Introduction
The history of insurance has been characterized, more than for most industries and services, by a wide range of organizational forms, including obligatory and voluntary public mutual institutions; private mutual associations; public and private stock corporations—some with monopoly powers; large unincorporated stock companies; small unincorporated private partnerships; and syndicates of individual underwriters managed in some places (such as Lloyd’s) by brokers.Footnote 1
The reasons for this plethora of vehicles remain unclear, as does their impact on the global development of insurance. It is likely that there were many country-specific factors at work that determined the balance of public and private forms of insurance in any one place over time. It may also be possible, however, to identify generic political, economic, and cultural factors, common to several markets, that explain why public forms of insurance were more prominent in some economies than in others.
This article examines the potency of path-dependent effects in determining the historical distribution of public and private forms of insurance in a range of developed and developing economies. The path-dependency literature has expanded enormously since its original focus on the persistence of inefficient technologies.Footnote 2 A variety of models, emphasizing institutional, locational, and other “fundamentals,” as well as economic determinants of path dependence, have been applied, for instance, to the evolution of business strategies, the size of cities, human capital accumulation in Brazil, and water rights in the American West, to name some examples.Footnote 3 Curiously, path-dependency theory appears to have been seldom applied to financial service industries or used to explain the development of organizational forms.Footnote 4 To this extent, this article makes a novel contribution to the literature on path dependency, although its main purpose is to understand the diversity of organizational forms that have characterized the business of insurance throughout its history.
In their critique of technological path dependence, Liebowitz and Margolis usefully identified three types.Footnote 5 First-degree path dependence is a simple assertion of intertemporal effects, wherein technological choices are sensitive to initial conditions but there is no implied inefficiency of outcomes. In second-degree path dependence, efficient decisions may not always turn out to be so in retrospect, but the inefficiency is not known at the outset. Third-degree path dependence describes a dynamic market failure that is brought about by the persistence of certain inefficient choices, wherein the initial errors in those choices were avoidable. The argument presented here conforms most closely to the first-degree model, the weakest form of the three. Our survey of a large number of national insurance markets from the eighteenth to the twentieth centuries points to the primary importance of the state and different political cultures in determining the persistence of certain organizational forms in national insurance markets and in ensuring the continuation of the organizational diversity noted earlier. Our argument, however, makes no claim that state actions locked in inefficient organizational forms and resulted in market failure, the strongest version of path-dependence theory.
Our focus, therefore, is on the state and the historical development of the insurance industry in a wide range of economies. The following section examines the history of the state as an exogenous force shaping insurance markets. The subsequent three sections examine the state as a participant in those markets in the early modern and modern eras, including its role in social insurance and nationalization. The conclusion identifies the determinants of organizational forms in insurance and also discusses the impact of different insurance vehicles on market development, thus touching on the efficiency question. The relative costs and benefits of public and private forms of insurance, however, amount to a huge topic for a future international comparative study, and much of the detailed research for many countries on questions such as market distortions and crowding out remains to be done.
The State as Gatekeeper, Regulator, and Facilitator
In relation to insurance markets, the state has had four principle historic functions: those of gatekeeper, regulator, facilitator, and participant. Through the exercise of these functions, states have, at different times and in different places, constricted, created, grown, and distorted markets both to the cost and benefit of consumers and insurers. The following sections focus on the state’s role as a participant in insurance and the forms in which this occurred. This section outlines the early history of the other three functions.
Since the fifteenth century, European states have acted as gatekeepers to the insurance market, prohibiting or authorizing certain types of insurance, certain types of organization, and other vehicles for insurance provision such as agents and, in places, the volume of insurance supplied by private individuals and organizations. The clearest example of prohibitory gatekeeping was the ban on forms of life insurance that were regarded as wagers in both Catholic and Protestant states between the fifteenth and eighteenth centuries. Thus, Venice banned wagers on the pope’s life in 1419, in Spain all forms of life insurance were suppressed by the Ordinances of Barcelona in 1435, and Genoa prohibited insurance on kings, princes, bishops, popes, cardinals, and other objects of insurance gambling in 1467, 1475, and 1494.Footnote 6 Other examples of state proscriptions included the parliamentary ban on marine reinsurance in England in 1746. This statute (19 Geo.II c.37) was enacted because of concerns about the lack of insurable interest in many insurance policies and the opportunity presented by reinsurance contracts for the fraudulent concealment of information by direct insurers.Footnote 7 Such prohibitions were imposed not just by monarchical regimes but also by republican governments. The first life and fire insurance corporations in France, licensed by royal authority, were banned by the National Convention in 1793. In many U.S. states in the nineteenth century, buying reinsurance from companies not authorized to do business in those states was prohibited.Footnote 8
The European prohibitions on life insurance derived from religious-ethical anxieties about the use of insurance as wagers and the negative social and political effects on ancien regime populations. In early modern England, by contrast, the lives of ship passengers continued to be insured, albeit in small numbers, in marine insurance policies that came to be governed by common law. The latter, unlike the continental Law Merchant, did not draw on Roman legal precepts that regarded life insurance as unethical because it was a form of trading in lives.Footnote 9 By the eighteenth century, as the importance of religious doctrines in political culture began to wane, and long before law courts drew a formal distinction between illegal wagers and legal life insurance based on an insurable interest, life insurance in England grew via small private mutual schemes such as “mortuary tontines”—at least sixty were launched between 1696 and 1721—as well as via larger and more permanent organizations such as the mutual Amicable Society of 1705 and the two London stock corporations of 1720.Footnote 10 Thus differences in political cultures and legal traditions helped determine variations between European states in the treatment of life insurance, and this in turn ensured a continuing diversity in the forms by which it was delivered.
