Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b6zl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T12:42:41.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Credibility and Distributional Effects of International Banking Regulations: Evidence from US Bank Stock Returns

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 November 2016

Abstract

Financial regulatory networks are a pervasive new type of global governance heralded by some as a flexible answer to globalization dilemmas and dismissed by others as ineffective because of weak enforcement mechanisms. Whether regulatory network agreements provide global public goods or private goods for certain states’ firms is a second debated issue. This article adjudicates among competing perspectives by examining whether Basel III, an international agreement about bank capital minimums negotiated by the bank regulatory network in 2009 and 2010, was viewed as credible and affecting regulated US firms. I use stock returns to measure investors’ perceptions, and an event study methodology to test whether regulated banks’ observed stock returns significantly differ from expected stock returns on days when new information about Basel III becomes available. If the agreement is viewed as credible and affecting firm value, banks’ stock returns will deviate from expectations. The direction of any deviation indicates whether regulations benefit or hurt banks. Although the direction of effects is not uniform across events, I find that the initial stock return reaction and the net effect across all five events are negative, and of a similar magnitude as regulated foreign banks, indicating that US banks were harmed, and did not benefit from, the new international regulations. US banks experienced stock returns that differed from expectations, providing evidence that international regulatory network agreements are viewed as credible and tangibly affect firms independent of domestic implementation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2016 

Do interstate obligations affect state behavior? Scholars have established numerous channels through which international institutions may have effects. Agreements solve collective action problems, create reputation costs of noncompliance, or provide focal points for domestic interest group mobilization.Footnote 1 An institution's existence may alter state incentives, strategies, or preferences over time, or commit a country to lock in future reforms or continue existing, desirable behaviors.Footnote 2 Institutions may, alternatively, codify existing preferences, norms, or power dynamics that would be expressed with or without the institution's existence.Footnote 3 A central premise that underlies much of this work is the assumption that agreements are credible—that state commitments matter and, in the short run, states will largely abide by their international obligations, albeit imperfectly and for various reasons. Distributional effects reflect underlying state power and determine whether an agreement can be reached and the shape of agreement.Footnote 4 State membership is a basic criterion for an organization to be considered an “international institution,”Footnote 5 and obligations are typically among state members, such as the World Trade Organization (WTO) or the International Monetary Fund (IMF).

Distinct from state obligations toward other states, regular meetings and cooperative agreements among state regulatory bodies are an increasingly common form of global governance. Regulatory network organizations—regularized, international collaboration of national regulators—have emerged as the primary fora for international cooperation within important issue areas such as international financial regulation.Footnote 6 Prominent financial regulatory networks include the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS)—whose members include forty-five central banks and bank supervisors representing twenty-six countries, Hong Kong, and the European Union (EU)—and the International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO)—whose members include 123 securities regulators representing more than 110 states.Footnote 7 Because international financial regulatory cooperation occurs among regulators, not states, resulting agreements are nonbinding within international law. Although members agree to implement regulatory network outcomes—such as best practices and standards—within their home countries, regulatory networks often have weak monitoring and no institutional enforcement provisions. Should scholars treat regulatory network organizations and their agreements in similar ways as formal, interstate, legally binding obligations? This article inductively concludes that credible global governance arrangements can and do occur outside of binding, international legal commitments.

Examination of an archetypal financial regulatory network agreement that increases regulatory stringency compared with the status quo, the BCBS's 2010 Basel III agreement on minimum bank capital regulations, pushes forward two open debates about the nature of regulatory networks. First, do investors view regulatory network agreements as credible? That is, at the time of international agreement, do investors believe that these commitments can and will be implemented at the national level? Some international legal scholars argue that regulatory network commitments are credible, functional equivalents to binding state commitments and facilitate international cooperation for which binding agreements might be blocked by domestic politics.Footnote 8 Other scholars argue that regulatory networks have weak formal characteristics—nonbinding international legal standing and weak monitoring—such that members and their home states face high barriers to implement resulting cooperative agreements.Footnote 9 Second, does increased regulatory stringency help or hurt regulated firms? Scholars alternatively argue that the 1988 precedent agreement, Basel I, created either global public goods (that is, greater financial stability associated with higher regulations) at the expense of regulated banks or private goods to US-regulated banks at the expense of foreign-regulated banks (because non-US banks incurred higher adjustment costs to comply than did US-regulated banks).Footnote 10 This article adjudicates among the competing claims of each debate.

To measure credibility and distributional effects, an event study research design isolates stock price movements of regulated firms attributable to Basel III. Regulated firms’ stock returns reflect equity investors’ aggregate perceptions of the impact of Basel III on regulated firm profitability and are thus a good measure of the perceived impact of an international regulatory network agreement. Between September 2009 and December 2010, the BCBS negotiated Basel III during five closed meetings. Following each meeting, the BCBS made a public press release that summarized negotiated outcomes and provided new, public information upon which investors might trade. Each day's press release is an event of interest. On each announcement day, for each US-regulated firm (large, US-headquartered banks), the difference between the firm's expected and observed stock return—the abnormal stock return—can be attributed to Basel III press release information.

The main quantity of interest is the average abnormal stock return, or Average Announcement Effect, across US-regulated firms on each event day. If the Average Announcement Effect substantially differs from 0, this is evidence that the international agreement is seen to be credible—that is, investors believe the agreement will be implemented at the national level and affect regulated firms. The direction of any deviation informs distributional effects; observed stock returns lower than expected indicate a perception that regulated firms’ profitability would be hurt, while greater-than-expected stock returns indicate a boost in perceived profitability attributable to the new information. To further inform distributional effects, I compare the magnitude and direction of US-regulated firm returns with two sets of foreign-headquartered banks that will also have to comply with Basel III.

A crucial modeling decision is how to arrive at each firm's expected stock return on the day of each event—that is, the stock return that is expected in the absence of an announcement. As unobserved counterfactuals, these values must be estimated from observed data. I use a variable selection method, a Lasso estimator, to select specific, unaffected firms to estimate a convincing counterfactual. For each regulated firm for each event, the Lasso estimator considers the full set of (nonfinancial) firms that should be unaffected by the Basel III announcements and the stock returns of the regulated firm in the immediate period prior to each press release. The Lasso estimator identifies a small subset among 2,884 unaffected firms and beta estimates such that the fitted value of these nonfinancial firm returns best approximates the regulated firm prior to the announcement. Then, on an announcement day, the selected nonfinancial firms’ observed stock returns are used to estimate the counterfactual—the regulated firm's expected stock return—for each regulated firm for each announcement. The Lasso variable selection method that identifies a set of specific, unaffected firms improves upon estimates from a traditional event study approach that uses an aggregate market index (such as the S&P 500) as a single regressor that yields correlated, predicted returns for all regulated firms for a given announcement.

Stock return patterns provide evidence that US stock market investors viewed Basel III to be credible. On each announcement day, regulated firms’ stock returns systematically differed from expectations. Although the direction of effects is not uniform across events, the initial reaction and net effect across all five events are negative, providing evidence consistent with the interpretation that regulations hurt regulated firms. Early events (the two 2009 announcements) are associated with US bank stock returns that are systematically lower than expected by an average of 1.43 percent and 0.41 percent, respectively, representing more than $9 billion and $2 billion in foregone equity value. On these days, investors either sold regulated bank stocks or did not buy as readily as expected. Foreign-regulated banks experienced similar declines as US-regulated firms—additional evidence that US banks did not benefit relative to foreign competitors.

The article contributes to existing literature in three ways. First, the theoretical framework places regulatory networks within existing typologies of international cooperation. Regulatory networks are most distinct from formal international institutions because members are not states, such that commitments are all nonbinding within international law. Second, the empirical results establish the importance of regulatory networks as international cooperation. Basel III, an important regulatory network agreement, was perceived by investors to be credible upon agreement at the international level and prior to domestic implementation. Finally, the article illustrates how, when conditions enable event study analysis, this method can precisely measure policy impact and is especially helpful to analyze policies with ambiguous a priori distributional effects.Footnote 11

Regulatory Networks as International Organizations

A type of transgovernmentalism, regulatory networks—regular meetings among state agencies that perform similar tasks—have become a common form of international financial regulatory cooperation.Footnote 12 The defining feature of regulatory networks is that members are substate actors rather than states, from which it directly follows that these organizations do not bind states within international law. Thus, these agreements are considered to be soft law or informal arrangements and distinct from hard law.Footnote 13

Two sets of scholarly debates surround the credibility and distributional effects of financial regulatory networks. One debate lies in whether or not regulatory networks should be viewed as effective, credible forms of international institutional governance. That is, do investors view international financial regulatory network agreements, at the time of agreement, as likely to be implemented into national regulations? A second debate lies in the nature of regulatory agreements’ underlying distributional effects. Increased national regulatory stringency could plausibly help or hurt regulated firms, a general insight for which it is empirically difficult to arrive at an answer.

Regulatory Network Credibility

International legal scholars, sensitive to the legal status of organizational outputs, debate about financial regulatory networks’ degrees of credibility. An affirmative functionalist perspective views the rise and proliferation of regulatory networks as evidence that demand exists for such governance structures. Slaughter argues that transgovernmental networks are flexible, efficient, and accountable; the nonbinding legal nature of agreements that arise among these groups facilitates governments’ willingness to delegate to international bodies.Footnote 14 She argues that, as globalization increases, negative cross-border externalities increase potential gains from international coordination, and yet states’ desires to delegate formal authority to international organizations decreases.Footnote 15 Thus, informal agreements enable de facto cooperation, resulting in net welfare gains. Within international institutions scholarship, scholars identify how publicly stated commitments among countries—whether formal or informal—may increase reputation costs of noncompliance and affect state behavior.Footnote 16

Other scholars alternatively conclude that regulatory network agreements will have limited effects because of these agreements’ formal institutional design characteristics—specifically, that such agreements lack international legal standing and contain weak enforcement mechanisms.Footnote 17 Theoretically, states will have incentives to defect from cooperative arrangements within issue areas marked by high distributional effects and without monitoring and enforcement.Footnote 18 Cheating may be rampant or agreement may be shallow.Footnote 19 Alternatively, the agreement might allow for mock compliance, whereby a country commits to compliance in name, but implements the agreement, in practice, to cater to vested interests within regulated industries.Footnote 20 In all conceptions, international agreement may not imply meaningful policies and outcomes. The nonbinding legal nature of regulatory network agreements render the agreement incredible at the international level.

