Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-14T11:42:38.970Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Achieving Economically Feasible Drinking Water Regulation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 June 2020

Richard B. Belzer*
Affiliation:
Independent Consultant, PO Box 319, Mt Vernon, VA22121, USA, e-mail: rbbelzer@post.harvard.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

United States Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA) has regulated drinking water since the 1974 Safe Drinking Water Act (SDWA). Congress directed it to achieve three conflicting goals: (i) establish stringent nationwide standards, (ii) ensure that these standards are both technologically and economically feasible, and (iii) accommodate significant differences in cost among water systems of different sizes with different water sources. USEPA chose to emphasize goal (i) at the expense of (ii) and (iii). In 1986, Congress intensified its preference for (i), was silent concerning goal (ii), and criticized USEPA for failing to achieve goal (iii). In lieu of economic feasibility, the Agency substituted “affordability,” defined as expenditures up to 2.5 % of national median household income irrespective of the benefits. This imposed deadweight losses, and substantial inequities on rural areas, low-income communities, and low-income households generally. In 1996, Congress directed USEPA to use benefit-cost analysis positively and normatively. Regulations issued since 1996 do not appear to comply, however. A review of post-1996 drinking water standards indicates that most were certified by USEPA as having benefits that justified costs, but these determinations were unsupported by the Agency’s own regulatory impact analyses. This article proposes that USEPA define by regulation that “economic feasibility” means marginal benefits exceed marginal costs for the smallest water system subject to SDWA, and that all future drinking water standards must be economically feasible. Economic efficiency would be greatly enhanced and the pervasive inequities of “affordability” greatly diminished. Unlike “affordability,” this definition is objective and compatible with lay intuition about the meaning of key regulatory terms.

Type
Article
Copyright
© Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2020

1 Introduction

Drinking water has been comprehensively regulated in the USA since the passage of the Federal Safe Drinking Water Act of 1974 (SDWA, 1974). Like other federal environmental statutes, SDWA 1974 assigned a dominant regulatory role to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA) in promulgating National Primary Drinking Water Regulations (NPDWRs), usually by setting uniform maximum contaminant levels (MCLs), and required the States to develop programs to implement federal standards. States that developed such programs could become primacy states authorized to enforce federal law; states that did not were subject to direct regulation by USEPA. Most drinking water was (and remains) supplied by intrastate utilities relying on intrastate sources, so the logic for Federal preemption is not clear-cut. State drinking water statutes mimic the federal SDWA, in some cases establishing a greater role for economic feasibility. For example, California drinking water standards are explicitly required to be both technologically and economically feasible (California HSC § 116365(b)).

SDWA 1974 sought to achieve three goals: (i) establishing national standards binding on all states and localities that are as close to zero risk as technologically possible, (ii) ensuring that these standards are both technologically and economically feasible, and (iii) accommodating significant differences in cost among water systems of different sizes relying on different sources. These three goals were in tension if not conflict from the start. Stringent national standards could provide robust public health protection only by sacrificing economic feasibility. Standards that were economically feasible for very large metropolitan water systems would not be economically feasible for the vast majority of public water systems, which were (and still are) small. Accommodating small systems’ diseconomies of scale requires sacrificing stringency.

USEPA implemented SDWA 1974 by emphasizing stringency over economic feasibility and the accommodation of small systems (Schnare, Reference Schnare1998). Congress amended SDWA in 1986 (SDWA, 1986) reiterating Congress’s preference for regulatory stringency. However, Congress changed direction in SDWA 1996, formally directing USEPA to apply benefit-cost principles positively and normatively. This included identifying and analyzing multiple regulatory alternatives, taking account of incremental effects, and estimating risks and benefits “in accordance with sound and objective scientific practices” (§ 1412(b)(3)). Also for the first time, Congress explicitly authorized USEPA to refrain from promulgating standards whose benefits did not justify their costs (§ 1412(b)(6)(A)).

However, SDWA does not define economically feasible or any of its analogues. In this paper, economic feasibility is defined as the condition in which benefits exceed costs, where both are typically calculated at the margin (i.e., marginal net benefits are positive). This definition is objective and grounded in economic principles. It also is intuitively appealing to non-economists, who may struggle to understand how a consumption decision ever could be economically “feasible” if it made them worse off – a necessary outcome if costs exceed benefits. Any scenario in which benefits are ignored cannot be economically feasible. Thus, economic feasibility explicitly excludes affordability.

2 Affordability

Since 1974, USEPA managers preferred to ensure that NPDWRs are affordable rather than economically feasible (Schnare, Reference Schnare1998). Unlike economic feasibility, the term affordability has no objective meaning; it is not grounded in economic principles; and its intuitive appeal among non-economists depends on its interpretation.Footnote 1 In SDWA 1996, Congress ratified affordability as a desirable policy goal but did not define it. Moreover, though presumably aware of USEPA’s similar pre-1996 definition of affordability in the context of water quality (not drinking water) (USEPA, 1995), Congress also did not necessarily endorse it. Rather, Congress directed the Agency to “publish information to assist the States in developing affordability criteria” (SDWA, 1996, § 1415(e)(7)(B)). Congress also did not authorize USEPA to promulgate federal affordability standards. Subsequently, affordability has become a blend of policy, guidance, and implicit regulation that is appropriately characterized as an Agency doctrine – “a codification of beliefs or a body of teachings or instructions, taught principles, or positions, as the essence of teachings in a given branch of knowledge or in a belief system” (Wikipedia, 2018).

The guidance describing USEPA’s post-SDWA 1996 affordability doctrine (USEPA, 1998a, b) is simple in some respects but complex in others. Its simplest features are a reliance on median household income (MHI); the choice of MHI domain (national); and the establishment of 2.5 % of national MHI as the upper-bound threshold for household expenditures on drinking water deemed to be affordable. Multiple dimensions of variability, including regions, systems within a size category, and households served by individual systems, are not taken into account. As USEPA stated in 2006:

Treatment technology costs are presumed affordable to the typical household if they do not cause median water bills to exceed an affordability threshold of 2.5 percent of MHI. This approach assumes that affordability to the median household in a system size category can serve as an adequate measure for the affordability of technologies to the size category as a whole (USEPA, 2006d, p. 10673).

Note that the affordability doctrine is strictly cost-based; it does not account for the benefits realized by drinking water regulation. Further, the doctrine provides only limited relief from economically infeasible NDPWRs, under limited circumstances, to a limited array of public water systems, for a limited period of time.

2.1 The affordability doctrine meets arsenic

The affordability doctrine was tested in 2001 when the Agency promulgated a revised NPDWR for arsenic (USEPA, 2001c). The Agency determined that aggregate estimated annualized benefits of $170 million justified aggregate estimated annualized costs of $210 million, with unquantified benefits making up the difference. USEPA’s benefit estimates were contested; for example, Burnett and Hahn (Reference Burnett and Hahn2001a, Reference Burnett and Hahnb) re-estimated them to be only $20 million.

