Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-lrblm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-07T13:06:45.576Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Can International Nongovernmental Organizations Boost Government Services? The Case of Health

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 July 2013

Amanda Murdie
Affiliation:
University of Missouri. E-mail: murdiea@missouri.edu
Alexander Hicks
Affiliation:
Emory University, Atlanta, Georgia. E-mail: ahicks@emory.edu

Abstract

Do international nongovernmental organizations (INGOs) lessen the need for states to provide their own services? In the case of health, many assume that INGOs limit health spending by governments. Against the conventional wisdom, we argue that these organizations create increased demand for governmental health spending through three mechanisms: (1) indirectly affecting the policy-making climate (“climatic conditioning”), (2) aiding domestic NGO and health activists in their efforts, and (3) directly pressuring governments for increased health spending themselves. Given these mechanisms, health INGOs, although typically supplying health services of their own within a country, should augment pressure for public service provision by the state and, it follows, lead to increased state health spending. We test our argument using a new data set on health INGOs, together with a well-established model of health spending, and find ample support for our arguments. Increases in health INGOs' activities do lead to increased governmental health spending, mainly by indirectly affecting the policy-making climate and, most especially, advancing the effective efforts of domestic activists.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2013 

How do international nongovernmental organizations (international NGOs, or INGOs) influence states? Do they lessen the need for states to provide their own services or, conversely, do they stimulate the growth of governmental services? Take, for instance, the case of health.Footnote 1 Many accounts assume that INGOs curtail public health services. Even prior to the devastating earthquake in Haiti in 2010, INGOs were estimated to provide 85 percent of public services.Footnote 2 As Haitian activist Patrick Elie reported in an interview to Dominion Magazine: “Everything that should be in the hands of the state has been taken away by business interests or by the plague of NGOs. NGOs are being used to slowly remove all the flesh from the state.”Footnote 3 In one recent report on the Balkans, health INGOs in particular were criticized for fragmenting government services and taking away talented government employees; many worry that “too much civil society [will] weaken institutions of government.”Footnote 4

Even the World Health Organization (WHO) is concerned about the potential impact of health INGOs on a state's ability to provide its own health services. In 2007, it warned that health INGOs often lack “long-term vision” in health care delivery.Footnote 5 Given these arguments, it would appear that health INGOs have negative consequences on public service provision in developing countries.

Conversely, many within the health INGO community speak of the potential positive impacts health INGOs have on public health provision within a middle- or low-income state; they see the role of health INGOs as a complement and not a substitute for state health provision.Footnote 6 For example, in Venezuela in 2004 several health INGOs pressed the administration of President Hugo Chavez to change the publicly provided antiretroviral drugs to correspond with a list of drugs recommended by WHO. A representative of the health INGOs involved there stated that the role of the organizations was to act as “social ombudsman” to the government.Footnote 7 In the Philippines in 2009, health INGOs proposed an increase in publicly provided midwives and rural doctors; many of their proposals were recently adopted by the government of President Gloria Arroyo.Footnote 8

Given the exponential growth in INGOs in the past thirty years, their impact on state spending in developing countries appears to be an important policy question. Yet, limited scholarly attention has focused on systematically examining INGOs' effects on the behavior of the state with regard to public service provision and spending. Do these organizations actually usurp state service activities, lessening the need for government spending for a particular social service? Or, conversely, does their involvement create increased state social service spending that could augment services provided by INGOs? Existing scholarship fails to offer many insights into these empirical questions and provides limited theory about the causal mechanisms connecting INGO activity to state spending.

We examine the effects of health INGOs active within a state on the health spending of states in the developing world. Health INGOs have both many incentives that motivate efforts to increase governmental health spending in host countries and many capabilities to do so. Drawing on sociological as well as political science literatures, we argue that health INGOs could theoretically create increased demand for governmental health spending through (1) indirectly affecting the policy-making climate, (2) aiding domestic NGO and health activists in their efforts, and (3) directly pressuring governments for increased health spending. Thus, health INGOs, although they typically supply their own health services within a country, should lead to more pressure for public service provision by the state and, it follows, increases in health spending by the government.

We test our argument using a new data set on health INGOs per capita, together with a well-established model of health spending.Footnote 9 Using new data, we also test for the operation of each of the three causal mechanisms. We find some support for our first mechanism, climatic conditioning, and strong support for our second mechanism, indirect transnational policy advocacy. We find very little support for our third mechanism, direct policy advocacy, indicating either that few organizations actually advocate for changes in health spending this way or that this mechanism is not very successful in leading to increased health spending. This leads us to conclude that health INGOs help increase health spending both by changing the policy-making climate and by aiding domestic efforts for increases in health spending.

Extant Literature

Determinants of State Social Spending

Middle- and lower-income states provide many forms of social services. Provision of primary education and basic health services has long been considered the mainstay of government provisions, often justified for their linkage to overall economic growth and political stability.Footnote 10 By improving a population's basic knowledge and health, these provisions can help improve the productivity of workers, benefiting economic development.Footnote 11 McGuire, for example, has found that government health spending on basic health care provision in East Asia and Latin America has dramatically reduced infant mortality.Footnote 12

What determines service provision? In the long term, Engerman and Sokoloff have linked variation in current social service provision to long-running inequality embedded in domestic political institutions; where social and geographic conditions favored political systems with an emphasis on equality (for example, democracies), social spending was higher, as was economic development.Footnote 13

Variation in health care spending in middle- and lower-income countries has been linked to democracy, welfare legacies, economic crisis, and fiscal constraint.Footnote 14 In general, democratization creates demand for new social services and expansion of existing health spending.Footnote 15 Expansion of the franchise creates incentives for political parties to advocate for expanded social services and provides new domestic interest groups the political space with which to pressure the existing government for expanded social spending.Footnote 16 Competing political parties that democracy gives rise to and empowers base their legitimacy on more widespread social services. As Huber and Stephens point out with reference to high-income countries in particular, some groups empowered through expansion of the franchise, particularly women's groups and leftist parties, can be important proponents of welfare spending.Footnote 17

Welfare legacies may limit as well as generate social spending. Haggard and Kaufman contend that entrenched interests limited the demand of social spending in Latin America.Footnote 18 Huber and colleagues echo this finding with regard to the limited impact of leftist parties in determining overall levels of health spending in Latin America.Footnote 19 Internal insecurity and dependence on foreign actors have been argued by Gough and colleagues to severely limit spending in Sub-Saharan Africa.Footnote 20 Legacies of public health spending in particular are especially strong in Eastern Europe and weak in East Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa.Footnote 21

Social spending is also dependent on governmental revenues and economic performance. During economic downturns, revenues contract and the governmental and private-sector benefits of social spending are often cut to conserve limited resources.Footnote 22 However, during economic upturns, revenues expand and facilitate public spending via the resulting increase in slack resources.Footnote 23 Moreover, revenues are a central indicator not only of cyclical fluctuation in state resources but of actual state capabilities.Footnote 24 Recession and economic affluence and growth also matter.Footnote 25

Factors outside of the political system also influence welfare spending.Footnote 26 Trade openness has been found to decrease social spending in lower-income countries. This is attributed to both changes in the ability of labor organizations and leftist parties to justify demands for welfare spending in the wake of globalization and in increased pressure from business groups to limit social spending in order to appear more competitive in the global market.Footnote 27 Rudra and Haggard find this link holds more in authoritarian regimes.Footnote 28 In contrast, however, Avelino and colleagues find that trade openness and capital mobility have little impact on health spending in Latin America.Footnote 29

In short, the extant literature on welfare spending, especially governmental health spending, in middle- and lower-income countries emphasizes the role of democratic institutions, ideological legacies, and fiscal constraints. Recent work on health spending in particular has also stressed that foreign aid may be used as a substitute for government spending.Footnote 30

Given these existing strands of literature, the role, if any, of health INGOs in determining health spending in developing countries is theoretically unclear. Health INGOs often contribute to domestic pressure for health spending increases. In line with the widespread literature on the influence of domestic interest groups on demand for social spending in democracies (in particular women's groups), it follows that health INGOs would have a positive impact on health spending.Footnote 31 Conversely, if health INGOs behave similarly to earmarked foreign aid, the effect of health INGOs on health spending may be negative. As activists fear, health INGO activities may substitute for governmental spending.

Effects of INGOs on State Policies

Before outlining how health INGOs can be incorporated into the theoretical literature on the determinants of health spending, it is worth mentioning that most of the literature on INGOs has focused predominantly on human rights and environmental advocacy organizations. As Edwards points out, even basic knowledge of the macro impact of INGOs outside of highly developed countries is still rather limited.Footnote 32 To our knowledge, no existing cross-national studies examine the impact of health INGOs on governmental spending. Indeed, there also appears to be little literature on the impact of any subgroup of INGOs on public spending.

