Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-cphqk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T07:10:40.527Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Policy and Regulatory Engagement with Corruption: Insights from Complexity Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 May 2021

Andrea MINTO
Affiliation:
Jean Monnet Professor in Law and Economics at Ca’ Foscari University of Venice, Visiting Professor at Cyprus International Institute of Management (CIIM), Visiting Professor at the University of Southern Denmark – Juridisk Institute; email: andrea.minto@unive.it.
Edoardo TRINCANATO
Affiliation:
VERA Fellow at Ca’ Foscari University, Venice Centre in Economic and Risk Analytics for Public Policies, Department of Economics.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

One of the few certainties we have in dealing with corruption lies in its adaptive nature. Over time, corruption has in fact proved to be able to change, evolve and adapt within all political systems. Such an adaptive nature calls for close scrutiny of the setting or space where corruption spreads out. Therefore, this raises questions about the unappreciated risks and immeasurable opportunities for corruption in the ever-changing and interconnected world of techno-social systems we live in. This article aims to advance the policy and regulatory debate surrounding corruption by focusing on its complex and adaptive nature. In applying the main tenets of complexity theory, the analysis builds on the well-known Cynefin framework. This decision-aiding framework proves to be an insightful tool for shedding light on some critical features of corruption (eg its perception and the affected confidence).

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

I. Introduction

No corruption scandal is an island. Each situation is most certainly the product of different contributing factors to the emergence of corruption practices. Yet, there are some common traits of corrupt acts, common types of corrupt human behaviour, normative spaces and grey areas in law that are common triggering factors that might allow for corruption. Footnote 1 These and other factors collectively form the always “lubricated” fabric of corruption practices and acts that have occurred over the centuries and that still contaminate modern society.

In today’s highly interconnected world the advent of new digital solutions and emergent technologies is incessantly reshaping the “techno-social systems” which consist of “… large-scale physical infrastructures (such as transportation systems and power distribution grids) embedded in a dense web of communication and computing infrastructures whose dynamics and evolution are defined and driven by human behavior”. Footnote 2 Such techno-social systems are relentlessly developing towards new forms of technology-enabled infrastructures, such as digital platforms, which have the potential to change the nature of (human) interactions. These profound advances are affecting society, human behaviour and the potential regulatory spaces and grey areas and therefore raise pressing questions on how corruption is evolving and adapting to all of this.

Due to the crucial and practical implications of the adaptive nature of corruption within policymaking and regulation contexts, this article thus aims to approach the phenomenon through the lens of complexity theory, in which is seen, in line with Byrne and Callaghan, an “ontologically framework of understanding”. Footnote 3 Consequently, it also seeks to explain the relevance of complexity theory in steering policymaking and risk regulation for preventing corruption. Along these lines, corruption will be regarded – in essence – as a non-linear cause and non-linear effect adaptive problem. This is because the wide set of consequences originating from it, as well as the driving factors behind it, are made up of several independent, non-linear and omnipresent – at different levels – elements.

The article accordingly presents an examination of the functional evolution of corruption practices and explains the main risks by revealing the less obvious links and mechanics lying behind complex phenomena. In highlighting the potential policy implications and regulatory recommendations arising from such a revelation, the analysis builds on the well-known Cynefin framework. This “sense-making” tool provides a valuable support to create a “sense of time and placeFootnote 4 in responding to complexity, helping to assimilate the wide array of issues faced by policymakers in addressing real-world corruption problems. Through the framework, such issues can indeed be orderly disentangled into five contextsFootnote 5 and differentiated by the relative nature of the relationships between “cause” and “effect”. In this respect, Cynefin proves to be an insightful tool for contextualizing the complexity of corruption and for shedding light on some critical issues of the same (eg its perception and its measurement), as well as to the affected confidence.

Building upon a rich foundation of interdisciplinary literature that spans law, economics and sociology, this article moves the policy and regulatory debate surrounding corruption. The analysis proceeds as follows. Section II approaches corruption as a complex phenomenon by providing a comprehensive literature overview. In Section III, complexity theory is further explored in order to develop the methodological premises underpinning our analysis and also to advance anti-corruption policy and regulation. Section IV describes the Cynefin framework and how it could be usefully deployed for the purposes of this analysis. Section V then addresses corruption policy and regulatory objectives vis-à-vis the Cynefin framework domains. Section VI continues to build on Cynefin’s insights and focuses on corruption perception and confidence within techno-social systems. Section VII concludes.

II. Approaching corruption as a complex phenomenon

One of the most enduring debates in all of legal and socio-political thoughts relates to the definition of corruption.Footnote 6 Such long-lasting debate is but a reflection of the struggle in delineating the term itselfFootnote 7 and, most importantly, in capturing the precise contours of the ever-evolving phenomenon it refers to.

Indeed, over time corruption has been differently characterised by scholars on the basis of distinct theoretical and methodological approaches.Footnote 8 Such differences were mainly due to the features of the specific phenomenon of corruption dealt with, such as the personal attributes of the people involved and/or country characteristics.Footnote 9 This therefore entailed a great relevance of psychological, cultural, social and institutional factors,Footnote 10 which, by their very nature, call for case-by-case analysis and ad hoc approaches. Against this backdrop, it comes as no surprise that even the United Nations Convention against Corruption (UNCAC), which is the first legally binding instrument against corruption, lacks a clear-cut definition of the phenomenon itself.Footnote 11

On top of that, the pace of innovation and technological advancement is prompting new challenges, chiefly respecting the setting or space where corruption spreads out. There is no need, in fact, to stress how much the structures of social and political systems have become “complex,” especially through the disruptive innovation that technological progress has brought.Footnote 12 Rather, it could be interesting to observe these drastic changes in light of the growing attention that the United Nations have recently paid to corruption’s systematic nature and its adaptability vis-à-vis the necessity to develop comprehensive and multidisciplinary approaches to prevent it. On this point, indeed, the United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC) has increasingly emphasised corruption as a “complex social, political and economic phenomenon that affects all countries”.Footnote 13

In parallel, the literature has also converged progressively towards a focus on certain characteristics of corruption. The scholarship has indeed been developing a more distinct systemic perspective in the analysis,Footnote 14 in the quest to clearly demonstrate that corruption is a complex phenomenon.

Interestingly, the literature review shows a frequent use of the term “complexity” associated with the analysis of corruption. As a matter of fact, however, complexity has mostly been seen as a sort of obstruction or hindrance to the examination of the phenomenon. Some studies approached complexity as a factor that increases the magnitude of corruption,Footnote 15 without appraising the nature of such “complexity” from a deeper and more comprehensive viewpoint. By way of example, corruption has been indicated as “a complex and multifaceted phenomenon, with a multiplicity of causes and effects, as it exhibits many different forms and functions in very diverse contexts”Footnote 16 (eg as it happens in organisationsFootnote 17 ). Moreover, considering that corruption in organisations is a complex phenomenon, in fact, it has also been also highlighted that controlling corruption becomes “even more complex”.Footnote 18 Finally, complexity has also been associated with difficulties in measuring it: given its “clandestine nature”, indeed, “corruption is intrinsically a complex phenomenon and hard to measure”.Footnote 19

By contrast, other approaches consider corruption rather as an “extremely complex phenomenon, which shows all the characteristic features of complex adaptive systems”.Footnote 20 This perspective incorporates contributions of complexity theory, excluding its connotation as a “complicated problem” and criticising from this standpoint traditional regulatory models that have, in general, “implicitly confused” them. Consistently, Habtemichael and Cloete state that “given the evolving nature of its forms, emergence of a universal understanding of its meaning, its fractal nature (omnipresence at various levels of society and government), non-linearity of its consequences (varying nature of its impact) and the back and forth movement of corrupt agents between various attractors (between betrayal and honesty), corruption is an adaptive complex phenomenon”.Footnote 21 Furthermore, Luna-Pla and Nicolás-Carlock have presented a comprehensive framework based on complex systems science for the analysis of corruption networks.Footnote 22

The contribution of the recent literature seems essential since it tries to overcome the limitations of the traditional approaches to corruption, which proved inadequate to handle the complex nature of the phenomenon.Footnote 23 Despite complexity theory not be defined as “a single coherent body of thought”,Footnote 24 the findings and methodologies arising from it represent “an ontologically founded framework of understanding”Footnote 25 to base the analysis on.

In embracing this canon of literature, this article aims to incorporate the insights arising from the advance of complexity theory into the policy debate surrounding corruption. More specifically, it deals with the various implications arising from the characterisation of the phenomenon as “complex”.Footnote 26 In parallel, we make an attempt to reconcile different strands of literature that could help in approaching questions pertaining to whether and how technology-enabled innovation can be deployed to fight corruption and foster market integrity. Innovation can most certainly contribute in devising instruments that can more adequately cope with a phenomenon that, as highlighted by Transparency International, “can happen anywhere”, “can involve anyone”, “happens in the shadows” and, finally, “adapts to different contexts and changing circumstances”.