The Agency’s cost estimate also was controversial (USEPA, 2001b, pp. 7038–7041). For a 10 μg/L MCL, Frey et al. (Reference Frey, Owen, Chowdhury, Raucher and Edwards1998, table 5) estimated annualized national compliance costs at $708 million, later revised downward to $495 million (Frey et al., Reference Frey, Chwirka, Narasimhan, Kommineni and Chowdhury2000, table 4.8). Gurian et al. (Reference Gurian, Small, Lockwood and Schervish2001) estimated annualized national compliance cost at $294 million, with 90th per cent confidence intervals ($177–$495 million) spanning the USEPA and Frey et al. (Reference Frey, Chwirka, Narasimhan, Kommineni and Chowdhury2000) estimates. Estimates of the national annualized incremental compliance cost for 10 μg/L instead of 20 μg/L include USEPA’s figure of $129 million (USEPA, 2001b, table III.E-1), $174 million by Gurian et al. (Reference Gurian, Small, Lockwood and Schervish2001, table 4), $360 million by Frey et al. (Reference Frey, Chwirka, Narasimhan, Kommineni and Chowdhury2000, table 4.8), and $550 million by Frost et al. (Reference Frost, Tollestrup, Craun, Raucher, Stomp and Chwirka2002, table 1). This disagreement did not subside after promulgation of the final rule (Tiemann, Reference Tiemann2006; Hilkert Colby et al., Reference Hilkert Colby, Young, Green and Darby2010; Gingerich et al., Reference Gingerich, Sengupta and Barnett2017).

Congress reacted swiftly to stakeholder concerns about economic feasibility, noting that the revised standard would impose “significant financial costs on many small communities, and many of these communities may find it impossible, because of the financial burden, to be in compliance by 2006 as the rule requires.” Members on the appropriations conference committee were “concerned that, because of their complexity, the current waiver and exemption provisions … may not provide sufficient flexibility for the small communities to receive additional time to reach compliance.” They also were “very concerned that … very small communities may abandon their municipal systems in favor of untreated and unregulated private wells which could create significant other health risks for these communities.” They directed USEPA to, by March 1, 2002, “review the Agency’s affordability criteria and how small system variance and exemption programs should be implemented for arsenic,” taking account of the “undue economic hardship” faced by communities served by small public water systems.” But the conferees also hedged their bets, averring that they “do not intend to create loopholes in the Safe Drinking Water Act for compliance to a national arsenic standard” (U.S. House of Representatives, 2001, pp. 174–175).

2.2 USEPA’s proposed revision to the affordability doctrine

In its report to Congress (USEPA, 2002a), USEPA defended the affordability doctrine but did not include the review Congress had directed be conducted. Instead, the Agency briefly summarized public comments received on the 2000 proposed arsenic rule and promised an “ongoing affordability review” that would include soliciting advice from the Science Advisory Board and obtaining “input from stakeholders” (p. 11). Two USEPA advisory committees weighed in with conflicting recommendations (U.S. EPA Science Advisory Board, 2002; U.S. EPA National Drinking Water Advisory Council 2003 [including a minority report]).

In 2006, USEPA proposed a revision to the affordability doctrine (USEPA, 2006d). The proposed changes would have had mixed or ambiguous effects, most notably the relaxation of the 2.5 % MHI regulatory budget. Doctrinally, the proposal reiterated the Agency’s longstanding view that economic feasibility is limited to “what may reasonably be afforded by large metropolitan or regional public water systems” (p. 10682), thus leaving unaddressed the economic inefficiency and inequity discussed in Section 3. The proposed revision was widely criticized by public commenters (USEPA, 2006c) and subsequently by others (Rubin et al., Reference Rubin, Raucher and Harrod2007; Crawford-Brown et al., Reference Crawford-Brown , Raucher, Rubin and Lawson2009; Raucher et al., Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011; U.S. Conference of Mayors et al., 2013a; U.S. Conference of Mayors, 2014). No revised guidance has been finalized.

2.3 Affordability v. economic feasibility in practice

USEPA has promulgated a number of drinking water rules since SDWA 1996, but in no case has the Agency clearly defined economic feasibility.Footnote 2 Some inferences can be made from the Stage 2 Disinfectants and Disinfection Byproducts Rule (Stage 2 DBPR), in which the Agency stated that “it may not be economically feasible for some small systems to install and operate an on-site [granular activated carbon] reactivation facility” (USEPA, 2006a, p. 413). USEPA estimated the 50th, 90th, and 95th percentile costs for small systems at $18, $169, and $198 per household served (USEPA, 2006a, p. 459, table VI.E-1). Thus, it might be inferred that USEPA believes the latter two average household-level costs are not economically feasible. However, because the Agency did not report benefit estimates by system size, apparent statements about economic feasibility actually may be about affordability.

Inferences also cannot be readily derived from pre-SDWA 1996 rulemakings. For example, in 1994 USEPA re-proposed a NPDWR for sulfates and said that four options “would be economically feasible” despite the financial difficulties presented to small systems (USEPA, 1994, p. 65597). With respect to an option costing on average $287 to $811 per household, depending on system size, the Agency acknowledged “concerns that this option would not be economically feasible for small systems” (table 9). As before, because benefits are absent from the discussion, these statements may be about affordability, not economic feasibility. Further, any inference about USEPA’s intentions must be tempered by the knowledge that the reproposed standard was not promulgated.

Nothing can be inferred from USEPA statements about feasibility without a modifier. The Agency interprets any unmodified use “in terms of technological limits of concentration removal (i.e., treatment) and analytical methods (i.e., sampling and measurement)” (Raucher & Cromwell, Reference Raucher and Cromwell2004, p. 2) – i.e., without economic content. In short, it appears that a general principle of economic feasibility is ground that USEPA has never plowed in the context of drinking water because it was supplanted by the affordability doctrine.

But the affordability doctrine appears to have reached its practical limit, as the cost of drinking water now approaches (and may even exceed) the 2.5 % MHI regulatory budget. Raucher and Cromwell (Reference Raucher and Cromwell2004) relied on USEPA RIAs to build their best estimates of aggregate compliance costs of SDWA 1996 regulations ($1.8 billion per year) and seven regulations promulgated under SDWA 1986 ($4.8 billion per year) (both at 2004 $; 7 %). Household-level equivalents are generally not available because they are absent from the RIAs. Nonetheless, household-level estimates may breach the affordability threshold. In the case of the Arsenic NPDWR, for example, Raucher and Cromwell conclude that “average households in the smallest system size category will pay at least 14 times as much (on average) as households served by utilities in the largest size categories,” with annual compliance cost per household exceeding $700 (pp. 20–21).

Other analyses have obtained similar results. In a recent California study, the median (SD) total cost of drinking water for surveyed communities was estimated at $1,172 ($488) per household, with costs in many jurisdictions exceeding the 2.5 % MHI regulatory budget (U.S. Conference of Mayors, 2014, pp. 4, 12, 13, table C). At some point, it may not be possible for USEPA to promulgate new NDPWSs without unambiguously violating its affordability doctrine.

3 Inefficiency, Inequity, and Arbitrariness in Federal Drinking Water Regulation

It is therefore not surprising that many NPDWRs are economically inefficient. From the outset, SDWA directed USEPA to set stringent national standards while providing ways for small systems to escape the higher cost of complying with standards that were not economically feasible. But the Agency emphasized regulatory stringency and provided limited accommodation to small systems (Schnare, Reference Schnare1998). This led Congress to require benefit-cost balancing in SDWA 1996.

SDWA regulations also are inequitable. They impose significantly disproportionate costs on nonmetropolitan areas, low-income communities, and low-income households generally. The tradeoff between efficiency and equity, made famous by Okun (Reference Okun1975), does not seem to apply.

3.1 Inefficiency

NPDWRs are economically inefficient at least four ways. First, as noted earlier, USEPA sets standards based on what it determines to be economically feasible for very large public water systems (USEPA, 2006d, p. 10682). Because economies of scale in drinking water supply and treatment are so strong, standards that are economically feasible for very large systems are virtually certain to be economically infeasible for small systems.

