Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-13T20:40:28.337Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Organization Theory in Business and Management History: Present Status and Future Prospects

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 August 2017

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

A common lament is that business history has been marginalized within mainstream business and management research. We propose that the remedy lies in part with more extensive engagement with organization theory. We illustrate our argument by exploring the potentialities for business history of three cognitive frameworks: institutional entrepreneurship, evolutionary theory, and Bourdieusian social theory. Exhibiting a higher level of theoretical fluency might enable business historians to accrue scholarly capital within the business and management field by producing theoretically informed historical discourse, demonstrating the potential of business history to extend theory, generate constructs, and elucidate complexities in unfolding relationships, situations, and events.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The President and Fellows of Harvard College 2017 

Business history has long been critiqued as lacking engagement with mainstream debates in business and management research. An overall criticism that it eschews the “big questions” of substance and consequence in social-scientific research implies that the field is somewhat introspective, overly narrow, and rather fragmented and thus neglects numerous themes and issues within the broad natural purview of the field.Footnote 1 Two related problems have been identified that have limited the appeal of business history and its accessibility to management and organization scholars. First, there is a lack of generalizability of its findings. Narratives tend to be very particular in relation to firms, locations, and time periods, emphasizing uniqueness, such that “it is not clear that historical settings, fine veined and particular as they may be, ever repeat themselves.”Footnote 2 Second, there is a lack of engagement with theory. This stems in part, according to Scott Taylor, Emma Bell, and Bill Cooke, from business history's own disinclination to specify the foundational but “hidden epistemological (and therefore theoretical) position” that underlies the historiographical operation.Footnote 3 These scholars are not alone in implying that business historians are to some degree the authors of their own marginalization in the wider field of management research—reluctant to grapple with and often dismissive of relevant conceptual lenses, failing to contribute significantly to interdisciplinary conversations, and seemingly preferring their own “solitude” to meaningful interaction with organization theory.Footnote 4

These deficiencies have long been recognized within the business history community itself. Business historians have lamented their lack of expertise in harnessing the power of theory, their appearance too often as “fact-mongers without theory,” and their consequent need to blend theory and history together to produce more incisive research.Footnote 5 It is increasingly acknowledged that complex, detailed, book-length studies, while still prized in history departments, may not always be the best outlets to amplify business history research and engage more broadly with the business and management scholarly community, which increasingly privileges journal articles.Footnote 6 While business historians have found homes in different types of schools and departments in different countries—including history in the United States and economics in Japan—many are based in business schools, especially in the United Kingdom, whose ranking is determined partly by the perceived quality of the journals in which their researchers publish. Allied to this is greater cognizance that the field, as it currently stands, exhibits a continued lack of reflexivity, maturity, and sophistication with regard to methodologies.Footnote 7 Methodological transparency is increasingly necessary for both interdisciplinary dialogue and scholarly legitimacy, as well as for publication in top management journals that the present preoccupation with business school rankings demands. There is greater willingness to recognize the requirement to broaden business history's cross-disciplinary appeal through more internationally comparative research that is “analytical, creative, and bold,” embracing other geographies.Footnote 8 This is accompanied by increasing awareness that the field has been contorted by a preponderance of American corporate ideas, assumptions, business models, and practices, promoting Western-style rationality and “narrative imperialism.”Footnote 9 Arguably, this has discouraged ethnic diversity.Footnote 10 It may also have limited engagement with “the other.”Footnote 11 These alleged failings, along with proposed solutions, are articulated in Table 1. In short, there is a growing consensus among many business historians of the need to move with the times, tempori parendum.