Other things being equal, governments have the power to limit moral hazard more thoroughly and cheaply than private insurers can through market operations. Rather than prohibiting insurance outright, some regimes employed their licensing procedures to control supply and demand in an attempt to eradicate overinsurance and what they perceived to be the attendant moral hazard and social evils. This practice was especially prevalent in northern and central Europe during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, where political cultures were generally characterized by autocratic governments, powerful bureaucracies, and police forces committed to an array of monitorial and social-disciplinary actions.Footnote 11 This was manifested in the form of “preventative controls” on fire insurance contracts and restrictions on who was permitted to insure, as well as tightly controlling the issue of licenses to companies and their agents. The Duchy of Magdeburg, for example, required farm laborers and other workers to subject any property they wished to insure to an exact valuation, in order to prevent “dissolute and immoral people” (liderliche Leute) from overinsuring. Regulations to reduce the moral hazard associated with overinsurance and excessive claims payments continued in Germany well into the nineteenth century, underpinned by the belief of state officials that not all citizens were “mature” enough for private insurance. A Saxon government order of 1828 required policyholders to obtain the approval of the local police captain (Amtshauptmann), before they could coinsure their property in more than one company. In Württemberg, a law of 1852 required policyholders to obtain a certificate of valuation from the local council (Gemeinderat).Footnote 12
Another device to regulate supply was the requirement in some states for companies to show that their business met a public “need.” In Prussia, for example, under a law of 1837, new companies wishing to obtain licenses from the Ministry of Interior or licensed companies wishing to appoint additional agents in cities had to provide proof that there was a “demand” (Bedürfnis) for their services. This proof took the form of a testimony from the local town or county administration that the demand existed. It does not seem to have been based on any empirical evidence or scientific investigation of data. Indeed, critics pointed out that many existing insurance companies in small towns appointed the local mayors and councilors as their agents, who therefore had a vested interest in preventing the admission of new competitors.Footnote 13 The requirement was abolished in Prussia in 1859, but survived longer in other states such as Austria and Baden.
Increasingly during the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, many governments, usually for ideological reasons or acting under external political pressure, extended their gatekeeping functions to impose discriminatory fiscal and regulatory burdens on foreign insurers in an effort to deter entry and encourage exit. Examples include the higher tax rates charged on foreign companies compared to their domestic competitors in Sweden in 1857, Belgium in 1907, and several American states such as Pennsylvania (1856), Massachusetts (1862), Missouri (1866), and Kansas (1899).Footnote 14 Deposit, policy, and reporting requirements could also be made taxing to foreign companies applying to enter a market. Legislation in Bulgaria in 1898, for example, required all foreign insurers to make deposits in government securities.Footnote 15 Some American states required foreign companies to deposit cash in each location in the state where they had agents. Thus, in Ohio in 1858, the deposits required ranged from $50,000 in Cincinnati to $10,000 or $20,000 in other cities.Footnote 16
In the past, states have also frequently restricted or directed the supply of insurance by issuing monopoly privileges to for-profit private groups, usually in return for some revenue benefit. With some of these ventures, the lines between state monopoly and private monopoly authorized by the state were particularly blurred, especially where compulsion was involved. This was a favorite device of ancien regime governments in Europe. One example is the monopoly on corporate marine insurance issued to two groups of investors in London in 1720, who formed the Royal Exchange Assurance and London Assurance companies in return for “loans” of £300,000 each to the Crown. The effect was to drive business toward underwriters at Lloyd’s, who were not subject to the restriction on corporate underwriting. The monopoly was finally repealed in 1824, but by then more than 95 percent of marine insurance in Britain was underwritten at Lloyd’s.Footnote 17 This is a good example of how state-authorized private monopolies could distort a market and skew it in one direction at the expense of alternative forms of supplier. Other examples occurred in Russia. Having rejected the idea of a public insurance institution, in 1827 the tsarist state issued an exclusive monopoly charter for the First Russian Fire Insurance Company of St. Petersburg to insure property in the residence towns, Odessa, and the Baltic provinces. In 1835 a similar charter was issued to the Second Russian Company for other gouvernements. These monopoly privileges were repealed in 1847, but important restrictions continued. Thereafter, Russians could only insure with foreign companies if they had already been refused insurance by the Russian companies.Footnote 18
The state could also facilitate the growth of insurance by reducing risk and by collecting and publishing information on hazards and other events. With its national resources, it could do this on a scale and frequency that private companies could not, until the latter began to collaborate more effectively toward the end of the nineteenth century when faced with a new range of technologies.Footnote 19 Early examples of state intervention in this area include data on deaths in English towns collected by local churchwardens in parish registers. In the early nineteenth century, most English life insurance companies based their premium rates on the mortality tables constructed from the registers of Northampton and Carlisle by Richard Price in 1781 and Joshua Milne in 1815, respectively. The actuarially unfair prices produced by these tables—which suggested a much higher level of mortality than contemporary life insurers were experiencing among their policyholders—probably acted as a stimulus to investment in new life insurance companies. There were only six such companies in England in 1800 but more than 150 by 1850. Legislation to combat overcrowding and poor sanitation in urban areas, together with improvements to public health services, by reducing the frequency and virulence of epidemics and lowering average mortality, were other ways in which the state contributed to the growth of cheaper life insurance.Footnote 20 Some £290 million was insured on lives in Britain in 1870, up from £12 million in 1800.Footnote 21
Public authorities at local and national levels, with their powers of enforcement and tax-raising capacity, were usually better equipped than private insurers to prevent or mitigate the number and intensity of physical hazards such as fire, flood, windstorm, and earthquake, as well as to counter the dangers of new technologies. From the late Middle Ages, the building codes of numerous English towns attempted to reduce the fire hazards caused by shoddy construction and inflammable materials.Footnote 22 In many places firefighting was organized, albeit often inefficiently, by local authorities, and parish fire brigades supplemented the private brigades of the fire insurance companies.