Second, neither variability across systems within a system-size category nor household variability within each system is considered (USEPA, 2006d, p. 10673). Thus, even if a NPDWR were economically feasible for the median system in a system-size category, it would be economically infeasible for as many as half of the systems in that category, and as many as half of the households in the median system.

Third, USEPA estimates compliance expenditures, not opportunity costs. At the household level, this means not counting the benefits foregone from reduced expenditures on food, shelter, education, health care, transportation, and expenditures on goods and services that improve health (Keeney, Reference Keeney1990, Reference Keeney1994; Lutter & Morrall III, Reference Lutter and Morrall1994; Lutter et al., Reference Lutter, Morrall and Viscusi1999; Cory & Taylor, Reference Cory and Taylor2017). At the system level, expenditures to comply with economically infeasible NPDWRs reduce resources available for infrastructure investments, the need for which has been estimated to exceed $1 trillion over 25 years (AWWA, 2012). This includes extensive replacement of drinking water service lines to reduce or eliminate lead exposure, ironically to comply with a different and notoriously expensive NPDWR. When net social benefits are estimated, they are upwardly biased because expenditures, not opportunity costs, are subtracted from estimated benefits.

Fourth, the affordability doctrine does not take account of benefits, and even if benefits were counted, USEPA’s estimates tend to be upwardly biased by the Agency’s longstanding practice of “policy framing” risk estimates at the “upper end” (U.S. EPA Office of the Science Advisor, 2004). Thus, even if opportunity costs were properly estimated and subtracted from benefits, estimates of net social benefits would be upwardly biased.

Evidence of economic inefficiency extends back to early SDWA 1974 regulations, when several economic inefficiencies were identified (Council on Wage and Price Stability, 1978) in USEPA’s 1978 proposed trihalomethane NPDWR (USEPA, 1977). The standard was estimated to cost on average $3.9–6.3 million ($1978) per excess cancer case prevented, depending on stringency, but exceed $12 million per case for water systems serving 75,000 or fewer persons. These inferences were confirmed and extended to other NPDWRs in subsequent analyses (Morrall III, Reference Morrall1986; Office of Management and Budget, 1991; Raucher et al., Reference Raucher, Dixon, Trabka and Drago1994).

3.2 Inequity

Households served by small systems are assured of being treated inequitably multiple ways. First, the affordability doctrine imposes disproportionate burdens on lower-income households (U.S. EPA Science Advisory Board, 2002, Berahzer, Reference Berahzer2012; Teodoro, Reference Teodoro2018). Households with income below the MHI must pay more than 2.5 % of their income for drinking water.

Second, USEPA ignores regional and State differences in MHI. Median households in regions and States with lower MHIs therefore must pay more than 2.5 % of their income for drinking water. National MHI in 2016 was $58,820 (90 % CIs: ± $102), but ranged from $40,528 (90 % CIs: ± $258) in Mississippi to $72,935 (90 % CIs: ± $1,164) in the District of Columbia – a range of 1.8x. About 60 % of Mississippi households earned $50,000 or less compared to 38 % of District households (U.S. Census Bureau, 2016).

Third, communities with below-average incomes must bear costs that the Agency regards as unaffordable by households served by large metropolitan systems. MHI in all 82 Mississippi counties was below the national MHI in 2016. In 20 % of Mississippi counties, MHI was less than half of the national MHI (U.S. Census Bureau, 2016). The affordability doctrine requires that they commit 5 % of income, or more, to drinking water. This is equivalent to a peculiar regressive tax that, instead of producing government revenue, transfers wealth from the poor to firms in the water treatment industry.

3.3 Arbitrariness

The affordability doctrine relies on other arbitrary elements besides the 2.5 % national MHI threshold, and thus results in outcomes that are inherently arbitrary on other margins as well (U.S. EPA Science Advisory Board, 2002; Irvin, Reference Irvin2017). Each of the 151,000 water systems in the USA (USEPA, 2017) could be defined as its own domain or aggregated into a single domain for standard-setting. In practice, water systems are aggregated into arbitrarily defined system-size categories in the expectation that variability is captured by economies of scale. But as Gingerich et al. (Reference Gingerich, Sengupta and Barnett2017) showed for small systems participating in an Agency-sponsored demonstration project exploring arsenic treatment alternatives, direct costs can be highly variable for reasons other than system size. The median annual treatment cost among systems in this demonstration project was $147 per household, but ranged from $17 to $662 per household. The median increase in total water bill was 55 %, but ranged from 6 to 274 %.Footnote 3 These ranges suggest that the arsenic MCL may not be technologically feasible for small systems “under field conditions,” as required by SDWA 1996 § 1412(b)(4)(D).

Similarly, there is nothing special about MHI as an affordability metric, nor does the particular MHI statistic obtained from the Census Bureau lack critics (see, e.g., Eskaf, Reference Eskaf2013; Irvin, Reference Irvin2017). Several alternative approaches have been suggested to make the affordability doctrine sensitive to the disproportionately high opportunity costs experienced by low-income households (Raucher et al., Reference Raucher, Rubin, Crawford-Brown and Lawson2011; U.S. Conference of Mayors et al., 2013a, b; UNC Environmental Finance Center, 2017; Teodoro, Reference Teodoro2018, Reference Teodoro2019; Czerwinski et al., Reference Czerwinski, Fretwell, Fosler, Lindsey and Pagano2018; Raucher et al., Reference Raucher, Clements, Rothstein, Mastracchio and Green2019). USEPA did not propose to adopt any of the earlier recommendations but may be considering the more recent ones.

3.4 USEPA’s policy of ensuring equal ex post health risk from drinking water imposes highly unequal ex post risk elsewhere

Equal protection can be defined as ensuring that people receive the same quantity at different prices or pay the same price and receive different quantities. Quantity-based equal protection is reasonable and appropriate for the provision of constitutional rights (e.g., free speech, protection from unreasonable search and seizure, trial by jury) and public goods supplied by government and funded by general taxation (e.g., national security). However, drinking water is a private good even where it is provided by a public entity. Consumption is rivalrous, and sellers can deny access to those who refuse to pay.

Drinking water is more like other private goods and services, such as electricity, natural gas and sewage treatment that often are supplied by regulated public or private monopolies because of high fixed costs. Where risk reduction is an attribute of a private good or service, consumers typically pay the same price but obtain different quantities of risk reduction depending on other factors, such as their propensity for risk-taking. The result is variability in ex post risk outcomes, not ex post price differences. Indeed, in some jurisdictions, public utilities are statutorily required to charge all customers the same rate (Berahzer, Reference Berahzer2012; U.S. EPA Environmental Financial Advisory Board, 2016; UNC Environmental Finance Center, 2017), a practice that is consistent with price-based equal protection.

A few examples from outside the world of public utilities provide additional insight. For decades, automobile manufacturers marketed as options various safety features, such as seat belts, air bags, and antilock brakes, charging the same price to all similarly situated customers. But customers varied greatly in the amount of risk reduction they obtained, largely due to fixed differences in baseline risk and their propensity to engage in risky behavior. The same pattern applies to newly invented automotive safety features, such as lane-departure, forward-collision, and blind-spot warning technologies. The unit price of these technologies is fixed, at least in broad categories, but the quantity of risk reduction obtained varies across consumers. Persons who are relatively risk-averse, or have reason to believe that they are riskier than average, are more likely to purchase these safety innovations. Some consumers also are more likely to adapt their behavior in ways that reduce risk-reduction benefits (Peltzman, Reference Peltzman1975). Regardless of their baseline risk, preference for risk-taking, or propensity to engage in adaptive responses that reduce benefits, they still pay the same price.