III. Complexity theory, social sciences and anti-corruption regulation: charting a course

Oddly enough, there is no consensus on what complexity is. This uncertainty is glaringly due to its very nature.Footnote 27 A multitude of definitions have been proposed, reflecting the specific angle of analysis adopted case by case. Consistently, “the scientific notion of complexity … has traditionally been conveyed using particular examples of real-word systems which scientist believe to be complex”.Footnote 28 So, following traditional practice, Johnson summed up complexity by the catchy example “Two’s company, three is a crowd”, which bluntly shows that complexity can be seen, first and foremost, “as the study of the phenomena which emerge from a collection of interacting objects”.Footnote 29

In this perspective, corruption has been regarded “as a phenomenon that occurs within systems whose structure and dynamics can evolve as a response to changes in its corresponding socio-political and regulation context, with a strong dependence on the interrelation of different factors and actors acting as a whole”.Footnote 30 In our view, such characteristics may assume particular relevance within the anti-corruption regulatory landscape. This is the case since corruption “shows all the characteristic features of complex adaptive systems” and has “direct and important practical implication because as a complex phenomenon, corruption largely resists traditional regulatory models”.Footnote 31

Beyond this general statement, however, it seems crucial to elaborate further on this standpoint of analysis.Footnote 32 Over recent decades, theories and methodological approaches on complexity were in fact understood and implemented over different philosophical, disciplinary and practical lenses.Footnote 33 Complexity theory in particular escalated in the managerial field.Footnote 34 It has indeed been used from “governance and public administration, to health care and service delivery, to education, and to the interface between the social and the natural considered in ecological terms”.Footnote 35 As elegantly presented by Byrne and Callaghan, not only does complexity theory lend itself well to the development of mathematical formulas, but also, most importantly, it may help us tackle the big questions raised in social sciences.Footnote 36 The authors warn that a major criticism stems from the fact that the use of complexity ideas in social sciences is “merely metaphorical,” and yet, at the same time, we all know that “metaphors are what we live by”, as well as models.Footnote 37 Therefore, social sciences benefit from complexity theory not because the latter can show what the truth is, but rather because it can inform the way reality is approached and analysed. For this reason, it is extremely important to be aware that “there are good models and bad models and indifferent models, and what model you use depends on the purposes for which you use it and the range of phenomena which you want to understand …”.Footnote 38

These considerations remind us that complexity theory overtook traditional reductionistic research, which was mainly focused on reducing complex phenomena to elementary pieces.Footnote 39 In fact, over recent decades, the limits of reductionism have become quite evident, especially due to “today’s complexity, globalization and interconnectedness”.Footnote 40 Indeed, as has been properly pointed out in this regard, “complexity science expands on the reductionistic framework by not only understanding the parts that contribute to the whole but by understanding how each part interacts with all the other parts and emerges into a new entity, thus having a more comprehensive and complete understanding of the whole”.Footnote 41

In the ambit of corruption studies, nonetheless, reductionistic approaches still seem to be widely adopted. As rightly observed by Yeboah-Assiamah, adopting traditional reductionistic tools in the area of corruption “would yield futility”; in fact, the complexity of corruption “… suggests that a reductionist approach or adopting piecemeal anti-corruption models will not be effective”.Footnote 42 When dealing with corruption, reductionism could oversimplify what corruption really is and overlook inherent dangers, such as those resulting from the interrelations and interlinkages between corruption and markets. This can increase system fragility,Footnote 43 since the reductionistic approach might obstruct the analysis of contagion and transmission effectsFootnote 44 or, again, the design of effective regulatory models for prevention.

In other words, aligning to what has been observed by Morin, reductionism claims that we are all individuals in society and ecosystem, namely “merely units inside the systems, and … not the connections”. In contrast, “complexity tries to understand the type of connections that are present”.Footnote 45 Looking at complex systems from this perspective changes our understanding of the causes behind corruption and, thus, the contribution that each single factor plays in the system itself. Consequently, for the purposes of this analysis, corruption is regarded as a system.Footnote 46 Namely, corruption is one of the most difficult adaptive systems to manage due to the fact that it involves individuals and their interactions. They cannot be singled out and examined separately from each other to explain the emergence of the collective phenomena that their decisions may originate. The problem is even compounded by the consideration that people generally operate with an understanding of having “free will”, thus making the systems “unpredictable”.Footnote 47 As has been similarly asserted by Caldarelli et al, looking at behaviour in these systems “introduces another source of difficulty, as not all individuals are the same”. Footnote 48 Rightly, the same authors suggest an approach to such intricacies by using the well-established art of modelling in physics in collaboration with the social sciences, thereby invoking collaborations between researchers from different disciplines in the context of today’s massive use of information and communication technologies. On the same point, Bastardas-Boada on the occasion of the Congrès Mondial Pour La Pensée Complexe stated that to gain “an adequate view of the whole and to understand the how and why of the process pursued by the agents in reaching the states that guide their decisions … it will probably be necessary to use computational research together with other types of research that are closer to the changing cognitive and emotional activity of the agents”.Footnote 49

In line with these multi- and trans-disciplinary views, we believe that the insights coming from complexity theory as applied to corruption studies should be accompanied by an attempt to gain a more robust understanding of the policy implication that flow from technology-enabled innovations vis-à-vis anti-corruption regulatory objectives. Policy fails, in fact, particularly “when complex problems are addressed using standard linear and reductionist approaches that presuppose more knowledge and control than is ever possible in such situations”.Footnote 50 Equally, “as the complexity and interaction strengths in our networked world increase, man-made systems can become unstable, creating uncontrollable situations even when decision-makers are well-skilled, have all data and technology at their disposal, and do their best”.Footnote 51

This entry point of analysis adds to the debate revolving around the fight against corruption, especially “in an increasingly interconnected world of techno-social systems”.Footnote 52 As the argument goes, it seems essential to explore empirical sources and data in the context of today’s technological advancements.

IV. Gathering corruption as a whole and its parts: “making sense” with the Cynefin framework

The foregoing discussion pointed out how complexity theory has advanced policymaking when dealing with complex systems like financial markets or highly globalised sectors. This also holds true for corruption, which is an interwoven, multifaceted and adaptive phenomenon that cannot be fully captured by a purely reductionistic and holistic approach. Complexity theory could in fact aid policymakers realise at least two things, which are usefully set forth by the widely known Cynefin framework.Footnote 53 First, complex systems show a great deal of uncertainty, and it is very difficult, if it is even possible at all, to put forward any prediction about the future developments of the matter under scrutiny for policy purposes.Footnote 54 In other words, policymakers and lawmakers are bounded by the unpredictability of complex systems that, by their very nature, are never subject to full control. Second, policymaking should pay much attention to the “micro” and “macro” levels of phenomena alike; that is, to the trees and to the forest, and to how each single tree is contributing to the entire ecosystem.Footnote 55 As such, complex systems instruct policymaking in looking at whether and how individual actions at the micro-level can lead to emergent phenomena (systems) at the macro-level. Such systems are highly dependent on initial conditions that give rise to such emergent phenomena and are always evolving, making them unpredictable over the long term.Footnote 56

Due to these two features, we deem the Cynefin framework, or “sense-making” tool,Footnote 57 a valuable support to facilitating the achievement of the purposes of this research. Cynefin uses “narrative analysis” for dealing with complexity,Footnote 58 and it provides, as asserted by McLeod and Childs, “… a strategic approach to taking action for change” and a “… new construct for re-perceiving the challenge …, favouring the transfer of research into practice”.Footnote 59 The framework, in fact, is rooted in knowledge management and in complexity theory, and it has been developed and applied, over the last two decades, in a wide range of domains, allowing executives to assimilate complex concepts for addressing real-world problems and opportunities.Footnote 60 This framework expressly enhances communications and makes more understandable the operational context, perfectly reflecting the advances in complexity theory, which is “… poised to help current and future leaders make sense of advanced technology, globalization, intricate markets, cultural change, and much more”.Footnote 61 Its aim, or “theme”, as appropriately argued by Browning and Boudès, is therefore identifiable in its ability to create a “sense of place” in responding to complexity, offering different views and narratives about the possible past and future scenarios.Footnote 62

The first version of the framework was displayed in a two-by-two matrix involving “chaos”, “complex”, “knowable” and “known” categories.Footnote 63 Kurtz and Snowden placed the state of “disorder” in the middle of the matrix, which applies when it is unclear which context prevails over another,Footnote 64 such as in the case of interaction or transition between different contexts.Footnote 65 The matrix is based on the idea that the different contexts have blurred boundaries and should not be interpreted as rigid categories.Footnote 66

Other representations of the Cynefin framework provided by Snowden name the four domains “chaotic”, “complex”, “complicated” and “simple”, as shown in Figure 1, where the – very often misunderstood – distinction given by Turner and Baker between the applicability of general systems theory (GST) and complexity theory in the social sciences has also been integrated.Footnote 67 According to the purpose of their study, the authors expressly recommend the implementation of complex adaptive systems (CASs) for addressing today’s complexity in the social sciences, allowing in this way complexity theory to operate in parallel with systems theory. As the authors maintain, “While GST can operate under the principle of system holism from a reductionistic perspective, complexity theory could expand the social sciences by providing a perspective counter to the principle of system holism that incorporates a connectionist approach rather than reductionism”.Footnote 68 In their contribution, the authors identify, indeed, several advantages for the social sciences in incorporating complexity theory as a formal theory. This is also by virtue of the use of the Cynefin framework to display the invoked shift from the complicated domain of GST (right half of the framework in Figure 1) into the one of complexity (left half of the framework in Figure 1) to deal with complex phenomena.

Figure 1. Cynefin framework’s adaptation from Kurtz and Snowden (see Note 53), Snowden and Boone (see Note 53) and Turner and Baker (see Note 35).