States could also help private insurers cope with the risks involved in insuring against the hazards brought by new technologies. The regulation of road traffic is one area in which the state played a major role in facilitating the growth of an insurance market in many countries.Footnote 23 Another example is engineering and machinery insurance. The boiler explosions acts passed by the British Parliament in 1882 and 1890 greatly added to the functions already carried out by the specialist boiler insurance companies that had emerged since the 1850s. The legislation made provision for the investigation of all commercial boiler explosions by engineers appointed by the Board of Trade. Further provision for the regular inspection of boilers was made by the Factory and Workshop acts of 1901, 1911, and 1920, and this principle of official safety inspection was extended in the early twentieth century to all classes of powered machinery, helping engineering insurance to develop as a specialist class of underwriting.Footnote 24
In sum, these three exogenous roles of the state—gatekeeper, regulator, and facilitator—in shaping the business and legal environment for different organizational forms in insurance, arguably created path-dependent effects, in the sense that state actions, and national political cultures more generally, helped particular business forms persist over time in different economies, and ensured the continuing diversity, rather than the organizational convergence, of the industry.
The State as Participant: Public Insurance and State Ownership in the Early Modern Period
Public authorities have also participated, directly or indirectly, in insurance markets. When entering these markets as actors and not simply regulators, states have certain advantages over private insurers. As Robert Wright has noted, governments have powers that private insurers do not, including the ability to limit adverse selection by compelling individuals and businesses to enroll in a public insurance program and forcing them to pay premiums and taxes.Footnote 25 Governments have longer time horizons that enable them to withstand economic downturns more efficiently than private companies, and they often have deeper pockets to provide emergency relief, victim compensation, and recovery support in the wake of large disaster events. There are disadvantages too, which have been widely commented upon. Public insurance can be inefficient, it can distort markets, and it can generate serious asymmetric information and adverse selection problems. These issues are examined later. First, however, this section outlines the different forms that have been taken by state actors in insurance markets.
In early modern Europe, while private underwriters and brokers continued to operate in many ports, some states moved to found monopoly institutions for marine insurance, such as those in Genoa and Copenhagen in 1742 and 1746, respectively.Footnote 26 In 1751 the Kingdom of Naples created the Real Compagnia di Assicurazioni Maritime. All merchant ships operating out of Naples were required to insure through the company, though many Neapolitans still preferred to insure in London, where premiums were lower. Once the Real Compagnia was abolished in 1802, the Neapolitan market was returned to private operators, but instead of being confined to individual underwriters as before, a number of new marine insurance companies began to appear, beginning with the Societa Napoletana di Assicurazioni Maritime in 1811. By the late 1850s several dozen companies—ranging from small partnerships to large joint stocks—had been founded in Naples, Messina, and Sorrento, suggesting that a pent-up supply of marine insurance capacity had been suppressed by the monopoly of the royal company.Footnote 27 Clearly the development of marine insurance in Genoa, Naples, and Copenhagen was skewed by these monopoly institutions, although given the current limited state of research, it is difficult to know whether in their absence private corporate forms would have emerged earlier than they did. In the case of Trieste, where there was no state monopoly, several private stock companies formed for marine insurance during the late eighteenth century, but most failed during the Napoleonic wars when Trieste lost business to more price-competitive centers in Hamburg, Amsterdam, and London.Footnote 28
On the whole, the evidence from early modern Europe suggests that direct participation by the state in marine insurance had limited success. One probable reason was that marine risks were nonstandardized and therefore relatively costly to handle for large corporations with high overheads. It was difficult to construct standard tariff schedules on an actuarial basis to price such risks. Second, the international regulation of marine underwriting at an early date reduced transaction costs for the individual underwriter and increased the confidence of shippers seeking insurance.Footnote 29 Third, as Kingston has argued, well-organized systems of individual underwriting such as Lloyd’s of London could deliver information advantages over their corporate rivals.Footnote 30 Where markets of individual underwriters were less developed, where there were doubts about the security of the contracts issued, and where the political, legal, and economic environment was conducive to the formation of joint stock enterprises, as in the United States around 1800, private corporations could prevail, but there were no obvious competitive advantages for state corporations in marine insurance, at least in peacetime.Footnote 31 Some states, however, retained a direct involvement in marine insurance for political reasons. During the 1870s in China, for instance, several public–private insurance ventures appeared, beginning with the China Merchants Steam Navigation Company, with the Manchu government as a shareholder. It was the first example of the Chinese state moving into the insurance business as part of a wider nationalist strategy to bolster the economy, and particularly Chinese shipping, against foreign competition. The China Merchants Steam Navigation Company and its related companies proved successful and opened overseas branches in Singapore, the Philippines, and San Francisco. They closed after the crash of 1929.Footnote 32
In early modern Europe, there is much greater evidence of state participation and success in fire insurance than marine insurance. This was part of a growing mercantilist interest in utilizing government powers to improve the security of private property and incomes, not least in response to the huge revenue needs of the fiscal-military state.Footnote 33 Public fire insurance derived from the medieval tradition of briefs and compulsory collections for victims of fires. Such collections, for example, took place at county and parish levels in Denmark, Germany, England, and Sweden. From the late seventeenth century, this traditional system of public post hoc relief for losses by fire was supplemented by various municipal and state institutions for the insurance of buildings, in some places accompanied by compulsion. The first successful public fire insurance institution was the Hamburger Feuerkasse of 1676, which originated in local “fire contracts,” written agreements between groups of about 100 owners of property within the town walls by which, in return for a fixed subscription, victims of fire would receive compensation toward repairing or rebuilding their properties.Footnote 34 The contracts were private arrangements, but from 1620 they were required to be confirmed by the town senate, thus lending them a degree of official recognition. By the 1670s there were some forty-six fire contracts in Hamburg. Their small scale and the difficulty of spreading risk in a confined area led the senate to combine all the contracts into one new insurance fund, the Feuerkasse, to be administered by council officials. There was no compulsion on existing householders to join the fund—compulsion was first introduced in 1817—but whoever built a new house or bought or inherited a house was required to join. Losses were adjusted by deputies of the Feuerkasse, assisted by selected craftsmen. In the event that the fund proved insufficient to cover payments, members were liable for further calls at fixed rates proportionate to the sums they had insured. The fund was also used to pay the medical bills of citizens injured fighting fires or a lifetime annuity to those rendered permanently disabled, as well as the burial costs of the victims of fires. The institution thus combined elements of a mutual association with those of a state-administered public welfare body.