There is a vibrant consumer market for inherently risky power tools. Operating risk varies greatly because consumers differ in baseline conditions (e.g., experience, technical skill, intensity of use) and their propensity to engage in risky behavior (e.g., read and follow directions, wear protective clothing and equipment). Still, all consumers pay the same price for each risk-reduction technology built into these products. What varies across consumers is the quantity of risk reduction obtained.

This pattern applies even to speculative benefits. The establishment of the National Organic Program by the Agricultural Marketing Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture gave food producers a government-sanctioned way to appeal to consumers who believe that foods certified as organic are safer than conventional foods. Consumers who purchase certified organic foods pay the same, higher unit prices regardless of how much psychological benefit they receive.

It is difficult to find examples of private goods with risk-reducing attributes that deliver the same ex post risk but, like drinking water under EPA’s quantity-based equal protection policy, cost consumers widely different amounts. The typical consumer experience is one of variable ex post risk resulting from differences in baseline risk, risk preferences, and the net quantity of risk reduced – not differences in the price of the risk-reducing attribute or feature.

Since 1974, USEPA has implemented SDWA to ensure the same level of ex post protection from drinking water contaminants (Schnare, Reference Schnare1998), not the same price for risk reduction. The practice appears to have been first codified as policy during the National Performance Review (NPR), a management effort to streamline federal government operations to improve performance and reduce costs (Gore Jr. Reference Gore1993, Reference Gore1994). Although official NPR reports are silent on equal protection, USEPA appears to have leveraged the NPR to make quantity-based equal protection as Agency policy (USEPA, 1996).Footnote 4

By insisting on quantity-based equal protection for potential health risks, USEPA imposes highly unequal protection from actual financial risks that inevitably result from highly unequal prices (Raucher, Reference Raucher and Pontius2003).Footnote 5 Households served by small systems cannot obtain the same quantity of ex post health risk except by bearing disproportionately large financial risks. Similarly troubling is the highly unequal protection from financial risk imposed on nonmetropolitan areas, low-income communities, and low-income households generally, that inevitably results from compulsory quantity-based equal protection from potential health risks. Environmental justice advocates have challenged differential health protection in drinking water as a violation of Title VI of the Civil Rights Act, but these efforts have not succeeded for lack of discriminatory intent (Lado, Reference Lado2017). But the case for intentional discrimination is stronger with respect to regulatory policies that, like USEPA’s practice in SDWA, knowingly impose disproportionate financial risks on the poor.

4 A Rational Economic Interpretation of the SDWA Statutory Framework

SDWA as amended can be interpreted as providing the rational economic framework for standard-setting that was missing from SDWA 1974 and SDWA 1986. For any given contaminant or constituent, SDWA 1996 directs USEPA to promulgate NPDWRs that are “as close to the maximum contaminant level goal as is [technologically] feasible” (SDWA, 1996 § 1412(b)(4)(B)). But at the same time, the Agency must determine “whether the benefits of the maximum contaminant level justify, or do not justify, the costs” (SDWA, 1996 § 1412(b)(4)(C)) after an objective analysis of risks, benefits, and costs (SDWA, 1996 § 1412(b)(3)). USEPA could interpret these texts as requiring the promulgation of NPDWRs that minimize health risk subject to the twin constraints of technological and economic feasibility, and account for system size, source water, and other key factors in determining both technological and economic feasibility.

4.1 Pre-SDWA 1996: Deadweight Losses and Inequity through Selective Economic Feasibility

For all but the largest metropolitan water systems, NDPWRs have been economically infeasible by design (USEPA, 2006d, p. 10673). Variances and exemptions were theoretically available for small water systems (Schnare, Reference Schnare1998), but relief if granted was temporary, and systems were generally required to comply with standards that were less stringent than NPDWRs but still economically infeasible. That is, systems for which NPDWRs were economically infeasible had no option except to comply by making their customers poorer.

This is illustrated in Figure 1. Assume six alternative MCLs ranging from MCLa (the most stringent) to MCLf (the least stringent), and three different sizes of public water systems (large [L], small [S] and very small [VS]), which for simplicity in exposition are all presumed to have the same baseline level of a contaminant. Economies of scale in water treatment result in three different marginal cost schedules (MCL, MCS, and MCVS) and the common marginal benefit schedule MB. All six alternative MCLs are technologically feasible for all three system sizes, so USEPA would have chosen MCLb as the NPDWR. MCLb is economically feasible for large systems because the marginal benefit of treatment equals the marginal cost (MB = MCL). Households served by large systems would pay a price of PL.

Figure 1. Traditional standard-setting under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

Though it is technologically feasible for small systems to achieve MCLb, they can only do so at the higher household price PS. Households served by small systems therefore are unambiguously worse off. At the margin, they pay PS to obtain benefits worth only P L. The difference in expenditure, PS – PL, multiplied by the quantity of drinking water consumed, is transferred from their family budgets to firms that design, manufacture, install, or operate water treatment technology. They suffer a deadweight loss equal to area A.

The situation is worse for households served by very small systems. They must pay PVS for benefits worth only PL. They must transfer even more income to firms in the water treatment industry. They suffer the deadweight loss of areas A plus B.

These inefficiencies have been defended on equity grounds by defining equity in terms of a quantity-based definition of equal protection. While it is true that all households gain the same ex post quantity of health risk, households served by small and very small public water systems obtain this only by being made permanently poorer. USEPA achieves quantity-based equal protection from health risk by reducing the welfare of those it purports to benefit.

4.2 Achieving efficiency and reducing inequity through economic feasibility

Interpreting SDWA 1996 as a problem of risk minimization subject to technological and economic constraints allows economic inefficiency and price-based unequal protection to be substantially reduced. This can be accomplished by setting NPDWRs that are both technologically and economically feasible for the smallest size systems subject to regulation. That is, USEPA would interpret SDWA 1996 §§ 1412(b)(4)(B)-(C) as applying consistently to all water systems subject to federal standards, not just the handful of metropolitan systems large enough to spread compliance costs over hundreds of thousands or even millions of households. The structure of the amended statute arguably is more consistent with this approach, which makes national standards a flexible floor instead of a de facto ceiling. States can choose to set more stringent standards, but they would have to transparently acknowledge, and take responsibility for, the resulting deadweight losses, reverse Robin Hood income transfers to the drinking water treatment industry, and the inequities of quantity-based equal protection.

Figure 2 shows how this would work. very small systems would be exempt. The MCL would be set at MCLd, the most stringent standard that is economically feasible for small systems. Households served by large and small systems would pay prices PL* and PS*, respectively. The deadweight loss in Figure 1 would be avoided.

Figure 2. Economically feasible standard-setting under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

Initially, large and very small systems would suffer the deadweight losses in areas C and D, respectively, because in both cases there would be uncaptured net benefits from more stringent controls. But these deadweight losses likely would be temporary. Households served by large systems would be willing to purchase treatment technology sufficient to achieve MCLb, the most stringent standard that is economically feasible for them. These households would pay $ {P}_L^{"} $ instead of the lower price $ {P}_L^{\ast } $ , but the marginal value of additional health benefits would exceed the price difference. Similarly, even though very small systems would be exempt, their customers would be willing to purchase treatment technology sufficient to achieve MCLf, the most stringent standard that is economically feasible for them. Households served by very small systems would be willing to pay $ {P}_{VS}^{"} $ to gain the value of additional health benefits, which exceed marginal cost for every unit of contaminant greater than MCLf. Footnote 6

These choices are rational because both groups of households would be better off than under MCLd. No regulatory coercion is needed to motivate large or very small systems to voluntarily achieve standards more stringent than MCLd. Firms in the drinking water treatment industry would gain new incentives to invest in research and development that reduces the cost of serving the needs of very small systems instead of lobbying for federal standards that are profitable for them but financially damaging for very small system customers.

