matters. Oxford: Oxbow.Google Scholar
Mayhew, N. J. (2013). Prices in England, 1170–1750. Past & Present, 219 (1), pp. 339.Google Scholar
Miskimin, H. A. (1964). Monetary movements and market structure: forces for contraction in fourteenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 24 (4), pp. 470–90.Google Scholar
Muldrew, C. (1998). The Economy of Obligation: The Culture of Credit and Social Relations in Early Modern England. London and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Muldrew, C. (2008). Wages and the problem of monetary scarcity in early modern England. In Lucassen, J. (ed.), Wages and Currency. Global Comparisons from Antiquity to the Twentieth Century Wages and Currency. Bern: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
Munro, J. (2011). The coinages and monetary policies of Henry VIII (r. 1509–1547): contrasts between defensive and aggressive debasements. University of Toronto, Department of Economics, Working Paper no. 417.Google Scholar
Nightingale, P. (1990). Monetary contraction and mercantile credit in later medieval England. Economic History Review, 43(4), pp. 560–75.Google Scholar
Nightingale, P. (1997). England and the European depression of the mid-fifteenth century. Journal of European Economic History 26(3), pp. 631–56.Google Scholar
Nightingale, P. (2010). Gold, credit, and mortality: distinguishing deflationary pressures on the late medieval English economy. Economic History Review, 63(4), pp. 10811104.Google Scholar
O'brien, P. (1988). The political economy of British taxation, 1660–1815. Economic History Review, 41(1), pp. 132.Google Scholar
O'brien, P. and Palma, N. (forthcoming). Danger to the Old Lady of Threadneedle Street? The Bank Restriction Act and the regime shift to paper money, 1797–1821. European Review of Economic History.Google Scholar
Palma, N. (2016). Sailing away from Malthus: intercontinental trade and European economic growth, 1500–1800. Cliometrica, 10(2), pp. 129–49.Google Scholar
Palma, N. (2016). The existence and persistence of liquidity effects: evidence from a large-scale historical natural experiment. GGDC Research Memorandum 158.Google Scholar
Palma, N. (2018). Reconstruction of money supply over the long-run: the case of England, 1270–1870. Economic History Review, 71(2), pp. 373–92.Google Scholar
Palma, N. and Reis, J. (forthcoming). From convergence to divergence: Portuguese demography and economic growth, 1500–1850. Journal of Economic History.Google Scholar
Palma, N. and Silva, A. C. (2016). Spending a windfall: American precious metals and Euro-Asian trade, 1531–1810. GGDC Research Memorandum 165.Google Scholar
Paterson, W. (1694). A Brief Account of the Intended Bank of England. London.Google Scholar
Persson, K. G. and Sharp, P. (2015). An Economic History of Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Porter, R. (1990). English Society in the Eighteenth Century. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Pressnell, L. S. (1956). Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Redish, A. (1990). The evolution of the Gold Standard in England. Journal of Economic History, 50(4), pp. 789805.Google Scholar
Richards, R. D. (2012). The Early History of Banking in England. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. and Velde, F. (2002). The Big Problem of Small Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schwarz, L. D. (1985). The standard of living in the long run: London, 1700–1860. Economic History Review, 38(1), pp. 2441.Google Scholar
Selgin, G. (2008). Good Money: Birmingham Button Makers, the Royal Mint, and the Beginnings of Modern Coinage, 1775–1821. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Shaw-Taylor, L. and Wrigley, E. A. (2014). Occupational structure and population change. In Floud, R., Humphries, J. and Johnson, P. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain, 4th edn. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (2003 [1776]). The Wealth of Nations. New York: Bantam Dell.Google Scholar
Spooner, F. C. (1972). The International Economy and Monetary Movements in France, 1493–1725. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Spufford, P. (1989). Money and Its Use in Medieval Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Spufford, P. (2002). Power and Profit: The Merchant in Medieval Europe. London and New York: Thames & Hudson.Google Scholar
Sussman, N. (1998). The late medieval bullion famine reconsidered. Journal of Economic History, 58(1), pp. 126–54.Google Scholar
Taylor, H. (1972). Trade, neutrality, and the ‘English Road’, 1630–1648. Economic History Review, 25(2), pp. 236–60.Google Scholar
Temin, P. and Voth, H-J. (2008). Interest rate restrictions in a natural experiment: loan allocation and the change in the usury laws in 1714. Economic Journal 118, pp. 743–58.Google Scholar
Velde, F. R. (2009). Chronicle of a deflation unforetold. Journal of Political Economy, 117(4), pp. 591634.Google Scholar
Wallis, P., Colson, J. and Chilosi, D. (2018). Structural change and economic growth in the British economy before the Industrial Revolution, 1500–1800. Journal of Economic History, 78(3), pp. 862903.Google Scholar
Wennerlind, C. (2011). Casualties of Credit: The English Financial Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Whittle, J. (2013). Introduction: Tawney's agrarian problem revisited. In Whittle, J. (ed.), Landlords and Tenants in Britain, 1440–1660: Tawney's Agrarian Problem Revisited. Woodbridge: Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Coin supply and price level, 1550–1790

Sources: Coin supply adjusted from Palma (2018); the price level is the GDP deflator of Broadberry et al. (2015).
Figure 1

Table 1. Estimates for the components of English nominal money supply (unit: millions of £)

Figure 2

Figure 2. The ratio between Bank of England notes and coin supply, 1694–1815

Sources: Bank of England (1967); O'Brien and Palma (forthcoming).
Figure 3

Figure 3. British per capita coin supply and M2 at constant prices of 1700. The area in grey can be interpreted as the approximate size of inside money in circulation and held as store of value.

Sources: This figure is derived using the indirect method described in Palma (2018), which in terms of data relies on Broadberry et al. (2015), Capie (2004) and Mayhew (2013).
Figure 4

Figure 4. Observed and counterfactual price levels

Source: Author's calculations, using the 1550 money supply from Palma (2018), and for the price level, the GDP deflator of Broadberry et al. (2015).
Figure 5

Figure 5. Real income and coin supply per capita

Sources: Broadberry et al. (2015); Palma (2018).
Figure 6

Figure 6. Real income and indirect M2 per capita

Sources: Palma (2018); and for the deflator, Broadberry et al. (2015).
Figure 7

Figure 7. Distribution of denominations for different periods

Source: Author's calculations, using the raw data from the Portable Antiquities Scheme.
Figure 8

Figure 8. Deep monetization necessary condition 1: existence of small denominations

Sources: Wages from Clark (2018), and for the threshold, see text.
Figure 9

Figure 9. Deep monetization necessary condition 2: availability of sufficient cash

Sources: see text.
Figure 10

Table A1. Main denominations issued 1509–1603

Figure 11

Table A2. Main denominations issued 1603–60

Figure 12

Table A3. Main denominations issued 1660–1702

Figure 13

Table A4. Main denominations issued 1714–1820