1. Introduction
The socio-economic impact of immigration strongly depends on the human capital and skills of immigrants that are formed both before and after migration. The research community has devoted particular attention to the initial differences between immigrants and natives with respect to several outcome variables such as wages, labor market participation, occupational choices, crime rates, use of welfare support schemes, fertility, gender gaps as well as to their relative dynamic evolution or assimilation processes. Less attention has been devoted to the processes that lead to the observed outcomes and the resources allocated to them.
In this paper, we study the time allocated to formal and informal education by immigrants and natives in the US. We define formal education as the whole set of activities linked to participation in courses organized by an educational institution and informal education as all the activities that have a formative content and are performed outside the formal educational system. Informal education includes, for instance, taking a class for personal interest or extracurricular club activities. These activities generally require, and at the same time stimulate, cognitive abilities of participants. They can also be defined as educational leisure as often there is both a strong consumption element and a productive one. These activities are also closely related to lifelong learning and are increasingly important, considering rapid technological changes and automation of production processes [OECD (2014)]. To our knowledge, this is the first study that analyzes immigrants' decisions to invest in informal and formal education using time-use data and that investigates the process of assimilation in terms of both educational activities over time.
For immigrants, the investment in education, particularly informal education, might represent a fundamental channel for accumulating human capital but also for socio-economic integration. In addition, these human capital enhancing activities generate individual-level as well as community-wide returns.Footnote 1 In their decision to invest in human capital, immigrants face different constraints compared to natives. As barriers to formal educational channels might be particularly high,Footnote 2 informal education might represent the only real channel for investing in human capital in the host country. Also, the opportunity cost of investing in these activities might diverge as the time allocated to non-market activities is closely related to the shadow price of time and to the productivity of consumption time [Becker (Reference Becker1965)]. Informal education can also be considered as an investment in social capital as, compared to natives, the density of immigrants' social networks is limited [Coleman (Reference Coleman1988)].
In the first part of the paper, we present a theoretical model on individuals' allocation of time to education and other competing activities which serves as the main background for our empirical analysis. We show how the optimal trajectory in terms of time devoted to educational activities depend, among other things, on the costs and returns to education and the initial level of human capital.
Immigrants are more likely to have higher returns to education in addition to a generally lower initial level of human capital; this is particularly true given the well-documented imperfect degree of transferability of human capital across borders. We expect that these factors positively impact both the propensity to engage and the intensity of participation in educational activities. On the other hand, the cost of engaging in these activities might be higher for immigrants compared to natives, for instance due to language barriers that reduce the effectiveness of learning. In the theoretical model we also emphasize the role of time preferences, which might also significantly differ between immigrants and natives [Gibson and McKenzie (Reference Gibson and McKenzie2011); Nowotny (Reference Nowotny2014); Goldbach and Schluter (Reference Goldbach and Achim2018)].
In the second part, we test the main predictions of the model using the American Time-use dataset (ATUS) for the period 2003–2015. One of the important novelties of our approach is the use of time allocation data. As argued by Hamermesh and Pfann (Reference Hamermesh and Pfann.2005, p. 2) “no other sorts of data allow us to analyze the determinants of how people allocate time outside the labor market.” This approach is able to shed more light on the process of immigrant's assimilation than previous studies as it focuses on both participation and the intensity immigrants engage in human capital formation activities at destination, rather than analyzing the effect of human capital levels (e.g., educational attainment, language attainment etc.) on socio-economic assimilation of immigrants. We show that foreign-bornFootnote 3 persons are more likely to engage in informal and formal education and, conditional on engaging, they spend more time on these activities than natives. These differences between the foreign-born and natives are generally larger in informal education than in formal education. As we are focusing on adults that have already made their decision over formal education when young, these findings show that informal education is fundamental in the process of investing in host-country specific human (and social) capital. Finally, we provide evidence of a slow assimilation process with natives in both educational activities, and that some differences carry on to second-generation immigrants.
Our paper contributes to the literature on the educational investments and, more generally, on skill acquisition of immigrants in the destination countries [see Dustmann and Glitz (Reference Dustmann, Glitz, Hanushek, Machin and Woessmann2011), for a review]. This literature argues that usually education and skills acquired in the home country are not always fully transferable at destination and immigrants need to further invest in education and training to acquire host-country specific skills [Chiswick (Reference Chiswick1978); Chiswick and Miller (Reference Chiswick and Miller2008)]. Recent studies on several countries—such as Mattoo et al. (Reference Mattoo, Neagu and Özden2008) on USA and Green et al. (Reference Green, Parvinder and Gareth2007) on Australia—find that differences in educational attainment and skill mismatch are at the basis of observed differences in economic outcomes between immigrants and natives. Borjas (Reference Borjas2015) finds a lower economic assimilation of recent cohorts of immigrants in the US, which depends heavily on the decline of human capital accumulation (i.e., English language skills). Chiswick and Miller (Reference Chiswick and Miller2012) show that the degree of earnings assimilation depends on the skills transferability—proxied by language distance—and on the time immigrants spend in the destination country. They find that immigrants being more similar to natives in terms of skills, experience a lower growth of their earnings due to a decreasing rent over time. Conversely, over time, immigrants endowed with less transferable skills, experience a higher growth in earnings due to accumulation of skills relevant for the destination labor market.