We do know, however, much about the impacts of domestic health NGOs and health INGOs on particular state projects. Further, by many accounts, government-INGO collaboration appears to be increasing. For example, Ullah and colleagues find that health INGOs help provide professional assistance to the governmental fight against tuberculosis in Bangladesh.Footnote 33 Alonso and Brugha found that health [I]NGO involvement led to a “rehabilitation” of the government health system in Timor.Footnote 34 Campos and colleagues report that NGOs were able to fill gaps in governmental services and increased the ability of the rural poor to organize politically and Shandra and colleagues find that health INGOs help decrease infant mortality rates in democracies.Footnote 35

The larger existing literature on the effects of INGOs on state policies centers on the role INGOs play in norms transmission, resource mobilization for domestic groups, and in their ability to attract international third-party support.Footnote 36 In particular, the transnational advocacy network (TAN) framework highlights the role advocacy INGOs play in aiding domestic pressure on a regime and in calling for outside actors, such as intergovernmental organizations and third-party states, to pressure state policy change.Footnote 37 INGOs often work with domestic interest groups and organizations to pressure their governments—they also try to craft alternative policies and pressure government officials themselves.Footnote 38 A somewhat distinct strain of literature, the world polity approach, sees INGOs as an important educator in global cultural standards.Footnote 39

In this literature on the effects of INGOs, the focus is typically on the impact of INGOs on state repression, treaty adoption, and environmental performance.Footnote 40 Kim also focuses on the impact human rights INGOs have on the establishment of domestic human rights institutions.Footnote 41 However, recent work by Chwieroth and colleagues does find that INGO ties inhibit capital account liberalization.Footnote 42 This work highlights the role INGOs play in climatic “mimetic isomorphism.”Footnote 43 In other words, these organizations influence policy through indirectly conditioning the cultural climate to reflect the policy positions advocated by the INGO. INGOs can influence policy indirectly by providing support for a particular type of policy model.Footnote 44

Much has been written on problems of accountability, coordination, and corruption in the field of INGOs.Footnote 45 Murdie has found that these problems can limit the impact of INGOs on human rights and development outcomes.Footnote 46 Although much of this literature has focused on development and humanitarian relief INGOs, we highlight this literature to stress two related points: (1) INGOs are not always a homogenous ideological lot; and (2) the motivations of INGOs are not all “principled” or lacking in material underpinnings. These points, although quite straightforward at first glance, deserve a little extrapolation.

First, as Boli and Thomas suggest, INGOs vary in their ideological leanings, methods of operations, and policy suggestions.Footnote 47 As Barnett points out with respect to four major humanitarian or health INGOs, wide variation exists in INGOs' behavior to governments.Footnote 48 Some want complete independence and would prefer to work separate from governmental agencies in their host or base state; others strive for coordination and shared resources at both levels. Second, as Cooley and Ron contend, there is often a “scramble” for donor funds and attention by INGOs.Footnote 49 Competition between INGOs for scarce resources can limit their incentives to coordinate on the ground. INGOs often have material incentives for involvement in certain locales or on certain advocacy issues.Footnote 50 This could be seen as counter to the larger transnational advocacy network framework, which often views advocacy actors as distinct from other actors by their principled, as opposed to material, motivations.Footnote 51 With regards to effect on state spending, these material motivations of INGOs may actually lead to an overall advocacy of increased social-service spending. Given current trends in governmental-INGO collaboration, INGOs may have material motivations for increased governmental social-service spending. This could be important to their long-term organizational survival. (We return to this logic shortly.)

In sum, the extant literature on the policy impacts of INGOs, although not focusing on state spending or health INGOs, stresses many mechanisms through which INGOs could affect policy outcomes.

Theoretical Argument and Hypotheses

Given the existing literature on the determinants of state social spending in middle- and lower-income countries, together with the existing literature on the policy effects of INGOs, we stress a trio of rationales underscoring our basic hypothesis that health INGOs within a country will have a positive impact on a country's governmental health spending.

Before highlighting these individual but related causal mechanisms, however, it must be generally stressed that health INGOs have multiple potential motivations and capabilities for increasing state spending on health services. For many health INGOs, their mission statements include the goal of improved self-sufficiency of the state where they are working.Footnote 52 It follows that health INGOs, even if providing health services within a country, would still advocate directly or indirectly for increased health spending—many journalistic accounts support this contention.Footnote 53

Our interviews with health INGOs working in developing countries support this idea. Organizations often try both explicitly and more subtly to “build capacity” within a country. This “capacity building” involves making sure that governments can take on the goods and services required for improved healthFootnote 54 In fact, we did have organizational personnel respond that their primary goal was “trying to leverage or increase government programs” for health instead of “providing services in lieu of the government providing them.”Footnote 55

Because health INGOs often partner with governments in delivering health services, they may have a material interest in increased health spending by the government.Footnote 56 This would especially be the case if there are lots of organizations within a state, increasing the need for additional funding sources.Footnote 57 INGOs may petition aid agencies for additional aid for the country with the idea that additional funds, even if bilateral, will also benefit themselves and their missions.Footnote 58

Some scholars and journalists actually suggest that INGOs are taking over state roles. As we will detail, we examined more than 2,000 mission statements of health INGOs without finding a single explicit account of such a bold INGO goal.Footnote 59 Theoretically, from a strictly materialistic view of INGO motivations, less governmental money in health spending could limit their resource gains from collaborative or subcontracted projects. Indeed, less spending by governments could draw negative attention to health INGOs from the aid community, limiting their own resources even more.

Additionally, unlike foreign aid donors, health INGOs involved domestically with a state are more in line with the preferences of their own service recipients.Footnote 60 Though this is not always the case, health INGOs' services can be thought of as more “locally” controlled than the provisions of bilateral or IGO aid. Health INGOs typically have staff or members from the local community and often try to involve local preferences into their decision making. Fungibility or substitution issues that arise from foreign IGO or bilateral donations, therefore, would not be as present for services provided by health INGOs, many of which are providing active advocacy efforts and budget support.Footnote 61

With these general thoughts in mind, we now turn to our three related causal mechanisms, two indirect and one direct. These rationales all underscore the same primary hypothesis:

H1: The greater the presence of health INGOs in a country, the higher the country's governmental health spending.

Though testing for this hypothesis is extremely important for policy, especially given existing debates on the role of health INGOs in service delivery, testing for the empirical implications of these causal mechanisms is also important for building our theoretical understanding of how health INGOs work. After providing each of these rationales underlying our primary hypothesis, we also provide a testable hypothesis for each of these causal mechanisms. Supplemental tests of these hypotheses will help us discern which causal mechanisms are at work in linking health INGOs to governmental health spending.

Climatic Conditioning

Our first mechanism, climatic conditioning, is a variant of DiMaggio and Powell's “mimetic isomorphism” that we might rather cumbersomely have dubbed “climatic mimetic isomorphism.”Footnote 62 This stresses the influences of policy models that are noncompetitive as well as indirect. According to this model, health INGOs indirectly have an impact on health spending by altering the intellectual climate in ways that enable or encourage a particular policy model, such as one within which health spending increases noncompetitively. By “noncompetitive,” we mean free from pressures to emulate successful competitors. By “indirect,” we refer to policy dispersion of models more likely to operate through shaping policy-making discourse, opinions, and options that frame policy decisions than by directly affecting final policy decisions themselves. Such climatic conditionings may be complemented by a weak variant of “normative isomorphism.”Footnote 63 True, classical normative isomorphism, in which professionals recruited from, or trained in, other nations bring their norms into actual policy-making positions, is unlikely to be advanced by the presence of health INGOs, for INGO personnel are less likely to occupy key policy-making positions. However, the norms of health INGO professionals, as with their more-detailed policy models, are likely to ripple though the policy-making culture of the hosts and acquaintances of health INGOs, altering their policy-making predispositions and options. Indeed, what we expect to be at play are both a classical, model-centered mimetic isomorphism that alters cognitive climates and a variant that more loosely conditions policy-making by affecting broad, normative policy-making predispositions rather than by providing blueprint-like policy models.

This view of health INGOs altering a state's policy-making culture is in line with the larger INGO literature. INGOs bring new ideas into a state and connect its citizens to those outside the geographic boundaries.Footnote 64 These new ideas can result in general learning or acceptance to increased governmental spending; in other words, both the general population and policy-makers may be more likely to adopt a policy utilized elsewhere because of general cultural changes and views toward the alternative approach.Footnote 65

Similar to the constructivist and learning schools on policy diffusion, this mechanism involves the idea that given countries will adopt policies that appear to work for other countries.Footnote 66 This mechanism is definitely apparent in the practice of health INGOs taking on local members or volunteers. These members could likely see themselves as connected to the larger subgrouping of states where the health INGO is working or otherwise has a membership base.

Given the large proportion of health INGOs based in Western Europe, existing liberal (that is, reformist liberal, social democratic, and Christian communitarian) views on social service spending there could spread and influence the policy-making climate in other areas where health INGOs have members. As such, through this mechanism, health INGOs should affect general views on governmental health care and the role of the state, especially in caring for the poor. This logic would lead to the following direct test of this mechanism:

H2: Health INGOs increase a population's support for governmental service provision, leading to increased health spending.

Indirect Transnational Advocacy Effects

Our second mechanism, indirect transnational advocacy, contends that health INGOs provide material resources, space, and personnel to domestic NGOs and health movement activists, reinforcing theses actors' pressures on policy-makers. This mechanism draws on a distinct, less culturally focused literature that deals in the ways in which INGOs aid domestic NGOs and more diffuse domestic social movements in their resource mobilization.Footnote 67

Health INGOs are organizations with resources useful for domestic pressure groups, such as labor organizations or women's groups, which form the backbone of the theoretical linkage between democracy and welfare spending.Footnote 68 INGOs can provide a meeting place for local interests, social programs that connect various domestic actors, and a sounding board through which domestic groups can gain attention.Footnote 69

Much in line with the classic literature on resource mobilization, all of these resources provided by INGOs help domestic groups mobilize, especially groups with similar ideological bents.Footnote 70 This has been recently seen in Benin, for example, where INGOs helped groups of domestic citizens protest for the government to continue its support of hospitals, carrying signs that read “Don't Kill the Hospitals” and “Health is Wealth.”Footnote 71

This is also in line with the transnational advocacy framework; INGOs provide resources and attention that enable domestic groups to petition their governments.Footnote 72 In other words, health INGOs can provide the resources necessary for citizens to have a voice; this will have payoffs not only on health spending but on health care quality.Footnote 73 Therefore, health INGOs present within a state should increase the resources and political power of health-oriented social groups. These groups will then be able to better pressure their government to increase health spending in an effort to improve health services within a state. Accordingly, this mechanism would see health INGOs affecting health spending through increasing the mobilization activities of citizens domestically.

As Bartley previously found in a study of the environmental movement and Murdie and Bhasin found in a study of human rights INGOs, this mechanism would imply that health INGOs help mobilize groups within the state to pressure their own government for change.Footnote 74 As such, this mechanism's underlying logic would lead to the following observable implications:

H3: Health INGOs increase a population's mobilizations against their government and these mobilization efforts should lead to increased health spending.