Table 1 Business History: Perceived Failings and Recommended Solutions

Sources: Charles Booth and Michael Rowlinson, “Management and Organizational History: Prospects,” Management & Organizational History 1, no. 1 (2006): 5–30; Walter A. Friedman and Geoffrey Jones, “Business History: Time for Debate,” Business History Review 85, no. 1 (2011): 1–8; John R. Hall, “Where History and Sociology Meet: Forms of Discourse and Sociohistorical Inquiry,” Sociological Theory 10, no. 2 (1992): 164–93; Charles Harvey and Geoffrey Jones, “Business History in Britain into the 1990s,” Business History 32, no. 1 (1990): 5–16; Naomi R. Lamoreaux, Daniel M. G. Raff, and Peter Temin, “Economic Theory and Business History,” in Geoffrey Jones and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., Oxford Handbook of Business History (Oxford, 2007), 37–66; Kenneth J. Lipartito, “The Future of Alfred Chandler,” Enterprise & Society 9, no. 3 (2008): 430–32; Kenneth Lipartito and David B. Sicilia, Constructing Corporate America: History, Politics, Culture (Oxford, 2004); Mairi Maclean, Charles Harvey, and Stewart R. Clegg, “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies,” Academy of Management Review 41, no. 4 (2016): 609–32; Daniel M. G. Raff, “How to Do Things with Time,” Enterprise & Society 14, no. 3 (2013): 435–66; Christine M. Rosen, “What Is Business History?” Enterprise & Society 14, no. 3 (2013): 475–85; Michael Rowlinson, John Hassard, and Stephanie Decker, “Strategies for Organizational History: A Dialogue between Historical Theory and Organization Theory,” Academy of Management Review 39 (2014): 250–74; Philip Scranton and Patrick Fridenson, Reimagining Business History (Baltimore, 2013); George Steinmetz, “The Relations between Sociology and History in the United States: The Current State of Affairs,” Journal of Historical Sociology 20, no. 1–2 (2007a): 1–12; George Steinmetz, “Transdisciplinarity as a Nonimperial Encounter: For an Open Sociology,” Thesis Eleven 91, no. 1 (2007b): 48–65; Scott Taylor, Emma Bell, and Bill Cooke, “Business History and the Historiographical Operation,” Management & Organizational History 4, no. 2 (2009): 151–66; Mira Wilkins, “Business History as a Discipline,” Business and Economic History, vol. 17 (1988): 1–7.

Those writers who have explored avenues for a fruitful synthesis between history and management research have tended to do so largely from the perspective of the latter rather than the former.Footnote 12 In other words, their primary concern is what history can bring to organization studies; far less frequently are they concerned with the converse: how organization theory can enrich business history. Herein lies the purpose of the present paper. We advance the proposition that business history should “come in from the cold” to play a more central role in business and management research. Doing this, we suggest, demands higher levels of theoretical fluency in business history research—a command of an appropriate conceptual language—than are presently found in most business history publications.Footnote 13 We illustrate this argument with particular reference to the potentialities for fruitful engagement with organization theory, much of which is germane to business and management history. We follow Haridimos Tsoukas and Christian Knudsen in defining organization theory here simply as “the academic field specializing in the study of organizational phenomena (both micro and macro).”Footnote 14 Greater engagement with organization theory might benefit the field by demonstrating the potential of business history research to explain the past and illuminate the present, highlighting both continuities and discontinuities in long-term organizational and institutional trajectories while simultaneously embracing a “forward-looking perspective” that harnesses “‘futures past’ . . . different pasts to address present concerns and to highlight future possibilities.”Footnote 15

In progressing our argument, we pose three principal questions. First, why do business and management academics typically prize theory development as integral to their research? Second, what can organization theory contribute to business historians, and which cognitive frameworks might lend themselves to application in business history research, helping business historians to theorize their accounts? Finally, what precisely is needed if business historians are to benefit from increased engagement with organization theory and thereby increase the reach and impact of their research?

Our paper is structured as follows. In the next section, we explain why theory, theorization, and theoretical development take center stage in business and management research, highlighting some of the ways that organization theory can illuminate business history research. We next seek to demonstrate the potential for business historians to engage fruitfully with organization theory, in ways that enable theory to illuminate and explain the past, with the rich data of business history helping to refine existing theoretical ideas as well as to develop new ones. We illustrate our argument with reference to three established bodies of organizational theory: institutional entrepreneurship, evolutionary theory, and Bourdieusian social theory. In our final main section, we examine more closely the requirements for extensive engagement with theory in business history research. In particular, we consider five key principles of historical organization studies—dual integrity, pluralistic understanding, representational truth, context sensitivity, and theoretical fluency—that make for a better, more seamless interplay between history and organization theory, doing so from a business historical perspective.Footnote 16 We conclude by discussing the benefits to business history and its practitioners of greater alignment of agendas and practices with the mainstream of business and management research.

Theory in Business and Management Research

The growing consensus on the part of business historians of the need to move with the times has been aided in recent years by the advent of a “historic turn” in business and management research, characterized by increasing attention to longitudinal studies and historical contexts.Footnote 17 This historic turn was prompted by a recognition among management researchers that organizational research was too often relatively timeless and ahistorical, failing to engage sufficiently with history and hence adequately to capture and reflect the rich “historicity of organizational life.”Footnote 18 This turn has now gathered fresh momentum, with recent research having played a key role in invigorating the discussion, prompting renewed calls for a rapprochement between the two disciplines.Footnote 19 Michael Rowlinson, John Hassard, and Stephanie Decker emphasize three salient epistemological dualisms that need to be overcome if meaningful interaction between organization studies and traditional narrative history is to ensue.Footnote 20 These dualisms relate to explanation, evidence, and temporality. The authors observe that management research promotes analysis over narration, self-generated data above the discovery of documentary evidence, and chronological or calendar time over periodization. Similarly, Matthias Kipping and Behlül Üsdiken propose three ways in which history might embrace organization theory at various levels of analysis: namely, as a way of testing theory (called “history to theory”); of permeating theoretical perspectives (“history in theory”); and of embedding historical complexity within the theorization exercise per se (“historical cognizance”).