Our study is also related to a limited number of recent contributions on the time-use of immigrants [see Ribar (Reference Ribar, Constant and Zimmermann2012) for a survey]. Significant differences between immigrants and natives in time allocated to “assimilation activities” (purchasing, education, work) are highlighted by the important contribution of Hamermesh and Trejo (Reference Hamermesh and Trejo2013). Using ATUS data, they show that immigrants are less likely to undertake assimilation activities, but those who do engage in such activities spend relatively more time than natives. They rationalize these findings on the basis of a theoretical framework in which immigrants experience both higher fixed costs and higher returns from time devoted to assimilation activities. An interesting study carried out by Zaiceva and Zimmermann (Reference Zaiceva and Zimmermann2014) shows, using data on a sample of immigrants and native women in the United Kingdom, that, compared to white women, non-white-women (mainly those originating from Pakistan and Bangladesh) spend significantly more time on food management and particularly religious activities. The study employs a double-hurdle model that jointly analyses the decision to engage in a particular activity (namely childcare, food management and religious observance) and time devoted to it. More recently, Caparrós (Reference Caparrós2017) has investigated immigrant workers' time-use in Spain, a country that has experienced a sudden and large increase in its immigrant population. In this study, important differences between immigrants and natives in the allocation of time to a broad set of categories emerge. Male immigrants from outside the EU are found to invest more time in studying and other activities related to training.
The only study on the determinants of time allocated to informal education activities is, to our knowledge, the analysis conducted by Fahr (Reference Fahr2005). Using time-use data for Germany, this study finds evidence of a strong relationship between formal and informal education. However, Fahr's analysis has no specific focus on immigrants.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the theoretical framework from which we derive some testable hypotheses. Section 3 describes the data used and the empirical strategy we employ in our analysis. Section 4 presents the results. Section 5 summarizes the results and presents the main conclusions of the paper.
2. Theoretical background
2.1 A simple model of education and human capital accumulation
In this subsection, we present a simple continuous-time model of the optimal trajectories of investment in education and the subsequent accumulation of human capital.
Let us consider an agent living during a finite duration time interval [0, T]. At every date t, the agent is endowed with $\bar{\theta }$ units of time that can be allocated to three different activities: consumption (c t), labor (l t) and education (e t). We can express the time constraint as follows:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn1.png?pub-status=live)
Time allocated to labor generates an income ω(h t)l t, where ω(h t) is the wage of the agent, which is a concave increasing function of her current human capital level, h t. Following Becker (Reference Becker1965), let us assume that consumption activities are carried out combining time and commodities (i.e., goods and services purchased in the market) and that time and commodities are perfect complements. In other words, c t units of time devoted to consumption needs g t = βc t units of commodities, bought in the market drawing from individual income at price p. Then, the agent faces the following budget constraint:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU1.png?pub-status=live)
that may also be written as:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn2.png?pub-status=live)
with w(h t) = ω(h t)/βp
Education contributes to the accumulation of human capital. More precisely, the accumulation of human capital follows the equation:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn3.png?pub-status=live)
where $h_t$ is the time derivative of h t, a is the efficiency of education in generating new human capital and $\varepsilon < \bar{\theta }$
is a sunk time cost: only time devoted to education beyond ɛ contributes to human capital accumulation.
The agent maximizes the following intertemporal utility function:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn4.png?pub-status=live)
where u(c t) is a standard concave increasing instantaneous utility function.
Given our assumption that informal education is not a direct source of utility, the existence of the sunk time cost, ɛ, implies that either the agent is not involved in informal education (e t = 0) or devotes ɛ units of time at least to informal education.Footnote 4
2.2 From theory to hypotheses
The solution of the individual's time allocation choice leads to the determination of optimal trajectories characterized by a pair (e t, h t), where e t is the optimal choice of education at time t and h t is the current level of human capital (see full details in Appendix B). For all trajectories, the investment in education (e t) decreases with time while the level of human capital (h t) increases. We show that if the agent has a long enough time horizon, at same date τ < T, the optimal level of education reaches the sunk time cost, $\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t\to \tau } e_t = \varepsilon$, and, from that date on, the agent stops educating: e t = 0 for t ≥ τ.
Intuitively, the structure of these optimal trajectories is determined by decreasing returns to human capital and the length of remaining life. For an agent to engage in educational activities the future return to human capital generated by education must be positive, the cost being more than covered by additional income induced by higher levels of human capital. The optimal amount of educational activities equalizes the marginal additional income to the marginal cost [see also Dustmann and Glitz (Reference Dustmann, Glitz, Hanushek, Machin and Woessmann2011)].
As t increases, the accumulation of educational output makes human capital increasing. But decreasing returns to human capital imply that, with a higher level of human capital and a shorter remaining lifetime, the future return to new human capital generated by education is lower [Chiswick and Miller (Reference Chiswick and Miller1994)], so that the agent invests less in education. This effect is particularly strong if education is largely undertaken for productive purposes rather than as a pure leisure good (i.e., for consumption purposes).
We also prove the existence of a limit trajectory: while all the trajectories below the limit are feasible there is no feasible one above it as investing in additional education does not generates utility gains. The existence of this limit trajectory implies that, if the initial level of human capital is high enough, the agent decides not to engage in education for two reasons. First, decreasing marginal returns to human capital imply that the marginal increase in future income generated by additional education is too low. Second, a higher level of human capital implies a higher marginal cost of time devoted to education, as this cost includes forgone earnings. For lower levels of human capital, the agent starts devoting some time to education, provided education is accessible and costs are not too high.
In the Appendix, we also analyze the impact of several factors that may influence the choice of the optimal trajectory. The first one, as emphasized above, is the initial level of human capital, h 0. We prove that time devoted to education is a decreasing function of h 0. The second one is the efficiency of education, measured by the parameter a. We prove that agents who have a higher efficiency in generating human capital from education (a being higher) devote more time to education. The third one is the fixed cost of education, ɛ. We find that a change in ɛ has an ambiguous effect on time devoted to education. The fourth one is time availability, $\bar{\theta }$. We find that agents who have more time resources devote some of these extra time resources to education. Time availability might be highly different across gender and, in particular, when the presence of children constrains the time that can be devoted to labor participation. The last one is the rate of time preference, ρ. We find that agents who are more impatient (ρ being higher) choose to devote less time to education, as they value less future gains from the increase in human capital generated by education.