Direct Transnational Advocacy Effects

More directly, it appears that some health INGOs themselves pressure governments for increases in health services.Footnote 75 They provide policy recommendations and technical advice for bureaucrats.Footnote 76 Many health INGOs attend the same meetings where governmental officials exchange ideas.Footnote 77 With respect to normative isomorphism, there is often a “revolving door” for professionals between work for a government agency and work for an INGO.Footnote 78 Therefore, health INGO professionals within a state may be able to influence health spending by taking on roles within the government itself.

This mechanism, direct transnational advocacy, should not be confused with coercive isomorphism.Footnote 79 Health INGOs hold little, if any, coercive power over states. Unlike the International Monetary Fund, for example, health INGOs cannot effectively force states to change their policies. While human rights INGOs often encourage outside coercive actors to pressure a state more aggressively,Footnote 80 this does not appear to be the modus operandi of health and other service delivery INGOs.Footnote 81 Their policy pressure appears to be more directed at the state itself through professional policy recommendations.Footnote 82 According to this mechanism, through providing these recommendations, health INGOs directly pressure governments to increase their health spending. Essentially, then, this mechanism would imply that:

H4: Health INGOs should provide policy recommendations to states and health spending should be determined by these policy recommendations alone.

In order for direct policy pressure by health INGOs to work, health INGO professionals must be providing similar advice to governmental bureaucrats and policy-makers. But INGOs are not a homogenous lot; there are many examples of INGOs in other issue areas advocating for opposite policy recommendations.Footnote 83 If, for example, some health INGOs were advocating for more liberal health spending while others were advocating, along with neoliberal economists, for restrictions on health spending, the overall impact of health INGOs might be limited. So, what are health INGOs advocating? At the end of the day, this is largely an empirical question that has not received much attention from the existing literature. However, given its importance for our research question, before conducting our study we did a content analysis of the mission statements of 2,260 INGOs that make reference to health in their stated goals.Footnote 84 Although we did find much ideological variation on other health issues (that is, abortion, end-of-life care, the use of psychiatric drugs), we did not find evidence of variation in policy opinions on health spending. Such variation might exist outside of the information provided by the mission statements that we examined, but it does not appear that there is much ideological variation among health INGOs on this issue.

Primary Hypothesis: Health INGOs Increase Health Spending

Research Design

To examine the validity of the primary hypothesis (H1), we use a quantitative data set of government health spending and health INGO activities in nonhighly developed countries for the years 1980 to 2000. Below, we outline the variables and model specification.

Data considerations

Our dependent variable, as with previous studies on health spending, is change in the amount of governmental spending on health, as a share of gross domestic product (GDP).Footnote 85 This variable captures annual changes in amount of funding the government spends for health care transfer and health services provision.Footnote 86

Our key independent variable must capture the activities and presence of health INGO activities within a state. Most previous quantitative studies on INGOs have utilized the number of all types of INGOs that have a member or volunteer within a country.Footnote 87 This data comes from the Yearbook of International Organizations, an INGO itself whose mission is to facilitate connections between organizations.Footnote 88 Very recently, some studies have tried to restrict this data to only INGOs with a certain mission statement, such as environmental rights or human rights.Footnote 89 Restricting INGO data to only a specific issue area averts bias that could occur from the unnecessary inclusion of INGOs that are not related to the specific issue at hand, such as the Star Trek Association or the World Association of Seaweed Processors. Therefore, it seems advisable to restrict our data to health INGOs only.

To do so, we utilize health ingos, a count of all health INGOs that self-report to the Yearbook as having a member or volunteer within a country in a given year. These data were graciously provided us by Smith and Wiest.Footnote 90After restricting their focus to only INGOs that focus on health, Smith and Wiest coded this data from hard copies of the Yearbook at two- and three-year intervals.Footnote 91 We use linear interpolation to fill in the years not coded. To account for differences in health INGOs numbers that can be attributed to the size of the country, we weigh this count by the natural log of the total population within a country.Footnote 92

In order to assess the validity of our primary hypothesis, we sought to situate our key health INGO variable into Haggard and Kaufman's existing model of health spending.Footnote 93 As such, we include a control for democracy, using the dichotomous indicator based on a Polity IV 21-point score of 6 or greater,Footnote 94recession, revenue (as a percent of GDP), representing fiscal constraints, gdp per capita,Footnote 95net transfers,Footnote 96 and total population size.Footnote 97 Consistent with existing literature, we expect democracy and revenue to be consistently associated with more health spending.Footnote 98

Model specification

We use an error-correction model with panel-corrected standard errors on pooled, time-series data. We do this for a number of reasons. First, the use of an error-correction model allows us to capture both short- and long-term changes in variables that are in a long-run relationship.Footnote 99 Second, by utilizing lagged dependent variables the model allows us to adjust for serially correlated errors.Footnote 100 Third, by using panel-corrected standard errors, we take account of and adjust for heteroskedasticity and contemporaneous correlation, as Haggard and Kaufman did.Footnote 101

Our theoretical argument should apply to a wide swath of countries outside of the most-developed countries. However, as Gough and colleagues point out, health spending in many areas of the world, most prominently Sub-Saharan Africa, has been historically extremely lacking.Footnote 102 As Smith and Wiest and Mawdsley and colleagues similarly point out, INGOs have not been uniformly active in the global South; their presence has been absent at times in the Middle East and North African and Sub-Saharan African regions.Footnote 103 To deal with these dynamics, we first restricted our focus to just the East Asian, Latin American, and Eastern European countries and years covered in Haggard and Kaufman.Footnote 104 Restricting our sample in this way allows us to concretely assess whether health INGOs have an impact on health spending in areas of the world where we have strong theoretical priors about the determinants of health spending.

For our baseline sample, however, we expand the Haggard and Kaufman sample to include a global sample of all nonhighly developed countries for which we have reliable data from the Global Development Network Growth Database/IMF Global Financial Database for the 1980 to 2000 period, as was used in the Haggard and Kaufman study.Footnote 105 Expanding the sample in this way allows us to ensure that our baseline findings apply to a wide range of countries outside of the most developed world. As an added test, we similarly restrict our sample to only non-Sub-Saharan African countries. We do so to remain attentive to the differences in health spending in Sub-Saharan Africa during this time period, as outlined in Gough and colleagues.Footnote 106 Our results are consistent in sign and similar in significance levels across samples, reiterating the robustness of our findings.

We do employ a few small changes from the Haggard and Kaufman specification of health spending.Footnote 107 First, Haggard and Kaufman pool data up to the regional level only.Footnote 108 As evidenced from the small number of countries and years in their sample of health spending (215 observations total) and combined with the use of an error-correction model, pooling to only the regional level could create problems with model overfitting. To account for issues of small sample size, we therefore pool the regions together and then estimated models with interaction terms between our key variable of interest and regional dummies. We were able to determine that the key variable (health ingos per capita) does not have statistically significant differing effect across regions. This is true no matter which region is specified as the left-out category. Therefore, we report model results for one model pooled across regions.Footnote 109

Additionally, Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) use a specification of error correction models that includes lagged levels and lagged changes of the regressors, unlike the more conventional approach of utilizing lagged levels and unlagged changes of the regressors.Footnote 110 In expanding our sample beyond the Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) country-years, we follow the conventional approach and estimate a model where we include lagged levels and unlagged changes of the regressors.Footnote 111 Finally, we include yearly fixed effects in our models, reflecting the idea that our intercept is not the same across time.Footnote 112

Therefore, the statistical model used in this study is as follows:

$$ \eqalign{ & \Delta {\rm GOVERNMENTAL}\;{\rm HEALTH}\;{\rm SPENDING}_{i,t} \cr & \quad = {\rm GOVERNMENTAL}\;{\rm HEALTH}\;{\rm SPENDING}_{i,t - 1} \cr & \quad = \Delta {\rm HEALTH}\;{\rm INGOS}\;{\rm PER}\;{\rm CAPITA}_{i,t} + {\rm HEALTH}\;{\rm INGOS}\;{\rm PER}\;{\rm CAPITA}_{i,t - 1} \cr & \quad + {\rm HAGGARD}\;{\rm AND}\;{\rm KAUFMAN}\;{\rm (2008)}\;{\rm CONTROLS}_{i,t - 1} \cr & \quad + \Delta {\rm HAGGARD}\;{\rm AND}\;{\rm KAUFMAN}\;{\rm (2008)}\;{\rm CONTROLS}_{i,t} + e_{i,t} \cr} $$

We have few theoretical priors about whether the relationship between health INGOs and health spending should be more short term, as will be captured through the changes in health INGOs per capita variable, or long term, as will be captured through the lagged level variable. On the one hand, it does seem likely that health INGOs would have only a temporary effect—that they would operate through the mechanisms we have outlined to directly or indirectly affect health spending mainly in the short term. This would be consistent with arguments laid out by Cooley and Ron for example, about the short-term planning cycles of most health INGOs.Footnote 113 On the other hand, long-term changes could be possible, however, if the “shocks” brought through these mechanisms by health INGOs would continue over multiple time periods or persist over the entire time of the model.