It is important to observe that the four domains primarily differ because of their cause-and-effect relationship. The chaotic domain has been associated with the absence of cause-and-effect relationships, whereas the complex domain is characterised by cause-and-effect relationships that are instead understandable “… in retrospect and do not repeat”.Footnote 69 “Instructive patterns, however, can emerge if the leaders conduct experiments that are safe to fail. That is why, instead of attempting to impose a course of action, leaders must patiently allow the path forward to reveal itself. They need to probe first, then sense, and then respond”.Footnote 70 Such a domain is hence the one of “emergence”. By contrast, the complicated domain has been associated with having cause-and-effect relationships, while the simple domain has been characterised by predictable cause-and-effect relationships and, accordingly, “best practice”.

Using the same logic, the Cynefin framework’s dynamism lends itself well to exploring and capturing the conditions – perpetually in flux – of corruption within a policymaking and regulation context.

As has been outlined, we are considering corruption as a non-linear cause and non-linear effect adaptive problem. This is because the wide set of consequences originating from it, as well as the driving factors behind it, are made up of several independent, non-linear and omnipresent – at different levels – elements. Applying the complex domain of Snowden and Boone – “probe, sense, respond” (ie “the leader’s job”) – we obtain a roadmap for the discussion. This sequence, in fact, refers respectively to: (1) the creation of environments and experiments that allow patterns to emerge; (2) the increase of the levels of interaction and communication; and finally (3), the use of methods that can help generate ideas (eg set barriers, stimulate attractors and monitor for emergence).Footnote 71

1. “Probing”

We can preliminarily observe that the application of complexity theory to policymaking shows, as Geyer maintains, that “there is no clear linear policy answer to all situations …”. Beyond creating a stable fundamental order within which individuals can learn, interact and adapt, there is little a state can do with linear certainty.Footnote 72 Mainzer agrees that the economy is a chaotic, non-linear system and that in the long run it is extremely difficult for policymakers to foresee what it is going to become. Nonetheless, he overcomes some of this scepticism by acknowledging the possibility of engaging in “local predictions” that avoid groping-in-the-dark types of exercises.Footnote 73 Planning therefore seems to be viable only over the short term since it is possible, in theory, to anticipate how actors are likely to behave under complex conditions. This is obviously a significant challenge for all-sectors policymakers who are pursuing long-run goals and might be confronted with a high degree of layering of international legal regimes.Footnote 74

2. “Sensing”

We can preliminarily value the levels of interaction and communication. In dealing with corruption, in fact, complexity theory and its policy implications can aid accounting for the ways in which individuals and other agents might be expected to interact within that system and the ways that such interactions on the micro level can lead to major issues at the macro level. Baxter calls for a shift in focus of governance from direction to adaptation.Footnote 75 As described by Chinen, “governance will continue to steer individual and corporate behaviour and to set out the basic structures for interaction but more with a view towards enhancing the resilience of complex social systems and certainly not towards establishing some kind of stasis”.Footnote 76 Miller and Page delved deep into the interaction of economic agents and came to the conclusion that in complex systems the only way to advance the understanding of policy implications lies in paying attention to the networks of communications agents use to interact.Footnote 77 In dealing with corruption, this entails paying attention to international, national and local institutions and other means through which actors and governments interact and develop governing norms within the regulatory landscape.

Helbing has also devoted much of his work to investigating policy engagement with CASs.Footnote 78 Departing from legal and regulatory top-down structures, he advocates for bottom-up mechanisms and for self-organisation solutions. In his own words, “we need to step back from centralizing top-down control and find new ways of letting the system work for us, based on distributed, ‘bottom-up’ approaches”.Footnote 79 This approach is based on the idea that complex systems are better managed from the inside by nudging the development of an assisted self-organisation approach to structuring, regulating and governing CASs.Footnote 80

3. “Responding”

We can preliminarily observe that assisted self-organisation represents a halfway approach between both top-down complexity control (in a “command and control” approach) and unfettered bottom-up self-organisation like free markets. The self-organisation, in fact, steers the management of complex system towards the achievement of the desired outcomes. This assisted self-organisation operates through techniques of influencing complex systems and through an operationalisation of these techniques in information and communication technologies.

Connecting the dots, the three tasks of the complex domain perfectly encapsulate the overall emphasis that the framework puts on understanding how to make sense of the experience in order to act upon it.Footnote 81 According to Snowden, in fact, the sense-making process brings up the three following connected questions: “Do we see the data?”, “Do we pay attention to the data?” and “Will we, or can we get others, to act on the data?”.Footnote 82 These issues appear, undoubtedly, to be of crucial importance not only because the context of anti-corruption is complex and uncertain,Footnote 83 but also because human perceptions and perception-based metrics are commonly used in anti-corruption policies and studies.Footnote 84 In fact, considering the seemingly intractable nature of corruption, Heywood asks how we measure something that is, by its very nature, largely hidden. Nonetheless, he goes on to provide three goods reasons for doing so: “first, it is important to assess the scale of the issue, in terms of its extent, location and trends, so that we know what we are dealing with. Second, we want to see whether there are any clear patterns in order, third, to help identify explanatory variables that will aid our understanding of why and where corruption develops”.Footnote 85

In summary, measuring corruption helps us improve our ability to see where to take action. Thus, in navigating anti-corruption complexity, the Cynefin framework appears – at the intersection of complexity studies and law – to be the right framework to provide meaningful policy insights in order to guide this process. Cynefin’s approach to sense-making, in fact, allows us to better understand the natural behaviour of humans and “… to build systems to build on that understanding”, rejecting the creation of “… an idealistic system based on how things should be, to which human behaviour is then conformed”.Footnote 86

V. Corruption policy and regulatory objectives vis-à-vis Cynefin’s domain

The decision-aiding framework described above has been incorporated into the discussion for several reasons. In providing a new way to approach and assimilate complexity – and complexity perception – of our real world, it orderly sorts the wide range of issues faced by policymakers into five contexts. In doing so, it offers an important distinction based on the relationships between cause and effect, differentiating the issues by their relative nature. This allowed us to contextualise what we previously discussed about complexity, the characterisation of corruption as “complex” and, accordingly, the advance of complexity theory into the connected policy and regulatory debate.

Moreover, since the framework has been conceived to deal with a variety of policy scenarios, its main characteristics have been thoroughly examined so as to foresee whether and how it could be effectively deployed for anti-corruption policy and regulation.

In this respect, Cynefin proves to be an insightful tool – we believe – for shedding light on some critical issues of corruption (ie its perception and its measurement). This, as has been seen, is not only because Cynefin’s approach to sense-making allows for a better understanding of the natural behaviour of humans, but also, in light of the three highlighted issues within its approach, it allows for a better understanding of whether we see data, whether we pay attention to the data and whether we can act – or whether we can get others to act – on the same.

As is well known, in fact, the policymaking process involves collecting as much information on an issue as possible, even though it is impossible to obtain all such information. It would ideally require sifting out all possible scenarios, despite it being impossible to consider all potential outcomes. It would ideally allow for revisions and adjustments any time that these are needed, but – again – it turns out to be impossible to guarantee ways to fix flaws as they come up. Footnote 87 And within anti-corruption, it is well acknowledged that such difficulties in collecting information and in measurement are exacerbated more and more by the very elusive nature of the phenomenon.

Over recent decades, for example, numerous sources of information have been employed to assess corruption and its impact on the environment, helping to delineate, for example, “regulatory, managerial, probing, compliance, promotional and reactive measures” in order to face the phenomenon. Footnote 88 However, as is observed in the Manual on Corruption Surveys, when the measurement of corruption begins, “the difficulty of collecting relevant evidence favoured the use of indirect approaches, in which the measurement is not based on the occurrence of the phenomenon of interest but on other methods of assessment”. Footnote 89 The manual therefore sets out the principal indirect approaches used in the assessment of corruption. It distinguishes between “expert assessments”, where a select group of experts is asked to provide an assessment of corruption trends and patterns, and “composite indices” (ie the application of methodologies to combine a variety of statistical data into a single indicator). Data may derive from evidence-based metrics, even if they generally arise from expert assessments and surveys, as well as from proxy indicators (eg freedom of the press). Footnote 90 Nonetheless, despite the advances in measurement, Footnote 91 such indicators still suffer from serious weaknesses in relation to their validity, relevance and use, as well as the other “perception-based indicators” and “experienced-based indicators”, placed by the Manual into the category of direct methods. Footnote 92

Such challenges relating to collecting and gauging corruption data could effectively be dealt with by drawing on Michaels’ pioneering contribution.Footnote 93 Michaels, in fact, examines how six different knowledge brokering strategies – “informing, consulting, matchmaking, engaging, collaborating and building capacity”Footnote 94 – might be employed in responding to the several environmental policy problems or policy setting recognised in decision-aiding frameworks. In building up her arguments, the author analyses the feasibility of primary knowledge brokering strategies with four different decision-aiding frameworks, comprising the Cynefin framework.