The Hamburg Feuerkasse provided a model for mercantilist regimes elsewhere to copy. Public buildings insurance societies were formed across much of Germany during the late seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.Footnote 35 They were also formed in Denmark in 1731; in Switzerland, where cantonal insurance began in 1782; and in Sweden, where the government organized a General Fire Insurance Fund in 1782. Most public societies were local or regional in scope, and as extensions of state bureaucracy and revenue systems, they were managed by civil servants and characteristic of the political cultures into which they were born. The Fire Society for the Towns in the Duchy of Cleve and the County of Mark, for example, was managed by an official commission appointed by the province, while the Westphalian state tax commissioner, appointed by the king, decided upon the contribution quota for each town. Here and in the other public insurance societies in Prussia, soldiers were on guard as claimants appeared personally before the town magistrates to receive their payouts. There was no corporate identity and often no specific building—they were administered from a desk in a government building as one of several public funds, including funds for schools, churches, and the poor. Insurance was generally issued on a non-actuarial basis. Policyholders were usually charged flat fees for all types of property, and the fees were paid like any other tax (a crude risk classification was first introduced by the Hamburger Feuerkasse in 1753, and only later by other societies). Public insurance societies were nonprofit organizations. Their primary purpose was to pay for the rebuilding of property damaged by fire, while any surplus was normally used to supplement other forms of welfare expenditure. There was often a compulsory rebuilding clause inserted into members’ contracts, and payments were usually made on the basis of historic rather than rebuilding costs.Footnote 36 Yet for all their limitations from a modern perspective, the public societies appear to have been remarkably successful, insuring between 50 and 75 percent of property in some parts of northern Europe.Footnote 37
With urban growth, the public societies increasingly faced a problem of changing cost structures. Where the public societies insisted on a level of self-insurance, property owners turned to private companies to fill the gap. From 1840, under the growing influence of liberal ideologies, authorities began to permit private insurers to compete freely with state institutions in three Prussian provinces: Rhineland, Westphalia, and Poznan.Footnote 38 Traditional suspicions of private insurance lingered, but states increasingly placed limits on the extent of their participation in fire insurance. A common weakness was the inability of public societies to accumulate sufficient funds to cope with major fire disasters in urban areas. This was true, for example, of the Swedish General Fire Insurance Fund of 1782, which, after several large town fires, ran out of money to meet claims. Its managers were also reluctant to insure poorer risks—housing not built with fire-resistant materials—which led to conflict between different interest groups in the fund. By 1828 the fund had split into three separate organizations, one insuring only rural property, one insuring urban property, and a third formed by policyholders themselves exclusively for the southernmost province of Sweden.Footnote 39
Private companies insuring contents against fire were tolerated by ancien regimes, not only because of the complexities of underwriting nonstandard risks that were increasingly subject to technological change, but also because the policyholders were mostly wealthier merchants and property owners who were regarded as literate and numerate enough to understand what they were buying. As private insurance companies began to carve out a market for the insurance of movable goods, nineteenth-century states responded by removing the monopoly of public societies for buildings insurance, thus forcing them to compete with private stock and mutual companies in a more open market. At the same time, efforts were made, for instance in Prussia during the 1820s and 1830s, to combine the smaller societies into larger regional bodies in order to improve their competitiveness.Footnote 40 In several countries this seems to have worked, for public fire insurance societies managed to sustain their share of the market. In Denmark in 1827, for example, state insurance on buildings amounted to £18.1 million, compared to £19.1 million insured by the largest private society, the Brandforsikkring for Huse og Gaarde.Footnote 41 In Germany, public societies accounted for 36 percent of all sums insured against fire in 1879, and 34 percent in 1910.Footnote 42 Around two-thirds of this derived from compulsory buildings insurance, the rest from voluntary buildings and contents policies.Footnote 43 There is little question that public insurance crowded out the supply of private fire insurance in such markets over a long period. It also contributed to the fragmentation of markets, and perhaps increased consumer choice and kept prices down by reducing the power of the tariff associations of private companies, although this requires confirmation by further research. In sum, different kinds of direct participation by early modern states in national insurance markets, and the political cultures that facilitated such participations, shaped the organizational structure of these markets in ways that proved remarkably persistent through time.
The State as Participant: Social Insurance in the Modern Era
Three basic types of social insurance existed from the late nineteenth century: voluntary and compulsory employment-based social insurance, largely delivered by private for-profit providers with some state oversight; and compulsory not-for-profit universal integrated social security and health insurance systems provided and managed by the state. In their different ways and at different times, these delivered insurance against sickness, workplace accidents, unemployment, and old age for ever-greater numbers of people. The voluntary accident insurance schemes provided by private companies were stimulated by the first generation of employers’ liability legislation in Europe. The Imperial German liability law of 1871, for example, made employers in sectors such as mining and railroads liable to their employees in the event of workplace injuries, though insurance was not obligatory. Any compensation paid by an employer’s insurance company was set against the compensation granted by a court, on the assumption that the insurance would cover only part of the employer’s legal liability. This greatly increased the demand in Germany for private accident insurance. The belief was that injured workers or their relatives would give up costly litigation against employers once compensated by such insurance payments.Footnote 44 Similarly in the United Kingdom, the Employers’ Liability Act of 1880 made employers liable for injuries caused to certain classes of employees by negligence in the workplace. The effect of this legislation was to give private providers a much wider field for personal accident insurance. The Workmen’s Compensation Acts of 1897 and 1906 extended the principle of compensation to new groups of British workers, to accidents not necessarily caused by negligence, and to ill health caused by industrial diseases. This was an example of state intervention intentionally creating a huge new market for private insurance companies without encroaching directly on the operation of the business.