One additional issue concerning model specification also deserves mention: where health INGOs go. In our theory, health INGOs are strategic actors, making decisions to work in ways that can lead to positive changes in health spending. Thinking of health INGOs in this way requires us to consider which countries these organizations are likely to go to. If health INGOs are drawn to countries for the same reasons that states increase their health spending, addressing these underlying reasons would be necessary to isolate any effect health INGOs could have on health spending. Similarly, if health INGOs were attracted to only “easy” states with high and increasing levels of health spending, we would have to address issues of endogeneity or self-selection in order to isolate the effects of health INGOs on health spending. As a first cut, models of the determinants of health INGOs per capita within a country do not show that health INGOs were drawn to states with higher levels or changes in health spending.Footnote 114 Interviews with health INGO officials also support this idea; when asked, health INGO officials do not indicate that they were drawn to states by either high or low levels of government health spending.Footnote 115

To our knowledge, a literature on the determinants of health INGOs within a state does not exist. However, there is a literature on the determinants of all types of INGOs and a small literature on the determinants of human rights INGOs in particular.Footnote 116 Drawing on this literature and on interviews with health INGO officials, we propose that these organizations are likely drawn to states with high health issue salience, such as states with new epidemics, or to countries with high media attention and connections to the outside world. Models where the dependent variable is health INGOs per capita show that these indicators are positively associated with health INGO presence. However, our models of health spending with these indicators as additional controls do not show that epidemics or indicators of connections to the outside world have a statistically significant impact on changes in health spending. Two-stage least squares models with the indicators as instruments show many of these indicators as statistically significant and strong instruments in the first stage, indicating that they are properly identified predictors of health INGOs.Footnote 117 Crucially, the Durbin-Wu-Hausman tests for two-stage models with all of these indicators as instruments are not significant, indicating the lagged health INGOs per capita is not an endogenous regressor of changes in health spending.Footnote 118 Though we hope that this is not the last word on the determinants of health INGOs within a country, we feel confident about the one-stage analysis of the impact of health INGOs on health spending that we use.Footnote 119

Results

Our primary hypothesis is supported in this analysis: health INGOs have a positive impact on governmental health spending. Table 1, column (1), provides results for health INGOs per capita in the context of the basic Haggard and Kaufman sample of Eastern European, Eastern Asian, and Latin American countries.Footnote 120 Both the lagged level and the change in health INGOs per capita are statistically significant and the coefficients are in the positive direction, indicating both a short- and a long-term effect on health spending. The effect of a one-time change in health INGOs is rather large, 1.96, larger than a temporary shock of a change to democracy (0.36). Within this sample, the long-term effect of a one-unit change in the health INGOs per capita within a country is also substantial, equating to a 6.09 increase in health spending as a percentage of GDP over the time period covered in the model.Footnote 121 The statistically significant control variables we used are also similar to Haggard and Kaufman and the larger literature on the determinants of health spending.Footnote 122democratization (change in democracy) has a robust positive impact. revenue increases also have a positive impact on health spending. The demographic variables, not shown in the tables in Haggard and Kaufman, are also similar to the original model without the addition of our health INGO variables.Footnote 123

TABLE 1. Regression of health spending on health INGOs and control variables, various samples 1980–2000

Notes: Error correction model with yearly fixed effects (omitted) and panel-corrected standard errors in parentheses.

*** p < 0.01;

** p < 0.05;

* p < 0.10 (two-tailed).

When we expand our sample beyond the Haggard and Kaufman country-years, however, as shown in Table 1, column (2), health INGOs per capita retains a positive and statistically significant impact on health spending only in the short term, as indicated by the coefficient on the changes in health INGOs per capita variable and the lack of statistical significance for the coefficient on the lagged level variable.Footnote 124 We see this as somewhat expected; health INGOs are working to change health spending in the immediate period with which they are working within a country. The goods and services they are providing, especially when we expand beyond the countries in Haggard and Kaufman's sample, may quickly dissipate if the “shock” of positive changes in health INGOs per capita does not continue.Footnote 125 If, however, the shock of a positive increase in health INGOs per capita remains, the total effect of these organizations can be much larger. As such, the results in Table 1, column (2) imply that a change in the number of health INGOs per capita for only one period would have a 0.67 effect on health spending. If the change would continue for ten years, half of the sample time period, however, the total effect would be a 5.188 increase in government health expenditure.

Table 1, column (3), reiterates these dynamics in a sample that excludes Sub-Saharan Africa, where we expect insecurity to severely limit health spending.Footnote 126 Our findings are very similar, albeit slightly heightened and at a slightly more precise statistical significance level, to the global sample results in Table 1, column (2). Changes in health INGOs per capita have a positive impact on health spending. Together, we feel these findings support our primary hypothesis. Health INGOs are not taking away from the role of the state; in fact, these organizations are actually leading to increases in government health spending.

We also conducted a series of robustness tests on this general finding. Due to concerns with aid fungibility, we add a control for aid per capita.Footnote 127 Reflecting Huber and colleagues, we added a control variable for leftist parties.Footnote 128 Reflecting Avelino and colleagues, we also made sure our results remained significant with the addition of a control for trade openness.Footnote 129 The positive effect of change in health INGOs on health spending continues to be positive with these additional controls.Footnote 130

Supplementary Hypotheses: Concerning Causal Mechanisms

All three of our identified causal mechanisms led to the same primary hypothesis, which was supported in the empirical analysis: health INGOs exert a positive effect on health spending. In novel ways, we attempt to test for implications of each of our causal mechanisms argued to be driving this primary finding. However, we do not see these causal mechanisms as competing. In fact, with our discussions of health INGO officials, we were struck by the multitude of ways in which health INGOs are working to affect health spending, consistent with our various causal mechanisms. These tests, instead, are simply to indicate whether evidence for any of these mechanisms exists in the larger world.

For all of these tests, we use the expanded global sample presented in Table 1, column (2). We think this expanded sample represents the hardest test of our theoretical implications.Footnote 131

Supplementary Hypothesis: Climatic Conditioning

Recall that our climatic conditioning mechanism (H2) implies both that health INGOs increase a population's support for governmental service provision and that this support augments health spending itself. To test this mechanism, we sought out measures of opinions about government's role in service provision and the availability of health care. The World Values Survey asks individuals for their agreement (on a 10-point scale) with whether “the government should take more responsibility to ensure that everyone is provided for.”Footnote 132 We use the proportion of a population that answers affirmatively (greater than 5 on the 10-point scale) with this statement as the dependent variable, arguing that more citizens within a state should agree with this statement if health INGOs are affecting policy-making opinion within a country in ways that support increased health spending.Footnote 133 As such, we are also arguing that greater proportions of a population answering this question affirmatively should be related to future increases in health spending.

Data on this variable are available for only eighteen observations of country-years utilized in the global sample used to test our primary hypothesis. Given this small number of observations, we rely on both a simple t-test for differences in means and ordinary least squares (OLS) regression for the first-stage equation looking at the influence that health INGOs have on public opinion and the latter stage looking at the effect that this public opinion has on future changes in health spending.

As to the first causal stage relationship between health INGOs and public opinion, for the t-test, we divide countries into two groups: those with below the regional mean of change in health INGOs per capita and those with above the regional mean. We use the regional mean to account for any regional differences in health INGO per capita effects. For the OLS regression, we control for regime type, Eastern European or post-Soviet region, and the log of GDP per capita. Our key independent variable is yearly change in the number of health INGOs per capita from year t−1 to year t; we expect a greater proportion of individuals within a country to agree that the state should have more responsibility in ensuring people are provided for when there is a greater change in health INGOs per capita. In other words, more people should agree to government's role in providing for its citizens as there is an increased change in the number of health INGOs per capita.

T-test results are supportive at this stage.Footnote 134 For countries with less than the regional mean of change in health INGOs per capita, their mean scores on the proportion of the population that agree the government should take more responsibility to help people is lower than in countries that had more than the regional mean of change in health INGOs per capita. The difference in these mean scores is statistically different across the groups at conventional levels, indicating that countries with more increases in health INGOs per capita have a greater proportion of people who agree to government's role in service provision.

This same pattern holds when looking at this through an OLS regression, as shown in Table 2, column (1): greater increases in health INGOs per capita are associated with more of a population agreeing to government having an expanded role in providing for its citizens. This would offer support for supplementary hypothesis (H2) and the underlying climatic conditioning mechanism.

TABLE 2. Regressions concerning mechanisms for health spending effects of INGOs; baseline specification, all countries

Notes: Column (1) uses ordinary least squares; column (2) uses a generalized estimating equations (GEE) negative binomial model with AR(1) correlation structure; and column (3) uses rare events logit, robust standard errors.

*** p < .01;

** p < .05;

* p < .10 (two-tailed).

We also have extended this logic to the final outcome variable that matters for changes in health spending: the proportion of the population that is climatically conditioned to think the government should help people.Footnote 135 First, using a t-test, we focused on the relationship between the proportion of the population that believes the government should help make sure everyone is provided for and differenced health spending in a given year. We divide states into two groups, those with below and above the mean proportion that answer this question affirmatively. Using this approach, we found moderate support that differenced health spending as a percentage of GDP is higher in countries with higher proportions of their population that believe everyone should be provided for.

We used an OLS regression to examine the role that the lagged proportion variable has on the differenced health spending outcome, accounting for the lagged level of health spending.Footnote 136 We find that increases in this proportion matter for future changes in health spending. Of course, due to data limitations, we could not use the fully specified error-correction model in this study. However, given these t-test and OLS regression results, we can say that this climatic conditioning mechanism appears to have some support in this limited examination: health INGOs matter for public opinion on government service provision and this opinion matters for actual changes in health spending. Further data collection projects, such as that currently being done by the WHO's World Health Survey, may help future research disentangle this relationship.Footnote 137

Research Design for Supplementary Hypothesis: Indirect Transnational Policy Advocacy

The first observable implication of our indirect transnational policy advocacy mechanism (H3) concerns the effect health INGOs have on domestic mobilization. Following work by Murdie and Bhasin on human rights INGOs, we test this mechanism by examining the impact changes in health INGOs per capita have on the level of peaceful demonstrations within a country.Footnote 138 Like Murdie and Bhasin, focusing on changes in INGO numbers reflects the “the idea of campaigning efforts” through which INGOs would work to increase demonstrations.Footnote 139 To capture our dependent variable, we utilize a measure from Banks's Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive.Footnote 140 This measure, anti-government demonstrations, is the number of peaceful gatherings of at least 100 people to show “opposition to government policies or authority.”Footnote 141 Given the count nature of the dependent variable and existing studies on political protests, we utilize a negative binomial model and control for regime type using the 21-point Polity scale, GDP per capita (ln), and population size (ln). We account for time series cross-sectional dynamics through the use of a generalized estimating equation with an AR(1) correlation structure and robust standard errors.