Knowledge brokers are people or organisations that move knowledge around,Footnote 95 creating connections and acting, in substance, as intermediaries between researchers, producers of knowledge and policymakers, who are the prospective consumers of that knowledge.Footnote 96 As Meyer maintains, in fact, knowledge brokers not only move knowledge, but they also produce a new kind of the same: “brokered knowledge”.Footnote 97 Given the above, Michaels, however, specifies that there is no exclusive, ideal form of knowledge brokering within policy development but, rather, a spectrum of strategies for brokering knowledge, from which the six ones discussed in her contribution have been selected, and matched, with the four decision-aiding frameworks.Footnote 98

For example, the author identifies as primary brokering strategies within Cynefin’s domains the following ones: within the simple or known domain, “informing”; within the complicated or knowable domain, “consulting”; within the complex domain, “engaging”; and, finally, within the chaotic domain, “opportunistic entrepreneurship”.Footnote 99 As is seen, in fact, in the ordered domain of known cause-and-effect relationships, the same relationships are linear and empirically proven. Therefore, as argued by Kurtz and Snowden, “consistency” and “efficiency” can be obtained through the incorporation of what is known into structured process like single-point forecasting, field manuals and operational procedures. The decision model is “… to sense incoming data, categorize that data, and then respond in accordance with predetermined practice”.Footnote 100 In the ordered domains of knowable causes and effects, instead, while stable cause-and-effect relationships exist, “… they may not be fully known, or they may be known only by a limited group of people”.Footnote 101 As stressed by the authors, in fact, this is the domain of system thinking, learning organisations or adaptive enterprise, which are too often confused with complexity theory. In this domain, therefore, “experiment, expert opinion, fact-finding, and scenario-planning are appropriate”; the decision model here is therefore “to sense incoming data, analyze that data, and then respond in accordance with expert advice or interpretation of that analysis”.Footnote 102

As the argument goes, it is possible to observe that, broadly speaking, the vast majority of current corruption proxies, indicators, indices and their traditional methods comes within the ordered domains. However, since they intrinsically approach corruption in a standardised and linear fashion, some issues may arise insofar as the domain, as discussed, will tend to be “complex” rather than “complicated” or “simple”. Footnote 103 As was seen in Section III, for example, the unpredictability of such systems is strictly connected to the fact that individuals – who generally operate with an understanding of having free will – cannot be singled out and examined separately from each other to explain the emergence of the collective phenomena that their decisions may originate. In other words, when complex problems are addressed using standard linear and reductionist approaches, serious risks can originate that have the potential, at the bottom, to nullify policy efforts.

Moving to the unordered domain of complex relationships, we finally land on the area where complexity theory studies, as we have seen, how patterns emerge through the interaction of many agents. Here, cause-and-effect relationships are present between the agents, but “… both the number of agents and the number of relationships defy categorization or analytic techniques”.Footnote 104 For these reasons, policymaking should be reluctant to fully incorporate experts’ opinions on historically stable trends and patterns in order to foresee and manage future scenarios. This reflects exactly the situation of corruption in expert assessments where a selected group of experts is asked to provide an assessment of corruption trends and patterns of meaning. Accordingly, the decision model within this domain aims to create “probes” in order to make the patterns or potential patterns more visible before we take any action; then we can sense those patterns and respond “… by stabilizing those patterns that we find desirable, by destabilizing those we do not want, and by seeding the space so that patterns we want are more likely to emerge”.Footnote 105 Here, as we have seen, Michaels identifies “engaging” as a primary brokering strategy that seems very appropriate for bringing about advantages in complex anti-corruption environments. Briefly, the intent of this strategy is to frame the discussion through terms of reference within the decision-making process, involving other parties in the fundamental aspects of the problem. Examples of engaging brokering techniques are, according to the author, “Royal commissions”, “Technical committees” and “Secondments” in order to identify those “… who need to be engaged and how” and to identify and expose decision-makers to “salient, multiple perspectives”.Footnote 106 By contrast, in the chaotic domain, everything changes. Here, there are no such perceivable relations, and the system is “turbulent”; therefore, the decision model aims “… to act, quickly and decisively, to reduce the turbulence and then, to sense immediately the reaction to that intervention so that we can respond accordingly”.Footnote 107

Therefore, as we have discussed, fostering collaborations and unconventional cross-sectional synergies between researchers from different disciplines in the context of today’s massive use of technologies appears crucial and is strongly recommended for gauging and responding to corruption. Similar objectives, however, seem achievable only if strongly supported by international organisations like the United Nations or, in the ambit of the European Union, if promoted by the European Commission. Such initiatives could in fact trigger a process of expansion of the existing methodologies, paving the way to innovative approaches to complex systems that could be valuable to both the system as such and each and every component of such system. Following this multi- and trans-disciplinary view within anti-corruption seems likely to be the best way to provide new perspectives for policymakers and leaders who are called to respond to a phenomenon that evolves at the same rate as today’s interconnected and networked world of techno-social systems, creating uncontrollable and unpredictable situations that exponentially increase their riskiness. Thus, enhancing the technological advancements conjointly with multi- and trans-disciplinary efforts in responding to corruption, as we have expressed, could represent a full-fledged opportunity to devise methodological approaches and instruments that can be more adequately deployed in the context of the times we are living in.

From this perspective, technology should favour the required dialogue addressing, for example, fundamental questions pertaining to corruption measurement and, hence, its perception and the related issues about trust and confidence.

In the next and evaluative section, we will further examine the relationship between the “perception” of corruption and “confidence” in light of technological advancement and complexity. As argued by Clausen et al, there exists a “… quantitatively large and statistically significant negative correlation between corruption and confidence in public institutions”.Footnote 108 This appears, in fact, to be crucial for understanding and controlling corruption, as well as being intimately connected to what is discussed in the final sections of this article. As such, “perception” and “confidence” lend themselves well to providing paradigmatic examples of possible connections between highly contextualised micro-level individual behaviours surrounding corruption and larger regulatory system-wide phenomena.

VI. Corruption perception and confidence within techno-social systems

The highlighted negative correlation that characterises the relationship between corruption and confidence in public institutions deserves to be further analysed for several reasons. The first and most basic of these reasons concerns the relationship between corruption and confidence “per se”. As also observed by Clausen et al, in fact, despite such a negative effect revealing an important channel through which corruption can inhibit economic and social development, it remains relatively under-examined in literature. Footnote 109 A second reason may concern, instead, the relationship between corruption, confidence and the emergence of other outcomes. To this point, the same authors find, for example, “… strong evidence that a lack of confidence in public institutions raises sympathy for violent protest, raises the desire to migrate, and reduces political participation”. Footnote 110

In zooming in on such a negative correlation, however, one of major contributing factors also lies in “perception”. To contextualise this, we still consider – at the risk of some oversimplification – certain findings arising from the mentioned study of Clausen et al that measure corruption and confidence in public institutions by using selected questions of the Gallup World Poll (GWP) survey – the largest (on a country coverage basis) annual multi-country household survey in the world. To create an index of confidence, the authors therefore sum together the responses pertaining to the confidence of respondents about the survey’s questions (a), (b), (c) and (h), which are representative of confidence in public institutions. Footnote 111 As their key measure of corruption, instead, the authors use a different question from the GWP about respondents’ personal experience with corruption. Footnote 112 In addition, as that GWP provides a more generic question about respondents’ personal perception of corruption, Footnote 113 the authors also use this more generic question as another measure. In parallel, the authors illustrate the country-level variation in these two measures of corruption and find that all countries “fall above the 45-degree line”, therefore indicating that “on average” all of the respondents are more likely to answer “yes” to the corruption perception question than to the corruption experience questions. Footnote 114

What consistently emerges from this corruption perception measure, in summary, is the respondents’ exposure to “second-hand” information about corruption activity. Such a “hearsay” effect, in fact, “… might very well artificially amplify the relationship between corruption and confidence in public institutions”, representing the centrality of perception in understanding corruption. Footnote 115 In light of this artificial amplification, the recent upsurge of technological innovations and the social changes they bring with them raise pressing questions regarding the consequences they may have on perception. Governments have indeed started to identify the technological revolution as a way of addressing the empowerment of individuals to participate in society as a whole. A new canon of literature has emerged in relation to e-government and corruption prevention, thanks, for example, to the adoption of artificial intelligence.Footnote 116 E-government is gaining popularity amongst practitioners and researchers due to its potential to increase transparency and combat corruption in government administration.Footnote 117 Some empirical studies in fact showed that, over the last decade, increases in the use of e-government have led to reductions in corruption in non-Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries.Footnote 118 Quite importantly, it has been noticed that e-government solutions can lower the interaction between government officials and citizens and hence diminish the discretionary power of officials, which, in turn, minimizes the opportunities for corrupt practices.Footnote 119

Digital technologies and emerging technologies, as a matter of fact, are not only fostering new ways of communication, involvement and cooperation between individuals and society, but they are also modifying the ways under in confidence and perceptions take shape.Footnote 120 It is well known, for instance, that blockchain has been launched as an initiative to regain public trust in traditional institutions and intermediaries by promising, in essence, to revolutionise the myriad of services provided by government agencies at all levels. Footnote 121 The decentralised ledger technology thus not only emerged as a potential solution to the erosion of trust, but, as it happens, it has also effectively and dramatically changed the idea – and perception – of the same. Footnote 122

Overall, emerging technologies therefore have the potential to affect individuals’ perceptions and their confidence. In this respect, coming back to the mentioned centrality of “perceptions” within the study of corruption, Bautista-Beauchense identifies, indeed, the necessity from a theoretical standpoint to develop a conceptual tool for the analysis of corruption perceptions and also to account for contextual norms that adapt flexibly to the changing nature of the phenomenon. The author similarly puts forward the concept of “corruption folklore” to address this gap. Footnote 123 Elaborating on Myrdal’s description of the concept, which refers to people’s “beliefs about corruption and the emotions attached to those beliefs, as disclosed in the public debate and in gossip”, Footnote 124 Bautista-Beauchense proposes to “… take the concept a step further”, arguing that “… folklore is not only constituted of ‘bad guesses’, but rather, a melting pot of facts, rumours, stories, gossip and hearsay. The folklore can be complex and contradictory, as it does not represent a dichotomous understanding of the state of corruption in a given context …”. Footnote 125 Therefore, the same author also specifies that folklore, as fully described in his study, creates somewhat of a “buffer” between perceptions of corruption and agents’ strategies and actions. Thus, in his view, “the key theoretical point is that corruption perceptions create a folklore, not strategies or actions. The folklore influences expected risks and rewards (as the principal-agent theory describes); and the folklore affects the broad understandings and shared expectations provided by the institutional context (as underlined by the collective action theorists)”. Footnote 126

Along similar lines, the link between the findings of the previous sections about the most referred to measures and indices of corruption therefore appears evident. Footnote 127 Likewise, this also holds true for Cynefin’s approach to sense-making, which allows for a better understanding of the natural behaviour of humans and for building systems on that understanding, questioning whether we see data, whether we pay attention to the data and whether we can act – or whether we can get others to act – on the same.

