Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-lrblm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T14:17:45.501Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

GARY BECKER’S CONTRIBUTIONS IN HEALTH ECONOMICS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 March 2015

Rodrigo R. Soares*
Affiliation:
Sao Paulo School of Economics – FGV and IZA, Brazil

Extract

Gary Becker's contributions to health economics started somewhat indirectly. The early development in human capital theory, to which Becker was one of the main contributors, had obvious implications to the analysis of expenditures on health, but were almost exclusively focused on schooling and training (Schultz 1960; Becker 1962, 1964). Human capital theory advanced the idea that actions that imply present costs but enhanced individual productivity in the future could be seen as investments in a form of capital. Expenditures in health had many dimensions where such trade-offs were present. A good diet or exercising might not be very much fun, but potentially delivered long-term benefits in the form of a longer and healthier life. Preventive medical care demanded time and money, but might also improve future health prospects. This was recognized early on (Mushkin, 1962), but the first explorations of health as human capital were conceptually timid and did not give the field a push that remotely resembled that received by the economic research on education. For the years that followed, health economics persisted mostly as a field dealing with the analysis of health systems and delivery of health technologies.

Type
Special Section: Essays in honor of Gary Becker
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2015 

1. INTRODUCTION

Gary Becker's contributions to health economics started somewhat indirectly. The early development in human capital theory, to which Becker was one of the main contributors, had obvious implications to the analysis of expenditures on health, but were almost exclusively focused on schooling and training (Schultz Reference Schultz1960; Becker Reference Becker1962, Reference Becker1964). Human capital theory advanced the idea that actions that imply present costs but enhanced individual productivity in the future could be seen as investments in a form of capital. Expenditures in health had many dimensions where such trade-offs were present. A good diet or exercising might not be very much fun, but potentially delivered long-term benefits in the form of a longer and healthier life. Preventive medical care demanded time and money, but might also improve future health prospects. This was recognized early on (Mushkin, Reference Mushkin1962), but the first explorations of health as human capital were conceptually timid and did not give the field a push that remotely resembled that received by the economic research on education. For the years that followed, health economics persisted mostly as a field dealing with the analysis of health systems and delivery of health technologies.

Only after a decade would health economics witness the development of an encompassing theoretical framework capable of incorporating the main dimensions of health as a consumption good and human capital. Again, this contribution did not carry the authorship of Gary Becker but was impregnated with his influence. The theory that would become the working horse model in health economics for generations to come was developed by Michael Grossman in his Ph.D. dissertation at Columbia University, under the guidance of Gary Becker and Jacob Mincer (Grossman Reference Grossman1972). In the words of Grossman (Reference Grossman2004, p. 631): “Gary in particular suggested the topic of my dissertation. Originally it was supposed to be a study of the effects of education on health, but along the way he encouraged (some might say demanded) me to broaden it into a theoretical and empirical analysis of the demand for health.”

The theory of Grossman (Reference Grossman1972) built heavily on Becker's “A Theory of the Allocation of Time” to develop a household production model where individuals could spend resources and time on investments to improve health (Becker Reference Becker1965). The benefits from improvements in health would materialize over time, as increased stocks of health capital delivered future utility flows (consumption value of good health), increased time available in each period of life for market and non-market production (akin to reduced morbidity, from the incapacitation perspective), and also increased length of life (reduced mortality). The seeds of virtually all of the ensuing literature on health as human capital and the welfare value of health improvements, even if mostly not explicitly considered, were already present in Grossman's early work. These were synthetized and somewhat extended by Becker himself, when later in life he became increasingly interested in topics related to health (Becker Reference Becker2007). Some of the issues considered in this synthesis have far reaching economic implications. Three of them deserve particular attention in a journal dedicated to demographic economics: determinants of optimal investments in health, the welfare value of health improvements, and complementarities between health and other behavior. I will use this classification to help structure the discussion of the contributions of Gary Becker to the field of health economics.

2. OPTIMAL INVESTMENTS IN HEALTH

The analysis of optimal investments in health involves the evolution of the stock of health over the life cycle, as considered by Grossman (Reference Grossman1972), and its interaction with the incentives provided by available technologies and institutions. Becker's early contribution to this topic came in a paper co-authored with Isaac Ehrlich, published just a few months after Grossman's own work (Ehrlich and Becker Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972). Ehrlich and Becker (Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972) considered, in the context of a model of market insurance, the possibility of self-insurance and self-protection. The former was identified with actions that individuals could take that would reduce the loss in case of occurrence of a bad state, and the latter was taken to refer to actions that could reduce the probability of occurrence of a “bad” state. Though they explored a general framework, health is an obvious candidate for this type of analysis and, in fact, was used by Ehrlich and Becker (Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972) as a main example of the application of their model. Preventive health care, such as exercising properly or following a good diet, may reduce the probability of a heart attack as well as the recovery prospects conditional on the occurrence of a heart attack. Ehrlich and Becker (Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972) explored for the first time the implications of self-protection and self-insurance, analyzing in particular how the possibility of such behavior interacted with existing institutions, such as market insurance. They showed that market insurance and self-insurance are substitutes, but that market insurance and self-protection can be complements. The possibility of such complementarity may lead, under certain conditions, to a reduction in the risk of hazardous events due to access to market insurance, overturning the moral hazard result typical from the insurance literature. This possibility arises because insurance may reduce the cost of self-protection, given that it increases consumption in the bad state (and this affects the opportunity cost of expenditures on self-protection). Such considerations can be important for understanding the optimal design of health systems, but have not been fully appreciated by the more recent literature.