Mairi Maclean, Charles Harvey, and Stewart Clegg take further the notion of developing a creative synthesis between history and organization studies in conceptualizing historical organization studies.Footnote 21 Historical organization studies incorporates historical data, methods, and knowledge, situating organizing and organizations within their sociohistorical contexts to engender historically informed theoretical narratives mindful of both disciplines, sensitive to evolving interpretations over time and the sedimentation of preexisting patterns. Building on extant research, these authors suggest a typology of four distinct conceptions of history in organizational research: history as evaluating (testing and refining existing theory), as explicating (applying and developing theory to reveal the operation of transformative social processes), as conceptualizing (generating new theoretical constructs), and as narrating (explaining the form and origins of significant contemporary phenomena).

A recent noteworthy volume edited by Marcelo Bucheli and Daniel Wadhwani likewise advances the use of historical methods and reasoning in organizational research. Importantly, this urges a historical perspective that demands “new ways of acting and not just new ways of thinking.Footnote 22 As Bucheli and Wadhwani insist, for the historic turn to realize its full promise requires that business historians are prepared to reevaluate and reorient their own institutionalized practices with greater intellectual boldness than they have displayed thus far, seizing the conspicuous opportunities that the historic turn in management research has indubitably provided. Yet despite the recent flurry of scholarly activity around this notion of a historic turn, business history research arguably remains cast in the classical mold of historical enquiry in which empirical research is valued mainly for its own sake, irrespective of audience size or whether or not it contributes to a collective, thematic endeavor. Reaching out to address the interests and concerns of a much wider constituency of potential readers might result in the “bigger tent” highlighted by Donald Hambrick as necessary to enhance scholarly impact, while helping to reengage the field at the center of broader economic, social, political, and cultural discourses and movements.Footnote 23

Business history has been defined by Mira Wilkins as a subject concerned with “the study of the growth and development of business as an institution.”Footnote 24 As such it pertains, as Daniel Raff observes, to “firms in an essential way: what happens among firms, and what happens within firms.”Footnote 25 In analogous fashion, Gerald Davis describes organization theory as being “broadly concerned with organizations and organizing, with a particular (but not exclusive) emphasis on organizations as distinct, countable units of analysis.”Footnote 26 Davis emphasizes the importance of periodization, pointing out that “empirical generalizations that are true during one period may be false in a different period”; he therefore encourages attentiveness to temporality, calling for “carefully done research that yields insights into particular processes at particular times.”Footnote 27 It is clear from these interrelated definitions that the two disciplines share much common ground. A conceptual interplay between the two would seem therefore to hold considerable promise.

Theory in business and management research, according to Hambrick, concerns the quest for explanation.Footnote 28 Theory aids the organization of thought processes, the articulation of cogent arguments, leading to improved projections and thereby enhancing comprehension. While business historians weave explanation into their narrative accounts so as to enhance understanding, organization scholars typically seek an explanatory theory as a point of departure for empirical studies.Footnote 29 Thus, an inherent tension exists between narrative accounts, whose character is primarily interpretive, and evaluative, theoretically informed accounts concerned with exposition.Footnote 30 Hüseyin Leblebici describes these contrasting approaches as follows: management researchers view theory as paramount “in order to select relevant facts, to search for generalizable causal mechanisms, to accumulate evidence . . . and to ultimately test theories and generate better theories.”Footnote 31 Business historians conversely “have their own explanatory theories even though these theories are expressed implicitly. The narrative form of the organizational historian is in a sense a form of theoretical explanation.”Footnote 32 Paul Ricoeur regards the apparent dichotomy between explanation and understanding as intrinsically false, insisting that these are not mutually exclusive but rather “relative moments in a complex process called interpretation.”Footnote 33 Nonetheless, it is important to clarify that business history research is not devoid of theory. The search for “patterns (for continuities and discontinuities) in the development of enterprise” advocated by Wilkins contains the rudiments of theory building.Footnote 34 It therefore facilitates new ways of seeing that enable researchers to “see things together” in order to link particular situations and contexts and thereby discern the bigger picture.Footnote 35 Indeed, it is precisely because business history is not atheoretical but encompasses the foundations of theory that a fruitful dialogue with organization theory has such potential.