Compulsory-contribution employment-based social insurance first appeared in Germany with Bismarck’s national health insurance legislation in 1883, statutory accident insurance in 1884, and state disability and old age insurance for workers in 1889. In the volatile political culture of the Second Reich, Bismarck expressly viewed these new social insurance schemes as devices to wean discontented industrial workers away from Social Democracy and Marxism.Footnote 45 Rising medical costs, together with the limited provision of medical and hospital services, increased incentives to insure against loss of income from sickness, but private health insurance remained beyond the pockets of most German workers. This weak market for private health insurance helps explain the limited resistance to the new legislation. The health insurance scheme of 1883, for example, comprised a system of sickness funds based either geographically or in particular firms or guilds. Employers were required to provide insurance for all employees earning less than 2000 marks per annum, although those who earned more were allowed to buy into the scheme. Premiums were paid two-thirds by the worker and one-third by the employer. The insured were entitled to free medical and other auxiliary treatment. Benefits also included cash payments up to half of the worker’s wage for a given period of sickness or incapacity, after which trade associations covered the cost of any treatment. Doctors were contracted and paid directly by the funds for their services.Footnote 46 The initial legislation applied only to certain categories of industrial worker, covering about 10 percent of the population, but by 1927 coverage had been extended to transport, clerical, farm, and forestry workers; domestic servants; government employees; seamen; and the unemployed. These statutory schemes helped spread the understanding of insurance through German society. Life insurance premiums in Germany, for instance, increased from 86 million marks in the 1880s to 278 million marks in the 1900s.Footnote 47
The development of a compulsory contribution system in Germany provided a model for many other countries. In Sweden, mandatory industrial injury insurance, delivered by private companies, was legislated for in 1901 and 1916. In Austria, accident insurance was made mandatory for large industrial firms in 1887.Footnote 48 In the United States between 1900 and 1920, three systems coexisted. Monopoly state funds to provide workmen’s compensation were set up in some states (Ohio and Washington in 1911; Nevada, Oregon, and West Virginia 1913; Wyoming 1915; North Dakota 1919) where insurance and farming interests were weak and unions strong or where progressives swept into power. Legislation to establish state funds against which private insurers were allowed to compete was passed in a further ten states beginning in Michigan in 1912. Elsewhere, experiments in state insurance were rejected. In many American states the debate was whether workmen’s compensation insurance should be purchased from a state fund or whether employers should be free to buy from private companies. Unions lobbied hard for state insurance on the grounds that private companies should not profit from the misfortunes of injured workers and that public insurance could eliminate the overheads and profits of selling private insurance, so that employers’ premiums could be reduced and workers’ benefits increased. The private companies claimed that the state had no actuarial experience and that only they had the expertise to adjust rates for the different accident rates experienced across industries. In sum, both the varying alignment of narrow interest groups and broader political interests in different states determined the fate of public monopoly legislation and the shape of accident insurance systems in the United States during the early twentieth century.Footnote 49
By contrast, in Britain the legislation of 1897 and 1906 failed to establish any public competitor to the private provision of workmen’s compensation insurance. Not until a government committee of 1920 was the question of a state fund, operating either as a monopoly or in conjunction with private companies, or a state system of mutual insurance, considered. By this time there were already sixty-five insurance companies underwriting workmen’s compensation. In addition, about 10,000 employers were organized in mutual associations in the seven industrial groups to which the 1906 act applied, covering perhaps one-third of all firms. The business had been profitable but expensive for employers. The committee of 1920 concluded that the existing system could be allowed to continue, but under stricter state supervision, led by a commissioner with powers to grant licenses to companies and mutual associations to write workmen’s compensation insurance. An act to this effect was passed in 1923. Not until 1945, however, was a comprehensive state system of contributory social insurance adopted, a system that finally superseded the private provision of workmen’s compensation insurance.Footnote 50
The statutory health insurance programs that appeared in Europe before 1914 differed greatly between countries in terms of their coverage, organization, finance, and method of delivering medical care. Health insurance was introduced by statute in Italy, Austria, Sweden, Denmark, Belgium, and France between 1886 and 1898, and then in the United Kingdom, Norway, and Switzerland between 1909 and 1911. Denmark and Sweden began with voluntary schemes after studying the German model. In 1894 and 1898 Belgium granted legal advantages to private sickness funds that registered with the government and subsidies to those that submitted to state regulation, but not until 1914 was health insurance made compulsory. In France from 1898 friendly societies that provided sickness benefits received government subsidies. Such schemes appear to have accelerated the reduction in European mortality before 1914.Footnote 51
In the United States, state and federal governments fostered the employment-based system of private provision that has remained dominant to the present day. Demand for health insurance increased from the 1930s with advances in medical technology and rising health-care costs. At same time, hospitals pushed to have prepaid plans developed for their services, which became combined under the names Blue Cross and Blue Shield. These plans gained nonprofit tax-exempt status, which initially gave them an advantage over commercial competitors. Several states also exempted them from existing insurance regulations and reserve requirements, while insisting that the same premiums be charged for sick members as healthy members. During the 1940s, commercial insurers gained ground on the Blues by basing their rates on experience and offering lower premiums to younger workers. In 1942 the War Labor Board allowed firms to attract workers using fringe benefit packages, which also boosted employment-based insurance. Tax subsidies and tax exemptions of employers’ health insurance premiums, introduced in 1943 and 1954, respectively, provided further state support to employer-provided health insurance, lowered its relative price, stimulated the growth of group schemes, and encouraged people to buy more comprehensive coverage. Thomasson has shown that from the 1950s Americans with health insurance spent significantly more on medical care than those who remained uninsured.Footnote 52