In the empirical exercise that follows we test these theoretical predictions and explicitly include explanatory and control variables that correspond, directly or indirectly, to the theoretical factors described above. However, some of these factors are not observable and, as they potentially differ across populations, may explain the observed difference between immigrants and natives sharing the same observable characteristics.
The main case is human capital. Even if an immigrant has the same observed level of education as a native, part of the education has been acquired in the origin country and is not fully transferable to the host country, so that the (effective) level of human capital in the host country is lower, leading to more time devoted to education. Unobservable differences in the rate of time preference may also matter, with a qualitatively similar effect. Generally, immigrants tend to discount the future less than natives, and are more likely to accept and trade-off temporary hardships against future gains [Gibson and McKenzie (Reference Gibson and McKenzie2011); Arcand and Mbaye (Reference Arcand and Mbaye2013); Nowotny (Reference Nowotny2014); Goldbach and Schluter (Reference Goldbach and Achim2018)].Footnote 5 Our model predicts that this lower discount of the future also leads to more time devoted to education.
There may also be unobservable differences in efficiency of education: immigrants are likely to face more difficulties generating human capital from education with an effect that is running counter the previous positive impacts (i.e., reducing the probability to engage in education) but, conditional on an immigrant engaging in learning activities, the time devoted to it might be higher.Footnote 6 This is the case, for example, when immigrants, especially those coming from countries that have educational systems very different from the US, have to adapt to a new educational system that applies different teaching methods, evaluation systems and learning approaches.
A further difference relates to the time constraint. In this respect, the status of immigrant might have an ambiguous effect. One the one hand immigrants—by being less rooted in the host society—might experience lower time-absorbing social obligations but, on the other hand, their time-use might be affected by more binding credit constraints or can be absorbed more by time-consuming non-productive-activities such as commuting [see Hamermesh and Trejo (Reference Hamermesh and Trejo2013)] or by time devoted to managing larger families.
3. Data and methodology
3.1 Description of the data
We use the American Time-use Survey (ATUS) for the years 2003–15 in our analysis.Footnote 7 Individuals surveyed in ATUS are selected randomly from households that participate in the Current Population Survey (CPS). The sample is representative of the population residing in the United States. Data are collected through one-day time diariesFootnote 8, where participants list the time (in minutes) allocated to activities performed in the 24 h prior to the survey. These activities are defined over a set of standardized categories (~400). Finally, for each respondent, information on time-use can be matched with a wide array of demographic characteristics and labor market situation collected by the CPS. The dataset we use includes approximately 170 thousand individuals aged 15 years or more, where immigrants account for 14.5% of the total number.
Time-diary method has several advantages compared to other data collection methods [see Ribar (Reference Ribar, Constant and Zimmermann2012); and Juster et al., (Reference Juster, Hiromi and Stafford2003) for an overview]. The most important one is accuracy that stems from the short recall period and the episodic format (must add up to 24 h) which allows for consistency checks by the user. Barrett and Hamermesh (Reference Barrett and Hamermesh2019) argue that this type of data also reduces errors related to the different importance given to activities by survey respondents [see Bound et al., (Reference Bound, Charles, Mathiowetz, Heckman and Leamer2001)]. Conversely, two main disadvantages of the data are worth mentioning. The first limitation of the time-use data is highlighted by Juster et al. (Reference Juster, Hiromi and Stafford2003), who show that reporting on occasionally performed activities tend to be less reliable. However, in our study, this limitation is not an issue as most activities that belong to the education category are not occasional and are likely to have a well-defined time schedule. The second limitation is related to the high variability of time-diary data due to the one-day observation.Footnote 9 If interviewed on different days during the year, responses are likely to vary across days. One possible effect of the high variability is the reduction of the statistical power of the model, especially when estimations use a low number of observations (usually the second tier in our estimations). We show below that this drawback is unlikely to undermine our results.
Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics of the dependent variables (informal and formal education). All statistics are weighted to reflect the behavior of a representative individual in the US on a representative day.
Table 1. Participation rate and time spent in formal and informal education by immigrants, natives and second-generation
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab1.png?pub-status=live)
Notes: Statistics are weighted using the variable wt06 (ATUS methodology for 2006).
Informal education activities are performed more frequently by immigrants (1.2%) than by natives (0.9%) while there is not much difference for formal education. Conditional on participation, immigrants are also shown to spend more time in informal education than natives (141 min vs. 108 min) while, once again, there is not much difference for formal education. Female immigrants participate more in informal education but spend significantly less time in these activities as compared to male immigrants. Formal education activities and the time dedicated to them are more uniform across genders. Second-generation immigrants show a similar participation in informal education and the time spent in these activities is like that of immigrants, whereas the rate of participation in formal education is twice that of immigrants and of natives.
Table A.1 in Appendix A shows that immigrants and natives are comparable in terms of gender, employment status and attainment of advanced degrees (degree and postgraduate).
Immigrants are of younger age, are more likely to be married and to have children than natives. They are also less likely to have obtained a high school diploma or equivalent than natives (50% and 64%, respectively). Summary statistics also show that the presence of individuals in the survey with less than elementary education is very low, among both immigrants and natives (1.06%). This feature reduces the likelihood of errors in reporting of activities from individuals.Footnote 10
3.2 Estimation strategy
To test our hypothesis, we employ a double-hurdle (two tier) method proposed by Cragg (Reference Cragg1971). This method is used to analyze differences in the allocation of time between natives and immigrants over broad classes of activities by Hamermesh and Trejo (Reference Hamermesh and Trejo2013). The double-hurdle method incorporates a probit model in the first tier that gives the probability that the observation has a positive value (extensive margin) and a truncated regression in the second tier (conditional intensive margin). As an alternative to a Tobit, this method allows for the possibility that different processes determine the two tiers, and hence the model could be estimated over two vectors of parameters. In terms of our analysis, the probit model (1st tier) will test if immigrants and natives have a dissimilar probability to participate in formal and informal education, while the truncated model (2nd tier), conditional on engaging in education, will test if immigrants participate more intensively than natives in such activities.