This article's focus on regulatory network credibility at the time of international agreement complements existing studies of domestic implementation of regulatory network agreements. Bach and Newman establish that international institutional membership in IOSCO, distinct from bilateral US ties, is associated with faster adoption of insider trading legislation and prosecutions and how the EU embedded international regulatory agreements into EU law, leading to the hardening of soft law.Footnote 21 These studies importantly establish that regulatory network outputs diffuse to the domestic level, while this article establishes that regulatory networks may have real effects prior to domestic implementation.

Regulatory Network Distributional Effects

A second scholarly debate concerns the distributional effects of financial regulatory network agreements. What motivates increased regulatory stringency cooperation through financial regulatory networks? Scholars interpret the 1988 Basel I agreement among BCBS members to coordinate bank capital minimums as, alternatively, the provision of global public goods and as private goods for US-regulated banks.Footnote 22 Each perspective assumes the agreement will be credibly implemented within BCBS member countries but holds a different expectation about the direction of the agreement's distributional effects for regulated firms.

One argument is that an agreement that increases regulatory stringency marks the provision of global public goods. This public goods perspective is that international agreements increase financial stability and, simultaneously, maintain competitive advantage across countries.Footnote 23 Regulators desire both financial stability and domestic bank competitiveness, yet when a regulator unilaterally decides on a level of national regulatory stringency, he faces a tradeoff between these two objectives, known as the “regulator's dilemma.”Footnote 24 Higher (lower) regulatory stringency increases (decreases) financial stability, but hinders (helps) competitiveness of regulated firms. However, simultaneous, coordinated regulatory increases across different countries alleviate each individual country's regulator's dilemma. Financial stability increases while competitiveness is maintained. The increase in financial stability is a global public good. Private, regulated firms may incur adjustment and ongoing compliance costs associated with increased regulatory stringency and greater financial stability.

A contrasting, private goods perspective is that higher regulatory stringency increases the competitiveness of firms in states that already maintain high regulatory stringency.Footnote 25 International agreements require member countries with low regulatory stringency to increase minimum regulatory levels, while member countries with higher regulatory stringency at the time of the agreement face lower adjustment costs to comply. In this way, banks in states with high regulatory stringency just prior to the agreement will enjoy private, competitive gains compared with banks in states with relatively low stringency. For example, prior to Basel I, Japanese regulators required Japanese banks to maintain extremely low capital minimums, while US regulators, following the Latin American debt crisis, required US banks to increase minimum capital levels.Footnote 26 To implement Basel I would require both US and Japanese firms to maintain higher minimums than the status quo, but US banks faced lower adjustment costs and were thought to benefit vis-à-vis Japanese competitors.Footnote 27

These perspectives anticipate opposite distributional effects, with US banks hurt if the public goods perspective prevails and helped (in an absolute or relative way) if private goods dominate. In sum, the direction of any effect will help adjudicate between these perspectives. Analysis of Basel III, an international regulatory network agreement that increased bank regulatory stringency in the aftermath of the 2008 global financial crisis, offers a unique opportunity to empirically adjudicate among equally plausible theoretical possibilities.

Basel III

Basel III, an archetypal regulatory network agreement that unambiguously increased the stringency of bank regulatory capital minimums by narrowing the definition of regulatory capital and increasing required minimum levels of high-quality capital that regulated banks must hold, was negotiated during five meetings between September 2009 and December 2010. The agreement contained public, detailed commitments among regulators such that Basel III is a best-case scenario where a regulatory network agreement may be viewed as credible at the international level. What follows is a brief history of precedent agreements Basel I (agreed on in 1988) and Basel II (agreed on in 2004), and a discussion of Basel III negotiations within the post-2008 financial crisis context. Of particular importance is the unexpected nature of the initial BCBS announcement to negotiate Basel III in September 2009.

The BCBS and Bank Regulatory Capital Agreements, 1973–2007

The BCBS was established in 1973 and rule-based member commitments were first codified in 1988's International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards report (also known as the Basel Accord, or, Basel I).Footnote 28 Regulatory capital is a bank's buffer against unexpected losses.Footnote 29 The capital ratio—regulatory capital as a percentage of risk-weighted assets—quantifies a bank's regulatory capital level at any time. Basel I stipulated that internationally active banks should maintain a minimum of 4 percent high-quality (Tier I), and 8 percent total capital as a percentage of risk-weighted assets. BCBS members committed to, and implemented, the terms of Basel I within their home countries within the agreed-on timeline.Footnote 30

During the 1990s and 2000s, Basel I was revised several times, including a significant revision finalized in 2004, the International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards: A Revised Framework (commonly called Basel II).Footnote 31 Basel II maintained the 8 percent capital adequacy minimum in name, but allowed each regulated firm to select among three approaches to define asset risk-weights.Footnote 32 Basel I's approach—BCBS-defined asset risk-weight classes—became known as the Standard Approach under Basel II; two additional options allowed banks to use internal firm models to determine asset risk-weights and calculate their firms’ regulatory capital positions at any given time. In practice, large banks used the new options and often held lower levels of capital than would have been required under Basel I or Basel II's Standard Approach.Footnote 33 Basel II was much more technically complex than Basel I. A simple measure to illustrate this is that the Basel II text ran 251 pages compared with Basel I's twenty-six pages of rules framework.Footnote 34 In contrast to Basel I, countries implemented Basel II with variable timeliness. BCBS countries agreed to implement Basel II by 2006 but it was implemented early by the EU (in October 2005, through a Capital Adequacy Directive) and late by the US (November 2007).Footnote 35

Beyond Basel I, II, and III, quarterly BCBS meetings included discussion of a range of ongoing bank regulatory issues. Upon the onset of the 2007 Global Financial Crisis, Basel I and Basel II capital adequacy regulations were the most formal agreement outputs among BCBS members, meaning that these were specific rules that members promised to domestically implement.

The 2008 Global Financial Crisis and Basel III, 2008–2010

The period following the peak of financial institutional failures in September 2008 was one of reform. The direction and content of reform emerged through evolving discussions among academics, practitioners, and policy-makers at both national and international levels.Footnote 36 Beginning in November 2008, rather than meet as a Group of Seven (G7), heads of government began to meet as a Group of Twenty (G20), and French and UK heads of state publicly sought a “new Bretton Woods.”Footnote 37 G20 guidance directed high-level, post-crisis initiatives of the Financial Stability Board (FSB), the IMF, and the BCBS, among others.Footnote 38 Nationally, within the United States, significant domestic financial reform—the Dodd-Frank Act—was proposed in December 2009 and signed into law on 21 July 2010.

Table 1 outlines the timing of five BCBS meetings that made up the Basel III international agreement negotiations. A BCBS press release followed each meeting—with all meetings conducted within closed sessions—and summarized key outcomes.

Table 1. Basel III negotiations occurred within five BCBS meetings between September 2009 and December 2010

Notes: Press releases that provided public information about Basel III negotiations were made at various times following each BCBS meeting, ranging from the same day (Event 4) to more than two weeks between meeting and press release (Event 5), increasing likelihood that investors cannot anticipate press release timing.

Source: BCBS press releases, available at <http://www.bis.org/list/press_releases/index.htm>.

The September 2009 press release announced a thorough revision of Basel II, a Basel III, would be negotiated. BCBS members agreed in principle to update capital standards, and offered broad direction of reforms. Minimum capital quantities and quality would increase compared with the status quo and a leverage ratio and liquidity ratio would be introduced.Footnote 39 Basel III would mark a clear increase in regulatory stringency. The Financial Times, London edition, reported on 8 September 2009 that “Regulators have agreed [on] tough rules for banks … that would force many institutions in Europe to raise tens of billions of euros in capital in coming months.”Footnote 40 Although investors expected some form of new regulations, the timing of the announcement and the significant degree of reform came as a surprise.

The December 2009 BCBS meeting press release was accompanied by two Basel III consultative proposals (draft documents) made available for public comment.Footnote 41 The media reported on draft content, “the description of what will count as tier 1 capital and how the leverage ratio will be calculated was stricter than some analysts had expected.”Footnote 42 At the same time, newspaper reports commented that the implementation timeline was longer than expected.Footnote 43

A BCBS press release on 26 July 2010 occurred in the wake of media reports that bankers were trying to weaken Basel III proposals. The Financial Times reported on 28 July that “the principles outlined late on Monday by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision contained far-reaching concessions [by regulators toward industry preferences for weaker regulations].”Footnote 44 The BCBS press release announced general agreement to move forward with negotiations, and included some intended modifications from the consultative proposals regarding certain specific capital definitions.Footnote 45

Finally, September and December 2010 BCBS press releases, respectively, provided regulatory details of capital minimum levels and confirmed the shape of rules. The 12 September press release, called “Calibration,” revealed required minimum capital levels.Footnote 46 The Wall Street Journal’s front page the next day read, “Banks Get New Restraints—Historic Refashioning of Rules,”Footnote 47 while the front page of the Financial Times explained, “global banking regulators on Sunday sealed a deal to in effect triple the size of the capital reserves that the world's banks must hold against losses.”Footnote 48 Regulatory stringency would unambiguously increase compared with pre-Basel III levels. At the same time, reports indicated regulated banks welcomed both certainty about the regulations and the long, nine-year implementation timeline. The 17 December BCBS press release confirmed regulatory details and the implementation timeline without significant changes from previous proposals.Footnote 49

Thus, Basel III clearly increased minimum levels of required capital compared with Basel I and Basel II.Footnote 50 For a bank to increase its capital ratio it must increase capital (the ratio's numerator) or decrease risk-weighted assets (the ratio's denominator), typically by issuing new stock shares, changing asset mixes, or selling assets. Each option is expensive because new equity issues dilute existing stock shares’ values, and selling assets or substantially changing asset mixes takes time. For this reason, higher minimum required levels of capital are associated with adjustment and ongoing opportunity costs for regulated banks.Footnote 51

Finally, from the start of Basel III negotiations, it was assumed that European and Japanese banks would face higher adjustment costs than US banks would. Media coverage of the initial Basel III announcement in September 2009 immediately identified European banks, especially French and German banks, as being hurt because of these countries’ firms' existing reliance on hybrid securities (combinations of debt and shareholder's equity) that were considered to be regulatory capital under Basel II but not under Basel III's more narrow definition.Footnote 52 Japanese media reported throughout late 2009 and 2010 that Basel III's narrow capital definition would require Japanese banks to raise capital.Footnote 53 In contrast, no reports singled out US banks as those that would incur especially high adjustment costs relative to other countries. Together, if any country's banks would benefit from relative competitive advantage, it would be US banks at the expense of European and Japanese banks. Thus, during the post-2008 worldwide reform period, Basel III was introduced in a surprise manner in September 2009 and marked a clear increase in regulatory stringency.