In the United Kingdom, the German model of compulsory contributions ran against the grain of Victorian liberalism and social policy. Arguments against compulsory schemes centered on the alleged need to incentivize the “respectable poor” and on the opposition of trade unions and friendly societies defending their own benefit funds. The German model did, however, have a major impact on the reforms of 1908 to 1911, when the Liberal government finally introduced compulsory contribution insurance for sickness, invalidity, old age, and unemployment.Footnote 53 In 1925 a contributory non–means tested social insurance was introduced in Britain, but membership was compulsory only for employees earning below £250 per annum. Not until the National Insurance Act of 1946 was compulsory, unified, and universal social insurance introduced in the United Kingdom, funded on a pay-as-you-go basis, that is, by a tax on current expenditure. In 1948 the state pension was underpinned by National Assistance, which retained a means test for supplementary benefits to help the poorest pensioners. The increasingly inadequate basic pension, which lagged in value behind average earnings, resulted in 27 percent of pensioners claiming the supplementary benefit by 1954.Footnote 54
Sweden introduced mandatory state pensions in 1913, to be delivered, like Sweden’s mandatory industrial injury insurance, by private companies. In the 1950s the Swedish Social Democrats argued for a supplementary pension reform built upon the mandatory scheme, with the state guaranteeing the benefits against inflation, while other parties supported a voluntary system with or without state guarantees. The result of the debate was the supplementary pension reform of 1959, introduced after the appointment of a Social Democrat minority government.Footnote 55
In the United States, mandatory pension insurance was finally enacted in 1935, after long resistance by private insurers. The United States was the last industrial country in the world to enact a national (federal) scheme to help the elderly. By 1920 mandatory old age insurance had already been established in ten European countries. By contrast, of twenty-one reports commissioned by U.S. state legislatures by 1929, only one recommended compulsory insurance. It took the exigencies of the Great Depression to compel American legislators to take action.Footnote 56 In Latin America, social insurance programs evolved in a piecemeal and stratified fashion, segmented by occupation, with interest groups extracting different levels of concessions from the state. The armed forces, civil servants, professionals, and white-collar employees obtained the most generous health-care benefits and pensions, while rural workers and workers in nonstrategic industries invariably obtained the worst due to their weaker bargaining power. While the latter had the lowest costs and contribution rates, they also experienced lower than average life expectancy and the poorest insurance coverage.Footnote 57 What the preceding survey clearly shows is that different political and legal regimes, as well as macroeconomic conditions such as average purchasing power and levels of development, were the primary determinants of the type of social insurance systems—public, private, or some blend of the two—that appeared from the late nineteenth century.
The State as Participant: Nationalization
It remains to ask why some modern states nationalized, or partly nationalized, their insurance industries. History suggests three, often interconnected, reasons. First, fiscal-monetary motives sometimes played a part: Faced with economic difficulties, some governments sought to gain control of the revenue streams generated by financial services. Second, policies of autarky or economic nationalism, often bound up with right- or left-wing political ideologies, viewed nationalization as a means to stop the outflow of funds to foreign companies. Third, certain regimes, sometimes socialist or social democratic, sometimes based on religious beliefs, viewed private insurance with hostility on moral or ideological grounds. They regarded nationalization as a device to counter practices harmful to public welfare, notably the high costs, poor governance, and rent seeking that they associated with private insurance organizations.
That last argument appeared in the debates on insurance nationalization that took place in Imperial Germany. Bismarck repeatedly accused private insurers of distributing excessive dividends to shareholders to the detriment of their policyholders. On religious-ethical grounds he claimed that profits should not be made out of the misfortune of individuals. On economic grounds he argued that a state institution could deliver insurance more cheaply than private companies, and called for a comprehensive scheme providing all types of insurance on a mutual basis. He received support from conservative agrarian groups, who thought this might help bind German workers to the existing social order, and from the influential economist Adolph Wagner, who saw in state insurance an opportunity to engage in social engineering by redistributing premiums from the wealthy to the poor, making those who represented the lowest risks pay the highest premiums. Opposition came from the private companies, the insurance press, liberal politicians, and the Congress of German Economists. In the end, Bismarck’s full nationalization was not carried through. Instead, as noted earlier, the growth of the private insurance sector in Germany was actually stimulated by the social insurance legislation of the 1880s and 1890s.Footnote 58
Other countries that opted to nationalize their insurance industries, or parts thereof, included New Zealand, which established a state life insurance office in 1870. By 1904, this office accounted for nearly half the life insurance sold in New Zealand. State insurance was compulsory for civil servants, whose premiums were paid by a deduction from salaries at source. The venture was run on a nonprofit basis, but the government did receive an annual revenue from the life insurance office, which was treated for tax purposes like a private corporation. Further state offices for accident and fire insurance were set up in competition with private companies in 1899 and 1903, respectively.Footnote 59
In Italy before World War I, there was a fierce debate over nationalizing life insurance.Footnote 60 Conservative politicians and economists argued against a state monopoly, because it ran counter to the principle of free competition and because they did not trust the state to run an insurance institution efficiently. Those arguing for a state monopoly emphasized the growing proportion of Italian life insurance that was in the hands of foreign companies—about 41 percent by 1912—and claimed that a state institution would help protect the savings and pensions of the wealthy and policyholders and investors from bankruptcies and from private company tariff rates. Despite the opposition, the Istituto Nazionale dell Assicurazioni (INA) was established in 1912. The law establishing INA allowed private companies to continue operating for up to ten years, but required them to hand over to INA 40 percent of every insurance they wrote. Few were prepared to do this, and many companies left the market. The perceived problem of revenue flows to foreign insurers was greatly reduced after 1919 when national borders changed and the large Trieste companies, such as Generali and RAS, that had previously belonged to the Austrian empire, became Italian.Footnote 61 INA’s monopoly was abolished by Mussolini in 1923, but it continued operating and played an important role after 1945 in the finance of housing construction.