The specification of the baseline model is presented below:
First tier: Probability of participation
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU2.png?pub-status=live)
Second tier: Intensity of participation
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU3.png?pub-status=live)
3.2.1 Dependent variables
We define formal education as all the non-work education activities such as taking classes and research and homework for a degree. Conversely, informal education includes all the extracurricular activities that have a human capital component and classes carried out outside the formal educational system. This definition is similar to the definition used by Fahr (Reference Fahr2005). Table A.2 in Appendix A reports the list of activities included in the definitions of formal and informal education. Given the nature of the data generation process, we could not further disaggregate the informal education variable and distinguish between activities such as language courses or academic classes from other activities which besides having human-capital enhancing effects, can be considered as quasi-leisure activities.Footnote 11 Although further disaggregation of this variable would have potentially revealed some heterogeneous effects depending on the specific activity, our main idea is to consider all the activities—including those that have a strong leisure component—that generate at least potentially positive effects on the accumulation of human as well as social capital. In this respect, participation in a chess club may be considered as a human capital enhancing activity in a way similar to participation in an English language course. Both activities lead to accumulation of skills and improve cognitive abilities that might be useful in the labor market. In addition, both activities lead to social interactions that might have positive effects by increasing returns to other production factors or simply by increasing the chances of employability. More specifically, the dependent variables in the 1st tier equation (Y ist) is dichotomous and equals 1 if the respondent i declares to have spent time (minutes > 0) in formal (informal) education during the day the time-diary was recorded, and 0 otherwise. The dependent variables—included in Edu ist%in the 2nd tier equation measure the time spent (in minutes) in formal or informal education by the respondent i during the day the time-diary was recorded.
3.2.2 Explanatory and control variables
Our main explanatory variable is ForeignBorn ist. It equals unity if the individual i, who resides in the US. State s in year t, was born abroad and 0 otherwise. Based on our theoretical framework, we expect that foreign-born persons might be more likely to allocate time to education for the following reasons (see section 2.2): (i) partial transferability of human capital might imply that marginal returns to education are higher even controlling for educational attainment; (ii) immigrants are generally more patient and discount the future relatively less than natives. Moreover, as immigrants might have a more restricted set of options for human capital enhancing activities, we expect them to rest more upon informal education.
In both equations, the vector ${\boldsymbol X}_{ist}^{\prime}$, includes individual level characteristics that, following our model, might condition the propensity to participate in educational activities and the intensity to perform these activities. The first characteristic of interest is the age of the respondent (Age) and its quadratic form (Age squared). Following our theoretical model that predicts that time devoted to education decreases along every trajectory, we expect age to have a negative effect on both the probability of participating in education and the intensity of this participation.
Our second characteristic of interest is educational attainment (Less than elementary, Elementary, Middle, Secondary, Degree, Postgraduate), which is our proxy for the initial level of human capital included in the theoretical framework. Following this framework, we expect that higher levels of formal education will be associated with lower incentives to invest in educational activities (see section 2.2), as a consequence of our assumption of decreasing returns related to these human capital enhancing activities.
A third group of characteristics encompasses gender (Female), marital status (Married), and whether the respondent has children in the following age groups: No children, children 0–2 years, children 3–5 years, children 6–12 years, children 13–17 years. These characteristics are highly correlated with time availability: homework rests more upon females than males, reducing time available for other activities; the presence of children also reduces time availability, again particularly for females. Then, in our theoretical framework, we expect working females and respondents with children to have less time available, leading to a lower probability of education and a lower intensity of participation.
We include a set of dummies for the work status of the individual (Employed, Unemployed, Not in labor force) and seven dummies for the size of the area where the individual resides. Work status is also likely to influence time-constraints that might affect the willingness/ability to allocate time to informal education. For instance, we expect that time-constraints will be less binding for unemployed or individuals not in the labor force.
Last, it is important to acknowledge that, for matters of simplification, our theoretical model neglects the leisure value of education, which is likely to be positively related with educational level. Besides, formal and informal education might have a certain degree of complementarity. Both these aspects might offset the effects explicitly formalized in our theoretical framework. Moreover, in the baseline model the dummy Holiday indicates whether the diary day is a holidayFootnote 12 while the vectors ${\boldsymbol \varphi }_s^{\prime}$ and ${\boldsymbol \gamma }_s^{\prime}$
refer to State fixed-effects and year fixed effects, respectively. For the exact definition of the variables included in our empirical specification, we refer the reader to Table A.3 in Appendix A.
4. Empirical results
4.1 Baseline results
Table 2 presents the results of the baseline model. Model 1 and model 2 (1st tier), estimated over the entire sample, show that the probability to participate in formal as well as informal education activities is 0.4% higher for the foreign-born than it is for natives. Conditional on participation (2nd tier), the foreign-born spend, on average, 62 min (or 57%)Footnote 13 more in informal education activities and 11 (or 4%) more in formal education than similar US-born people do in the diary day; then, if the impact of being foreign born is similar for formal and informal education, the impact on time spent in much higher for informal education. In this model, we control for a wide range of individual level characteristics, which explain a good part of the heterogeneity in the time spent in informal education across individuals. Consistent with our theoretical prediction, we find that younger individuals and females are more likely to participate in both formal and informal education activities. However, the intensity of time spent in such activities is higher for younger individuals, and lower for females than for male. Moreover, the negative impact of age on the participation to educational activities is much stronger for formal education than for informal education.