As has been seen, Cynefin could therefore help us to incorporate the complexity of perceptions of modern techno-social systems, guiding policymaking to look at corruption phenomena from different perspectives.

Moreover, as we have already seen, complexity theory emphasises how important the components and their interactions are in the system. Footnote 128 Furthermore, such interactions “… among the system’s constituents are not centrally controlled, but rather local”, Footnote 129 as has been seen, and are not random, since we have “the response time” when investigating the change. Footnote 130 This decentralisation of a system’s constituents aligns with the centrality of perception as well as with the potential stemming from modern technology.

For example, the European Union’s anti-corruption report Footnote 131 of 2014 evaluated the cost of corruption “alone” at about €120 billion per year. To this point, Shalvi highlights that such a report “makes it clear that the costs are not just financial”, even considering that “corruption not only deprives people of economic prosperity and growth, but also jeopardizes their intrinsic honesty”. Footnote 132 Nonetheless, as an extremely stylised example, an increment in dishonesty within a given population can multiply the possibility that corruption scandals will emerge, which will likely in turn make corruption perception grow. Along these lines, as observed by Melgar et al, a “high level of corruption perception could have more devastating effects than corruption itself; it generates a ‘culture of distrust’ towards some institutions and may create a cultural tradition of giving and hence, raising corruption”. Footnote 133 Furthermore, relating to the mentioned “distrust”, as the vast majority of the literature has affirmed, corruption negatively affects “trust” and “confidence” in several ways and, therefore, both foreign direct investment and domestic investment. Footnote 134

As has been shown, corruption lead to a wide array of consequences that impact at the level of perception. In this respect, complexity theory provides an enlightening perspective on such a matter, especially regarding confidence. To this point, Luhman Footnote 135 and De Filippi et al, for example, stress that “interacting with a complex system is likely to require more trust than interacting with a single entity, or with a system made of only a few simple parts. Indeed, lack of trust in any of the constitutive parts of a system might bring people to distrust the system as a whole”. Footnote 136 The same authors therefore state that “the higher the complexity of a system, the longer it will take for concrete expectations to develop about the operations of that system”. Footnote 137

Human perceptions escalate and thus create what could be described as “corruption reverberations” that bounce around the systems. Such reverberations develop and spread over the systems, setting in motion a chain of consequences that call for policy action. Indeed, a loss of confidence brings about systemic risk that has the potential to dramatically undermine the integrity and soundness of the system itself.

VII. Concluding remarks

Technology is reshaping the way interactions take place. Technological advancement will likely morph and manifest in a myriad of media, offering untold conveniences and unknown challenges and creating unappreciated risks and immeasurable opportunities for corruption. In this perspective, emergent technology may play a role in creating considerable rewards for measuring corruption or, better, the perception of it. A theme that is likely to persist is the enduring relevance of the confidence underpinning such interactions. In the end, all humans are moved and tied by an inescapable network of perception mutuality, the fruits of which are relentlessly destined to shape individual and collective behaviour. The greater the number of the components in the systems (bureaucrats, constituencies, individuals, intermediaries), the higher the level of confidence that needs to be built in. The more complex, layered and intertwined the society, the greater the size of the “grey areas” where corruption can emerge in ways that are still to be fully understood. The Cynefin framework could aid policymakers to take a systematic approach and focus on the determinants of corruption as a complex adaptive phenomenon. Cynefin could in fact account for interactions and interrelationships between the different contributing factors, helping qualify the linear or non-linear nature of the relationships between “causes” and “effects”. In increasingly complex techno-social systems, future research could further investigate ways by which to capture the connections between the highly contextualised micro-level individual behaviours surrounding corruption and larger regulatory system-wide phenomena.

Footnotes

This research has been carried out thanks to the generous support and funding of the Prince Mohammad Bin Fahd Center for Futuristic Studies at Prince Mohammad Bin Fahd University (first “Futures Research Grant”).

References

1 See, eg, JC Andvig et al, “Corruption. A review of contemporary research” (2001) <http://hdl.handle.net/11250/247368> (last accessed 3 April 2021); M Riccardi and F Sarno, “Corruption” in G Bruinsma and D Weisburd (eds), Encyclopedia of Criminology and Criminal Justice (Berlin, Springer 2014) pp 630–41; E Dávid-Barrett et al, “Controlling corruption in development aid: new evidence from contract-level data” (2020) 55 Studies in Comparative International Development 481–515.

2 A Vespigiani, “Predicting the behavior of techno-social systems” (2009) 325 Science 425–28.

3 D Byrne and G Callaghan, Complexity Theory and the Social Sciences. The State of the Art (London, Routledge 2014) p 8.

4 D Snowden, “Cynefin, a sense of time and place: an ecological approach to sense making and learning in formal and informal communities” (2000) <https://www.researchgate.net/publication/264884267_Cynefin_A_Sense_of_Time_and_Place_an_Ecological_Approach_to_Sense_Making_and_Learning_in_Formal_and_Informal_Communities> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

5 Such contexts are not clear-cut categories as they rather present blurred boundaries, as explained in Section IV.

6 Such a debate has been extremely relevant not only for the conceptualisation of corruption as such, but also for the study of it. In this respect, see, eg, MJ Farrales, “What is corruption? A history of corruption studies and the great definitions debate” (2005) <https://ssrn.com/abstract=1739962> (last accessed 3 April 2021). The author stresses that, since the beginning of such study, it has not aimed to develop a universally acceptable definition of “corruption” because this would be an undertaking both “Herculean” and “Sisyphean” in nature – “Herculean” in terms of the immense amount of knowledge historically developed in the field and “Sisyphean” because our perception of corruption has evolved (and continues to evolve) over time. See also G Brooks et al, “Defining corruption” in Preventing Corruption, Crime Prevention and Security Management (London, Palgrave Macmillan 2013).

7 The term “corruption”, per se, has been analysed in depth by scholars over recent decades. See, eg, AJ Heidenheimer and M Johnston, Political Corruption. Concepts & Contexts (3rd edn, London, Routledge 2001). This work has incorporated economic, cultural and linguistic perspectives, with a systemic focus on the relationship between the terminology and the concepts involved in it. Due to the importance of this distinction, more specifically, the authors have always stressed the importance of conducting scientific research regarding it. As highlighted by Génaux, the term “corruption” appears in many languages, “… but behind it lie several contrasting strands of thought and language”. See M Génaux, “Social sciences and the evolving concept of corruption” (2004) 42 Crime, Law and Social Change 13. Along these lines, Génaux analyses the evolution of the term within the context of Anglo-Saxon legal thought from its Roman roots, also considering the French lexicographic and the Biblical origins of the same. In such a way, the author shows how the richness of the term is often lost in the “more technical usages that dominate contemporary debate and analysis”.

8 See, eg, VJ Klaveren, “Corruption as a historical phenomenon” in AJ Heidenheimer and M Johnston (eds), Political Corruption. Concepts & Contexts (3rd edn, London, Routledge 2001); A Barr. and D Serra, “Corruption and culture: an experimental analysis” (2010) 94(11–12) Journal of Public Economics 862–69; E Fein and J Weibler, “Review and shortcomings of literature on corruption in organizations in offering a multi-faceted and integrative understanding of the phenomenon” (2014) 19(3) Behavioral Development Bulletin 67–77; D Torsello and B Venard, “The anthropology of corruption” (2016) 25(1) Journal of Managment Inquiry 34–54.

9 N Mocan, “What determines corruption? International evidence from microdata” (2008) 46(4) Economic Inquiry 493–510.

10 See, eg, S Pillay and N Dorasamy, “Linking cultural dimensions with the nature of corruption: an institutional theory perspective” (2010) 10(3) International Journal of Cross Cultural Management 363–78; VG Fitzsimons, “Economic models of corruption” in S Bracking (ed.), Corruption and Development: The Anti-Corruption Campaigns (London, Palgrave Macmillan 2007).

11 Transparency International, instead, recently defined corruption as “the abuse of public office for private gain” and, as is known, this definition represents one of the most adopted notions to refer to it, being also shared by other organisations such as the World Bank. It is important to note that Transparency International used another, more general version of the same definition (ie “the abuse of entrusted power for private gain”) that, in 2012, was selected as the best option for the purposes of the Corruption Perception Index (CPI) of the same non-governmental organisation.