Table 2, column (2) provides this empirical test's results. Increased change in health INGOs per capita corresponds to an increase in peaceful demonstrations. Based on these results, as the change in health INGOs per capita variable moves from its minimum to its maximum in the sample, for example, there is expected to be an increase of 0.391 demonstrations (95 percent confidence interval from 0.041 to 0.777). This is larger than the 0.287 peaceful demonstrations that would occur as democracy goes from its minimum to its maximum in the sample (95 percent confidence interval of 0.109 to 0.464) but is smaller than the almost three additional demonstrations that would occur if a country's population went from the smallest to the largest in the sample (95 percent confidence interval of 2.32 to 3.77). For an organization type that is not commonly thought of as specialized on nonviolent protest promotion, this result seems very substantial.

Table 1, column (4) illustrates the next step in the empirical implications of this mechanism: the impact of peaceful demonstrations on health spending. The logic here is that now we know that health INGOs affect domestic mobilization, we can examine whether this domestic mobilization does increase health spending. We do this through adding our variable for peaceful demonstrations to the specification of health spending outlined earlier. As Table 1, column (4) shows, the differenced health INGOs per capita measure remains statistically significant and in the expected direction. Additionally, we find that change in the number of peaceful demonstrations has a positive and statistically significant impact on health spending. Overall, these results provide support for the observable implications of the indirect transnational policy advocacy mechanism, as outlined in H3.

Research Design for Supplementary Hypothesis: Direct Advocacy Mechanism

Our final mechanism (H4) concerns the effects of direct policy advocacy by health INGOs on health spending. To examine this mechanism, we utilize newly created events data from the Integrated Data for Events Analysis (IDEA) project that we think closely captures direct actions by health INGOs to governments.

To create this data, Murdie first used the March 2007 online edition of the Yearbook of International Organizations to search for all INGOs active during any portion of the period utilized for this study.Footnote 142 She then restricted the focus to INGOs identified by the Yearbook as predominantly health in orientation; there were 2,260 INGOs that fit this definition. A dictionary of the names, in English as well as in any other language identified by the INGO, and common acronyms of the INGOs was then sent to Virtual Research Associates. Using the Integrated Data for Events Analysis (IDEA) framework, Virtual Research Associates isolated all events in Reuters Global News Service that mention these INGOs and are targeted to a state or governmental actor.Footnote 143 We collapse this data to the country-year. The reason is that this variable, health ingo direct advocacy, captures events of direct advocacy by health INGOs to states.Footnote 144 Following common practice, we also account for any media bias in IDEA by controlling for the natural log of the total number of reports recorded about that country-year in Reuters. The availability of this data restricts the start date of our sample to 1990.

One thing worth noticing at the outset is the paucity of events of health INGO direct advocacy. More than 75 percent of the observations have no health INGO direct advocacy events in a country-year. In fact, in the larger sample of all countries from 1990 to 2009, only two observations had more than thirty health INGO direct advocacy events within a country-year: Algeria in 1999 and 2000. This is in stark contrast to one hundred human rights INGO direct advocacy, for example, where observations were routinely above one hundred. The paucity of events in this sample could indicate that most health INGOs do not directly advocate for policy change, at least in ways captured by events data. This makes some theoretical sense: health INGOs are traditionally not focused on state shaming—their ability to increase health spending may be expected to be more directly linked to the resources they bring to the domestic population within a state (indirect advocacy) and the ideas they help to permeate (climatic conditioning). Because of the paucity of events captured in health ingo direct advocacy, we operationalize this final variable as a dichotomous indicator with a 0 equating to no events and a 1 equating to one or more events.Footnote 145

As a first-cut test of this direct advocacy mechanism, we examine whether a change in health INGOs per capita increases the likelihood of a health INGO direct advocacy event. Such an effect would constitute the first half of the logic of how health INGOs affect health spending via a causal chain that runs from INGOs to the presence of direct advocacy by INGOs to health spending. We use the health INGO direct advocacy dummy as the dependent variable, change in health INGOs per capita as the key independent variable, and control for population (ln), GDP per capita (ln), total events in Reuters (ln), and the 21-point Polity scale. Given the large amount of zeroes in this health INGO dummy, we utilize a rare events logit model.Footnote 146

Table 2, column (3) provides the result of this first-stage relationship between health INGOs and health INGO direct advocacy. As expected, we find a positive and statistically significant relationship, indicating that health INGOs per capita do lead to direct advocacy events.

To complete the logic connecting health INGOs to health spending via this direct advocacy mechanism, we add our new health INGO direct advocacy variable to the basic model of health spending outlined to test our primary hypothesis. As Table 1, column (5) shows (and as somewhat expected, given the low number of direct advocacy events), we find no statistically significant effect of health INGO direct advocacy on health spending. This result indicates that we should reject the hypothesis that health INGOs increase health spending via direct INGO advocacy of such increases, for there can be no INGO effect via direct advocacy if there is no direct advocacy effect. However, because the test is based on a limited count of direct advocacy events that no doubt limits its power, the lack of a direct advocacy effect may not be robust. As evidence for a health INGO effect on direct advocacy activities has emerged, as shown in Table 2, column (3), any evidence that health INGO direct advocacy has an impact on health spending that might emerge from future research would be closer to evidence for health INGO effects channeled via direct advocacy than would otherwise be the case. In short, further research on a possible direct advocacy mechanism is necessary.Footnote 147

Given these results from the tests of the supplemental hypotheses, it appears that the main role of health INGOs in increasing health spending comes either indirectly from general changes in policy opinions (climatic conditioning) or from aiding in resources available to domestic groups (indirect policy advocacy).

Conclusion

Although conventional wisdom often posits that INGOs hinder governmental services, in the case of health, we find that INGOs actually increase governmental spending. This finding is consistent to a myriad of different control variables and specifications. This effect could occur through three causal channels: (1) changing the policy-making environment (climatic conditioning) and (2) mobilizing resources that help generate domestic pressure for increased health spending, as well as (3) directly impacting health spending through advocating themselves for increased governmental health provision. Supplementary tests of the observable implications of these causal mechanisms provide support for the first two mechanisms, especially the indirect advocacy mechanism. Health INGOs have both pragmatic and principled motivations to improve government spending on health care within a state; they provide a “citizen voice” that does not undermine governmental social service spending. This result has important implications for both those in the policy and academic worlds.

In contrast to popular calls that INGOs limit the role of the state, we find that INGOs can actually lead to increased state health spending. INGO presence in a country advances its state's health outputs as much as if the INGOs had advocated for such increase. Moreover, through examining the implications of the causal mechanisms underlying this argument, we find support for very advocacy-like outcomes as a result of health INGO activities.

Theoretically, this project draws attention to an often-missing subtype of INGOs, health INGOs, and shows the utility in looking at INGOs by issue-area focus. Our theory is general; the logic could be extended to other issues INGOs often focus on, such as democracy assistance, education, or economic development. Moreover, this research outlines how an actor without much formal power can still have an impact on domestic political outcomes. This study thus supports the “second image reversed” literature in international relations, indicating that international actors can have an influence on domestic decisions and behavior.Footnote 148 By moving beyond the typical focus on intergovernmental organizations, this study adds to the second-image reversed literature by focusing on the domestic impact of an international nongovernmental actor.

This present study regarding INGO policy influence bears on broad theoretical discussions in a number of literatures, for example, transnational advocacy networks, global civil society, and global social movementsFootnote 149 Further, utilizing the cross-disciplinary literature on policy diffusion and adaptation, this study builds on previous theoretical attempts to articulate causal mechanisms through which INGOs exert influence.Footnote 150 Empirically, this article uses new data that allow us to cast some quantitative light on such conceptual distinctions. Future empirical work in this vein would also add to the overall literature.

Finally, this research provides an important step in understanding the effects of health INGOs. The possibility of other health INGO effects calls out for further research. Future projects should examine the impact of health INGOs on health outcomes, services provided, and public opinion of health quality.

Footnotes

1 We define INGOs as any nonprofit, open-membership organization that is not controlled by a government or intergovernmental organization and that is active in at least three states. By this definition, we focus on only INGOs with a stated mission that refers to health provision. Union of International Associations 2008/2009; Boli and Thomas Reference Boli, Thomas, Boli and Thomas1999.

2 Darren Ell, “Haiti's Catch-22: An Interview with Patrick Elie,” Dominion (Internet ed.), 27 February 2008, available at ⟨http://www.dominionpaper.ca/articles/1736⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

4 Risto Karajkov, “NGOs in the Balkans: Too Much of a Good Thing?” Worldpress (Internet ed.), 22 November 2007, available at ⟨http://www.worldpress.org/Europe/2994.cfm⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

5 “Analysis: Afghan Health NGOs—A Mixed Blessing?” IRIN News (Internet ed.), 12 October 2009, available at ⟨http://www.irinnews.org/Report/86542/Analysis-Afghan-health-NGOs-a-mixed-blessing⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

6 See Richard Phinney, “A Model NGO?” Radio Netherlands (Internet ed.), 5 December 2002; and Campos et al. Reference Campos, Khan and Tessendorf2004, available at ⟨http://www.globalpolicy.org/component/content/article/176/31470.html⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

7 Humberto Marquez, “Venezuela: NGOs Successfully Press for Replacement of Dubious AIDS Drugs,” Inter Press Service (Internet ed.), 19 July 2004, available at ⟨http://www.ipsnews.net/2004/07/venezuela-ngos-successfully-press-for-replacement-of-dubious-aids-drugs/⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

8 “NGO Lauds Lawmakers for Adopting its Budget Proposals,” GMA News (Internet ed.), 9 April 2009, available at ⟨http://www.gmanetwork.com/news/story/156312/news/nation/ngo-lauds-lawmakers-for-adopting-its-budget-proposals⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

9 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

13 Engerman and Sokoloff Reference Engerman and Sokoloff2002.

14 See Hall and Soskice Reference Hall and Soskice2001; Lindert Reference Lindert2004; and Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008, 181–200, especially 182.