Table 2. Time spent in informal and formal education: immigrants vs. natives (baseline estimations on the full sample)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab2.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal or formal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal or formal education. Reference categories are: No children; Elementary; Employed. Area size dummies, state and year fixed effects are used in all models. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
As expected, individuals with young children are less likely to engage in educational activities, whether they are formal or informal, than those who have no children, and when they engage, the time spent in these activities is significantly lower. Informal education activities are performed more frequently but less intensively during holidays. The labor market status of individuals determines the time spent in informal education activities. Unemployed and inactive individuals are more likely to engage in both formal and informal education activities than employed individuals, and the time spent in these activities is evidently higher. Unemployed individuals might engage more intensively in educational activities to acquire skills and competences that grant a (future) labor-market return.
Besides, these individuals are likely to be less time constrained than employed individuals are, as highlighted in our model. Finally, the educational attainment is positively associated with the likelihood to engage in informal education activities. According to Fahr (Reference Fahr2005), highly educated people have a higher opportunity cost of their non-market-time and a preference for educational leisure. Another possible explanation is the higher complementarity—both in production and consumption—between formal and informal education.
In Table 3, we exclude unemployed and inactive individuals from the sample—and focus on employed individuals only—as these two groups substantially differ in terms of time constraints as well as in terms of the opportunity cost of allocating time to non-market activities.Footnote 14 The results are similar to the results for the full sample. However, the marginal impact of being a foreign born is now higher for formal education that for informal education and the marginal impact on time devoted to educational activities is very high for informal education. This result could be partially explained by the well-defined time schedule of curricular activities.
Table 3. Time spent in informal and formal education: immigrants vs. natives (baseline estimations on the sample of employed only)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab3.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal or formal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal or formal education. Reference categories are: No children; Elementary; Employed. Area size dummies, state and year fixed effects are used in all models. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
An additional driver of the higher propensity and intensity of investment in informal education activities by foreign workers can be due to reduced access to on-the-job training. As training is paid by the firm, more informal education undertaken by foreign born might be (at least partly) the results of firms transferring a higher share of these costs to immigrant workers or/and a higher concentration of immigrants' workers in sectors where a higher proportion of these costs is transferred to workers.Footnote 15
Our theoretical framework and the results of the analysis in Table 2 suggest that one reason why immigrants spend more time in education is the higher returns they obtain from these activities. Consistent with the theoretical prediction, the economic incentive to engage in human capital enhancing activities is higher for individuals that could reap the benefits for longer time. For instance, those who are close to retirement could have a lower incentive to invest in informal education than individuals at an early stage of their working life.
In Table 4, we test the validity of this argument by including in the baseline model an interaction between the dummy for foreign-born individuals who are 45 years of age or younger and a dummy for foreign-born individuals who are older than 45 years of age.Footnote 16 In model 1, which includes the results of estimations having informal education as a dependent variable, foreign-born individuals who are 45 years of age or younger are twice more likely to engage in informal education activities (compared to natives) than foreign-born individuals who are older than 45 years of age. The results show the same tendency when the conditional amount of time spent in such activities is considered. A different picture emerges when looking at formal education (model 2). Older immigrants are more inclined to invest time in formal education than younger immigrants (compared to natives), and they also spend significantly more time in these activities.
Table 4. Residual working life and time-use in formal and informal education
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab4.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal or formal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal or formal education. Individuals over 17 years old are considered. This table includes all control variables as in Table 2. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
As argued above, informal education activities could represent a fundamental source of knowledge and country-specific human (and social) capital for immigrants. For example, attending language club activities or taking art and craft courses may boost host country-specific skills/knowledge and language proficiency. It is highly likely that these activities will be particularly rewarding for immigrants originating from countries where English is not the official language. We test this hypothesis and report the results in Table 5 where we consider the official language of immigrants home countries [we follow the definition of Bleakley and Chin (Reference Bleakley and Chin2004)]. We find that foreign born from non-English speaking countries have the strongest propensity to invest in informal education (both at the extensive and intensive margins). Interestingly, the probability of engaging in formal education is lower compared to immigrants from countries where English is the official language or a widely spoken one. The latter result suggests higher cost of entry for these immigrants in formal education.
Table 5. Time spent in education and home country language
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab5.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st Tier is informal and formal education (0,1); 2nd Tier is time spent in informal and formal education. This table includes all control variables as in Table 2. Reference categories are: No children; Primary; Employed; native-born. Area size dummies, state and year fixed effects are used in all models. For the 1st Tier, marginal effects at means are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1
Jointly, these results suggest that for foreign born from non-English-speaking countries informal education might be a fundamental (and maybe the only) channel for acquiring the required human capital that would allow socio-economic integration.
It is also reasonable to expect that the longer the immigrants reside in the host country, the higher is the level of country-specific human capital accumulated and the lower will be the difference with the human capital of natives. This argument is in line with the assimilation theory suggesting convergence in the use of time between immigrants and natives. To test the validity of this argument, we replace the foreign-born dummy of the baseline model by a set of dummy variables categorizing the time since migration of individuals and a dummy for second-generation Americans.Footnote 17 The results are displayed in Table 6. They are quite similar for formal and informal education. In line with our predictions, the propensity to engage in both formal and informal education is higher for recent immigrants and decreases steadily with the time spent in the US. Immigrants residing in the US for less than 6 years are almost 8 times more likely to engage in educational activities than immigrants who have been in the US for more than 20 years. However, the results also show that the amount of time spent in educational activities does not follow a clear decreasing pattern when time since immigration increases.