12 The layering of governmental institutions and the relationship between individuals and economic actors have reached levels of interconnectedness and complexity that are very hard to describe. As has been stated, a key role in this ongoing condition is certainly played by the impact of technological change. An example of such interaction comes from environmental studies. See, eg, AB Jaffe et al, “Environmental policy and technological change” (2002) 22 Environmental and Resource Economics 41–69. In addition, technological progress had changed how transactions take place in the entire global financial system. For a functional overview of “how technologies are making us rethink leading, regulation and compliance, risk management, insurance, stock trading, payments, and money in the fourth industrial age”, see T Lynn et al, Disrupting Finance: Fintech and Strategy in the 21st Century (Berlin, Springer Nature 2019).

13 UNODC, “The United Nations and action against corruption: a global response to a global challenge” <https://www.unodc.org/pdf/9dec04/Action_E.pdf≥ (last accessed 3 April 2021).

14 See, eg, BE Ashforth et al, “Re-viewing organizational corruption” (2008) 33(3) Academy of Management Review 670–84; A Persson et al, “Why anticorruption reforms fail – systemic corruption as a collective action problem” (2013) 26(3) Governance 449–71; A Minto, “Characterising corruption by adopting a systemic risk perspective: importing macro prudential financial regulation into the policy debate” (2020) 11(1) European Journal of Risk Regulation 1–17.

15 A Lambert-Mogiliansky, “Why firms pay occasional bribes: the connection economy” (2002) 18(1) European Journal of Political Economy 47–60. More specifically, the author, regarding the legal and administrative system, provides arguments in support of the claim that “instability and complexity are factors that favour corruption”.

16 Brooks et al, supra, note 6.

17 Y Luo, “An organizational perspective of corruption” (2004) 1(1) Management and Organization Review 119–54. This study proposes that “institutional transparency, institutional fairness and institutional complexity” are important components in relation to corruption environment.

18 See, eg, Ashforth et al, supra, note 14.

19 See, eg, S Saha et al, “Is there a ‘consensus’ towards Transparency: international’s corruption perceptions index?” (2012) 20(1) International Journal of Business Studies 1–9.

20 R Calderón and JL Álvarez-Arce, “Corruption, complexity and governance: the role of transparency in highly complex systems” (2011) 8(3) Corporate Ownership and Control 245–57.

21 F Habtemichael and F Cloete, “Complexity thinking in the fight against corruption: some perspectives from South Africa” (2010) 37(1) Politikon 93. For a more “conceptual” view on the complexity of corruption, see also J Hazy et al, “Notes on the complexity of corruption” (Academy of Management Review Annual Meeting Proceedings 2017) <https://doi.org/10.5465/AMBPP.2017.13073abstract> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

22 I Luna-Pla and JR Nicolás-Carlock, “Corruption and complexity: a scientific framework for the analysis of corruption networks” (2020) 5(13) Applied Network Science 2–18. Wachs et al have used methods from network science “to analyze corruption risk in a large administrative dataset of over 4 million public procurement contracts from European Union members”. Covering the years 2008–2016, indeed, their work aims to visualise and describe the distribution of corruption risk. See J Wachs, M Fazekas and J Kertész, ‘“Corruption risk in contracting markets: a network science perspective” (2020) International Journal of Data Science Analysis <https://doi.org/10.1007/s41060-019-00204-1> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

23 See, eg, A Mungiu-Pippidi, “The time has come for evidence-based anticorruption” (2017) 1(1) Nature Human Behaviour 1–3.

24 M Walton, “Applying complexity theory: a review to inform evaluation design” (2014) 45 Evaluation and Program Planning 119–26.

25 Byrne and Callaghan, supra, note 3, 8.

26 Complex systems are generally made up of several and different interacting “elements”, “components” or “systems” that are more often than not different between themselves. For an introductory overview see, eg, M Mitchell, Complexity: A Guided Tour (Oxford, Oxford University Press 2009); F Capra and PF Luisi, The Systems View of Life: A Unifying Vision (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press 2016). In the same vein, see also M De Domenico et al, “Complexity explained” (2019) <https://complexityexplained.github.io/ComplexityExplained.pdf> (last accessed 3 April 2021). In this article it is also possible to find a synthetic and well-organised review of some of the most fundamental contributions from the fields of complexity, divided into the following seven sections: “Interactions”, “Emergence”, “Dynamics”, “Self-Organization”, “Adaptation”, Interdisciplinarity” and “Methods”.

27 Nonetheless, it is possible to state, as observed by Byrne and Callaghan (supra, note 3), that “complexity” refers to systems, as it is a property of some of them. On this point, see R Rosen, “On complex systems” (1987) 30(2) European Journal of Operational Research 129–34.

28 NF Johnson, “Two’s company, three is complexity” in Simply Complexity: A Clear Guide to Complexity Theory (London, Oneworld Publications 2009).

29 ibid. In this well-known contribution, the author finds in a crowd a “perfect example” of such an emergent phenomenon, “since it is a phenomenon which emerges from a collection of interacting people”. Furthermore, the author adds that everyday examples of crowds include collections of “commuters, financial markets, traders, human cells, or insurgents – and the associated crowd-like phenomena which emerge are traffic jams, market crashes, cancer tumors, and guerrilla wars”.

30 Luna-Pla and Nicolás-Carlock, supra, note 22, 6.

31 Calderón and Álvarez-Arce, supra, note 20, 245.

32 It has been argued, for example, that “complexity theory does not refer to one theory or set of ideas but rather is an umbrella term for an array of concepts that share similar assumptions about the nature of reality and how researchers come to know this reality”. LM Kallemeyn, JN Hall and E Gates, “Exploring the relevance of complexity theory for mixed methods research” (2020) 14(3) Journal of Mixed Methods Research 288–304.

33 As discussed by Castellani, scholars generally refer to this as “the advance of the complexity sciences or, alternatively, complexity theory or complex systems theory”. B Castellani, “Complexity and the failure of quantitative social science” (2014) 12(12) Focus.

34 See, eg, Kallemeyn et al, supra, note 32.

35 Byrne and Callaghan, supra, note 3. See also DS Byrne, Complexity Theory and the Social Sciences: An Introduction (Hove, Psychology Press 1998); JR Turner and RM Baker, “Complexity theory: an overview with potential applications for the social sciences” (2019) 7(1) Systems 4.

36 Byrne and Callaghan, supra, note 3.

37 Models are of central relevance in many scientific contexts across all fields of study. However, despite the abundance of the recognised types of models, what is important to underline with regards to the main discussion lies in the fact that the mentioned models raise questions “in semantic (how, if at all, do models represent?), ontology (what kind of things are models?), epistemology (how do we learn and explain with models?), and, of course, in other domains within philosophy of science”. See R Frigg and S Hartmann, “Models in science” <https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2020/entries/models-science/> (last accessed 3 April 2021). This quote shows how important semantic, ontological and epistemological questions are in relation to complexity theory and its application to the corruption problem. On this point, see also A Williams, “Complexity from the sciences to social systems” in Political Hegemony and Social Complexity (London, Palgrave Macmillan 2020).

38 J Cohen and I Stewart, The Collapse of Chaos: Discovering Simplicity in a Complex World (London, Penguin Books 1994).

39 Reduction, as a scientific procedure, has been applied in a variety of domains. Nevertheless, the science of complexity now “is based on a new way of thinking that stands in sharp contrast to the philosophy underlying Newtonian science, which is based on reductionism, determinism, and objective knowledge”. For an overview of the historical development of the philosophical foundation of the field, see F Heylighen et al, “Complexity and philosophy” (2006) <arXiv:cs/0604072> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

40 Turner and Baker, supra, note 35, 2. See also V Vasiliauskaite and FE Rosas, “Understanding complexity via network theory: a gentle introduction” (2020) <https://arxiv.org/pdf/2004.14845.pdf> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

41 Turner and Baker, supra, note 40, 2 (emphasis added).

42 E Yeboah-Assiamah, “‘Strong personalities’ and ‘strong institutions’ mediated by a ‘strong third force’: thinking ‘systems’ in corruption control” 17(4) Public Organization Review 547.

43 I Goldin and T Vogel, “Global governance and systemic risk in the 21st century: lessons from the financial crisis” (2010) 1(1) Global Policy 4–15.

44 See, eg, Minto, supra, note 14.

45 E Morin, “Complex thinking for a complex world – about reductionism, disjunction and systemism” (2014) 2(1) Systema 17. According to the author, looking at complex systems from this perspective reveals something interesting: “not only is the part inside the whole but the whole is inside the part”.

46 As stated by Calderón and Álvarez-Arce (supra, note 20), corruption “… is a system and, therefore, systemic descriptions represent the only way to a correct understanding”. Moreover, the mentioned statement is then followed by four hypotheses regarding, respectively, the high number of “heterogeneous elements” that form such a systemic structure; the relationships among elements, which are essentially “non-trivial interactions”; the fact that the described system is capable of “surprising behaviours”, “by responding in more than one way to any change in its environment”; and, finally, the fact that it is capable of “novelty”, “by evolving into states that are not apparent from its constituents”.

47 Turner and Baker, supra, note 35.

48 G Caldarelli, S Wolf and Y Moreno, “Physics of humans, physics for society” (2018) 14(9) Nature Physics 870. In this letter to the editors, the authors start with a reflection on today’s massive use of information and communication technologies that has made it possible “to attach a traceable set of data to almost any person”. They argue that, since the beginning, these data provide the opportunity to build a “physics of society: describing a society – composed of many interacting heterogeneous entities (people, businesses, institutions) – as a physical system”.