15 See Brown and Hunter Reference Brown and Hunter1999; and Franzese Reference Franzese2002.

16 Huber, Mustillo, and Stephens Reference Huber, Mustillo and Stephens2008.

17 Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2000.

18 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

19 Huber, Mustillo, and Stephens Reference Huber, Mustillo and Stephens2008.

21 See Footnote ibid.; and Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008, 181–200, 182.

22 See Bruno and Easterly Reference Bruno and Easterly1996; and Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

23 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

24 Relatedly, leftist parties, labor union, and other reformist actors who often champion increased social spending may also find their political influence weakened in economic downturns. This is especially true outside of highly developed democracies in Western Europe. See Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008; Slater Reference Slater2010; and Rudra Reference Rudra2002.

25 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

26 See Rodrik Reference Rodrik1997; Rudra Reference Rudra2002; Avelino, Brown, and Hunter Reference Avelino, Brown and Hunter2005; and Rudra and Haggard Reference Rudra and Haggard2005.

27 See Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo Reference Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo2001; and Rudra Reference Rudra2002 and Reference Rudra2004.

28 Rudra and Haggard Reference Rudra and Haggard2005.

29 Avelino, Brown, and Hunter Reference Avelino, Brown and Hunter2005.

30 Foreign aid—mainly bilateral and multilateral as conventionally discussed—has also been recently discussed as substituting for or limiting governmental health care spending. See Waddington Reference Waddington2004; and Van de Walle and Mu Reference Van de Walle and Mu2007. Even though donors may earmark money as supplements to existing government programs, governments “circumvent donors' intentions by changing their own expenditure patterns.” Farag et al. Reference Farag, Nandakumar, Wallack, Gaumer and Hodgkin2009, 1046. We return later to this dynamic and its relationship to health INGO spending.

31 Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2000.

34 Alonso and Brugha Reference Alonso and Brugha2006.

35 See Campos, Khan, and Tessendorf Reference Campos, Khan and Tessendorf2004; and Shandra, Shandra, and London Reference Shandra, Shandra and London2010.

40 See Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998; Hathaway Reference Hathaway2007; and Von Stein Reference Von Stein2008.

42 Chwieroth, Hicks, and Pinheiro Reference Chwieroth, Hicks and Pinheiro2011.

43 DiMaggio and Powell Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983.

44 See Footnote ibid.; and Chwieroth, Hicks, and Pinheiro Reference Chwieroth, Hicks and Pinheiro2011.

49 Cooley and Ron Reference Cooley and Ron2002.

50 See Petras Reference Petras1997; and Sundstrom Reference Sundstrom2006.

51 Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998, 7–8.

52 Union of International Associations 2008/2009.

53 See Humberto Marquez, “Venezuela: NGOs Successfully Press for Replacement of Dubious AIDS Drugs,” Inter Press Service (Internet ed.), 19 July 2004, available at ⟨http://www.ipsnews.net/2004/07/venezuela-ngos-successfully-press-for-replacement-of-dubious-aids-drugs/⟩, accessed 30 April 2013; and “NGO Lauds Lawmakers for Adopting its Budget Proposals,” GMA News (Internet ed.), 9 April 2009, available at ⟨http://www.gmanetwork.com/news/story/156312/news/nation/ngo-lauds-lawmakers-for-adopting-its-budget-proposals⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

54 Murdie's phone interview with health INGO official, 9 February 2012, Decatur, Ga.; and author's interview with health donor agency official, 15 March 2012, Afghanistan. Interview notes available by request.

55 Murdie's interview with health INGO official, 9 February 2012, Decatur, Ga. Interview notes available by request.

57 Cooley and Ron Reference Cooley and Ron2002.

59 Union of International Associations 2008/2009.

61 Gottret and Schieber Reference Gottret and Schieber2006.

62 DiMaggio and Powell Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983.

64 See Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998; and Dobbin, Simmons, and Garrett Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007.

65 See Weyland Reference Weyland2007; and Dobbin, Simmons, and Garrett Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007.

66 See Mintrom and Vergari Reference Mintrom and Vergari1998; Simmons and Elkins Reference Simmons and Elkins2004; Dobbin, Simmons, and Garrett Reference Dobbin, Simmons and Garrett2007; and Weyland Reference Weyland2007.

68 See Marée and Groenewegen Reference Marée and Groenewegen1997; Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2000; Hall and Soskice Reference Hall and Soskice2001; and Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

69 Murdie and Bhasin Reference Murdie and Bhasin2011.

70 See McCarthy and Zald Reference McCarthy and Zald1977; Jenkins Reference Jenkins1983; and Klandermans Reference Klandermans1984.

71 “NGOs Protest Strike by Edo Health Workers,” The Nation (Internet ed.), 8 September 2010, available at ⟨http://thenationonlineng.net/web3/index.php?news=8939⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

73 Filmer, Hammer, and Pritchett Reference Filmer, Hammer and Pritchett2000.

74 See Bartley Reference Bartley2007; and Murdie and Bhasin Reference Murdie and Bhasin2011.

75 See Humberto Marquez, “Venezuela: NGOs Successfully Press for Replacement of Dubious AIDS Drugs,” Inter Press Service (Internet ed.), 19 July 2004, available at ⟨http://www.ipsnews.net/2004/07/venezuela-ngos-successfully-press-for-replacement-of-dubious-aids-drugs/⟩, accessed 30 April 2013; and “NGO Lauds Lawmakers for Adopting Its Budget Proposals,” GMA News (Internet ed.) 9 April 2009, available at ⟨http://www.gmanetwork.com/news/story/156312/news/nation/ngo-lauds-lawmakers-for-adopting-its-budget-proposals⟩, accessed 30 April 2013.

78 Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998, 9.

82 This idea was also indicated to us in a phone interview with a health INGO official, 9 February 2012, Decatur, Ga.

84 Union of International Associations 2008/2009.

85 See Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008; International Monetary Fund 2009; and Global Development Network Growth Database 2009.

86 Notably, increases in health spending do not automatically equate with better health status in developing countries; institutional capacity and targeting of programs to the poor does matter (see Filmer, Hammer, and Pritchett Reference Filmer, Hammer and Pritchett2000; and McGuire Reference McGuire2010). Filmer, Hammer, and Pritchett (Reference Filmer, Hammer and Pritchett2000, 219) call for increased “citizen voice” to help improve outcomes. Increased spending can mean increases in inefficiency and corruption. True, in many countries during the 1980s and 1990s, expanded health service spending was accompanied by efforts to control corruption, especially in Latin America (see Gupta, Davoodi, and Tiongson Reference Gupta, Davoodi, Tiongson and Jain2001; and Franko Reference Franko2007). However, efforts at health spending reform in Latin America also included, in many instances, a move toward more privatization and fractionalization of services, often at the detriment of overall health levels (see Kaufman and Nelson Reference Kaufman and Nelson2004; Franko Reference Franko2007; and Rudra Reference Rudra2008). Gupta, Verhoeven, and Tiongson (Reference Gupta, Verhoeven and Tiongson1999) do find that, ceteris paribus, higher public health spending in developing countries does improve infant mortality rates. McGuire (Reference McGuire2010) finds that this is the case when programs are directed at basic health services for the poor.

87 See Landman Reference Landman2005; and Neumayer Reference Neumayer2005.

88 Union of International Associations 2008/2009.

89 See Tsutsui and Wotipka Reference Tsutsui and Wotipka2004; and Murdie Reference Murdie2009.

90 Smith and Wiest Reference Smith and Wiest2005.

92 We also considered operational use of the number of health INGOs that report having a permanent location within a state. Data on this were collected by Murdie (Reference Murdie2009) and the results with this alternative specification are largely consistent with the results presented in this article; however, we focus on the number of health INGOs with a member within a state to be consistent with the larger quantitative literature on INGOs. Still if models with permanent location instead of membership are run, results of the global sample are similar in sign and significance as the health INGO member per capita models. When focusing only on the regions in the Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) sample, results are also similar, for either lagged or differenced health INGO secretariats, in Latin American and East Asia. Also, as checks on robustness, we ran models where the number of health INGOs was not weighted by population size and the results were consistent, even slightly improved, as to sign and significance. These results and summary statistics are available in the online appendix.

93 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

94 Marshall and Jaggers Reference Marshall and Jaggers2007.

95 World Bank 2012.

98 See Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo Reference Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo2001; and Rudra Reference Rudra2002 and Reference Rudra2004. Because of high variance inflation factors (VIFs > 17), we do not include Haggard and Kaufman's (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) controls for population under age fourteen and those age sixty-five or older. The results for our key independent variable, however, remain consistent if these variables are included in their sample. Also, our results remain consistent if trade (raw values or ppp values), leftist parties, or capital controls are included as additional independent variables in their sample. For economy, the model presented here does not include these additional controls. They can be found in the replication materials located at www.journals.cambridge.org/ino2013008. We also ran preliminary models for the Haggard and Kaufman sample with an additional control for International Monetary Fund (IMF) program presence. This control was not statistically significant. The inclusion of the IMF control did not change the sign or significance of our key independent variables. We did not include the IMF in the final models to be consistent with Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008).

100 See Beck and Katz Reference Beck and Katz1996; and De Boef and Keele Reference De Boef and Keele2008.

101 See Beck and Katz Reference Beck and Katz1996; and Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008. We perform a variety of tests to (1) see whether the variables used in our error-correction model are stationary or nonstationary and (2) see whether the sets of variables (regressed and repressor) are cointegrated (prescribed in De Boef and Keele Reference De Boef and Keele2008). First, relying on the p statistic, we find that all variables in the lagged level are stationary except for the democracy indicator using the Philips-Perron version of the Fisher test. With a trend specified, we find that all variables are stationary except for the democracy indicator. Additionally, with a drift specified, we find that all lagged variables lagged are stationary. Three regressor variables are nonstationary when we examine z and L* statistics of Fisher tests of simple unlagged levels without trend or drift augmentations of tests (that is, health ingos per capita, gdp per capita, and the democracy indicator); only the democracy indicator is still deemed nonstationary when focusing on the p statistic. However, cointegration tests show that the dependent and independent variables of our ECM regression models are cointegrated, which renders the inclusion of nonstationary variables in models acceptable. As an additional robustness test, we also ran a first-differenced model; the results here are similar as for our key independent variable. All of these tests are available in the online appendix.