Empirical Analysis

Because international institutions are endogenous to member selection into institutions, and international agreements are endogenous to member negotiations, it is a general challenge to isolate and measure direct effects of international institutions and international agreements.Footnote 54 This challenge is heightened during periods such as post-2008 when multiple regulatory and legal reforms occur in quick succession. Figure 1 shows that US-regulated banks, on average, underperformed the total stock market between 2008 and the end of 2012.Footnote 55 Within an event study research design, this article analyzes firm stock returns at precise times to measure how investors react to new information about Basel III negotiations. Such a focused, localized analysis isolates effects attributable to the regulation of interest (Basel III) while controlling for other reforms that advance during 2009 and 2010.

Figure 1. Regulated bank and stock market indices, 2 January 2008 to 31 December 2012

Basel III provides a unique opportunity to apply a standard event study research design to inform the two debates of interest—the credibility and distributional effects of regulatory networks and their agreements. To calculate the counterfactual within this design, I utilize a variable selection (Lasso) method that improves on in-sample and out-of-sample fit compared with standard event study estimators. I analyze US-headquartered, regulated firms as well as two sets of foreign-headquartered, regulated firms. Results provide evidence that investors do perceive regulations to be credible, more consistent with the functionalist perspective regarding regulatory network credibility and less consistent with institutional design perspectives. The Basel III agreement was globally perceived to hurt regulated firm profits rather than to benefit US firms at the expense of foreign competitors. This is more consistent with a global public goods perspective and less consistent with a private goods perspective.

Event Study Methodology and Basel III

Event studies analyze effects attributable to new information. For this study, five information events are the five BCBS press releases that report on the shape and cadence of Basel III negotiations. Stock returns of banks that will have to comply with the regulation—that is, regulated firms—measure effects of the press release information.

Press releases as new information

BCBS press releases are surprises in both release dates and content. Table 1 shows that BCBS press release timing ranges from being announced on the same day as the BCBS meeting (for example, Event 4) to being announced more than two weeks after the meeting (for example, Event 5). Between any two events, newspaper coverage provides no indication that the BCBS provided interim or informal information about the negotiation's progress.

The BCBS is an extremely opaque negotiating body and indications suggest that BCBS press release content is unknown to the public or to private interests prior to formal announcements.Footnote 56 Meeting minutes are never publicly released, and the organization maintains closed archives.Footnote 57 Although the public may know BCBS meeting dates, newspaper coverage never reports meeting outcomes prior to press releases, increasing confidence that press releases reflect new public information.Footnote 58 Interview evidence suggests that, during 2009 and 2010, the BCBS maintained especially formal and distant relations with private interests.Footnote 59

Finally, BCBS meeting outcomes cannot be known with certainty prior to each meeting because BCBS members actively negotiate within meetings. In a rare description of BCBS meeting proceedings, Sheila Bair, the chairwoman of the US Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) during the Basel III negotiation period, documents a fragmented US negotiating position just days prior to certain BCBS meetings about Basel III.Footnote 60 If the US position was unclear prior to meetings, it is reasonable that the collective outcome of a negotiation involving forty-five agencies was also unforeseeable. No negotiation updates occur between BCBS meetings. Overall, BCBS press releases about Basel III negotiations represent new public information upon which investors may trade.

Stock returns as outcome variable

Stock prices adjust to public news almost immediately, and this analysis uses stock returns to proxy for investors’ perceptions about an international agreement's credibility and distributional effects. Considering only the immediate period following each announcement isolates reaction to the expected effects of the international agreement. Stock returns offer a costly, observable measure of investors’ changing perceptions of a firm's value within investors’ portfolios.Footnote 61 New information that changes investor perception of a stock's value will cause investors to act, with the change reflected in the stock price and occurring on the day that new information is available. Firms regulated by the agreement are those that should be affected by investor actions.

Stock returns are a commonly used outcome variable and appropriate for this study. Stock returns, the percentage change in each stock's price today compared with yesterday, provide normalized measures of stock price changes across firms. For example, on the first trading day of 2009, Wells Fargo's 1.76 percent stock return reflected a $0.56 per share stock price increase ($29.48 to $30.00). This stock return is approximately equal to Bank of America's 1.78 percent stock return, reflecting a $0.25 per share increase ($14.08 to $14.33). The analysis uses stock returns that account for dividends and stock splits.Footnote 62

The trading day on which an event occurs is the day when any estimated effect is most attributable to investors’ reactions to Basel III news.Footnote 63 For the two BCBS press releases that occur on nontrading days (for example, Event 1 on US's Labor Day holiday and Event 4 on a Sunday), adjustment is expected on the first trading day following the press release.Footnote 64

US-regulated firms

If credible, Basel III should affect firms that will have to comply with its content. Regulated firms are identifiable and cannot opt into or out of being regulated.Footnote 65 Large US banks, which had to comply with Basel I and Basel II, were certain to be regulated by Basel III. For this reason, main results include the largest available sample of publicly traded, US-headquartered banks with more than $10 billion in consolidated assets in 2009.Footnote 66 This leaves a sample of forty-five firms, detailed in online appendix Table A. Nonfinancial firms are those that should not be directly affected by Basel III and will be used as the set of potential control firms; 2,884 nonfinancial firms publicly traded on US stock exchanges have full stock return data to include in this group.Footnote 67 For each event, for each regulated firm of interest, a subset of nonfinancial firms will be used to create a counterfactual stock return on the event day.

Hypotheses

Illustrated in Figure 2, for each firm for each event, I measure the difference between each regulated firm's observed stock return compared with its counterfactual stock return. The difference is the estimated effect of the announcement for the firm, called the Abnormal Firm Return. The average effect across all firms on an event day is the average effect of the press release (Average Announcement Effect).Footnote 68 Average Announcement Effect is estimated for each of the five BCBS press release announcements between September 2009 and December 2010, and each firm's cumulative abnormal return across the five events is averaged to arrive at a net effect.

Figure 2. Calculating firm abnormal return, illustrative example

Associated with the credibility debate is the following question: Do investors perceive that international agreement implies domestic implementation and firm effects? If the Basel III agreement is viewed to be credible and to have significant effects, consistent with the functionalist perspective, despite its nonbinding nature, investors should react to negotiation news.

H1a

Credibility, functionalist perspective: Days of BCBS press releases will be associated with Average Announcement Effects that differ from 0.

Alternatively, consistent with the institutional design perspective, if the Basel III agreement is not viewed as credible—either because the agreement is shallow or because it is unlikely that regulatory network members will implement the agreement domestically—then new information about Basel III negotiations should not lead investors to buy or sell regulated firm stocks and we will not observe abnormal returns.

H1b

Credibility, institutional design perspective: Days of BCBS press releases will be associated with Average Announcement Effects that do not statistically differ from 0.

Scholars debate the nature of distributional effects associated with increased regulatory stringency: should US-regulated firms—that may incur lower adjustment costs than foreign-headquartered rivals—be hurt by regulations, consistent with a global public goods approach, or be helped by regulations, consistent with a private goods approach? If abnormal returns are negative, investors perceive US-regulated firms to be hurt by the regulations, consistent with the public goods argument.

H2a

Global public goods distributional effects: Days of BCBS press releases will be associated with Average Announcement Effects less than 0.

In contrast, positive abnormal returns imply that US-regulated firms are helped by regulations in an absolute way, consistent with a private goods argument. If US-regulated firms have negative abnormal returns but benefit in a relative manner to foreign rivals, this might be consistent with a private goods argument in a relative manner. I consider both possibilities.

H2b(i)

Private goods absolute distributional effects: Days of BCBS press releases will be associated with Average Announcement Effects greater than 0.

H2b(ii)

Private goods relative distributional effects: Days of BCBS press releases will be associated with Average Announcement Effects significantly higher than foreign rivals.

To evaluate H2b(ii), I compare abnormal returns of US-regulated firms with two sets of foreign-headquartered, regulated firms.

Interpretation

To interpret empirical findings, I focus on results from Event 1, and the net effect across all five events. Although Basel III marks an increase in regulatory stringency, each of the five press releases provides new information that supplements existing information and accumulated investor expectations. For example, investor reactions to new information contained in the Event 2 press release is the marginal reaction to Event 2's information compared with expectations set by Event 1. Similarly, Event 3 stock return movement measures the marginal effect of new information compared with expectations set from Event 1 and Event 2 information, and so on.