Becker revisited the interaction between market institutions and incentives to invest in health almost 30 years later, in Philipson and Becker (Reference Philipson and Becker1998). Philipson and Becker (Reference Philipson and Becker1998) analyzed how the presence of old age mortality-contingent claims—such as annuities, survival benefits in pension plans, or any other payment conditional on individuals’ length of life—affects behavior related to survival into old age. They showed that the presence of these types of assets, which have increased dramatically across the world since the mid-20th century, increase investments in old age survival above the socially optimum level, leading, in a sense, to an inefficiently high-level of old-age longevity. Philipson and Becker (Reference Philipson and Becker1998) called this effect a type of moral hazard, but notice that it works in an opposite direction to that typically discussed in the insurance literature. This is somewhat similar to the possibility of complementarity between market insurance and self-protection discussed by Ehrlich and Becker (Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972). In Philipson and Becker (Reference Philipson and Becker1998), individuals do not take into account that their self-protective behavior extending survival into old age increases the cost of the old-age insurance mechanism, leading to a socially inefficient length of life.

3. THE WELFARE VALUE OF HEALTH IMPROVEMENTS

The results from Philipson and Becker (Reference Philipson and Becker1998) come from the trade-off between quantity and quality of life that arises when one thinks about the length of life as a variable that can be changed and that affects human welfare. Their main conclusion derived from the way that the introduction of annuities affects such trade-off and the incentives to invest in extended survival. The interaction between quantity and quality of life also featured prominently in Becker's contribution to the analysis of the welfare value of health improvements. Becker, Philipson, and Soares (Reference Becker, Philipson and Soares2005) developed a parameterized version of a simplified life-cycle model in order to use the framework from the value of life literature to include health in an economically meaningful measure of aggregate welfare. Their framework considered a hypothetical individual who earned the average income per capita of a country in every year of life and that was subject to the survival probabilities observed in that country at that same point in time. Welfare comparisons across countries in a given year were then based on the evaluation of this hypothetical individual, and the income value of health gains could be expressed as the equivalent compensating variation. Based on this notion, Becker, Philipson, and Soares (Reference Becker, Philipson and Soares2005) developed a concept of “full-income” that incorporated both gains in health and income per capita, and that could be used to assess the evolution of overall welfare and its inequality across countries. Since cross-country inequality in mortality was reduced substantially over the post-war period, while income inequality did not change much, this measure of “full-income” led to very different conclusions regarding the evolution of welfare inequality across countries, when compared to inequality in income per capita alone. Once survival was incorporated into the picture, one could see a monotonic reduction in welfare inequality across the world during the post-war period. Becker, Philipson, and Soares (Reference Becker, Philipson and Soares2005) also showed that the reduction in mortality inequality across countries was mainly driven by infectious diseases and mortality at early ages. More recent advances in medical sciences – related to reductions in mortality by heart and circulatory conditions and other old age causes of death – had in fact contributed to increase health inequality across countries in the second half of the 20th century. This paper had substantial influence on large subsequent literatures on the economic value of improvements in health, on multidimensional (economically based) welfare indices, and on the determinants and patterns of evolution of health inequalities across the world.

4. COMPLEMENTARITIES BETWEEN HEALTH AND OTHER BEHAVIOR

Though not directly focused on health itself, maybe the most influential contribution of Becker to the field of health economics was related to the complementarities between health and other behavior. His works on habits, time preferences, and investments in human capital have shed light on the important complementarities between health and addiction, health and forward looking behavior, and health and education. The theory of rational addiction of Becker and Murphy (Reference Becker and Murphy1988) explored a setting where past consumption of an addictive—or habit—good increases the current marginal utility of consumption, though possibly reducing the current level of utility. This framework explains how individuals may engage in addictive behavior even rationally and in full anticipation of the future consequences of their acts. It also sheds light on the relationship between health and addictive behavior. “Bad” addictions—those that lower future utility levels—are more costly when survival probabilities are higher. Also, individuals in good health have stronger incentives to develop good habitual behavior, which tends to increase future utility levels together with marginal utilities. This type of effect would be further reinforced if the health consequences of “bad” and “good” addictions—such as risks of overdose from drug consumption and increased probability of survival from exercising—were explicitly incorporated into the model developed by Becker and Murphy (Reference Becker and Murphy1988). In that case, as Becker (Reference Becker2007) alludes to, the additional effect of competing risks would further reinforce the interaction between poor health and addictive risky behavior.