This solves the allocative efficiency problem because NPDWRs would not impose an economically infeasible drinking water treatment technology on anyone. Price-based unequal protection would remain, however, because households would pay prices inversely related to the size of the system serving them. But these price differences would reflect differences in cost of service, which generally are not perceived as a discriminatory practice in drinking water supply (UNC Environmental Finance Center, 2017, pp. 17–18).

The only other alternative that solves the allocative efficiency problem and achieves similarly equitable results requires EPA to set multiple MCLs within a single NPDWR.Footnote 7 This might be compatible with SDWA 1996, but it would have other significant drawbacks. First, it would require the Agency to obtain much more extensive knowledge across tens of thousands of water systems in the USA. This would be expensive and undoubtedly require a significant expansion in the ranks of its technical staff. Second, the task would be duplicative. The only logical sources for this information are local water systems. It is suboptimal to recycle local information through USEPA and return it as a regulation imposed on the same systems from which the data were obtained. A suboptimal federal information recycling loop might make sense if systems lacked sufficient expertise or faced perverse incentives to analyze their situations incorrectly. But systems have access to a wealth of technical expertise elsewhere (e.g., the American Water Works Association and the National Rural Water Association, among others), and the incentives they face are compatible with allocative efficiency, minimizing price-based unequal treatment, and responding to customer concerns.

5 Effects of Adopting the Economic Feasibility Principle

Predictions about the effects of the economic feasibility principle on future USEPA actions are inherently speculative. There is limited public information concerning which contaminants the Agency expects to advance to rulemaking. The Agency has disclosed, via the Fall 2018 Semiannual Regulatory Agenda, that it intends to propose revisions to the Lead and Copper NPDWR (RIN 2040-AF15) and a new NPDWR for perchlorate (RIN 2040-AF28) (Regulatory Information Service Center 2018). However, insufficient information has been publicly disclosed to allow even a preliminary determination of which alternatives, if any, may be both technologically and economically feasible.

The economic feasibility principle may receive its first test elsewhere. The California State Water Resources Control Board (SWRCB) is developing guidelines or regulations defining economic feasibility. This effort follows the remand and vacatur of a drinking water standard for hexavalent chromium (CMTA et al. v. SWRCB, 2017). The court interpreted the California SDWA, which is modeled on the federal SDWA, in a manner that is theoretically very similar to the economic feasibility principle proposed here, except that it left to the SWRCB the task of defining the term.Footnote 8

Would the adoption of the economic feasibility principle after SDWA 1996 have resulted in reduced inefficiency and inequity? Some insight can be gleaned by reviewing post-SDWA 1996 regulations and attempting to discern whether USEPA would have chosen different regulatory alternatives. Retrospective inferences of this sort are necessarily limited to the economic analyses the Agency performed, and different alternatives likely would have been examined if economic feasibility had been an explicit regulatory objective. For this reason, any retrospective look at past regulations should be viewed as suggestive rather than dispositive.

Since 1974, USEPA has promulgated NPDWRs for 7 microorganisms, 3 disinfectants, 4 disinfection byproducts, 4 radionuclides, 16 inorganic chemicals, and 53 organic chemicals (USEPA, 2018b). This section summarizes the extent to which regulations promulgated since 1996 were economically feasible, and if not, whether an economically feasible alternative was considered. Further information is provided in the Online Appendix.

Table 1 lists the most relevant post-SDWA 1996 regulations, and reports whether (i) USEPA determined that benefits justified costs and (ii) the economic analysis identifies an option that would have been preferred under the economic feasibility principle. Only a few regulations meet both criteria; some do so, but inferences about alternative regulatory choices are still elusive. Details are summarized here; more information about the economic feasibility of these regulations is provided in the Online Appendix.

Table 1. Post-SDWA 1996 rulemakings and economic feasibility.

a The Agency has determined that the benefits of the FBRR justify their cost on a qualitative basis.

b Key analytic documents are not publicly available.

5.1 Surface water treatment regulations

A suite of surface water treatment rules targeting Cryptosporidium (USEPA, 1998d, 2001a, 2002b, 2006b) depended on benefit estimates obtained by risk modeling. These rules were determined to be economically feasible, but modeled illnesses and deaths averted substantially exceeded the number of illnesses and deaths reported from all pathways by the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC). Because the model was not validated and the substantial gap between modeled and reported illnesses and (especially) deaths was not adequately explained, it is reasonable to be skeptical about economic feasibility claims. It is possible that some or all of these rules were economically feasible for very large systems, where economies of scale yield low marginal costs. However, the gap between modeled and reported illnesses and (especially) deaths is so great that even this inference is doubtful. Moreover, it is highly unlikely that any of these rules were economically feasible for smaller systems.

5.2 Disinfection byproduct regulations

Two regulations were promulgated to manage risks from disinfection byproducts (DBP) (USEPA, 1998c, 2005). Any determination of economic feasibility depends on the assumption that mixed, weak, and unconfirmed epidemiological associations between DBP and cancer are causal. USEPA acknowledged that estimated cancer risks could be zero but assumed causality anyway. Without this assumption, neither regulation would have been economically feasible even for very large systems.

5.3 Specific contaminant NPDWRs

For radionuclides, USEPA retained then-existing MCLs for combined Ra226 and Ra228 (though with intensified monitoring requirements), beta particle and photon emitters, and gross alpha activity. It declined to set a more stringent MCL.

For uranium, USEPA’s estimates of aggregate net benefits were negative at every analyzed alternative. Thus, even the least stringent alternative analyzed (80 μg/L) was too stringent to be an economically feasible uniform NPDWR. According to USEPA’s economic analysis, the 30 μg/L uranium MCL was estimated to yield about $50 million in negative net benefits, with a marginal cost of $68 million per cancer case averted. Promulgating 80 μg/L instead of 30 μg/L as the MCL would have saved $36.4 million while reducing the number of cancer cases averted by 0.35, a marginal cost of $190 million per cancer case. It is possible that 80 μg/L (or 30 μg/L, the MCL promulgated) would have been economically feasible for very large systems. However, uranium is not a significant constituent in source waters used by very large systems, so it is probable that the rule was economically feasible for no water system.

Similarly, the arsenic MCL (10 μg/L) was estimated to yield negative aggregate net benefits at every MCL examined. The MCL was economically feasible for systems serving ≥ 1 million persons under fairly broad conditions, however. Under several restrictive conditions (3 % discount rate, upper-bound arsenic exposure, average household size ≥ 5), the MCL may have been economically feasible for the 10,001–50,000 person system size category. These restrictions are so significant – especially the minimum average household size – that no systems in this size category probably qualifies.