103 See Smith and Wiest Reference Smith and Wiest2005; and Mawdsley, Townsend, and Porter Reference Mawdsley, Townsend and Porter2005.

104 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

107 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

109 Worth mentioning, however, when pooling only to the regional level with the restricted Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) sample, the Eastern European slope estimate for health INGO membership is significantly lower than the slope for any other region; it is the only region-specific slope that is not significantly greater than 0 at least at the 0.05 test level for a one-tailed or directional hypothesis test. When the model for Eastern Europe, however, is estimated for the years 1994–2000 instead of 1990–2000, the effect of health INGOs becomes statistically significant in the expected positive direction. This could indicate that the effect of health INGOs on health spending became important after some time had passed following the end of communism. This result is available in the online appendix. Also, regional dummies and an indicator for Sub-Saharan Africa in the larger sample were not statistically significant on their own. This result is available in the online appendix.

110 Granger and Weiss 2001.

111 In restricting our focus to the Haggard and Kaufman (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) sample, we estimate health INGO effects with the conventional lagged levels and unlagged changes of the health INGO regressors. However, we do not presume to modify Haggard and Kaufman's (Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008) specifications of their own regressors (that is, our controls). Our results for the key independent variable of differenced health INGOs per capita remains consistent whether we follow their approach or the more conventional approach of utilizing lagged levels and unlagged changes of the regressors. See Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008, 383.

112 We thank an anonymous reviewer for this idea. Any error in application, of course, remains our own.

113 Cooley and Ron Reference Cooley and Ron2002.

114 These tables can be found in our online appendix.

115 Murdie's phone interview with health INGO official, 9 February 2012, Decatur, Ga. Interview notes available by request.

117 Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman Reference Baum, Schaffer and Stillman2003.

118 These tables can be found in our online appendix.

119 These tables can be found in our online appendix.

120 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

121 This is calculated using the formula in Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008, 385, and a model for the number of health INGOs.

122 Haggard and Kaufman Reference Haggard and Kaufman2008.

127 World Bank 2012.

128 Huber, Mustillo, and Stephens Reference Huber, Mustillo and Stephens2008.

129 Avelino, Brown, and Hunter Reference Avelino, Brown and Hunter2005.

130 This result can be found in our online appendix.

131 Results are similar across samples and are available in the online appendix.

132 This is question e037 in this survey.

133 We realize that this proxy variable has its limitations in terms of country coverage. However, we believe it is the proxy best suited to test this very difficult and previously unquantified causal mechanism.

134 Due to space limitations, these are found in the online appendix.

135 These results are provided in the online appendix.

136 Results (also found in the online appendix) are also consistent if differenced health INGOs is included as a right-hand-side variable. We lose two observations (El Salvador in 1999 and Russia in 1995) here due to the use of future (t+1) differenced health spending as the dependent variable. Results are consistent if these two observations are included with their differenced health spending in the same year.

137 Although the World Values Survey question examined here captures the role of the government in service provision well, it lacks a clear connection to health provision. In searching for alternative proxy variables to test the climatic conditioning mechanism, we also found a question, V392, in the 1999 International Social Survey Programme that asked whether people agree that health care should be better for the rich. This question was asked for twenty-three observations for which we have data on health INGOs per capita. The results of t-tests similar to those used above also support our basic findings concerning H2: given data limitations, there appears to be evidence consistent with the climatic conditioning mechanism.

138 Murdie and Bhasin Reference Murdie and Bhasin2011.

139 Footnote Ibid., 176. Also see Iqbal and Zorn Reference Iqbal and Zorn2008; and Inclan Reference Inclan2009. Murdie and Bhasin (Reference Murdie and Bhasin2011) also provide extended theoretical justification for using change in INGO numbers as a key independent variable when the dependent variable is political protest. The basic point is that short-term increases in INGO numbers bring in the resources necessary to aid mobilization.

141 Banks Reference Banks2008a, 12.

144 A similar approach has been previously used to capture the advocacy of human rights INGOs in Murdie and Davis Reference Murdie and Davis2012.

145 Results remain similar as to sign and significance if this variable is not dichotomized.

146 King and Zeng Reference King and Zeng2001.

147 In a robustness test, we combined the indirect and direct advocacy mechanism tests in one model of health spending. The results reinforce the robustness of the indirect advocacy mechanism and will be available in the online appendix.

148 See Reiter Reference Reiter2001; Pevehouse Reference Pevehouse2005; and Gleditsch and Ward Reference Gleditsch and Ward2006.

149 See Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998; Tsutsui and Wotipka Reference Tsutsui and Wotipka2004; and Smith and Wiest Reference Smith and Wiest2012.