Knowing that Basel III increased stringency compared with the status quo leads to reasonably clear interpretations of abnormal returns associated with the initial announcement of Basel III negotiations (Event 1, the September 2009 press release) and the net effect across all five events. Ideally, it would be possible to determine investors’ expectations of the stringency of Basel III at a moment just prior to a press release, and to compare that with the actual stringency update contained within the press release. In this way, those press releases that are most different from investors’ expectations would be where one should see the greatest effect. However, a measure of Basel III investor expectations does not exist.Footnote 69 Although second-best, that Basel III increased regulatory stringency, and that the initial announcement was a surprise, allows us to focus on Event 1. Further, the net effect across all five press releases informs how the effect accumulates across press release days. Media reports supplement our understanding and inform the plausibility of results across events.

Counterfactual Estimation and Model

All estimations follow from the set-up illustrated in Figure 2. On an event day, each regulated firm's stock return is observed and compared with its unobserved, expected stock return on that day. To calculate the expected return, event studies analyze the typical pattern between the regulated firm's stock returns and some other, unaffected asset just prior to the event. On the event day, the unaffected asset's price is observed and the fitted value—using the pre-event relationship between the regulated firm and the unaffected firm—is the expected return.

Formally, the following estimation is conducted for each of the five events listed in Table 1. Let i represent each regulated bank (i = 1, 2, …, 45) and t be a trading day relative to the event (t = –∞, …, –1, 0, 1, …,∞), with the event occurring on day t = 0. Each regulated bank's stock return is observed on each trading day and denoted R it . Thus, the event day and relative trading days’ counts are common to all firms, but returns are distinct.

For each regulated bank, I observe the end-of-day stock return on the event day (R i0), and decompose this return into expected firm return ( $R_{i0}^* $ ) and an error term ( $\varepsilon _{i0}^* $ ), which is the abnormal firm return, to obtain the following:

(1) $$\underbrace {R_{i0}} _{{\rm Observed}\,\,{\rm Firm}\,\,{\rm Return}} = \underbrace {R_{i0}^*} _{{\rm Expected}\,\,{\rm Firm}\,\,{\rm Return}} + \underbrace {\varepsilon _{i0}^*} _{{\rm Abnormal \ Firm}\,\,{\rm Return}}\comma$$

where Expected Firm Return is the estimated stock return for the regulated firm in the absence of an announcement. Abnormal Firm Return is the difference between Observed Firm Return and Expected Firm Return and is visually illustrated for one firm for one event in the gray panel in Figure 2. The calculation is repeated for each regulated firm for each event. The overall quantity of interest for each event is the average Abnormal Firm Return across all regulated firms on event day, and denoted the Average Announcement Effect (P).

(2) $$\underbrace P_{{\rm Average \ Announcement \ Effcet}} = \underbrace {\displaystyle{1 \over N}\sum\limits_{i = 1}^N {\varepsilon _{i0}^*}} _{{\rm Average \ Abnormal \ Firm \ Return}} $$

Specific to this analysis, there are forty-five US-headquartered, regulated firms that trade on major US stock exchanges (N = 45).

Calculation of the unobserved, counterfactual Expected Firm Return on an event day is a crucial part of analysis. Event studies regress a regulated firm's stock returns on unaffected firms’ stock returns for the period prior to the event such that, in the absence of an event, this correlation should provide a reasonable measure of the expected stock return of the regulated firm. Within this standard, conceptual design, I use a variable selection method, a Lasso estimator, to identify specific firms that together create a custom market index for each firm for each event. Although the Lasso regression differs from the traditional approach that uses an aggregate stock market index, both the Lasso regression and the traditional approach use data prior to the event to identify a relationship between each regulated firm and a measure of the stock market. Both approaches assume that data observed prior to the (unanticipated) event capture the relationship between an individual stock and the stock market generally, and that, on the event day, the relationship observed prior to the event can be used to calculate a counterfactual stock return for the regulated firm.

To calculate Expected Firm Return, an estimation window is defined as the period of trading days prior to the event that captures a general relationship between a regulated bank and unregulated, nonfinancial stocks. Formally, the estimation window [a, b] is the set of trading days a < b < 0 prior to the event (t = 0). The estimation window is of length l = ba + 1. For instance, the main event window specification ([–20, –1]) uses a twenty-day estimation window (l = 20) that includes the twenty trading days immediately prior to the event.

Traditional approach: Stock market index

Traditional event studies often model each regulated firm's stock returns over the estimation window as a function of one stock market index, such as the S&P 500 (the weighted-average stock returns of 500 large companies) or an equally weighted index (the simple average of all publicly traded firm stock returns).Footnote 70 The traditional approach applies a simple linear regression to the estimation window data. The dependent variable is the regulated firm's stock return each day during the estimation window, and the explanatory variable is the stock market index return each day. Formally, define M t as the stock market index return on a given trading day. For each regulated firm, for the set of all trading days within the estimation window, a ≤ t ≤ b, the following model is fit: R it  = α i  + β i Mt  + ε i. The stock market index provides a single, daily measure of performance to fit all regulated firms. Because the daily index reflects an average over many firms’ stock returns, it poorly fits different regulated banks’ individual stock returns (R it ). Further, each stock market index may include some regulated firms themselves within the aggregate index measure, resulting in inconsistencies. Regulated firms of interest include large firms, such as Bank of America (Forbes’ 11th largest firm in 2009), Citigroup (12th largest), JPMorgan Chase (16th largest), and Wells Fargo (41st largest).Footnote 71 Because regulated firm stocks are likely to affect general stock market indices (which are supposed to act as a control group), this is a serious concern for this analysis.

Variable selection model: Custom firm index via Lasso estimator

I use a variable selection model, called a Lasso estimator, to identify a subset of nonfinancial firms for each event whose weighted-average stock returns over the estimation window are most similar to each regulated firm of interest. Using patterns in the estimation window data, the Lasso estimator selects a subset of nonfinancial firms that create a custom market index for each regulated firm. This approach better fits estimation window data, creating precise estimations and the ability to test for model sensitivity across estimation windows.

The variable selection method utilizes individual stock returns of unregulated firms over an estimation window. Nonfinancial firms should not be affected by the Basel III regulations and thus the set of all nonfinancial firms compose the control group. Formally, let j denote a publicly traded, nonfinancial firm (j = 1, 2, …, 2,884), where ji. The observed stock return of each nonfinancial firm on trading day t is denoted R jt .

This model also uses a simple regression, but one with a Lasso constraint and with individual firm returns as possible regressors. The dependent variable is the regulated firm's stock return each day during the estimation window (R jt ), and N j explanatory variables are the stock returns of each unregulated firm. Because there are many more possible regressors (N j  = 2,884) than observations during the event window, the Lasso estimator imposes a constraint such that most weights are constrained to 0; only regressors that best approximate the regulated firm's returns over the estimation window have nonzero weights. Formally, the estimation window data are fit by the following model: $R_{it} = \alpha _i + \sum\nolimits_{j \ne i} {R_{jt}} \beta _{ij} + \varepsilon _i $ subject to the constraint $\sum\nolimits_{j \ne i} {\left\vert {\beta _j} \right\vert} \lt \lambda $ .Footnote 72 Thus, the series of $\widehat{{\beta _{ij}}} $ over the set of j control firms is the weight given to each nonfinancial control firm j to fit regulated bank i’s stock returns over the estimation window. Most $\widehat{{\beta _{ij}}} $ equal 0.Footnote 73 Thus, only a few nonfinancial firms emerge as regressors for each regulated firm and they are specifically selected based on the regulated bank's own stock returns over the estimation window. When estimation windows change, selected regressors change accordingly. Table B in the online appendix shows variation for the largest US banks (for example, Wells Fargo, JPMorgan Chase, Bank of America, and Citigroup), illustrating that even the most similar banks have largely different regressors across firms and events.

Figure 3 shows that the Lasso estimation method has significantly higher goodness of fit and better predictive power than the traditional stock market index approach, indicating that Lasso provides more precise counterfactuals than the traditional approach. The left graph of Figure 3 plots density of goodness of fit (that is, adjusted R 2) under each estimation strategy for a twenty-day estimation window.Footnote 74 The interquartile range of the full set of adjusted R 2 values using the Lasso estimator is between 0.58 (first quartile adjusted R 2) and 0.95 (third quartile adjusted R 2). This range is smaller, and has a higher fit, than the full set of adjusted R 2 using the traditional approach (which is between 0.29 [first quartile] and 0.67 [third quartile]). The Lasso regression fits observed data during the estimation window better than the traditional approach does. The right graph of Figure 3 shows that the better goodness of fit of sample data translates into better predictive values outside of the estimation window. I calculate the root mean square error (RMSE) for random samples of nonfinancial firms using both the Lasso method and the traditional approach. RMSE measures variation in observed values compared with predicted values, with lower RMSE indicating a regression line with better predictive value. Lasso regression has lower RMSE than the traditional event in each calculation, and RMSE using the traditional approach is, on average, forty-three times larger than RMSE using the Lasso regression.Footnote 75 High goodness of fit and better predictive power using the Lasso estimator lowers estimation noise and leads to higher confidence in estimates than under the traditional method.

Figure 3. Comparing in-sample (historic) and out-of-sample (predictive) fit across estimation methods

To estimate uncertainty around Average Announcement Effect, I compute 95 percent confidence intervals by following a modified bootstrap method specific to the Lasso estimator.Footnote 76

Estimation Specifications

The base specification uses an estimation window made up of the twenty trading days just prior to each event ([–20, –1]). The results from these models indicate whether stock returns on an event day differ from stock return patterns just prior to press releases. Three additional estimation window specifications—a thirty-day estimation window immediately prior to each event ([–30, –1]), a long, 180-day estimation window ([–180, –1]), and a final, additional specification uses a twenty-day estimation window but controls for the possibility of anticipation effects by ending the estimation window ten trading days prior to each press release ([–30, –11])—ensure that results do not change across different estimation window lengths.Footnote 77

Given a relatively small baseline sample of forty-five firms, two tests ensure that the Average Announcement Effect's signs and statistical significance are not driven by outliers. First, a jackknife procedure drops each firm individually and recalculates Average Announcement Effect and the 95 percent confidence interval to ensure results are not driven by any one firm.Footnote 78 Second, after estimating Abnormal Firm Returns for all regulated firms for an event, I regress Abnormal Firm Returns on Observed Firm Return and use Cook's Distance to identify any influential points. The set of regulated firms whose returns are identified as influential points are simultaneously dropped and the Average Announcement Effect is recalculated with remaining firms. Results are not sensitive to either test.