The 1991 lead and copper rule (LCR) was estimated by USEPA to cost systems $460–$750 million per year and States $40 million per year (USEPA, 1991, table 20). USEPA did not report benefit and cost estimates for the 2000 LCR revision (USEPA, 2000a), so no inferences can be gleaned concerning the specific effect of the economic feasibility principle had it been adopted.Footnote 9 Abernethy et al. (Reference Abernethy, Chojnacki, Farahi, Schwartz and Webb2018) addresses the high cost of simply determining where lead service lines exist and developing a cost-effective strategy for line replacement. The USEPA Science Advisory Board (2011) has raised concerns that service line replacement may increase rather than reduce risk. This has obvious relevance under the economic feasibility principle, but it is immaterial if technological feasibility alone controls decision-making. USEPA’s forthcoming Long-Term LCR (USEPA, 2018a), which purports to overcome limitations that made the 2000 regulation ineffective, has been estimated to cost another $44–274 million per year (Slabaugh et al., Reference Slabaugh, Arnold, Chaparro and Hill2015, table 6), with annual costs rising exponentially as system size declines (Slabaugh et al., Reference Slabaugh, Arnold, Chaparro and Hill2015, fig. 5).

5.4 Summary

If USEPA had adopted the economic feasibility principle after SDWA 1996, the entire portfolio of SDWA 1996 regulations would have looked very different. USEPA would have set MCLs such that they were economically feasible for the smallest system size subject to regulation. The Agency would have made tradeoffs between stringency and regulatory scope. These tradeoffs would have been more striking if the Agency had also complied with the relevant SDWA 1996 provisions governing objective risk assessment and benefit cost analysis.

Allocative inefficiency would have been reduced or avoided to an extent dependent on the objectivity of USEPA's risk and economic analyses. Cost-savings would have totaled hundreds of millions of dollars annually. These savings would have enabled systems to better fund key infrastructure improvements, and households would have had greater disposable income for more highly valued uses.

Post-1996 drinking water regulations, like those that preceded SDWA 1996, imposed gross inequities on nonmetropolitan areas, low-income communities, and low-income households. The economic feasibility principle would have substantially attenuated these inequities. The poor would not have borne disproportionately high and rising costs for drinking water, and drinking water regulation would not have made them poorer with each successive regulation action.

6 Conclusion

The SDWA has been implemented in ways that cause significant allocative inefficiency by subordinating economic feasibility to stringent standards regardless of health benefits. Regulations also have achieved quantity-based equal protection against health risks at the cost of substantial unequal protection against financial risks, most notably on households served by small systems, less wealthy regions and States, low-income communities, and low-income households generally.

In SDWA 1996, Congress changed direction and permitted that USEPA promulgate standards supported by objective risk assessment and benefit-cost analysis such that costs are justified by benefits. Ceteris paribus, adoption of the economic feasibility principle would have led to less stringent MCLs, the exemption of smaller system sizes, or both. How USEPA would have traded off stringency for regulatory scope cannot be determined because policy choices delegated to the administrator can be informed but not determined by economic analysis.

It also appears that post-SDWA 1996 NPDWRs did not adhere to SDWA 1996 requirements for objective risk analysis and benefits assessment or Agency guidance on economic analysis (USEPA, 2000b, 2008, 2010). Each determination that benefits justified costs depended on estimating expenditures instead of opportunity costs, using risk analysis methods that were not designed to be compatible with benefit-cost analysis, or invoking speculative unquantified co-benefits to make up any difference between estimated benefits and estimated expenditures.

USEPA can adopt the economic feasibility principle by regulation as the most reasonable interpretation of SDWA 1996. The Agency can set MCLs at the most health-protective level consistent with technological and economic feasibility for the smallest size system subject to regulation. Systems that can achieve more stringent controls in an economically feasible manner will be motivated to do so without a federal mandate. This includes both large water systems (for which even very stringent standards may be economically feasible because of economies of scale) and very small systems (which would be exempt because of their diseconomies of scale). The economic feasibility principle would balance customers’ interests in protection from risk and their aversion to expenditures that exceed the value of benefits received.

In the economic analysis of a USEPA regulation outside the drinking water realm, Wagner (Reference Wagner, Harrington, Heinzerling and Morgenstern2009) detected a material bias favoring the Agency’s preferred standard rather than a fair comparison of alternatives that could have informed the administrator’s decision. Many of the economic analyses for post-SDWA 1996 regulations are consistent with Wagner’s observations; none of the analyses contradicts it. This means adoption of the economic feasibility principle is likely to be an essential prerequisite for SDWA 1996-compliant standard setting, with the courts serving as arbiters of compliance with SDWA 1996 procedural requirements.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/bca.2019.21.

Footnotes

1 A policy is both affordable and economically feasible if and only if benefits exceed costs.

2 Two final rules mention the similar term economically feasible, but in neither case is the term explicitly defined. See USEPA (1998c, p. 69400 [a restatement of statutory language] and p. 69412 [a declarative statement that a particular standard is “technically and economically feasible”]); and USEPA (2006a, p. 413 [stating that a particular technology “may not be economically feasible for some small systems to install and operate”]).

3 Figures derived from Gingerich et al. (Reference Gingerich, Sengupta and Barnett2017, table 3).

4 See p. 2: “The basic concept of environmental protection has evolved beyond just pollution control to include broader issues, such as pollution prevention, sustainability, and environmental justice – e.g., businesses are looking to cut waste in order to prevent pollution and improve profitability; government agencies are developing incentives that can lead businesses and communities to go beyond compliance and continuously improve environmental performance; citizens demand government policies that ensure equal protection against environmental risks and create economic opportunity for present and future generations” (emphasis added).

5 See p. 232: “While a uniform MCL for small and large systems does provide households with roughly ‘equal health protection’ in terms of exposure, regardless of where they live or the size of the community water system (CWS) that serves them, the cost burden that each system bears can be significantly different. In essence, any given MCL is likely to impose much higher costs per unit of risk reduction benefit received by households served in small systems relative to the costs per risk reduction borne in larger communities. This raises a fundamental issue of fairness — should families served by small systems be forced through regulations to pay much higher costs for their risk reduction benefits than do households in larger, more urban settings?”

6 In theory, a water system could respond strategically by breaking up into smaller units in order for each part to belong to a smaller system size category. If the purportedly smaller systems shared management control and, more importantly, treatment technology, States likely would recognize such responses as shams and deny them regulatory approval. On the other hand, both efficiency gains and inequity reductions might be realized in cases where water systems (typically those relying on groundwater) are inefficiently large as a result of prior efforts to comply with NPDWRs that disadvantage small systems. In these cases, subdivision might well be justified.

7 The option of setting dual standards is discussed in U.S. EPA National Drinking Water Advisory Council (2003), and U.S. EPA National Environmental Justice Advisory Council (2009).

8 “[T]he court interprets the [California] Safe Drinking Water Act as requiring the Department to set the MCL at a level that is as close as economically feasible to” the Public Health Goal. CMTA et al. v. SWRCB, 2017, p. 6 (emphasis added).