150 See Keck and Sikkink Reference Keck and Sikkink1998; and Murdie and Bhasin Reference Murdie and Bhasin2011.

References

Ahmed, Shamima, and Potter, David M.. 2006. NGOs in International Politics. Bloomfield, Conn.: Kumarian Press.Google Scholar
Alonso, Alvaro, and Brugha, Ruairí. 2006. Rehabilitating the Health System After Conflict in East Timor: A Shift from NGO to Government Leadership. Health Policy and Planning 21 (3):206–16.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Avelino, George, Brown, David S., and Hunter, Wendy. 2005. The Effects of Capital Mobility, Trade Openness, and Democracy on Social Spending in Latin America, 1980–1999. American Journal of Political Science 49 (3):625–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Arthur S. 2008a. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive User's Manual. Databanks International. Jerusalem. Available at ⟨http://www.databanksinternational.com⟩. Accessed 20 January 2010.Google Scholar
Banks, Arthur S. 2008b. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive. Databanks International. Jerusalem. Version 18 December 2008. Available at ⟨http://www.databanksinternational.com⟩. Accessed 20 January 2010.Google Scholar
Barnett, Michael. 2009. Evolution Without Progress? Humanitarianism in a World of Hurt. International Organization 63 (4):621–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartley, Tim. 2007. How Foundations Shape Social Movements: The Construction of an Organizational Field and the Rise of Forest Certification. Social Problems 54 (3):229–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, Christopher F., Schaffer, Mark E., and Stillman, Steven. 2003. Instrumental Variables and GMM: Estimation and Testing. Stata Journal 3 (1):131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Katz, Jonathan N.. 1996. Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross-Section Models. Political Analysis 6 (1):136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boli, John, and Thomas, George M.. 1999. INGOs and the Organization of World Culture. In Constructing World Culture: International Nongovernmental Organizations Since 1875, edited by Boli, John and Thomas, George M., 1349. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bond, Doug, Bond, Joe, Oh, Churl, Jenkins, J. Craig, and Taylor, Charles Lewis. 2003. Integrated Data for Events Analysis (IDEA): An Event Typology for Automated Events Data Development. Journal of Peace Research 40 (6):733–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, David S., and Hunter, Wendy. 1999. Democracy and Social Spending in Latin America, 1980–92. American Political Science Review 93 (4):779–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruno, Michael, and Easterly, William. 1996. Inflation's Children: Tales of Crises That Beget Reforms. American Economic Review 86 (2):213–17.Google Scholar
Campos, Nauro F., Khan, Feisal U., and Tessendorf, Jennifer E.. 2004. From Substitution to Complementarity: Some Econometric Evidence on the Evolving NGO-State Relationship in Pakistan. Journal of Developing Areas 37 (2):4972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chwieroth, Jeffrey M., Hicks, Alexander, and Pinheiro, Diogo. 2011. New Institutionalism and Economic Globalization: The Case of Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America. Working Paper. Atlanta, Ga.: Emory University.Google Scholar
Cooley, Alexander, and Ron, James. 2002. The NGO Scramble: Organizational Insecurity and the Political Economy of Transnational Action. International Security 27 (1):539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Boef, Suzanna, and Keele, Luke. 2008. Taking Time Seriously. American Journal of Political Science 52 (1):180200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W.. 1983. The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. American Sociological Review 48 (2):147–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, Frank, Simmons, Beth, and Garrett, Geoffrey. 2007. The Global Diffusion of Public Policies: Social Construction, Coercion, Competition, or Learning? Annual Review of Sociology 33:449–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, Michael. 2010. Why “Philanthrocapitalism” Is Not the Answer: Private Initiatives and International Development. In Doing Good or Doing Better: Development Policies in a Globalizing World, edited by Kremer, Monique, van Lieshout, Peter, and Went, Robert, 237–54. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.Google Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L., and Sokoloff, Kenneth L.. 2002. Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development Among New World Economies. Economia 3 (1):4188.Google Scholar
Engle, Robert F., and Granger, C.W.J.. 1987. Co-Integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing. Econometrica 55 (2):251–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farag, Marwa, Nandakumar, A.K., Wallack, Stanley S., Gaumer, Gary, and Hodgkin, Dominic. 2009. Does Funding from Donors Displace Government Spending for Health in Developing Countries? Health Affairs 28 (4):1045–55.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Filmer, Deon, Hammer, Jeffrey S., and Pritchett, Lant H.. 2000. Weak Links in the Chain: A Diagnosis of Health Policy in Poor Countries. World Bank Research Observer 15 (2):199224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franko, Patrice. 2007. The Puzzle of Latin American Economic Development. Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. 2002. Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, and Ward, Michael D.. 2006. Diffusion and the International Context of Democratization. International Organization 60 (4):911–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Global Development Network Growth Database. 2009. Available at ⟨http://nyudri.org/resources/global-development-network-growth-database⟩. Accessed 10 January 2012.Google Scholar
Gottret, Pablo, and Schieber, George. 2006. Health Financing Revisited: A Practitioner's Guide. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gough, Ian, Wood, Geof, Barrientos, Armando, Bevan, Philippa, Davis, Peter, and Room, Graham. 2004. Insecurity and Welfare Regimes in Asia, Africa and Latin America: Social Policy in Development Contexts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granger, Clive W.J., and Weiss, Andrew A.. 1983. Time Series Analysis of Error-Correcting Models. In Studies in Econometrics, Time Series, and Multivariate Statistics, edited by Karlin, Samuel, Amemiya, Takeshi, and Goodman, Leo A., 255–78. New York: Academic Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, Ruth W., and Keohane, Robert O.. 2005. Accountability and Abuses in World Politics. American Political Science Review 99 (1):2943.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, Sanjeev, Verhoeven, Marijin, and Tiongson, Erwin. 1999. Does Higher Government Spending Buy Better Results in Education and Health Care? IMF Working Paper 99/21. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, Sanjeev, Davoodi, Hamid, and Tiongson, Erwin. 2001. Corruption and the Provision of Health Care and Education Services. In The Political Economy of Corruption, edited by Jain, Arvind K., 111–41. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephen, and Kaufman, Robert R.. 2008. Development, Democracy, and Welfare States: Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Soskice, David, eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hathaway, Oona A. 2007. Why Do Countries Commit to Human Rights Treaties? Journal of Conflict Resolution 51 (4):588621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, Witold J., Zelner, Bennet A., and Guillen, Mauro F.. 2005. The Worldwide Diffusion of Market-Oriented Infrastructure Reform, 1977–1999. American Sociological Review 70 (6):871–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilhorst, Dorothea. 2002. Being Good at Doing Good? Quality and Accountability of Humanitarian NGOs. Disasters 26 (3):193212.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Huber, Evelyne, Mustillo, Thomas, and Stephens, John D.. 2008. Politics and Social Spending in Latin America. Journal of Politics 70 (2):420–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D.. 2000. Partisan Governance, Women's Employment, and the Social Democratic Service State. American Sociological Review 65 (3):323–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inclan, Maria de la Luz. 2009. Repressive Threats, Procedural Concessions, and the Zapatista Cycle of Protests, 1994–2003. Journal of Conflict Resolution 53 (5):794819.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2009. Government Finance Statistics. Available at ⟨http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm⟩. Accessed 10 January 2010.Google Scholar
Iqbal, Zaryab, and Zorn, Christopher. 2008. The Political Consequences of Assassination. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 (3):385400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, J. Craig. 1983. Resource Mobilization Theory and the Study of Social Movements. Annual Review of Sociology 9:527–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Robert R., and Nelson, Joan M., eds. 2004. Crucial Needs, Weak Incentives: Social Sector Reform, Democratization, and Globalization in Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, Robert, and Segura-Ubiergo, Alex. 2001. Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social Spending in Latin America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973–97. World Politics 53 (4):553–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keck, Margaret E., and Sikkink, Kathryn. 1998. Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kim, Dongwook. 2013. International Nongovernmental Organizations and the Global Diffusion of National Human Rights Institutions. International Organization 67 (3):505539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Gary, and Zeng, Langche. 2001. Logistic Regression in Rare Events Data. Political Analysis 9 (2):137–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klandermans, Bert. 1984. Mobilization and Participation: Social-Psychological Expansions of Resource Mobilization Theory. American Sociological Review 49 (5):583600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, Bruce, and MacPherson, J. Muir. 2007. The Decision to Privatize: Economists and the Construction of Ideas and Policies. In The Global Diffusion of Markets and Democracies, edited by Simmons, Beth, Dobbin, Frank, and Garrett, Geoffrey, 104–40. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Landman, Todd. 2005. Protecting Human Rights: A Comparative Study. Washington, D.C.: Georgetown University Press.Google Scholar
Lindert, Peter H. 2004. Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth since the Eighteenth Century. Vol. 1, . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marée, Jörgen, and Groenewegen, Peter P.. 1997. Back to Bismarck: Eastern European Health Care Systems in Transition. Aldershot, UK: Avebury Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Monty, and Jaggers, Keith. 2007. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2006. Dataset Users' Manual. Center for Systemic Peace. College Park: University of Maryland. Available at ⟨http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2006.pdf⟩. Accessed 1 March 2008.Google Scholar
Mawdsley, Emma, Townsend, Janet G., and Porter, Gina. 2005. Trust, Accountability, and Face-to-Face Interaction in North-South NGO Relations. Development in Practice 15 (1):7782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCarthy, John D., and Zald, Mayer N.. 1977. Resource Mobilization and Social Movements: A Partial Theory. American Journal of Sociology 82 (6):1212–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, James W. 2010. Wealth, Health, and Democracy in East Asia and Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintrom, Michael, and Vergari, Sandra. 1998. Policy Networks and Innovation Diffusion: The Case of State Education Reforms. Journal of Politics 60 (1):126–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdie, Amanda M. 2009. Signals Without Borders: The Conditional Impact of INGOs. Ph.D. diss., Emory University, Atlanta, Ga.Google Scholar
Murdie, Amanda M., and Bhasin, Tavishi. 2011. Aiding and Abetting: Human Rights INGOs and Domestic Protest. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55 (2):163–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdie, Amanda M., and Davis, David R.. 2012. Shaming and Blaming: Using Events Data to Assess the Impact of Human Rights INGOs. International Studies Quarterly 56 (1):116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neumayer, Eric. 2005. Do International Human Rights Treaties Improve Respect for Human Rights? Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (6):925–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okafor, Obiora Chinedu. 2006. Legitimizing Human Rights NGOs: Lessons from Nigeria. Trenton, N.J.: Africa World Press.Google Scholar
Oliver, Pamela E., and Myers, Daniel J.. 2002. The Coevolution of Social Movements. Mobilization: An International Quarterly 8 (1):124.Google Scholar
Olzak, Susan. 2006. The Global Dynamics of Racial and Ethnic Mobilization. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petras, James. 1997. Imperialism and NGOs in Latin America. Monthly Review 49 (7):1027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pevehouse, Jon C. 2005. Democracy from Above: Regional Organizations and Democratization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiter, Dan. 2001. Does Peace Nurture Democracy? Journal of Politics 63 (3):935–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Risse, Thomas, and Ropp, Stephen C.. 1999. International Human Rights Norms and Domestic Change: Conclusions. In The Power of Human Rights: International Norms and Domestic Change, edited by Risse, Thomas, Ropp, Stephen C., and Sikkink, Kathryn, 234–78. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2002. Globalization and the Decline of the Welfare State in Less-Developed Countries. International Organization 56 (2):411–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2004. Openness, Welfare Spending, and Inequality in the Developing World. International Studies Quarterly 48 (3):683709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2007. Welfare States in Developing Countries: Unique or Universal? Journal of Politics 69 (2):378–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita. 2008. Globalization and the Race to the Bottom in Developing Countries: Who Really Gets Hurt? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudra, Nita, and Haggard, Stephen. 2005. Globalization, Democracy, and Effective Welfare Spending in the Developing World. Comparative Political Studies 38 (9):1015–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, Hans Peter. 2002. From Lobbying to Shaming: The Evolution of Human Rights Activism Since the 1940s. Paper presented at the 43rd annual meeting of the International Studies Association, March, New Orleans, La.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1999. Development as Freedom. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shandra, John M., Shandra, Carrie L., and London, Bruce. 2010. Do Non-Governmental Organizations Impact Health? A Cross-National Analysis of Infant Mortality. International Journal of Comparative Sociology 51 (1-2):137–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A., and Elkins, Zachary. 2004. The Globalization of Liberalization: Policy Diffusion in the International Political Economy. American Political Science Review 98 (1):171–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slater, Dan. 2010. Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Jackie, and Wiest, Dawn. 2005. The Uneven Geography of Global Civil Society: National and Global Influences on Transnational Association. Social Forces 84 (2):621–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Jackie, and Wiest, Dawn. 2012. Social Movements in the World System: The Politics of Crisis and Transformation. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Sundstrom, Lisa McIntosh. 2006. Funding Civil Society: Foreign Assistance and NGO Development in Russia. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Tsutsui, Kiyoteru, and Wotipka, Christine M.. 2004. Global Civil Society and the International Human Rights Movement: Citizen Participation in Human Rights International Nongovernmental Organizations. Social Forces 83 (2):587620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ullah, A.N. Zafar, Newell, James N., Ahmed, Jalal Uddin, Hyder, M.K.A., and Islam, Akramul. 2006. Government-NGO Collaboration: The Case of Tuberculosis Control in Bangladesh. Health Policy and Planning 21 (2):143–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Union of International Associations (UIA). 2008/2009. Yearbook of International Organizations. 35th ed., Vol. 14. Munich, Germany: K.G. Saur Verlag.Google Scholar
Van de Walle, Dominique, and Mu, Ren. 2007. Fungibility and the Flypaper Effect of Project Aid: Micro-Evidence for Vietnam. Journal of Development Economics 84 (2):667–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Von Stein, Jana. 2008. The International Law and Politics of Climate Change: Ratification of the United Nations Framework Convention and the Kyoto Protocol. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 (2):243–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waddington, Catriona. 2004. Does Earmarked Donor Funding Make It More or Less Likely That Developing Countries Will Allocate Their Resources Towards Programmes That Yield the Greatest Health Benefits? Bulletin of the World Health Organization 82 (9):703–6.Google ScholarPubMed
Weyland, Kurt. 2007. Bounded Rationality and Policy Diffusion: Social Sector Reform in Latin America. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2012. World Development Indicators. Available at ⟨http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators⟩. Accessed 6 January 2012.Google Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1. Regression of health spending on health INGOs and control variables, various samples 1980–2000

Figure 1

TABLE 2. Regressions concerning mechanisms for health spending effects of INGOs; baseline specification, all countries

Supplementary material: File

Amanda Murdie and Alexander Hicks Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Amanda Murdie and Alexander Hicks Supplementary Material(File)
File 682 KB