To inform the distributional effects of the agreement, I compare US-regulated firm returns with two sets of foreign banks—Japanese-regulated banks that trade on the Tokyo Stock Exchange (n = 88) and foreign-headquartered banks that trade on major US stock exchanges (n = 12).Footnote 79 As discussed earlier, Japanese- and European-headquartered banks expected to face the highest adjustment costs to comply with Basel III. To compare US-headquartered, regulated firm results with foreign-headquartered competitors provides greater insight into the distributional effects of regulations.

Finally, to establish the validity of the method as a whole, I run a placebo test randomly selecting samples of unregulated firms and estimating Average Announcement Effect for these firms that should not be affected by Basel III regulations. Among nonfinancial firms, I expect Average Announcement Effect to be statistically indistinguishable from 0.Footnote 80 Specifically, of the 2,884 nonfinancial firms, I take 100 random samples of 200 nonfinancial firms without replacement and treat each as if it were a regulated bank. I estimate the Average Announcement Effect using a twenty-day estimation window.

Results

Figure 4 displays Average Announcement Effects for each of the five events of interest, and the net effect across those five events. The left graph of Figure 4 plots the base specification (shown with white circles)—US-headquartered firms using a twenty-day estimation window immediately prior to each event—and the placebo test results (shown with black squares). The twenty-day estimation window results indicate stock returns statistically differ from 0, evidence in support of H1a that investors systematically traded these stocks on announcement days. The largest estimated effect is Event 1, where observed stock returns were lower than expected stock returns by 1.43 percent on average (that is, an Average Announcement Effect of –1.43 percent). This is the equivalent of $783 million foregone equity for Citigroup shareholders and $2.1 billion foregone equity for Bank of America shareholders.Footnote 81 Event 2 (consultative paper release) and Event 5 (final rules release) also resulted in negative and statistically significant stock returns, but with smaller magnitudes (Average Announcement Effects of –0.41 percent and –0.51 percent, respectively). Event 3 and Event 4 are associated with firm stock returns greater than expected by 0.78 percent and 0.79 percent, respectively. Results imply that stock returns do deviate on days of press releases. Each event's effect measures the marginal change in expectations from just prior to the announcement to just after the press release. It is thus appropriate that reaction to the initial announcement is largest, and that the direction and magnitude of estimated effects of Events 2 through 5 plausibly reflect the qualitative media reports discussed earlier. While the direction of deviations vary, the net effect is negative and statistically significant, averaging –0.77 percent.

Figure 4. Average Announcement Effect on event days, base specification and placebo (left) and base specification and foreign-headquartered firms (right)

Placebo point estimates and 95 percent confidence intervals—represented by black squares in the left graph of Figure 4—do not statistically differ from 0. This increases confidence that the method is measuring a bank-specific effect rather than a general market effect. It establishes that the statistical method is able to produce a null result.

Although the left graph of Figure 4 provides initial evidence that Basel III negotiations hurt regulated firms, to more fully consider Basel III's distributional effects (to evaluate H2b(i) and H2b(ii)), the right graph of Figure 4 shows estimated effects for the base specification of US-headquartered firms (shown with white circles) compared with two sets of foreign firms—foreign-headquartered banks (from countries with BCBS member agencies) that trade on US stock exchanges (black circles) and Japanese-headquartered banks that trade on the Tokyo Stock Exchange (white triangles). Japan was expected to endure especially high adjustment costs and thus Japanese-regulated firms should be the most affected. Empirically, however, the right graph of Figure 4 displays remarkable similarity, in both direction and magnitude, between US-regulated firms and the two sets of foreign firms. If anything, Japanese-regulated banks seemed to enjoy slightly better outcomes than did US banks in Event 1 and as a net effect across events. Thus, there is little evidence in support of H2b(ii) that US-regulated firm returns are relatively higher than foreign firms’ returns. Overall, there is little support for either absolute or relative private goods perspective, and empirical analysis provides evidence in support of H2(a), that Basel III was perceived to hurt US-regulated firms as it provided global public goods.

As a robustness check, Figure 5 shows that results for US-regulated firm models are consistent when using alternative estimation window lengths—twenty-day base specification (white circles), thirty-day (black circles), 180-day (white triangles) and twenty-day plus a ten-day anticipation control (black triangles). When using a ten-day anticipation control, the net effect across firms is not statistically significant, though this results from a large positive Average Announcement Effect on Event 4. Event 1 remains negative and statistically significant, consistent with previous findings.

Figure 5. Average Announcement Effect on event days, base specification, and alternative estimation windows

What is the magnitude of these effects? Figure 6 displays the implied total effect on baseline firms' equity values, calculated in two ways—by the average estimated firm effect applied to all firms (representative firm estimates are white circles), and by the firm-specific estimates (firm-specific estimates are black circles). Estimates are the sum total among all forty-five firms. On Event 1—the day that Basel III was announced—regulated firms’ shareholder equity was $9.3 to $10.4 billion lower than was expected in the absence of the announcement. Across all five events, the net effect is smaller, with foregone shareholder value between $700 million and $1.5 billion, on average. Because Basel III was negotiated during a period where new financial regulations were being discussed at national and international levels, this localized measure plausibly isolates the marginal effect of Basel III negotiations, distinct from other reforms.Footnote 82

Figure 6. Implied equity effect on event days

Overall, results provide consistent evidence that investors viewed Basel III to be a credible agreement that imposed costs on regulated firms (evidence in support of H1a and H2a). Returning to the two theoretical debates, there exists empirical evidence in favor of the functionalist perspective of credible regulatory network agreements (H1a) and less evidence to support the institutional design perspective (H1b). Related to distributional effects, there is little evidence that Basel III acted as private goods for US-regulated firms in either a relative or absolute manner (that is, little evidence in support of H2b(i) and H2b(ii)) and there is evidence that US-regulated firms incurred a negative net effect that was as great or larger than foreign-regulated firms, more consistent with Basel III acting as a global public good (H2a). It is striking to find evidence that, following the height of crisis, when investors expected more stringent regulations, investors perceived actual regulations to be even more stringent than expected.

Conclusion

Basel III negotiations provide an opportunity to observe and measure effects of a financial regulatory network output that increases stringency compared with the status quo. Basel III is a most-likely financial regulatory network agreement to result in effects because its content is detailed and public, and because it supplants some of the most legalized existing arrangements (that is, Basel I and Basel II). Despite being a most-likely case, Basel III is simultaneously nonbinding within international law and lacks enforcement mechanisms, such that some scholars doubt that an arrangement such as Basel III should have real effects on national policies and regulated firms. If cooperation in a strong case had yielded no effect, scholars would conclude that these organizations are largely symbolic. Yet, this article establishes that investors did perceive Basel III to be credible at the international agreement's establishment, and to affect firms subject to Basel III in a negative manner. This finding for an important case of cooperation—although it does not imply that all regulatory network outputs have effects or that all outputs will harm regulated firms—points us toward fruitful, future research areas.

First, this article holds direct implications for institutional design literature.Footnote 83 State membership—often a criterion for an organization to be considered an international institution—is not a necessary condition for an international organization's outputs to lead to anticipated national policies and subsequent distributional effects. Depending on a researcher's purpose, excluding informal institutions from the full population of international governance organizations may create biased results.

Second, the specific source of credibility to which investors react remains an open question. For Basel III, three possible sources include historical precedent, hegemonic leadership, and/or technocratic member identity. Historical precedents (Basel I and Basel II) that established an existing “Basel” brand since 1988 may have been necessary for Basel III to be seen as credible; if so, it supports the basic insight that institutions are easier to continue than to create.Footnote 84 Second, the reputation of regulatory agency members, or the fact that they are from leading financial centers—the United States, the United Kingdom, and European Union—may have significantly bolstered credibility.Footnote 85 Finally, that regulatory agencies are (relatively) independent technocrats perhaps led outputs to be credible.Footnote 86 Although it may be a combination of these items that matters for credibility rather than any individual characteristic, distinguishing among them creates a set of possibilities for future inquiry. To unpack these theoretically distinct sources of credibility requires a research design that analyzes across-time or across-output variation of institutional characteristics. An opportunity to do so may arise with the establishment of BRICS-led financial organizations—such as the New Development Bank (NDB) and Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB)—because the emerging population of financial governance organizations will display variation on all three dimensions.

Third, cursory comparison of Basel I and Basel III illustrates distinct ways in which international organizations may constrain private, special interests. Both agreements narrowed regulatory differences across jurisdictions and increased regulatory stringency compared with the status quo. It is fairly straightforward that these international agreements may limit regulated special interest leverage over national level regulatory outcomes. Yet, Basel I may be seen as addressing across-country preference heterogeneity and constraining special interests in a few BCBS regulators’ home countries; in contrast, Basel III could be interpreted as BCBS member regulators (with relatively homogeneous preferences for high regulations) using the agreement to tie their hands at the international level in preparation for parallel negotiations between each and every BCBS member and domestic interests. Initial evidence for this is the dissatisfaction of even the largest US banks with Basel III, with Jamie Dimon, the chief executive officer of JPMorgan, calling the agreement “anti-American.”Footnote 87 It is generally important to identify and understand different types of special interest constraint. That financial regulatory networks may act to constrain special interests is an important contrasting perspective to existing literature that emphasizes how international organizations are easily captured by strong financial industry special interests.Footnote 88

Finally, this article illustrates how ambiguous policy effects, even during periods of multiple, simultaneous policy reforms, may be measured through well-defined identification strategies (such as the event study used here, or a regression discontinuity design) and/or through isolating and measuring a third-party, exogenous action (such as, in the context of this paper, stock returns). Opportunities to apply such designs are limited by external factors (such as the availability of new information for event studies or the implementation of a policy for regression discontinuity) to find and analyze even small-N effects acts as a valuable supplement to broader trend analyses (for example, time-series cross-section). This approach will inform questions within policy areas where distributional effects are a priori uncertain (as they are in banking regulation). Again, while limited to certain instances, these are compelling ways to identify policy effects.