Table 6. Time since migration and time-use in informal and formal education
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab6.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal or formal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal or formal education. Individuals over 17 years old are considered. This table includes all control variables as in Table 2. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
Second-generation Americans look like natives in terms of time spent in informal education and devote more time to formal education. Their propensity to engage in these activities is higher than that of natives but does not differ much from that of immigrants who have been in the US for more than 20 years. Overall, the results suggest that a slow process of assimilation with natives is ongoing and that this process is not fully completed for the second-generation immigrants.
4.1 Formal and informal education: the complementarity issue
So far, in our analysis, we have excluded the possibility that the time spent in formal education and informal education activities might complement each other. In many cases, classes for a degree could be complemented with additional extracurricular classes or club activities aimed at enhancing the knowledge of a topic or gaining new skills. However, individuals might combine investment in formal and informal education differently. For example, individuals that have already completed their formal educational track may decide to further invest in informal education as a way to avoid skills and human capital depreciation or to update their skills and competences. Evidently, investments in informal education complement previous investments in formal education and occur when individuals have already completed the formal educational track. This latter typology of complementarity has a sequential rather than a contemporary nature.Footnote 18
When individuals' choices over these two activities are simultaneous (that is, taken in the same period under analysis), the estimates presented above are likely to be biased if formal (resp. informal) education is not considered explicitly in the analysis of informal (resp. formal) education.Footnote 19 One way to deal with this issue is to restrict the sample to only those individuals that are not enrolled in formal education, for which the risk of simultaneity is quite low or even absent. The ATUS data have detailed information on whether the respondent was enrolled in school, high school or university in the week preceding the survey. We use this information to identify all individuals that declared to be enrolled in the formal educational system and exclude them from the estimations.Footnote 20 In Table 7, we investigate the presence of simultaneity and its effect on the baseline results. In model 1, where we use the entire sample, we insert a dummy for individuals enrolled in formal education (In education) and its interaction with foreign-born (Foreign-born*In education). The results of model 1 are informative in several ways: (i) the positive and significant coefficient of In education suggests the presence of simultaneity (i.e., enrolled individuals are more likely to engage in informal education); (ii) the positive and significant coefficient of the interaction indicates that simultaneity could be higher for enrolled immigrants; (iii) the positive and highly significant coefficient of the dummy Foreign-born indicates that, even after controlling for formal education, immigrants are still more likely to engage in informal education, and conditional on participation, they spend more time in these activities (coefficient of Foreign-born in tier 2).Footnote 21
Table 7. Informal and formal education of immigrants: substitutes or complements?
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab7.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal education. This table includes all control variables as in Table 2. In model 3, only individuals over 17 years old are considered. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
To address the simultaneity issue, in model 2 and model 3 we include in the sample only individuals that are not enrolled in the formal educational system. The results of these estimations certify the results obtained on the whole sample of individuals and presented above in Tables 2 and 4.
A further robustness check on the issue of potential simultaneity is reported in Table 8 where we estimate the baseline model separately for individuals that spend a positive amount of time in formal education (model 1) and those who spend no time in formal education in the diary day (model 2). In the former specification (i.e., when simultaneity is present), the probability to engage in informal education is not significantly different for foreign born compared to natives. On the contrary, in model 2—where simultaneity is less likely—results confirm what was previously found in the baseline estimations presented above. Overall, the tests presented in this section confirm that our baseline results are not significantly affected by simultaneity.
Table 8. Informal and formal education for immigrants: substitute or complements?
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab8.png?pub-status=live)
Dependent variables: 1st tier is informal education (0,1); 2nd tier is time spent in informal education. This table includes all control variables as in Table 2. State fixed effects are not included in model 1 because the model does not converge. For the 1st tier, marginal effects at means of all independent variables are reported. Errors are clustered at the state level. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
5. Discussion and concluding remarks
The accumulation of human capital in a society is fundamental for boosting growth, and more generally, the well-being of citizens. When this investment is carried out by immigrants there is an additional gain for the community at large as human capital speeds up the process of socio-economic integration.
In this paper, we study the allocation of time to informal as well as formal learning and education by immigrants and natives. We have focused our attention on informal education, a crucial channel (often the only available one) of human capital enhancement for immigrants. A theoretical framework allows us to generate hypotheses about the factors that drive individuals' incentives to invest in informal education, and to discuss how immigrants may diverge from natives with respect to some of these drivers. Our empirical findings, in line with our theoretical predictions, show that foreign-born individuals invest more than natives in educational activities, formal as well as informal. The probability of engaging in training and extracurricular formative activities is higher for foreign-born people than for natives, and the time devoted to these activities, conditional on engaging in it, is longer. We show that the main drivers are economic incentives mostly in the early phase of working life, as differences tends to disappear over time, and in particular, when the residual working time is shortened. We also show that differences between the foreign-born and natives are generally larger in informal education than in formal education. As we are focusing on adults that have already made their decision over formal education when young, these findings show that informal education is fundamental in the process of investing in host-country specific human (and social) capital. Interestingly, the differences between natives and immigrants persist across generations. We find that second-generation immigrants tend to allocate more time to both informal and formal educational activities and that a slow process of assimilation with natives is ongoing.
Given the potential importance of informal education for immigrants' integration in the host economy and society, it would be interesting to explore additional dimensions that might facilitate or inhibit time allocated to these activities. Immigrants from different origin countries or living in different areas (such as more or less ethnically segregated ones) might have different propensities to invest in informal education. Analysis on other destination countries might also deliver interesting information that relates to the context in which migration takes place and the policies that govern the phenomena. More data on time-use in different countries are becoming available and more immigrants are being included in these data collection efforts. These interesting questions are left for future research.
