Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T07:11:11.281Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Rogue Empires: Contracts and Conmen in Europe's Scramble for Africa. BySteven Press. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2017. iv + 371 pp. Maps, notes, index. Cloth, $39.95. ISBN: 978-0-674-97185-1.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 March 2019

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Book Reviews
Copyright
Copyright © The President and Fellows of Harvard College 2019 

This is a history of private-enterprise empires, intended and achieved, during the nineteenth century. Ultimately, the book is about European imperialism in Africa, with the origins of King Leopold's Independent State of the Congo as its focus. But the argument starts in Southeast Asia, because Steven Press argues that Borneo furnished a legal and political model that inspired many imitators from European adventurers interested in sub-Saharan Africa. In particular, he highlights the success of James Brooke, a British commercial-political entrepreneur, not only in obtaining sovereign rights over the province of Sarawak from the Sultan of Brunei in 1841, but in going on to win recognition for his regime from Western governments, as an independent state—a status that was to last over a century. Press shows that this example was much noticed and quoted by the many other individual Europeans who sought to establish their own states in Southeast Asia and, especially, in Africa during the decades that followed. The recognition of Leopold's state by the Berlin conference of 1884–1885 was the apogee of the movement, within which Press also counts the last round of chartered companies, including Goldie's Roger Niger Company and Rhodes's British South Africa Company (though the book does not examine the latter in any detail).

The appeal of private empires to European politicians, elites, and electors in general was that they offered colonialism without (in principle) cost to metropolitan taxpayers and that most of them claimed to be based not on conquest but on negotiation, with the private states being established supposedly by indigenous rulers voluntarily transferring sovereignty to the incoming foreign merchants. At each stage in the story, what happened next usually turned on the relationship between the actual or would-be private ruler and the Western government(s) whose acquiescence and active support he sought. The rise of private empires was halted within a few years of the Berlin conference, not because of the often-transparent dishonesty of the claims of the adventurers to have secured informed consent from the indigenous authorities, but because most of them proved unable to maintain the revenue inflows required to maintain themselves even on the low-cost scale that became characteristic of European colonies in Africa. This failure obliged the European state concerned either to take over the territory, or risk losing it to a rival, amid accusations of betrayal from pressure groups and politicians back home.

Rogue Empires tells this story in considerable detail. The study is primarily based on an immense range of archival and contemporary printed sources, mainly in English, German, and French. Press prefers to go straight to the primary sources; the downside is a rather minimal engagement with the secondary literature and its debates. In the end, what difference did the phenomenon of private colonies make to the renewed expansion of overseas empires during the nineteenth century? Press considers this briefly (mainly on pages 246–49). The nakedness of the bloody extraction of natural resources under Leopold's rule provoked an international scandal, not least within the imperialist “community,” but, as Press notes, the comparable scandal—in terms of scale of violence—in German Southwest Africa (Namibia), over the genocidal Herero war, happened several years after chartered-company rule had given way to German-government rule. Press points to specific legacies, such as the legal continuity in ownership of Namibia's diamonds from the “state” founded by the German adventurer Adolf Lüderitz to the present proprietorship of De Beers. This is an evocative case, but is it so different in substance from the many other cases of long-term mining in colonial and postcolonial Africa? Would the share of the mineral revenues benefiting ordinary Namibians have been much different had colonial rule been introduced a few years later, and by a European state rather than a private enterprise? On the process of European colonization of Africa, Press suggests briefly that without the model of Brooke in Sarawak, the partition would not have accelerated dramatically in 1884–1885, as it did with the Berlin conference (p. 248). What is perhaps most likely is that without this apparent option of colonialization on the (very) cheap, German participation in the Scramble for Africa would have been delayed—possibly until it was over, given the contrast between Bismarck's enthusiasm for German private companies (well documented by Press) and his reluctance to countenance the establishment of official German colonies.

The writing is lucid and the references dense. Unfortunately, the latter are consigned to endnotes. In the print version, the pain of endnotes is offset by the pleasure of handling a very well-bound and nicely printed book, which is also unusually free from typographic errors. The maps are all contemporary, which enables the author to make useful observations about the limits of the imperialists’ knowledge and control on the ground; however, at times I regretted the lack of a map of the Congo showing clearly where places mentioned in the text actually were.

Rogue Empires is essentially about European imperial history; Africans themselves barely feature, except as rulers giving their rights away or being portrayed as doing so by dishonest foreigners. The book is interesting for business historians for three main reasons. First, it is, after all, about a form of business: profit-seeking companies that sought the freedom to govern. Second, the deals between the “rogues” and indigenous rulers are well worth discussion in any class on the problems of contracting under asymmetric information. Third, for the history of capitalism: How far, and in what historical circumstances, can personal or company empires be viewed as intended or actual solutions to the problem of establishing the political conditions required for capital to move into poor economies? The latter question is raised more than answered in this energetically researched and stimulating account. The very phenomenon of private colonies seems odd today—but perhaps no odder than privately run prisons did in Western countries not so long ago.