Between the 1920s and the 1950s, full nationalization, or alternatively some form of compulsion to insure or reinsure in a state-run institution, became popular with many regimes that aspired to economic autarky, such as those in Chile, Uruguay, Turkey, and Spain. In Argentina, the establishment of a public–private joint reinsurance venture, the Instituto Mixto Argentino de Reaseguros (IMAR) was part of a package of financial reforms introduced by the government of Juan Perón in 1946 that were designed to give the state greater control over the economy and to aid economic planning. Foreign insurers were required to reinsure with the IMAR 30 percent of any business they wrote in Argentina. The IMAR was also tasked with examining all applications for licenses and testing these against market “need,” along the lines of the old police licensing systems in Europe. In 1952 the IMAR was replaced by the fully nationalized Instituto Nacional de Reaseguros, managed out of the Ministry of Finance. The effect of this two-stage process of nationalization was dramatic. In 1946, 44 percent of reinsurance on Argentine risks was retroceded abroad. By 1958 that figure had fallen to below 1 percent. Footnote 62
Most of the these cases involved countries where native insurers were increasingly resorting to foreign companies for their reinsurance needs after foreign direct insurers had been squeezed out of the market by competition and discriminatory regulation and taxation. States such as Argentina then became concerned about the growing dependency of their countries on foreign supplies of reinsurance, though many recognized that there were limits to the domestic supply of reinsurance, which by its nature required an international distribution of risks. The nationalization of life insurance in India also followed after the market share of foreign companies had been declining for some time. After Independence, the new Indian government sought to reshape the economy in a socialist direction, and in 1951 it introduced its first five-year plan. At the end of this plan, life insurance was nationalized and a new state-owned Life Insurance Company of India (LIC) was set up. The finance minister, C. D. Deshmukh, explained that nationalization would spread the life insurance habit into the rural population and provide policyholders with benefits that they could not expect from a privately owned enterprise. The real objective, however, was to mobilize life insurance funds for social investment. Jitschin’s analysis shows that loans and mortgages together accounted for 54 percent of the LIC’s investments by 1968.Footnote 63 Before nationalization, mortgages had never amounted to more than 5 percent of the assets of private life insurance companies. The LIC even introduced an “Own Your Own Home” house-building scheme in 1964. Jitschin concludes that the LIC acted as a proxy for the Indian state in its investment strategy, supporting national political objectives.
Elsewhere, debates over nationalization led to different outcomes. In Sweden in 1936, a nationalization bill was only narrowly rejected by Parliament. A year later the private insurance companies formed the Swedish Insurance Federation to lobby against the ongoing threat. In 1946, after ten years of discussion, a parliamentary commission finally recommended new laws that supported a private system with closer state regulation. The “Swedish model” of insurance that emerged ended the long debate over nationalization. The new laws greatly expanded the powers of the Swedish Insurance Inspectorate from the traditional monitoring of company solvency, which had been its primary function since 1886, to assessing market demand when issuing licenses, monitoring the costs and premium rates of life insurance companies, requiring the separation of life insurance from other branches of insurance, requiring the representation of policyholders on the boards of both mutual and stock companies, and enforcing a “mutuality” principle, namely that all life insurance companies must return profits to their policyholders, regardless of ownership structure. The private companies were not enthusiastic about the new regime, but they recognized that it was better for them than outright nationalization. One effect of the legislation was to raise barriers to entry, which encouraged the larger companies to develop new low-cost products, to increase efficiency, and to expand via consolidation and mergers.Footnote 64
Conclusions: The Determinants and Consequences of Organizational Form
Throughout modern history the primary function of the state has been to protect its citizens and their property from hazards and threats, external and internal. It is clear that there has seldom been any time or place in which the state has not been involved in the amelioration of risk, and therefore in some way or other, directly or indirectly, in the business of insurance. Public authorities have been gatekeepers, regulators, and facilitators for private insurance markets, regulating the supply of insurance, monitoring sources of moral hazard, protecting domestic insurance companies by restricting the operations of foreign competitors, and trying to ensure that companies met their obligations to policyholders and creditors. In its non-insurance regulatory role, the state has had the capacity to facilitate the growth of insurance by reducing risk and by diffusing data and technical knowledge about hazards. It has also been able to stimulate new markets, for example, in personal and professional liability insurance, by regulating in the areas of consumer protection, environmental protection, and health and safety.
Many states have also participated, directly or indirectly, in insurance markets, exploiting their power to compel citizens to pay premiums and taxes. What mainly determined the emergence of public insurance provision in the past? The changing nature of risk—a technology explanation—seems to have played, at most, a minor role. The problem of assessing and pricing new risks has largely been handled by the private sector—the explosion of new insurance products launched by Lloyd’s underwriters from the 1880s is one obvious example.Footnote 65 During industrialization in nineteenth-century Europe, public fire insurance associations usually left more complex risks related to industrial property and contents to private companies. Another possible explanation—that public insurance emerged because of the inefficiency or failure of private markets—was often put forward by its advocates as a justification for state intervention, either indirectly through regulation or directly through the establishment of a state insurance institution. Yet there is only limited historical evidence that public insurance was any more efficient than private provision. There are examples to consider. Due to the efficiency of its loss adjustment procedures and its relatively low rate of contributions, the Salzburg buildings insurance association, established under Bavarian occupation in 1811, proved popular with local policyholders, and it survived the return of the Tirol region to Hapsburg rule in 1816, despite the fact that the government in Vienna was already encouraging the formation of private companies for fire insurance.Footnote 66 Here and in other places in Europe, some public institutions were able to compete with private companies even without powers of compulsion or monopoly. This does not prove, however, that they were intrinsically more efficient. When gaps in the market were left by public providers, or when licensing restrictions or monopoly privileges were removed—as in marine insurance in Naples after 1811 or fire insurance in Prussia from the 1860s—private insurers were usually quick to move in. Further research is required on the relative cost advantages and productivity of public and private forms of insurance before we can be sure how to evaluate the market-efficiency explanation.