This article confirms the significance of an increasingly utilized form of international governance: financial regulatory networks. While this is a small subset of the full population of international governance organizations it is an example of an informal institution with a moderate-and increasing-level of legalization. To prioritize the study of formal organizations dismisses such important subsets of international governance organizations whose policy outputs market actors care about and respond to. Future scholarship should continue to better understand the nature of individual institutions, along with collective political interactions, within this dynamic environment.

Supplementary Material

Supplementary material for this article is available at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818316000291.

Footnotes

2. On the former, see Simmons Reference Simmons2000; and Johnston Reference Johnston2001. Regarding the latter, see Moravcsik Reference Moravcsik1995; Pevehouse Reference Pevehouse2002; Allee and Scalera Reference Allee and Scalera2012; and Baccini and Urpelainen Reference Baccini and Urpelainen2015.

3. See Strange Reference Strange1982; Mearsheimer Reference Mearsheimer1995; Downs, Rocke, and Barsoom Reference Downs, Rocke and Barsoom1996; and Von Stein Reference Von Stein2005.

4. See Koremenos, Lipson, and Snidal Reference Koremenos, Lipson and Snidal1991; Fearon Reference Fearon1998; Drezner Reference Drezner2007; and Kim Reference Kim2010.

5. Pevehouse, Nordstrom, and Warnke Reference Pevehouse, Nordstrom and Warnke2004.

6. On transgovernmentalism, see, generally, Slaughter Reference Slaughter1997, Reference Slaughter2004. Specific to international financial regulation, see Zaring Reference Zaring1998; Porter Reference Porter2005; and Kahler and Lake Reference Kahler and Lake2009.

7. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) 2015; and International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) 2015.

9. See Verdier Reference Verdier2009; and Brummer Reference Brummer2011.

10. On the former, see Kapstein Reference Kapstein1989, Reference Kapstein1994. On the latter, see Kapstein Reference Kapstein1991; Oatley and Nabors Reference Oatley and Nabors1998; Drezner Reference Drezner2007; and Simmons Reference Simmons2001.

11. Other political science event studies measure international institutional effects of the European Security and Defense Policy and WTO dispute settlement. Respectively, see Bechtel and Schneider Reference Bechtel and Schneider2010; and Pelc Reference Pelc2013.

12. Whereas a more broad definition might include informal meetings, this article uses a narrow definition of regulatory networks as regular meetings to reflect that the organizations of interest are formal arrangements distinct from international institutions based on member identity. International cooperation regarding “financial regulation”—the rules that financial institutions must follow—arose in the post–Bretton Woods Monetary era and is distinct from monetary cooperation (exchange rate and currency policy) where cooperation has occurred since the early 1800s. On financial regulation, see Zaring Reference Zaring1998; Porter Reference Porter2005; and Kahler and Lake Reference Kahler and Lake2009; on monetary cooperation, see Eichengreen Reference Eichengreen, Feenstra and Taylor2014.

14. Slaughter Reference Slaughter1997, 185–86, and Reference Slaughter2004, 1–64.

15. Footnote Ibid., 1–64. A similar question—how to govern increased interdependence—motivates the study by Keohane and Nye Reference Keohane and Nye1977.

16. See Lipson Reference Lipson1991; and Simmons Reference Simmons2000.

17. See Gadinis Reference Gadinis2008; Verdier Reference Verdier2009, especially 132–33, 162–63; and Brummer Reference Brummer2011, especially 263–64.

18. See Keohane Reference Keohane1984; and Koremenos, Lipson, and Snidal Reference Koremenos, Lipson and Snidal2001.

19. See Downs, Rocke, and Barsoom Reference Downs, Rocke and Barsoom1996; Fearon Reference Fearon1998; and Von Stein Reference Von Stein2005.

20. Walter Reference Walter2008.

22. See Kapstein Reference Kapstein1989; and Oatley and Nabors Reference Oatley and Nabors1998, respectively. Singer broadens the debate to identify general scope conditions under which regulators will prefer international cooperation. Singer Reference Singer2004, Reference Singer2007.

23. Kapstein, Reference Kapstein1989.

24. Footnote Ibid., 324.

25. Oatley and Nabors Reference Oatley and Nabors1998.

26. See ibid., 36; and Tarullo Reference Tarullo2008, 45–54.

27. Oatley and Nabors, Reference Oatley and Nabors1998.

28. The BCBS and Basel I's history are well documented; see, for instance, Wood Reference Wood2005; and Goodhart Reference Goodhart2011.

29. In contrast to unexpected loss, an expected loss is an estimated, unpaid loan percentage and is directly reported as a balance sheet line item.

30. GAO 1991, 2–3.

31. An interim revision was the 1996 Market Risk Amendment.

32. Claessens, Underhill, and Zhang Reference Claessens, Underhill and Zhang2008, 316–18.

33. Footnote Ibid., 322–27.

34. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) 1988, 2004.

35. Tarullo Reference Tarullo2008, 126–30.

36. See Baker Reference Baker2013; and Seabrooke and Tsingou Reference Seabrooke and Tsingou2014.

37. Ben Hall and Jean Eaglesham, “Brown, Sarkozy Seek ‘New Bretton Woods’,” Financial Times, 2 November 2008.

38. Helleiner Reference Helleiner2010.

39. BCBS, “Comprehensive Response to the Global Banking Crisis,” press release, 7 September 2009.

40. Patrick Jenkins, Norma Cohen, and James Wilson, “Europe's Banks Face Capital Push After Regulators Agree to Tough Rules,” Financial Times, 8 September 2009, 1.

41. BCBS, “Consultative Proposals to Strengthen the Resilience of the Banking Sector Announced by the Basel Committee,” Press release, 17 December 2009. Public comments were due 16 April 2010.

42. Jenkins, Patrick, and Brooke Masters, “Tougher Than Expected Framework Leaves Room for Manoeuvre,” Financial Times, 18 December 2009, 8.

43. See Nikkei Report, “Banks Given Ten Years to Meet Tougher Capital Rules,” 16 December 2009; and Atsuko Fukase, “Basel Group to Ease Bank Rules,” Wall Street Journal Europe, 17 December 2009, 23.

44. Megan Murphy and Patrick Jenkins, “Shares Bounce as Regulators Soften Rules,” Financial Times, 28 July 2010, 5.

45. BCBS, “The Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Reach Broad Agreement on Basel Committee Capital and Liquidity Reform Package,” press release, 26 July 2010.

46. BCBS, “Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision Announces Higher Global Minimum Capital Standards,” press release, 12 September 2010.

47. Damian Paletta and David Enrich, “Banks Get New Restraints—Historic Refashioning of Rules,” Wall Street Journal, 13 September 2010, A1.

48. Brooke Masters, “Basel Deal Reached on Banks’ Reserves,” Financial Times, 13 September 2010, 1.

49. BCBS, “Basel III Rules Text and Results of the Quantitative Impact Study Issued by the Basel Committee,” press release, 16 December 2010.

50. For detailed comparison, see GAO 2012, 8.

51. This is a common assumption but not a fact. For a strong argument that holding higher levels of capital does not increase firms’ ongoing opportunity costs, see Admati and Hellwig Reference Admati and Hellwig2013. Additionally, many banks overcomply with capital regulations on an ongoing basis and therefore perhaps adjustment costs are small.

52. For instance, Reuters News, “Banks Eye Clock on Tougher Capital Rules,” 15 September 2009; and Courtney Weaver, “Capital Rules Worries Hurt Banks,” Financial Times, 13 January 2010, 22.

53. For instance, “Narrower Definition of Core Capital to Hurt Japanese Banks,” Nikkei Report, 6 November 2009; and “Japan Still Wary About Early Enforcement of New Basel Rules,” Nikkei Report, 24 December 2009.

55. Specifically, the average of sample banks’ price indices is lower than stock prices at the beginning of 2008 and lower than the S&P index, a measure of the stock market as a whole. This may be surprising given a common perception that banks benefited from the financial crisis.

56. Zaring Reference Zaring1998, 288.

57. Even for a top scholar writing a BCBS history, access to its archives was granted under special permission only, not all archives were made available, and access was restricted to pre-1998. Nout Wellink in Goodhart Reference Goodhart2011, ix–x.

58. This statement is a generalization of all Financial Times and Wall Street Journal newspaper coverage surrounding the events. One exception is a leak on the Japanese market just prior to Event 5.

59. Young Reference Young2013.

60. Bair Reference Bair2012, 257–72, especially 266.

61. I make no assumptions that investors’ motivations to trade a regulated stock are consistent with efficient market theories, behavioral theories, or both. In reaction to Basel III information, stock price change through either mechanism provides evidence of perceived credibility and distributional effects. For an overview of the efficient market hypothesis and behavioral theory challenges, see Malkiel Reference Malkiel2003; and Kindleberger Reference Kindleberger2005, 38–63. For examples of behavioral theories across time, see Kindleberger Reference Kindleberger2005; Galbraith Reference Galbraith1954, 71–92; and Akerlof and Shiller Reference Akerlof and Shiller2009.