What lies behind this discussion is the idea that health, given its human capital nature, is intrinsically connected to any other behavior that implies trade-offs over time. This connection manifested itself again when Becker and Mulligan (Reference Becker and Mulligan1997) analyzed the determinants and consequences of investments in the subjective rate of discount over time. They considered a theory where individuals could spend resources to reduce the discount applied on future utility, or, in other words, to increase the relative value attributed to future welfare in comparison to current welfare. Becker and Mulligan (Reference Becker and Mulligan1997) conceived these investments as being related to an effort on the part of individuals to increase their own appreciation of the future, mostly through imagination and introspection, but also through consumption of market goods that would increase focus on future objectives. They extensively explored the interrelations between the possibility of investment in this “future-oriented” capital and various dimensions of health. In their theory, increases in longevity—or, equivalently, reductions in mortality rates—increase the return to investments in future-oriented capital, therefore increasing the utility weight attributed to each future period of life. Similar effects would also be triggered by the perspective of good health in the future as refers to lower morbidity, for a given pattern of survival.

The complementarity with health is probably most pervasive and economically relevant in the case of education. The early contributions of human capital theory already implied that increases in the planning horizon increase the returns to investments in education (Becker Reference Becker1964). But following developments in the economics of the family further reinforced this link and highlighted its relevance in an intergenerational setting. Becker and Tomes (Reference Becker and Tomes1976) explored how the incorporation of children's endowments in the household problem affects the decision of parents. They showed that when deciding how much to invest in children with different endowments, parents face two opposing forces: those with higher endowments generate higher returns, but those with lower endowments are more dependent on parental transfers to increase future welfare.

We now understand that a substantial part of these endowments is determined by health conditions before birth and during the first years of life. So it is natural to think about endowments of children and adults, and their relationship with investments in human capital, as in fact reflecting the complementarity between health and education. Large empirical literatures have followed the initial theoretical explorations of Becker on investments in human capital and have analyzed the impacts of health on education, and vice-versa. Once one thinks of endowments as related to health, the relationship between child health and fertility can also be better understood. By reducing the relative cost of child quality, improvements in health tend to shift the quantity–quality trade-off towards fewer and better educated children. The effect of child mortality can also be immediately incorporated in a setting like this, as an extreme case in which investments in children deliver no return whatsoever.

This interaction of health with human capital, embedded within a context of fertility choice, assumed yet an additional relevance when human capital theory was brought to the analysis of the determinants of the demographic transition. Becker, Murphy, and Tamura (Reference Becker, Murphy and Tamura1990) brought together several aspects of the theories of human capital, investments in children, fertility, and growth in order to develop a model that could reproduce the main economic and demographic changes observed during the last centuries. In their model, economies could display an equilibrium without investments in human capital, with high fertility, and without growth, or an equilibrium with investments in human capital, low fertility, and growth. Initial conditions and the value of some key parameters—such as productivity, cost of children, and length of life—would determine where the economy would end up. Though Becker, Murphy, and Tamura (Reference Becker, Murphy and Tamura1990) did not pay much attention to health, their framework, when coupled with the complementarities between health, human capital, and fertility discussed before, opened up the possibility of understanding the role of “exogenous” changes in health, driven by advances in medical and biological sciences, as driving forces behind the process of demographic transition. This approach generated a stream of research, with both theoretical and empirical contributions, exploring the role of improvements in health as determinants of the historical reductions in fertility and increases in schooling that typically follow the transition.

5. CONCLUDING COMMENTS

Health economics represented a relatively small and somewhat late interest in the broader research agenda of Gary Becker. Yet, it is difficult not to see his influence on virtually every topic of research in the area involving any sort of theoretical analysis or motivation. As in many other areas that he touched but briefly, Becker has left permanent imprints on the economic analysis of health as consumption good and human capital. The longevity of his ideas will continue to be strong complements to future advances in health economics for a long time to come.

References

REFERENCES

Becker, G. S. (1962) Investment in human capital: a theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 70 (5), part 2, 949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1964) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1965) A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal LXX (299), 493508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (2007) Health as human capital: synthesis and extensions. Oxford Economic Papers 59 (3), 379410.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Mulligan, C. B. (1997) The endogenous determination of time preference. Quarterly Journal of Economics CXII (2), 729758.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Murphy, K. M. (1988) A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy 96 (4), 675700.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., and Tamura, R. (1990) Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 98 (2), S12–S70.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., Philipson, T. J., and Soares, R. R. (2005) The quantity and quality of life and the evolution of world inequality. American Economic Review 95 (1), 277291.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Tomes, N. (1976) Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy 84 (4), Part 2, S143–S162.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, I. and Becker, G. S. (1972) Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. Journal of Political Economy 80 (4), 623648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, M. (1972) On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 80 (2), 223255.Google Scholar
Grossman, M. (2004) The demand for health, 30 years later: a very personal retrospective and prospective reflection. Journal of Health Economics 23 (4), 629636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mushkin, S. J. (1962) Health as an investment. Journal of Political Economy 70 (5), Part 2: Investment in Human Beings, 129157.Google Scholar
Philipson, T. J. and Becker, G. S. (1998) Old-age longevity and mortality-contingent claims. Journal of Political Economy 106 (3), 551573.Google Scholar
Schultz, T. W. (1960) Capital formation by education. Journal of Political Economy 68 (6), 571583.Google Scholar