49 A Bastardas-Boada, “Complexics as a meta-transdisciplinary field” (Congrès Mondial Pour la Penséè Complexe. Les Défis d’Un Monde Globalisè. Paris, UNESCO, December 2026) p 6; LG Rodríguez Zoia and P Roggero, “Sur le Lien Entre Pensée et Systèmes Complexes” 60 <http://hdl.handle.net/2042/45460> (last accessed 3 April 2021) pp 151–56; LG Rodríguez Zoia and G Leonardo, “Le Modèle Épistémologique de la Pensée Complexe. Analyse Critique de la Construction de la Connaissance en Systèmes Complexes” (DPhil thesis, University of Toulouse 2013).

50 B Mueller, “Why public policies fail: policymaking under complexity” (2020) 21(2) Economica 311–23.

51 D Helbing, “Globally networked risks and how to respond” (2013) 497 Nature 51–59.

52 Vespignani, supra, note 2.

53 See D Snowden, “Complex Acts of Knowing: Paradox and Descriptive Self-awareness” (2002) 6(2) Journal of Knowledge Management 100–11; CF Kurtz and D Snowden, “The new dynamics of strategy: sense-making in a complex and complicated world” (2003) 42(3) IBM Systems Journal 462–83; D Snowden “Strategy in the context of uncertainty” (2005) 6(1) Handbook of Business Strategy 47–54; D Snowden and ME Boone, “A leader’s framework for decision making” (2007) 85(11) Harvard Business Review 69–76.

54 According to Snowden and Boone, the complex domain’s crucial characteristic is represented by the fact that it is possible to understand why things happen only “in retrospect”. See Snowden and Boone, supra, note 53.

55 Using the words of Snowden and Boone, the difference between the complicated and the complex is like the difference between a Ferrari and the Brazilian rainforest. “The car is static, and the whole is the sum of its parts. The rainforest, on the other hand, is in a constant flux – a species becomes extinct, weather patterns change … – and the whole is far more than the sum of its parts”. See Snowden and Boone, supra, note 53.

56 Westerhoff, for example, proposed a computer simulation to show how interactions amongst investors can lead to bubbles and crashes endogenous to the system. See F Westerhoff, “The use of agent-based financial market models to test the effectiveness of regulatory policies” (2008) 228(2–3) Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 195–227.

57 As pointed out by Browning and Boudès, Snowden uses the compound term “sense-making” to describe a whole set of processes such as, for example, the Story Circles and “knowledge disclosure points” (KDPs), as well as to indicate the use of narrative theory to understand the complexity of organisational environments. See LD Browning and T Boudès, “The use of narrative to understand and respond to complexity: a comparative analysis of the Cynefin and Weickian models” (2005) 7(3–4) E:CO Issue 32–39.

58 ibid.

59 J McLeod and S Childs, “The Cynefin framework: a tool for analyzing qualitative data in information science?” (2013) 35(4) Library & Information Science Research 307. More specifically, in their contribution, the authors explore the potential of the framework not only to structure findings or discussions and draw conclusions, but also to be used as “… a qualitative data analysis tool and also as a collaborative qualitative data collection tool”.

60 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53. More specifically, the framework is rooted in knowledge management studies of process development under uncertain conditions. Nevertheless, its application has grown over the years through the progressive incorporation of insights and methodologies coming from complexity theory. It has been applied in the fields of strategy, management, training, cultural change and policymaking, thus from governments to organisations, and from natural disaster to terrorist attacks.

61 Snowden and Boone, supra, note 53.

62 Browning and Boudès, supra, note 57. According to Kurtz and Snowden, in fact, possible uses of this model include “contextualization” and “narrative history exercises”. On this point, see Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53.

63 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53.

64 Snowden and Boone, supra, note 53.

65 RJ Hammer, JS Edwards and E Tapinos, “Examining the strategy development process through the lens of complex adaptive systems theory” (2012) 63 Journal of the Operational Research Society 909–19.

66 Turner and Baker (supra, note 35) observe that some “complicated” states, for example, “could have a touch of complexity up to a point”. See also S French, “Cynefin: uncertainty, small worlds and scenarios” (2015) 66(10) Journal of the Operational Research Society 1635–45. It is crucial to observe that it would be an error to think of the domains as hard categorisations. On this point, French rightly argued that “… the boundaries are soft and contexts lying near these have characteristics drawn from both sides”. However, taken with a suitably large “pinch of salt”, as is maintained by the same author, Cynefin will consistently help our discussion.

67 Turner and Baker, supra, note 35.

68 ibid.

69 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53, 469. More specifically, patterns “… may indeed repeat for a time in this space, but we cannot be sure that they will continue to repeat”.

70 Snowden and Boone, supra, note 53 (emphasis added).

71 ibid.

72 R Geyer, “Beyond the third way: the science of complexity and the politics of choice” (2003) 5(2) British Journal of Political Science 253.

73 K Mainzer, Thinking in Complexity: The Computational Dynamics of Matter, Mind, and Mankind (4th edn, Berlin, Springer 2004).

74 JK Alter and S Meunier, “The politics of international regime complexity” (2009) 7(1) Perspectives on Politics 13–24. In the financial sector, for example, the overarching goal of policy institutions all over the world is to guarantee financial stability over time and protect against systemic threats in the long term.

75 LG Baxter, “Adaptive regulation in the amoral bazaar” (2011) 128(2) South Africa Law Journal 264–68.

76 MA Chinen, “Governing complexity” in J Murray, T Webb and S Wheatley (eds), Complexity Theory and Law: Mapping an Emergent Jurisprudence (London, Routledge 2018) p 155.

77 JH Miller and SE Page, Complex Adaptive Systems: An Introduction to Computational Models of Social Life (Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press 2007).

78 See. eg, D Helbing (ed.), Managing Complexity: Insights, Concepts, Application (Berlin, Springer 2008); D Helbing, Thinking Ahead. Essays on Big Data, Digital Revolution, and Participatory Market Society (Berlin, Springer 2015).

79 Helbing (2015), supra, note 78.

80 Helbing (2008), supra, note 78, 7. The author believes that complex systems possess in themselves immanent capacities to self-organise and to create resilient order.

81 D Snowden, “Perspectives around emergent connectivity, sense-making and asymmetric threat management” (2006) 26(5) Public Money Management 275. More specifically, Snowden maintains that sense-making comes in many forms. However, within that context he defines the same with the following question: “How do we make sense of the world so that we can act in it?”. Such a definition falls back on natural science and pragmatism, as well as the naturalism in epistemology (ie a naturalistic approach to epistemological theorising).

82 ibid, p 277.

83 As well as that of anti-terrorism, take the just mentioned contribution by Snowden as an example. See Snowden, supra, note 81.

84 See, eg, PM Heywood, “Measuring corruption, perspectives, critiques and limits” in PM Heywood (ed.), Routledge Handbook of Political Corruption (London, Routledge 2015) pp 137–53.

85 ibid, p 1.

86 Snowden, supra, note 81, 275–76.

87 P Cilliers, Complexity Theory and Postmodernism: Understanding Complex Systems (London, Routledge 1998) pp 139–40.

88 EK Owusu, AP Chan, OM DeGraft, EE Ameyaw and OK Robert, “Contemporary review of anti-corruption measures in construction project management” (2019) 50(1) Project Management Journal 40–56. This article is taken as an example because it identifies thirty-nine anti-corruption measures from thirty-eight selected publications in engineering management research.

89 UNODC, UNDP and UNODC-INEGI, Manual on Corruption Surveys (Center of Excellence in Statistical Information on Government, Crime, Victimization and Justice 2018) p 20 <https://www.unodc.org/documents/data-and-analysis/Crime-statistics/CorruptionManual_2018_web.pdf> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

90 Well-known examples of such indicators are the Control of Corruption Indicator of the World Bank Governance Indicators, the Transparency International Corruption Perceptions Index and the Global Integrity Index of Global Integrity.

91 S Sequeira, “Advances in measuring corruption in the field” in D Serra and L Wantchekon (eds), New Advances in Experimental Research on Corruption. Research in Experimental Economics (Bingley, Emerald Group Publishing 2011) pp 145–76.

92 There is a plethora of studies that highlights such weaknesses. As examples, see S Andersson and PM Heywood, “The politics of perception: use and abuse of Transparency International’s approach to measuring corruption” (2009) 57(4) Political Studies 746–67; K Ko and A Samajdar, “Evaluation of international corruption indexes: should we believe them or not?” (2010) 47(3) The Social Science Journal 508–40; F Méndez and F Sepúlveda, “What do we talk about when we talk about corruption?” (2010) 26(3) Journal of Law, Economics & Organation 493–514; N Charron, “Do corruption measures have a perception problem? Assessing the relationship between experiences and perceptions of corruption among citizens and experts” (2016) 8(1) European Political Science Review; G Qu et al, “Explaining the standard errors of corruption perception indices” (2019) 47(4) Journal of Comparative Economics 907–20.

93 S Michaels, “Matching knowledge brokering strategies to environmental policy problems and settings” (2009) 12(17) Environmental Science & Policy 994–1011.

94 ibid, p 994.

95 M Meyer, “The rise of the knowledge broker” (2010) 32(1) Science Communications 118.

96 Michaels, supra, note 93, p. 996. See also KT Litfin, Ozone Discourses: Science and Politics in Global Environmental Cooperation (New York, Columbia University Press 1994).

97 Meyer, supra, note 95, p 118.

98 Michaels, supra, note 93, p 997. The author considers explicitly how the six mentioned knowledge brokering strategies fit within the four analysed frameworks in order to determine the most constructive “as a useful complement” for use.