9 USEPA acknowledged in the 1991 LCR that it did not take benefits into account in setting the NPDWR. See USEPA (1991).

References

Abernethy, J., Chojnacki, A., Farahi, A., Schwartz, E., and Webb, J. 2018. “ActiveRemediation: The Search for Lead Pipes in Flint, Michigan.” In Proceedings of the 24th ACM SIGKDD International Conference on Knowledge Discovery & Data Mining, August 19-23, London, UK, 514.Google Scholar
American Water Works Association. 2012. Buried No Longer: Confronting America’s Water Infrastructure Challenge. Washington, DC: AWWA.Google Scholar
Berahzer, S. 2012. “The Increasing Need to Address Customer Affordability.” In Environmental Finance Blog, Vol. 2018. Chapel Hill, NC: UNC Environmental Finance Center.Google Scholar
Burnett, J. K., and Hahn, R. W. 2001a. EPA’s Arsenic Rule: The Benefits of the Standard Do Not Justify the Costs. Washington, DC: AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.Google Scholar
Burnett, J. K., and Hahn, R. W. 2001b. “A Costly Benefit: Economic Analysis Does Not Support EPA’s New Arsenic Rule.” Regulation, 24 (Fall): 4449.Google Scholar
CMTA et al. v. SWRCB. 2017. Docket No. 34-2015-80001850 (Superior Court, Sacramento County, CA), May 5.Google Scholar
Cory, D.C., Taylor, L. D. 2017. “On the Distributional Implications of Safe Drinking Water Standards.” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 8: 4990.10.1017/bca.2017.2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Council on Wage and Price Stability. 1978. Comments Submitted to the Enviornmental Protection Agency on the Proposed Drinking Water Regulations. Washington, DC: Council on Wage and Price Stability.Google Scholar
Crawford-Brown , D., Raucher, R., Rubin, S., Lawson, M. 2009. Risk Trade-offs in Public Health when Water Prices Rise: The Implications for Small Community Supplies. Washington, DC: National Water Resources Association.Google Scholar
Czerwinski, S. J., Fretwell, E., Fosler, R. S., Lindsey, G., and Pagano, M. A. (2018). Developing a New Framework for Community Affordability of Clean Water Services. Washington DC: National Academy of Public Administration.Google Scholar
Eskaf, S. 2013. “Percent MHI as an Indicator of Affordability of Residential Rates: Using the U.S. Census Bureau’s Median Household Income Data.” In Environmental Finance Blog, Vol. 2018. Chapel Hill, NC: UNH Environmental Finance Center.Google Scholar
Frey, M. M., Chwirka, J., Narasimhan, R., Kommineni, S., Chowdhury, Z. 2000. Update: Cost Implications of a Lower Arsenic MCL. Denver, CO: AWWA Research Foundation.Google Scholar
Frey, M. M., Owen, D. M., Chowdhury, Z. K., Raucher, R. S., Edwards, M. A. 1998. “Cost to Utilities of a Lower MCL for Arsenic.” Journal ‑ American Water Works Association, 90(March ): 89102.10.1002/j.1551-8833.1998.tb08401.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frost, F. J., Tollestrup, K., Craun, G. F., Raucher, R., Stomp, J., Chwirka, J. 2002. “Evaluation of Costs and Benefits of a Lower Arsenic MCL.” Journal ‑ American Water Works Association, 94(March ): 7180.10.1002/j.1551-8833.2002.tb09435.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gingerich, D. B., Sengupta, A., Barnett, M. O. 2017. “Is the Arsenic Rule Affordable?Journal ‑ American Water Works Association, 109(September ): E381E392.10.5942/jawwa.2017.109.0086CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gore, A. Jr. 1993. From Red Tape to Results: Creating a Government That Works Better and Costs Less: Report of the National Performance Review. Washington, DC: National Performance Review.Google Scholar
Gore, A. Jr. 1994. Creating a Government that Works Better and Costs Less: Status Report. Washington DC: National Performance Review.Google Scholar
Gurian, P. L., Small, M. J., Lockwood, J. R., Schervish, M. J. 2001. “Benefit‐Cost Estimation for Alternative Drinking Water Maximum Contaminant Levels.” Water Resources Research, 37: 22132226.10.1029/2000WR900387CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilkert Colby, E. J., Young, T. M., Green, P. G., Darby, J. L. 2010. “Costs of Arsenic Treatment for Potable Water in California and Comparison to US Environmental Protection Agency Affordability Metrics.” Journal of the American Water Resources Association, 46(December ): 12381254.10.1111/j.1752-1688.2010.00488.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irvin, D. 2017. “Is Percent MHI the Best Way to Measure Affordability?” In Environmental Finance Blog, Vol. 2018. Chapel Hill, NC: UNC Environmental Finance Center.Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L. 1990. “Mortality Risks Induced by Economic Expenditures.” Risk Analysis, 10: 147159.10.1111/j.1539-6924.1990.tb01029.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Keeney, R. L. 1994. “Mortality Risks Induced by the Costs of Regulations.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8: 95110.Google Scholar
Lado, M. E. 2017. “Toward Civil Rights Enforcement in the Environmental Justice Context: Step One: Acknowledging the Problem.” Fordham Environmental Law Review 29: 1.Google Scholar
Lutter, R, Morrall, JF. III 1994. Health-Health Analysis: A New Way to Evaluate Health and Safety Regulation. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8: 43-66.10.1007/BF01064085CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutter, R, Morrall, JF, Viscusi, WK 1999. The Cost‐per‐Life‐Saved Cutoff for Safety‐Enhancing Regulations. Economic Inquiry 37:599-608.10.1111/j.1465-7295.1999.tb01450.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrall, J. F. III. 1986. “A Review of the Record.” Regulation, 10: 2534.Google Scholar
Office of Management and Budget. 1991. “Regulating Risk: The Cost-Effectiveness of Federal Efforts to Reduce Health and Safety Risks.” In Regulatory Program of the United States Government; April 1, 1991–March 31, 1992. Washington, DC: OMB, 816.Google Scholar
Okun, A. 1975. Efficiency and Equity: The Big Tradeoff. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. 1975. “The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation.” Journal of Political Economy, 83: 49.10.1086/260352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raucher, R. S. 2003. “Benefit-Cost Analysis and Drinking Water Regulation.” In Drinking Water Regulation and Health, edited by Pontius, F. W., 225250. Lakewood, CO: Wiley-Interscience .CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raucher, R. S., Cromwell, J. 2004. “Safe Drinking Water Act: Costs of Compliance.” Working Paper 35. Arlington, VA: GMU Mercatus Center.Google Scholar
Raucher, R. S., Dixon, A. M., Trabka, E., Drago, J. A. 1994. “Cost‐effectiveness of SDWA Regulations.” Journal – American Water Works Association, 86: 2836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raucher, R. S., Rubin, S. J., Crawford-Brown , D., Lawson, M. M. 2011. “Benefit-Cost Analysis for Drinking Water Standards: Efficiency, Equity, and Affordability Considerations in Small Communities.” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2:124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raucher, R, Clements, J, Rothstein, E, Mastracchio, J, Green, Z. 2019. Developing a New Framework for Household Affordability and Financial Capability Assessment in the Water Sector. Washington, DC: The American Water Works Association, National Association of Clean Water Agencies, and Water Environment Federation.Google Scholar
Rubin, S. J., Raucher, R., Harrod, M. 2007. The Relationship Between Household Financial Distress and Health: Implications for Drinking Water Regulation. Washington DC: National Rural Water Association.Google Scholar
Safe Drinking Water Act. 1974. Pub. L. 93-523 (88 Stat. 1660), December 14, 1974.Google Scholar
Safe Drinking Water Act. 1986. Pub. L. 99-339 (100 Stat. 642), June 19, 1986.Google Scholar
Safe Drinking Water Act. 1996. Pub. L. 104-182 (110 Stat. 1613), August 6, 1996.Google Scholar
Schnare, D. W. 1998. “Environmental Rationality and Judicial Review: When Benefits Justify Costs Under the Safe Drinking Water Act Amendments of 1996.” Hastings West-Northwest Journal of Environmental Law and Policy, 5: 65111.Google Scholar
Slabaugh, R. M., Arnold, R. B. Jr., Chaparro, S., Hill, C. P. 2015. “National Cost Implications of Potential Long-Term LCR Requirements.” Journal ‑ American Water Works Association, 107: E389E400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teodoro, MP 2018. Measuring Household Affordability for Water and Sewer Utilities. Journal – American Water Works Association, 110(1): 1324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teodoro, MP 2019. Water and Sewer Affordability in the United States. AWWA Water Science, 1(2): e1129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tiemann, M. 2006. Arsenic in Drinking Water: Regulatory Developments and Issues. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.Google Scholar