62. Specifically, the Center for Research in Security Prices’ (CRSP's) holding period return.

63. The logic is not that BCBS announcements about Basel III are the only events leading to systematic returns. Instead, conditional on a Basel III negotiating announcement, an effect is expected if investors follow negotiation news about the international agreement. Media reports on announcement days reveal no obvious news that might affect all large banks but not the market as a whole, which might confound interpretation of announcement days as reaction to Basel III; an exception is Event 3 that occurred just before the US Dodd-Frank Act was signed into law.

64. The first trading day following each event is 8 September 2009 and 13 September 2010, respectively.

65. Theoretically, the firms could leave because of bankruptcy or enter if they experience high growth or through mergers. For this sample, however, no firms grow to become large enough to meet the threshold during this period, and firms that go bankrupt are excluded because of the criterion that trading data must be available for all trading days during 2009 and 2010.

66. Size threshold is based on the Federal Reserve's standard to identify the largest banks (called Peer 1 banks). The sample is the largest set of banks meeting all of the following criteria: (1) the bank must be publicly traded on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), the American Stock Exchange (AMEX), or the NASDAQ exchanges; (2) the bank must be US-headquartered (that is, federally incorporated in the United States); (3) the bank must be actively traded on all trading days between 2 January 2009 and 31 December 2010; (4) the bank must have regulatory capital data available for Q1 2009; and (5) the bank must be designated by the Federal Reserve as a Peer 1 Bank Holding Company as of Q1 2009. Stock data come from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP), regulatory capital data come from Compustat, and the Federal Reserve Bank Holding company designation comes from BHCPR Peer Group Average Reports. The sample excludes First Bancorp PR (NYSE: FBP), which meets the criteria but was identified as an outlier firm.

67. More specifically, each of the 2,884 firms meet all of the following criteria: (1) nonfinancial firms (SIC code < 6000 or SIC code > 6999); (2) that trade on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), American Stock Exchange (AMEX), or NASDAQ stock exchanges; and (3) had active trading data on all trading days between 1 January 2009 through 11 April 2011. Stock price and SIC code data come from CRSP.

68. For an overview of event study calculations and intuition, see MacKinlay Reference MacKinlay1997; and Corrado Reference Corrado2011. For event study methodological issues, see McWilliams and Siegel Reference McWilliams and Siegel1997.

69. There are many dimensions to the Basel III regulation that investors might care about—including level of capital, definition of capital and risk-weights, and implementation timeline—such that an additional determination would have to be made about how to collapse these dimensions into one measure.

70. Prominent extensions use multiple measures of stock market performance, yet the general critique remains. Fama and French Reference Fama and French2014 have a three-factor model (with three regressors capturing overall market, firm size, and market-to-book ratio) and Carhart Reference Carhart1997 has a four-factor model (using the Fama-French regressors plus a measure of stock return momentum).

71. “Fortune 500 2009,” Fortune. Available at <http://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/fortune500/2009/full_list/>, accessed 1 July 2013.

72. See Tibshirani Reference Tibshirani1996; and Hastie, Tibshirani, and Friedman Reference Hastie, Tibshirani and Friedman2009, 68–72. In all specifications I use fivefold cross-validation to produce a series of 100 lambda and select the largest lambda within one standard deviation of the minimum.

73. Of 2,884 nonfinancial firms that are potential regressors, the Lasso constraint identified 17.5 regressors, on average, for twenty-day estimation windows.

74. Adjusted R 2 controls for the number of regressors. Separating by individual events, or creating a parallel plot for 180-day estimation window, does not meaningfully change the shape or distribution of each curve.

75. Specifically, for each event, I calculated RMSE using Lasso regression and the traditional approach for five random samples of 200 randomly selected nonfinancial firms without replacement. In each of the twenty-five samples (five samples for each of the five events) the Lasso regression consistently had significantly lower RMSE. For summary purposes, pooling the twenty-five samples, average RMSE for Lasso was 0.039 (with a range between 0.002 to 0.261) versus 0.392 for the traditional approach (with a range between 0.167 and 0.600). Among the average RMSE values, Lasso is ten times lower than the traditional approach, while taking the relative RMSE values (traditional versus Lasso) for each observation results in the average forty-three times referenced in the text.

76. Chatterjee and Lahiri Reference Chatterjee and Lahiri2011 show their modified bootstrap process yields a consistent confidence interval for Lasso estimators. The specific process first entails calculating the set of residuals from the set of regulated firms’ expected stock returns on an event day. The set of residuals is sampled, with replacement, and added to the fitted values of the original data to create a new sample of (bootstrapped) observed stock returns. For each of 100 bootstrapped samples per event, I use bootstrapped observed returns to reestimate Abnormal Firm Return and calculate Average Announcement Effect. Assuming a normal distribution, I obtain 95 percent confidence intervals using point estimates from the bootstrapped sample data and standard deviation calculated from the bootstrapped samples.

77. Event 1 occurs on the 172nd day of trading data, so the estimation window for Event 1's third model is [–171, –1] instead of [–180, –1]. Alternative anticipation periods, including five trading days prior to each announcement, or an event-specific anticipation period based on media reports, do not change substantive results.

78. Again, a forty-sixth firm, First Bancorp PR (NYSE: FBP), meets all criteria in note 66, but was identified as an outlier firm driving net effect direction and therefore removed from the sample.

79. Tokyo Stock Exchange data are from Compustat, and potential regressors for these banks are the full set of (between 2,304 and 2,390) nonfinancial firms that trade on the Tokyo Stock Exchange. Data for foreign-headquartered banks that trade on US stock exchange are from CSRP.

80. For each randomly selected firm that I treat as a financial firm, I limit possible estimates to firms outside the selected firm's industry at the broadest, one-digit SIC specification.

81. Citigroup's previous closing day price was $4.85 with 11.3 billion stock shares outstanding, and Bank of America's previous close was $17.09 with 8.65 billion shares outstanding.

82. To estimate the total cost of Basel III for regulated firms would additionally require measuring effects through domestic implementation. Distinct from the opaque international negotiations and subsequent press release reports, domestic implementation lacks clear new information events to justify a similar event study research design.

83. Recent work on legal institutional variation focuses upon preferential trade agreements (PTAs), bilateral investment treaties (BITs), and other issue areas. Respectively, Dür, Baccini, and Elsig Reference Dür, Baccini and Elsig2014; Allee and Peinhardt Reference Allee and Peinhardt2014; and Koremenos Reference Koremenos2016. Related work emphasizes the rise of nonformal international organizations. Abbott, Green, and Keohane Reference Abbott, Green and Keohane2016.

84. Keohane Reference Keohane1984, 102, 107.

85. See Gray Reference Gray2013; Simmons Reference Simmons2001; and Drezner Reference Drezner2007.

86. See Haas Reference Haas1992; Chwieroth Reference Chwieroth2007; and Bodea and Hicks Reference Bodea and Hicks2015.

87. Tom Braithwaite and Patrick Jenkins, “JPMorgan Says Basel Rules ‘Anti-US’,” Financial Times, 12 September 2011, 1. Specifically, the Financial Times quoted Dimon as saying, “I'm very close to thinking the United States shouldn't be in Basel any more. I would not have agreed to rules that are blatantly anti-American … Our regulators should go [to the BCBS] and say: If it's not in the interests of the United States, we're not doing it.”