What comes across clearly from our investigation is the importance of political factors. The wave of public institutions for fire and marine insurance founded across Europe in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries reflected a growing interest on the part of governments to utilize their powers to improve the security of private property and incomes. This in turn was the product of changing economic, political, and legal relations within states as the commercial and industrial bourgeoisie grew in wealth and influence. In the twentieth century, some states began to nationalize or partly nationalize their insurance industries both for fiscal-monetary motives and also because of the logic of the politics of autarky and the desire to exercise control over major economic sectors such as financial services. Underlying the policies of various states was also often an ideological hostility to private enterprise, or at least a concern that for-profit insurance might be detrimental to public welfare. Moreover, as we have seen, the varying alignments of narrow interest groups and broader political interests in different states could determine the fate of public insurance legislation and, for example, the shape of accident insurance in the United States during the early twentieth century or the social insurance systems developed in Sweden and the United Kingdom after 1945. In sum, it is probable that political cultures and their associated bureaucratic and legal frameworks created important path-dependent effects, which determined and locked in, though not irreversibly, the organizational structure of markets and the distribution of insurance provision between the public and private sectors and between different forms of private insurance—cooperatives, mutual associations, stock corporations, unincorporated stock companies, and syndicates of individual underwriters.
As noted in the “Introduction,” the stronger version of path-dependent theory posits that a sensitivity of choices to initial conditions leads to outcomes, most notably technologies, which are not only inefficient but which could have been avoided because more efficient alternatives were available. The argument made here for the importance of political cultures and state action in shaping persistent structures in national insurance markets makes no claims for the efficiency or inefficiency of the organizational forms thus locked in. Nevertheless, although it is not the principal object of this article, our historical survey does shed some light on the relative advantages and disadvantages of public insurance that are worth discussing.
There is no question that forms of state intervention have in many instances provided an enormous boost to the diffusion of insurance throughout the population. Mandatory state social insurance has delivered better cover against sickness, workplace injuries, unemployment, and old age for growing numbers of people since the late nineteenth century. Many of these schemes, where they were not part of a universal integrated social security provision by the state, greatly expanded the market for private insurance companies. The result in many countries has been huge improvements in public welfare. State sickness insurance helped reduce mortality in Europe before 1914. Mandatory state schemes resulted in pensions for more workers in the United Kingdom from 1911, Sweden from 1913, and the United States from 1935. The nationalization of life insurance in India led to increased investment in public housing from the 1950s. Government treasuries were replenished by revenue from state insurance and reinsurance institutions in South America and New Zealand. Municipal firefighting in eighteenth- and nineteenth-century Europe was supported by revenue garnered from public buildings insurance associations.
The disadvantages of public insurance have been widely commented on. First, it has been argued that state-run insurance is inefficient. There is evidence to support this from across the period. Some public buildings associations, for example, struggled to accumulate sufficient funds to enable them to cope with the claims arising from large fires in their localities. This was the case in Sweden in the 1820s and in Hamburg after the great fire of 1842. The key problem was the high concentration of insured properties within an urban area, sometimes exacerbated by compulsory insurance, together with the lack of reinsurance facilities at the time. Direct participation in marine insurance by some European states during the eighteenth century had limited success. The heterogeneity of shipping risks was relatively costly for public (or indeed private) corporations to handle, and it was difficult to find an actuarial basis upon which to price such risks. The low costs and information advantages developed by underwriters at Lloyd’s of London and other centers of marine insurance usually gave them a competitive advantage over state corporations.
Second, it has been claimed that state insurance can distort the market, destroy privately provided alternatives, and redistribute funds from the broad base of taxpayers to special interest groups.Footnote 67 Certainly public buildings insurance crowded out private fire insurance in markets such as Scandinavia and Germany over a long period of time. It also contributed to the fragmentation of these markets, though arguably it also increased consumer choice and kept prices down by reducing the power of the cartels formed by private companies. Third, it is said that state insurance can generate serious asymmetric information and adverse selection problems. History suggests there is validity in this argument. In early nineteenth-century Sweden, for example, the state fire insurance fund tended to select the safest risks, leaving the poorest timber-built property uninsured or for private underwriters to cover. Research shows that U.S. farmers with access to state-subsidized insurance, price supports, and disaster relief take on more financial and production risks than unsubsidized farmers do. The government flood insurance program in Louisiana induced construction in the southern part of the state, which weakened natural defenses against flooding and increased the damage caused by hurricanes. Federal disaster relief and compensation has encouraged continued risk-taking and underinsurance by property owners in catastrophe-prone regions such as California and Florida.Footnote 68 Similar arguments have been put forward for social security and national health insurance, that they discourage savings and private insurance provision and perpetuate poverty and intergenerational wealth disparities by reducing the bequests of the less affluent to their children. A study of the expansion of the Medicaid program in the United States between 1987 and 1992, for example, concluded that this had reduced the take-up of employer-based private insurance and resulted in diminished coverage for workers’ dependents.Footnote 69
State insurance can leave a lasting footprint that is difficult to erase, even when governments resolve to liberalize and deregulate insurance markets. This is clearly shown in Kwon’s study of Afghanistan, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, and Nepal.Footnote 70 Between 1950 and 1975, they all nationalized insurance or established state-owned corporations and restricted the licensing of private companies shortly after independence. Since the early 1990s, all have gradually privatized their insurance industries. Yet the legacy of nationalization has proved tenacious. These markets continued until very recently to be dominated by state-owned institutions. Most continued to enforce compulsory cession requirements as a means of retaining reinsurance premiums in the country, which has increased the concentration of risk. Most failed to provide policyholder protection funds and continued to maintain premium rate tariffs, lack effective solvency regulations, and prohibit cross-border insurance transactions. In short, for insurance throughout history, there has been and continues to be no escaping the state.