Appendix A
Table A.1. Descriptive statistics of variables used in the estimation
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab9.png?pub-status=live)
Table A.2. Definitions of informal and formal education
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab10.png?pub-status=live)
Table A.3. Description of the variables
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_tab11.png?pub-status=live)
Appendix B
B.1. Theoretical model
B.1.1 Determination of the trajectories of informal education and human capital accumulation
In this section, we describe in details the analysis of the optimal trajectories of investment in informal education by the agent and the subsequent accumulation of human capital. Let us start from the fact that, once time devoted to education, e t, is known, the amounts of time allocated respectively to consumption, c t, and work, l t, are determined by the budget constraint c t ≤ w(h t)l t and the time constraint $l_t + c_t + e_t \le \bar{\theta }$. Knowing that both constraints will always be binding, we can combine them, getting
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn5.png?pub-status=live)
and the utility of the agent at date t may be written as:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU4.png?pub-status=live)
Then, the agent's optimal choice is the solution to the dynamic problem:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU5.png?pub-status=live)
where the control variable, e t, meets the constraint $0 \le e_t \le \bar{\theta }$ and the state variable measuring human capital at time t, h t, follows the movement equation:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU6.png?pub-status=live)
There is no terminal condition. The current value Lagrangian of this problem is:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU7.png?pub-status=live)
where λ t is the cofactor associated to the movement equation, $\mu _t^0$ is the Lagrange multiplier associated to the constraint 0 ≤ e t, and $\mu _t^1$
is the Lagrange multiplier associated to the constraint $e_t \le \bar{\theta }$
.
Following the Maximum Principle, the conditions for an optimum are:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn6.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn7.png?pub-status=live)
where ${\rm { I}}$() is the indicator function for positive values: ${\rm { I}}$
(e t − ɛ) = 0 if e t − ɛ ≤ 0 and ${\rm { I}}$
(e t − ɛ) = 1 if e t − ɛ > 0. We also have the transversality condition:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU8.png?pub-status=live)
Note that e t < ɛ ⇒ e t = 0. More precisely, if e t < ɛ, then $\mu _t^1 = 0$ and ${\rm { I}}$
(e t − ɛ) = 0, so that (B.2) becomes
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU9.png?pub-status=live)
which implies that no time is allocated to education, e t = 0. Then, if for some date τ, $\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t\to \tau } e_t = \varepsilon$, at τ time devoted to education jumps to zero: $e_\tau = 0$
. This jump is the straightforward consequence of the fact that, as soon as time devoted to education falls below ɛ, education does not produce human capital any longer. Then, the agent decides not to engage in education for not sparing time.
Moreover, e t = 0 implies that no human capital is accumulated, $h_t = 0$, so that h t does not change. Then, with an invariant stock of human capital, the agent always takes the same decision: as soon as the agent has decided not to engage in education at some date, she will not engage in education in the future.
In addition, the terminal condition λ T = 0 also implies $\mu _T^0 > 0$ and then $\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t\to T} e_t = \varepsilon$
, with the consequence that e T = 0.
If $\varepsilon < e_t < \bar{\theta }$, then $\mu _t^0 = \mu _t^1 = 0$
, so that (B.2) becomes:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn8.png?pub-status=live)
and then, calculating the log derivative with respect to time and using the movement equation:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU10.png?pub-status=live)
where $-\eta ( {c_t} ) = {-}c_tu^"( {c_t} ) /{u}^{\prime}( {c_t} ) > 0$. Calculating the log derivative of (B.1), we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU11.png?pub-status=live)
so that:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn9.png?pub-status=live)
Using (B.4), we can rewrite (B.3) as:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU12.png?pub-status=live)
And then:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn10.png?pub-status=live)
so that, combining (B.5) and (B.6) we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU13.png?pub-status=live)
leading to the equation defining the optimal trajectory for the education variable:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn11.png?pub-status=live)
Along a trajectory (h t, e t) starting from the initial level of human capital, h 0, and the initial choice of education, e 0, we have:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn12.png?pub-status=live)
Then, knowing that η(c t) > 0 and $e_t \le \bar{\theta }$:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU14.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU15.png?pub-status=live)
where Z(h t) is the function giving the value of e t equalizing the value of the bracketed term in (B.8) to 0:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn13.png?pub-status=live)
Let us now focus on the iso-elastic case, with η(c t) = η ∈ [0, 1] and $w( {h_t} ) = ( {h_t} ) ^\gamma$ with γ ∈ [0, 1]. Equations (B.7–B.9) can be re-written as:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn14.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn15.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqn16.png?pub-status=live)
The dynamics of the agent's choice are represented in Figure B.1.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_fig1.png?pub-status=live)
Figure B.1. Dynamics of the agent's choice.
The black thick curve represents the highest possible trajectory of investment in education where we have $\dot{e}_t = 0$. This curve has two parts: a horizontal part, corresponding to the time constraint, $e_t = \bar{\theta }$
, where the agent allocates all the available time to education and a decreasing part, corresponding to e t = Z(h t). This line crosses the horizontal line e t = ɛ — that is the level of investment in education below which human capital accumulation stops — at a threshold level of human capital equal to h t = h +; for any level of initial human capital h t > h +, agents will never invest in education.
For meeting the transversality condition, a trajectory must end on the horizontal axis, knowing that if, at some τ < T, $e_\tau = \varepsilon$, then e t = 0 for every t ∈ ] τ, T]. This rules out all the trajectories that are above the curve $\dot{e}_t = 0$
, as along these trajectories e t increases and then moves away from the horizontal axis. This also rules out the trajectories that are above the thick gray curve, which is the trajectory crossing the intersection of the curve $\dot{e}_t = 0$
at h t = h +, as these trajectories cross the curve $\dot{e}_t = 0$
and then end with e t increasing (an example is the thin dotted gray line). A typical trajectory has the shape given by the thin gray line. If the agent's human capital is not too high (h t < h +), the agent starts with a time devoted to education e t > ɛ. Then, the time devoted to education decreases along the trajectory until e t = ɛ; at that time, the agent jumps to e t = 0 until the end of her life. The agent chooses the highest possible trajectory which implies that, if the life is not too long, she ends at e T = ɛ. If her lifetime is longer, the agent chooses the limit trajectory and, at some age <T, we have $\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t\to \tau } e_t = \varepsilon$
and $h_\tau = h^ +$
. Then, for the end of her life, e t = 0 and the agent stops engaging in education.