88. See Claessens, Underhill, and Zhang Reference Claessens, Underhill and Zhang2008; and Baker Reference Baker2013.

References

Abbott, Kenneth W., Green, Jessica F., and Keohane, Robert O.. 2016. Organizational Ecology and Institutional Change in Global Governance. International Organization 70 (2):247–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbott, Kenneth W., Keohane, Robert O., Moravcsik, Andrew, and Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2000. The Concept of Legalization. International Organization 54 (3):401–19.Google Scholar
Abbott, Kenneth W., and Snidal, Duncan. 2000. Hard and Soft Law in International Governance. International Organization 54 (3):421–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Admati, Anat, and Hellwig, Martin. 2013. The Bankers’ New Clothes: What's Wrong with Banking and What to Do About It. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Shiller, Robert. 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Allee, Todd, and Peinhardt, Clint. 2014. Evaluating Three Explanations for the Design of Bilateral Investment Treaties. World Politics 66 (1):4787.Google Scholar
Allee, Todd L., and Scalera, Jamie E.. 2012. The Divergent Effects of Joining International Organizations: Trade Gains and the Rigors of WTO Accession. International Organization 66 (2):243–76.Google Scholar
Baccini, Leonardo, and Urpelainen, Johannes. 2015. Cutting the Gordian Knot of Economic Reform: When and How Institutions Help. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bach, David, and Newman, Abraham L.. 2010. Transgovernmental Networks and Domestic Policy Convergence: Evidence from Insider Trading Regulation. International Organization 64 (3):505–28.Google Scholar
Bach, David, and Newman, Abraham L.. 2014. The European Union as Hardening Agent: Soft Law and the Diffusion of Global Financial Regulation. Journal of European Public Policy 21 (3):430–52.Google Scholar
Bair, Sheila. 2012. Bull by the Horns: Fighting to Save Main Street from Wall Street and Wall Street from Itself. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Baker, Andrew. 2013. The New Political Economy of the Macroprudential Ideational Shift. New Political Economy 18 (1):112–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS). 1988. International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards. Basel, Switzerland: BCBS. Available at <http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs04a.pdf>..>Google Scholar
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS). 2004. International Convergence of Capital Measurement and Capital Standards: A Revised Framework. Basel, Switzerland: BCBS. Available at <http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs107.pdf>..>Google Scholar
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS). 2015. Basel Committee Membership. Available at <http://www.bis.org/bcbs/membership.htm>. Accessed 29 November 2015. Basel, Switzerland: BCBS..+Accessed+29+November+2015.+Basel,+Switzerland:+BCBS.>Google Scholar
Bechtel, Michael M., and Schneider, Gerald. 2010. Eliciting Substance from “Hot Air”: Financial Market Responses to EU Summit Decisions on European Defense. International Organization 64 (2):199223.Google Scholar
Bodea, Cristina, and Hicks, Raymond. 2015. Price Stability and Central Bank Independence: Discipline, Credibility, and Democratic Institutions. International Organization 69 (1):3561.Google Scholar
Brummer, Chris. 2011. How International Financial Law Works (and How It Doesn't). Georgetown Law Journal 99 (2):257327.Google Scholar
Carhart, Mark M. 1997. On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Finance 52 (1):5782.Google Scholar
Chatterjee, Arindam, and Lahiri, Soumendra Nath. 2011. Bootstrapping Lasso Estimators. Journal of the American Statistical Association 106 (494):608–25.Google Scholar
Chwieroth, Jeffrey. 2007. Neoliberal Economists and Capital Account Liberalization in Emerging Markets. International Organization 61 (2):443–63.Google Scholar
Claessens, Stijn, Underhill, Geoffrey R.D., and Zhang, Xiaoke. 2008. The Political Economy of Basle II: The Costs for Poor Countries. World Economy 31 (3):313–44.Google Scholar
Corrado, Charles J. 2011. Event Studies: A Methodology Review. Accounting and Finance 51 (1):207–34.Google Scholar
Dai, Xinyuan. 2007. International Institutions and National Policies. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Barsoom, Peter N.. 1996. Is the Good News About Compliance Good News About Cooperation? International Organization 50 (3):379406.Google Scholar
Drezner, Daniel W. 2007. All Politics Is Global: Explaining International Regulatory Regimes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dür, Andreas, Baccini, Leonardo, and Elsig, Manfred. 2014. The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a New Dataset. Review of International Organizations 9 (3):353–75.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. 2014. International Policy Coordination: The Long View. In Globalization in an Age of Crisis: Multilateral Economic Cooperation in the Twenty-First Century, edited by Feenstra, Robert C. and Taylor, Alan M., 4382. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Fama, Eugene F., and French, Kenneth R.. 2014. Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33 (1):356.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1998. Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation. International Organization 52 (2):269305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gadinis, Stavros. 2008. The Politics of Competition in International Financial Regulation. Harvard International Law Journal 49 (2):447507.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1954. The Great Crash 1929. Cambridge, UK: Riverside Press.Google Scholar
General Accounting Office. (GAO). 1991. International Banking: Implementation of Risk-Based Capital Adequacy Standards. Report to the Chairmen, Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, US Senate, and Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, US House of Representatives GAO/NSIAD-91-80. Washington, DC: GAO. Available at <http://www.gao.gov/products/NSIAD-91-80>..>Google Scholar
General Accounting Office. (GAO). 2012. Bank Capital Requirements: Potential Effects of New Changes on Foreign Holding Companies and US Banks Abroad. Report to Congressional Committees GAO-12-235. Washington, DC: GAO. Available at <http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-12-235>..>Google Scholar
Goodhart, Charles. 2011. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: A History of the Early Years, 1974–1997. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gray, Julia. 2013. The Company States Keep: International Economic Organizations and Investor Perceptions. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Haas, Peter M. 1992. Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coordination. International Organization 46 (1):135.Google Scholar
Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Victor, David G., and Lupu, Yonatan. 2012. Political Science Research on International Law: The State of the Field. American Journal of International Law 106 (1):4797.Google Scholar
Hastie, Trevor, Tibshirani, Robert, and Friedman, Jerome. 2009. The Elements of Statistical Learning: Data Mining, Inference, and Prediction. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Helleiner, Eric. 2010. What Role for the New Financial Stability Board? The Politics of International Standards After the Crisis. Global Policy 1 (3):282–90.Google Scholar
International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO). 2015. Ordinary Members of IOSCO. Available at <https://www.iosco.org/about/?subsection=membership&memid=1>. Accessed 29 November 2015. Madrid, Spain: IOSCO..+Accessed+29+November+2015.+Madrid,+Spain:+IOSCO.>Google Scholar
Johnston, Alastair Iain. 2001. Treating International Institutions as Social Environments. International Studies Quarterly 45 (4):487515.Google Scholar
Kahler, Miles, and Lake, David A.. 2009. Economic Integration and Global Governance: Why So Little Supranationalism? In The Politics of Global Regulation, edited by Walter Mattli and Ngaire Woods , 242–75. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B. 1989. Resolving the Regulator's Dilemma: International Coordination of Banking Regulations. International Organization 43 (2):323–47.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B. 1991. Supervising International Banks: Origins and Implications of Basle Accord. Unpublished manuscript, Princeton Studies in International Economics, International Economics Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B. 1994. Governing the Global Economy: International Finance and the State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O., and Nye, Joseph S.. 1977. Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition. Boston, MA: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Kim, Soo Yeon. 2010. Power and the Governance of Global Trade: From the GATT to the WTO. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P. 2005. Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara. 2016. The Continent of International Law: Explaining Agreement Design. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles, and Snidal, Duncan. 1991. Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier. World Politics 43 (3):336–66.Google Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles, and Snidal, Duncan. 2001. The Rational Design of International Institutions. International Organization 55 (4):761–99.Google Scholar
Lipson, Charles. 1991. Why Are Some International Agreements Informal? International Organization 45 (4):495538.Google Scholar
MacKinlay, A. Craig. 1997. Event Studies in Economics and Finance. Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1):1339.Google Scholar
Malkiel, Burton G. 2003. The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (1):5982.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 2013. Against Compliance. In International Law and International Relations: Synthesizing Insights from Interdisciplinary Scholarship, edited by Dunoff, Jeffrey L. and Pollack, Mark, 591610. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McWilliams, Abagail, and Siegel, Donald. 1997. Event Studies in Management Research: Theoretical and Empirical Issues. Academy of Management Journal 40 (3):626–57.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John. 1995. The False Promise of International Institutions. International Security 19 (3):549.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1995. Explaining International Human Rights Regimes: Liberal Theory and Western Europe. European Journal of International Relations 1 (2):157–89.Google Scholar
Oatley, Thomas, and Nabors, Robert. 1998. Redistributive Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord. International Organization 52 (1):3554.Google Scholar
Pauwelyn, Joost, Wessel, Ramses A., and Wouters, Jan, eds. 2012. Informal International Lawmaking. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pelc, Krzysztof J. 2013. Googling the WTO: What Search Engine Data Tell Us About the Political Economy of Institutions. International Organization 67 (3):629–55.Google Scholar
Pevehouse, Jon. 2002. Democracy from the Outside-In? International Organizations and Democratization. International Organization 56 (3):515–49.Google Scholar
Pevehouse, Jon, Nordstrom, Timothy, and Warnke, Kevin. 2004. The Correlates of War 2 International Governmental Organizations Data Version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science 21 (2):101–19.Google Scholar
Porter, Tony. 2005. Globalization and Finance. Malden, MA: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Seabrooke, Leonard, and Tsingou, Eleni. 2014. Distinctions, Affiliations, and Professional Knowledge in Financial Reform Expert Groups. Journal of European Public Policy 21 (3):389407.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2000. International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs. American Political Science Review 94 (4):819–35.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2001. The International Politics of Harmonization: The Case of Capital Market Regulation. International Organization 55 (3):589620.Google Scholar
Singer, David Andrew. 2004. Capital Rules: The Domestic Politics of International Regulatory Harmonization. International Organization 58 (3):531–65.Google Scholar
Singer, David Andrew. 2007. Regulating Capital: Setting Standards for the International Financial System. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 1997. The Real New World Order. Foreign Affairs 76 (5):183–97.Google Scholar
Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2004. A New World Order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Strange, Susan. 1982. “Cave! Hic Dragones”: A Critique of Regime Analysis. International Organization 36 (2):479–96.Google Scholar
Tarullo, Daniel K. 2008. Banking on Basel: The Future of International Financial Regulation. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Tibshirani, Robert. 1996. Regression Shrinkage and Selection via the Lasso. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological) 58 (1):267–88.Google Scholar
Vabulas, Felicity, and Snidal, Duncan. 2013. Organization Without Delegation: Informal Intergovernmental Organizations (IIGOs) and the Spectrum of Intergovernmental Arrangements. Review of International Organizations 8 (2):193220.Google Scholar
Verdier, Pierre-Hugues. 2009. Transnational Regulatory Networks and Their Limits. Yale Journal of International Law 34 (1):113–72.Google Scholar
Von Stein, Jana. 2005. Do Treaties Constrain or Screen? Selection Bias and Treaty Compliance. American Political Science Review 99 (4):611–22.Google Scholar
Walter, Andrew. 2008. Governing Finance: East Asia's Adoption of International Standards. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Wood, Duncan. 2005. Governing Global Banking: The Basel Committee and the Politics of Financial Globalisation. Burlington, VT: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Young, Kevin. 2013. Financial Industry Groups’ Adaptation to the Post-Crisis Regulatory Environment: Changing Approaches to the Policy Cycle. Regulation and Governance 7 (4):460–80.Google Scholar
Zaring, David. 1998. International Law By Other Means: The Twilight Existence of International Financial Regulatory Organizations. Texas International Law Journal 33 (2):281330.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Basel III negotiations occurred within five BCBS meetings between September 2009 and December 2010

Figure 1

Figure 1. Regulated bank and stock market indices, 2 January 2008 to 31 December 2012

Figure 2

Figure 2. Calculating firm abnormal return, illustrative example

Figure 3

Figure 3. Comparing in-sample (historic) and out-of-sample (predictive) fit across estimation methods

Figure 4

Figure 4. Average Announcement Effect on event days, base specification and placebo (left) and base specification and foreign-headquartered firms (right)

Figure 5

Figure 5. Average Announcement Effect on event days, base specification, and alternative estimation windows

Figure 6

Figure 6. Implied equity effect on event days

Supplementary material: File

Wilf supplementary material

Wilf supplementary material

Download Wilf supplementary material(File)
File 30.9 MB