99 ibid. What is required from a broker within the chaotic domain is not mentioned in the earlier listed strategies. This is because in such a case it is impossible to learn from experience. Here, the decision model requires acting immediately in order to respond more appropriately.

100 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53, p 8 (emphasis in original).

101 ibid.

102 ibid (emphasis in original).

103 Over recent decades, researchers from all fields have shown how often problems are non-linear. In parallel, complexity theory emerged with the aim of filling the persistent gap left by traditional and linear research assumptions.

104 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53, p 469. Emergent patterns can be perceived but not predicted; the authors call this phenomenon “retrospective coherence”.

105 ibid. The authors therefore conclude that understanding this space “… requires us to gain multiple perspectives on the nature of the system”, stressing that the methods, tools and techniques of the ordered domains do not work in the complexity realm.

106 Michaels, supra, note 93, table 1, p 997 and table 5, p 1005.

107 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53. Within the chaotic domain, as has been seen, Michaels indeed identifies “opportunistic entrepreneurship” as the primary brokering strategy; ibid.

108 B Clausen, A Kraay and Z Nyiri, “Corruption and confidence in public institutions: evidence from a global survey” (2011) 25(2) World Bank Economic Review 212–49. The authors also show how this finding “… can plausibly be interpreted as reflecting at least in part a causal effect from corruption to confidence”. This result is highly relevant since this contribution substantially differs from previous ones, addressing concerns about the endogeneity of the variables and thus about the direction of the causation between the same. In fact, as is maintained by the authors, “Perhaps respondents’ perceptions of the prevalence of corruption drive their low confidence in institutions, but just as plausibly the opposite could be true: individuals who lack confidence in public institutions might as a result express the view that corruption is widespread” (see p 214).

109 ibid, p 243.

110 ibid, p 241. In table 6, these authors also document the relationship between corruption, confidence and the three other mentioned outcomes: the support for violent forms of protest; the desire to emigrate; and, finally, political participation.

111 Specifically, the GWP asks respondents, “Do you have confidence in each of the following?”: “(a) the military, (b) judicial system and courts, (c) national government, (d) health care or medical systems, (e) financial institutions or banks, (f) religious organizations, (g) quality and integrity of the media, and (h) honesty of elections”; ibid., pp 219–20.

112 The question is the following: “Sometimes people have to give a bribe or present in order to solve their problems. In the last 12 months, were you, personally, faced with this kind of situation, or not (regardless of whether you gave a bribe/present)?”. According to the authors, a crucial advantage of such an experience-based question is that it is less likely to suffer from so-called reverse causality (ie here, the possibility that individuals’ confidence in institutions affects their corruption experiences); ibid, p 217.

113 The question is the following: “Is corruption widespread throughout the government in this country, or not?”; ibid.

114 ibid, p 219. In some countries (eg Italy and Japan), this gap is large, and thus they have a “strong” perception of widespread corruption in government.

115 ibid.

116 On the opportunities offered by artificial intelligence see, eg, YK Dwivedi et al, “Artificial intelligence (AI): multidisciplinary perspectives on emerging challenges, opportunities, and agenda for research, practice and policy” (2019) 57 International Journal of Information Management 2–47; H Mehr et al, “Artificial intelligence for citizen services and government” (2017) Ash Center for Democratic Governance and Innovation, Harvard Kennedy School, pp 1–16 <https://ash.harvard.edu/files/ash/files/artificial_intelligence_for_citizen_services.pdf> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

117 See, eg, S Kim et al, “An institutional analysis of an e-government system for anti-corruption: the case of OPEN” (2009) 26(1) Government Information Quarterly 42–50; J Arayankalam et al, “How to deal with corruption? Examining the roles of e-government maturity, government administrative effectiveness, and virtual social networks diffusion” (2020) 58 International Journal of Information Management 102203.

118 TB Andersen, “E-government as an anti-corruption strategy” (2009) 21(3) Information Economics and Policy 201–10.

119 NG Elbahnasawy, “E-government, Internet adoption, and corruption: an empirical investigation” (2014), 57 World Development 114–26.

120 On the range of contributions delving into the relationship between technology and trust, see, eg, P Cofta, Trust, Complexity and Control: Confidence in a Convergent World (Hoboken, NJ, John Wiley & Sons 2007); P Sumpf, System Trust: Researching the Architecture of Trust in Systems (Berlin, Springer 2019); E Keymolen, Trust on the Line: A Philosophical Exploration of Trust in the Networked Era (Nijmegen, Wolf Legal Publishers 2016); M Coeckelbergh, “Can we trust robots?” (2012) 14(1) Ethics and Information Technology 53–60; M Taddeo, “Trust in technology: a distinctive and a problematic relation” (2010) 23(3–4) Knowledge, Technology & Policy 283–86; H Nissenbaum, “Will security enhance trust online, or supplant it?” in RM Kramer and KS Cook (eds), Trust and Distrust in Organizations: Dilemmas and Approaches (New York, Russell Sage Foundation 2004) pp 155–88.

121 See, eg, M Warkentin and C Orgeron, “Using the security triad to assess blockchain technology in public sector applications” (2020) 52 International Journal of Information Management 102090.

122 See, eg, P De Filippi et al, “Blockchain as a confidence machine: the problem of trust & challenges of governance” (2020) 62 Technology in Society 101284. The authors observe that blockchain’s premise, indeed, is based on the fact that “… users subject themselves to the authority of a technological system that they are confident is immutable, rather than to the authority of centralized institutions which are deemed untrustworthy”. However, they also maintain that the academic discussion only considers this central property from a negative perspective (ie that this technology does not need trust to operate). By contrast, drawing on complexity, they argue that blockchain technology should be regarded as a “confidence machine”, in the sense that “… it increases the confidence in the operation of a particular system, and only indirectly (i.e. as a corollary to that) reduces the need for trust in that system” (see p 11).

123 N Bautista-Beauchense, “Corruption and anti-corruption: a folklore problem?” (2020) 73 Crime, Law and Social Change 162.

124 See, as indicated by Bautista-Beauchense, ibid, G Myrdal, Asian Drama. An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations (New York, Pantheon 1968); G Myrdal, “Corruption as a hindrance to modernization in South Asia” in AJ Heidenheimer and M Johnston (eds) Political Corruption, Concepts and Contexts (London, Routledge 2011). See also N Melgar et al, “The perception of corruption” (2010) 22(1) International Journal of Public Opinion Research 120. Melgar et al indeed maintain that both corruption and corruption perception can be considered as cultural phenomena “… because they depend on how a society understands the rules and what constitutes a deviation”. According to the authors, therefore, this implies its influence not only on societies, but also on personal values and moral views.

125 Bautista-Beauchense, supra, note 123.

126 ibid.

127 As has been seen, such measures play a pivotal role in focusing attention on the phenomenon, exercising great influence at individual, academic and government levels of the analysis.

128 M Leach, “Complexity regulatory space and banking” in Murray et al (eds), supra, note 76, p 170. The author in fact stresses that complexity theory “… studies large-scale, multi-bodied composite structures that have interacting, networked components”.

129 Turner and Baker, supra, note 35, p 6.

130 Kurtz and Snowden, supra, note 53, p 469.

131 This is a report from the European Commission to the Council and the European Parliament. See EC Report on Eu-Anti-Corruption, released on 3 February 2014 <https://www.tagesschau.de/wirtschaft/eukorruptionsbericht100.pdf> (last accessed 3 April 2021).

132 S Shalvi, “Corruption corrupts” (2016) 531(7595) Nature 456–57.

133 Melgar et al, supra, note 124. The authors indeed observe that “Even when corruption perception may strongly differ from the current level of corruption, the latter influences the former. Hence, high levels of corruption perception are enough to cause negative effects in the economy (the growth of institutional instability and the deterioration of the relationships among individuals, institutions and states)”.

134 Among others, see Campos et al, “The impact of corruption on investment: predictability matters” (1999) 27(6) World Development 1059–67; M Habib and L Zurawicki, “Country-level investments and the effect of corruption – some empirical evidence” (2001) 10(6) International Business Review 687–700; M Habib and L Zurawicki, “Corruption and foreign direct investment” (2002) 33(2) Journal of International Business Studies 291–307; E Asiedu and J Freeman, “The effect of corruption on investment growth: evidence from firms in Latin America, Sub-Saharan Africa, and transition countries” (2009) 13(2) Review of Development Economics 200–14; S Richey, “The impact of corruption on social trust” (2010) 38(4) American Politics Research 676–90; A Pellegata and V Memoli, “Can corruption erode confidence in political institutions among European countries? Comparing the effects of different measures of perceived corruption” (2016) 128(1) Social Indicators Research 391–412; A Cieślik and Ł Goczek, “Control of corruption, international investment, and economic growth–evidence from panel data” (2018) 103 World Development 323–35; A Solé-Ollé and P Sorribas-Navarro, “Trust no more? On the lasting effects of corruption scandals” (2018) 55 European Journal of Political Economy 185–203; L Olmos et al, “The effects of mega-events on perceived corruption” (2020) 61 European Journal of Political Economy 101826.

135 RT Golembiewski, “Trust and power: two works by Niklas Luhmann” (1981) 75(2) American Political Science Review 480–81. See also N Luhmann, Trust and Power (New York, John Wiley & Sons 2018).

136 De Filippi et al, supra, note 122, p 6.

137 ibid.

Figure 0

Figure 1. Cynefin framework’s adaptation from Kurtz and Snowden (see Note 53), Snowden and Boone (see Note 53) and Turner and Baker (see Note 35).