UNC Environmental Finance Center. 2017. Navigating Legal Pathways to Rate-Funded Customer Assistance Programs: A Guide for Water and Wastewater Utilities. Chapel Hill, NC: UNC EFC.Google Scholar
U.S. Census Bureau. 2016. American FactFinder: 2016. Available at https://factfinder.census.gov/faces/nav/jsf/pages/index.xhtml (accessed October 23, 2018)Google Scholar
U.S. Conference of Mayors, American Water Works Association, Water Environment Federation. 2013a. Assessing the Affordability of Federal Water Mandates. Boulder, CO: Stratus Consulting.Google Scholar
U.S. Conference of Mayors, American Water Works Association, Water Environment Federation. 2013b. Affordability Assessment Tool for Federal Water Mandates. Boulder, CO: Stratus Consulting.Google Scholar
U.S. Conference of Mayors. 2014. Public Water Cost Per Household: Assessing Financial Impacts of EPA Affordability Criteria in California Cities. Washington, DC: USCMe.Google Scholar
U.S. House of Representatives. 2001. “Making Appropriations for the Departments of Veterans Affairs and Housing and Urban Development, and for Sundry Independent Agencies, Boards, Commissions, Corporations, and Offices for the Fiscal Year Ending September 30, 2002, and for Other Purposes.” Conference Report 107-272. Washington, DC: GPO.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1977. Economic Impact Analysis of a Trihalomethane Regulation for Drinking Water. Washinton, DC: EPA/Office of Water Supply.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1991. “Maximum Contaminant Level Coals and National Primary Drinking Water Regulations for Lead and Copper; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 56:26460-26564.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1994. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations—Sulfate; Proposed Rule.” Federal Register, 59: 6557865604.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1995. “Interim Economic Guidance for Water Quality Standards: Workbook.” EPA 823-B-95-002. Washington DC: USEPA/OW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1996. Reinventing Environmental Regulation: EPA’s Approach. Washington, DC: USEPA/Office of Reinvention.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1998a. “Information for States on Developing Affordability Criteria for Drinking Water.” EPA 816-R-98-002. Washington, DC: USEPA/OW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1998b. “National-Level Affordability Criteria Under the 1996 Amendments to the Safe Drinking Water Act (Final Draft Report).” EPA-SAB-DWC-ADV-99-001. Washington DC: USWEPA/OGW&DW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1998c. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations: Disinfectants and Disinfection Byproducts; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 63: 6939069476.Google Scholar
USEPA. 1998d. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations: Interim Enhanced Surface Water Treatment; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 63: 6947869521.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2000a. National Primary Drinking Water Regulations for Lead and Copper; Final Rule. Federal Register, 65: 19502015.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2000b. “Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses.” EPA 240-R-00-003. Washington, DC: USEPA.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2001a. “Economic Analysis for the Long Term 1 Enhanced Surface Water Treatment Rule.” EPA 815-R-00-021. Washington, DC: USEPA/OW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2001b. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 66: 69767066.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2001c. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations; Arsenic and Clarifications to Compliance and New Source Contaminants Monitoring: Delay of Effective Date; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 66: 2834128360.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2002a. “Report to Congress: Small Systems Arsenic Implementation Issues.” EPA 815-R-02-003. Washington, DC: USEPA/OW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2002b. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations: Long Term 1 Enhanced Surface Water Treatment Rule; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 67: 18111844.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2005. “Economic Analysis for the Final Stage 2 Disinfectants and Disinfection Byproducts Rule.” EPA 815-R-05-010. Washington, DC: USEPA/OW.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2006a. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations: Stage 2 Disinfectants and Disinfection Byproducts Rule; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 71: 388493.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2006b. “National Primary Drinking Water Regulations: Long Term 2 Enhanced Surface Water Treatment Rule; Final Rule.” Federal Register, 71: 653786.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2006c. “Small Drinking Water Systems Variances; Revision of Existing National-Level Affordability Methodology and Proposed Methodology to Indentify Variance Technology That is Protective of Public Health.” Docket ID: EPA-HQ-OW-2005-0005. Available at https://www.regulations.gov/docket?D=EPA-HQ-OW-2005-0005. (accessed January 26, 2018)Google Scholar
USEPA. 2006d. “Small Drinking Water Systems Variances—Revision of Existing National-Level Affordability Methodology and Methodology To Identify Variance Technologies That Are Protective of Public Health; Notice.” Federal Register, 71: 1067110685.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2008. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. Washington, DC: USEPA.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2010. “Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses.” EPA 240-R-10-001. Washington, DC: USEPA/National Center for Environmental Economics.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2017. Ground Water and Drinking Water; Basic Information about Your Drinking Water. Available at https://www.epa.gov/ground-water-and-drinking-water/basic-information-about-your-drinking-water (accessed July 1, 2018).Google Scholar
USEPA. 2018a. Lead and Copper Rule Long-Term Revisions. Available at https://www.epa.gov/dwstandardsregulations/lead-and-copper-rule-long-term-revisions. (accessed February 16, 2019)Google Scholar
USEPA. 2018b. National Primary Drinking Water Regulations. Available at https://www.epa.gov/ground-water-and-drinking-water/national-primary-drinking-water-regulations. (accessed October 23, 2018)Google Scholar
USEPA Environmental Financial Advisory Board. 2016. Household Affordability Challenges in the Water Sector. Washington, DC: USEPA/EFAB.Google Scholar
USEPA National Drinking Water Advisory Council. 2003. Recommendations of the National Drinking Water Advisory Council to U.S. EPA on Its National Small Systems Affordability Criteria. Washington, DC: USEPA.Google Scholar
USEPA National Environmental Justice Advisory Council. 2009. Letter to Lisa P. Jackson, Administrator. Washington, DC: USEPA/NEJAC.Google Scholar
USEPA Office of the Science Advisor. 2004. “An Examination of EPA Risk Assessment Principles and Practices; Staff Paper.” EPA/100/B-04/001. Washington, DC: USEPA/Risk Assessment Task Force.Google Scholar
USEPA Science Advisory Board. 2002. “Affordability Criteria for Small Drinking Water Systems: An EPA Science Advisory Board Report.” EPA-SAB-EEAC-03-004. Washington, DC: EPA SAB.Google Scholar
USEPA Science Advisory Board. 2011. “SAB Evaluation of the Effectiveness of Partial Lead Service Line Replacements.” EPA-SAB-11-015. Washington, DC: USEPA/SAB.Google Scholar
Wagner, WE. 2009. “The CAIR RIA: Advocacy Dressed Up as Policy Analysis.” In Reforming Regulatory Impact Analysis, edited by Harrington, W., Heinzerling, L., Morgenstern, R. D., 6581. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Wikipedia. 2018. Doctrine. Available at https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Doctrine. (accessed October 15, 2018)Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Traditional standard-setting under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Economically feasible standard-setting under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

Figure 2

Table 1. Post-SDWA 1996 rulemakings and economic feasibility.

Supplementary material: File

Belzer supplementary material

Belzer supplementary material

Download Belzer supplementary material(File)
File 101 KB