B.1.2 Impact of parameters
The analysis of the impact of parameters is carried out in the isoelastic case and their signs are derived under the assumption that $\dot{e}_t < 0$. We choose parameters that may significantly differ between the two populations of interest, immigrants and natives: initial level of human capital, h 0, efficiency of education, a, fixed cost of education, ɛ, time availability, $\bar{\theta }$
, time preference, ρ.
Before looking at these impacts, we need to calculate some derivatives with respect to the state variable, h t, and the control variables, e t. The derivatives with respect to h t are:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU16.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU17.png?pub-status=live)
The derivatives with respect to e t are:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU18.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU19.png?pub-status=live)
Impact of a change in the initial level of human capital, h 0:
Let the initial level of human capital increase from h 0 to h 0 + δh 0, with δh 0 > 0. If the agent were choosing the trajectory starting at the initial level of education, e 0, this new trajectory would be on the right of the initial one so that, for every value of e t, h t is higher on the new trajectory than on the initial one. Then, $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial h_t$ being negative, e t decreases on the new trajectory at a lower speed than on the initial one and the new trajectory takes more time. The consequence is that, for reaching the target e T = ɛ, the agent starts from a higher value of e 0.
An agent who has a higher initial level of human capital chooses to devote less time to education. Intuitively, decreasing returns to human capital imply that an agent who starts with a higher level of human capital has lower future returns from extra human capital generated by extra education, and then has a lower incentive to devote time to education.
Impact of a change in the efficiency of education, a :
Differentiating (B.10) and (B.11) with respect to a, we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU20.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU21.png?pub-status=live)
If a increases, then the slope de t/dh t of every trajectory is more negative implying that, for the same starting point (h 0, e 0), the new trajectory is below the old one. Consequently, for every level h t of human capital, e t is lower (or, reciprocally, for every e t, the value of h t on the trajectory is lower). The direct effect of an increase in a on $\dot{e}_t$ is negative; moreover, h t being lower and $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial h_t > 0$
, the indirect effect is also negative. Along the new trajectory, e t decreases at a higher speed ($-\dot{e}_t > 0$
is higher) and the new trajectory takes less time. Then, for reaching the target e T = ɛ, the agent starts from a higher value of e 0.
An agent who is more efficient in using education for generating human capital devotes more time to education. Intuitively, a more efficient education generates more human capital and then increases the future returns to education, increasing the incentive to educate.
Impact of a change in the fixed cost of education, ɛ:
Differentiating (B.10) and (B.11) with respect to ɛ, we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU22.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU23.png?pub-status=live)
If ɛ increases, then the slope de t/dh t of every trajectory is more negative implying that, for the same starting point (h 0, e 0), the new trajectory is below the old one. Consequently, for every level h t of human capital, e t is lower (or, reciprocally, for every e t, the value of h t on the trajectory is lower). The direct effect of an increase in ɛ on $\dot{e}_t$ is positive, but h t being lower and $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial h_t < 0$
, there a positive indirect effect. Then, we cannot tell whether the new trajectory takes more or less time than the new one and the impact of ɛ on e t is ambiguous.
Impact of a change in time availability, $\bar{\theta }$:
Differentiating (B.10) and (B.11) with respect to $\bar{\theta }$, we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU24.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU25.png?pub-status=live)
If $\bar{\theta }$ increases, then the slope de t/dh t of every trajectory is more negative implying that, for the same starting point (h 0, e 0), the new trajectory is below the old one. Consequently, for every level h t of human capital, e t is lower (or, reciprocally, for every e t, the value of h t on the trajectory is lower). Then, the higher value of $\bar{\theta }$
implies a more negative value of $\dot{e}_t$
, both directly because $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial \bar{\theta } < 0$
and indirectly because h t is lower and $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial h_t > 0$
. Along the new trajectory, e t decreases at a higher speed ($-\dot{e}_t > 0$
is higher) and the new trajectory takes less time.
Then, for reaching the target e T = ɛ, the agent starts from a higher value of e 0.
An agent who has more time available devotes some part of the extra time available for getting more education: time devoted to education behaves like a normal good
Impact of a change in the rate of time preference, ρ:
Differentiating (B.10) and (B.11) with respect to ρ, we get:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU26.png?pub-status=live)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20221117023639204-0724:S2054089221000171:S2054089221000171_eqnU27.png?pub-status=live)
If ρ increases, then the slope de t/dh t of every trajectory is less negative implying that, for the same starting point (h 0, e 0), the new trajectory is above the old one. Consequently, for every level h t of human capital, e t is higher (or, reciprocally, for every e t, the value of h t on the trajectory is higher). Then, the higher value of ρ implies a less negative value of $\dot{e}_t$, both directly because $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial \rho > 0$
and indirectly because h t is higher and $\partial \dot{e}_t/\partial h_t > 0$
. Along the new trajectory, e t decreases at a lower speed ($-\dot{e}_t < 0$
is higher) and the new trajectory takes more time. Then, for reaching the target e T = ɛ, the agent starts from a lower value of e 0.
An agent who has a higher rate of time preference devotes less time to education because, as she discounts less the future, the current aggregate value of the future gains generated by education is higher.