The work of Alfred Chandler is emblematic in this regard, with his oeuvre proving generative, indicative of business history's conceptual potential. Chandler fashioned constructs in each of his three master works that were influential in shaping research agendas within business and management, through which he elucidated the emergence of managerial capitalism.Footnote 36 In inductively deriving the proposition that structure follows strategy, with which he explained the growth of multidivisional enterprises, Chandler combined interpretation with an analytical framework.Footnote 37 His research embraced corporate, sectoral, and international comparisons.Footnote 38 Chandler's work has been criticized by some commentators for its apparent universalism, for ignoring the fact that managerial revolutions assume varying forms.Footnote 39 It has also been critiqued for its alleged unidirectional irreversibility of time, whereby “chains of cause and effect proceed in a path-dependent fashion.”Footnote 40 His work nevertheless injected the impetus to generalization that the discipline required.Footnote 41 Moreover, setting it in context—in “the broad sweep of a history . . . both complex and still unfolding”—arguably casts it in a new light, inviting reconceptualization.Footnote 42 Similarly, in his work on international business, Geoffrey Jones has been instrumental in promoting the international reach of business history research in a globalizing world in a way that embraces wide-ranging methodological approaches.Footnote 43 Together with Walter Friedman, Jones has advocated not only “dissension and debate” in unsettling assumptions but also an agenda that involves “the construction of broad frameworks.”Footnote 44 Given that management theory has been charged with failing to reflect the rich diversity of organizations in society, and given that about two-thirds of management research is estimated to be embedded in theories imported from other disciplines (as, for example, in population ecology and evolutionary theory), pursuit of the theoretical intersection between the two disciplines makes considerable sense.Footnote 45 If indigenous theory is to be generated, Roy Suddaby suggests, it is most likely to emerge from the domain of business history.Footnote 46

We contend that the reasons why business and management scholars prize organization theory, as outlined above, are also relevant to business historians. Studying a phenomenon through a given cognitive lens can generate new cross-disciplinary conversations. Recasting an event in a different conceptual light can trigger fresh insights that in turn challenge received views, putting the empirical terrain in a new perspective. Temporal-theoretical perspectives originating in one historical setting may be applied to other research contexts, improving understanding. Adoption of a theoretical lens stemming from organization theory can yield new comparative perspectives that might otherwise go unobserved, emphasizing links with similar studies to clarify the “bigger picture” by stretching time frames and expanding geographies, helping researchers to distinguish relations and processes diachronically.Footnote 47 As Stephen Lippmann and Howard Aldrich put it, “when researchers make more direct connections between their cases and other, similar cases, they strengthen the findings of business historians and others interested in historical organization studies.”Footnote 48

One question that arises is whether business historians actually see any purpose in searching for connections, seeking comparisons, analogies, and emerging patterns, or prefer instead to focus on particularities and the unique aspects of events and situations? However, we are not advocating a blueprint here that can be universally applied, but rather suggesting more and better sensemaking. Making connections between cases in this way is also a means of finding a pathway through them. As Tony Judt observes, “There are lots and lots of paths, real and potential, marked and unmarked, through this forest. The past is full of stuff. But if you don't have a path through it, you stare at the ground, you search for footing, you can't appreciate the trees.”Footnote 49 Given the constraints of a journal article, of course not all the opportunities that are possible can be explored. In what follows, we briefly suggest potential pathways drawn from organization theory that business historians might consider following, before alighting on three that hold particular promise in helping business historians to theorize their accounts: namely, institutional entrepreneurship, evolutionary theory, and Bourdieusian social theory.

Organization Theory and Business History

Numerous theoretical strands within organization studies contain a historical dynamic that resonates with business history. Organizational theories sensitive to the fundamental historicity of experience that promote a longitudinal approach include path dependence and associated theories encompassing structural inertia and imprinting.Footnote 50 Theory pertaining to the resource-based view of the firm and dynamic capabilities similarly strike a chord with historical research, alongside organizational ecology and organizational emergence.Footnote 51 Historians have been drawn to institutional theory and historical institutionalism.Footnote 52 Postmodernist and Foucauldian perspectives on genealogy have proved attractive, alongside organizational memory, entrepreneurship, process theory, strategic change, and strategy as practice.Footnote 53 Sensemaking, storytelling, and discourse analysis likewise lend themselves to a business historical approach.Footnote 54

Space constraints do not permit us to explore each of these organizational frameworks at this juncture—and in numerous cases, other commentators have already highlighted their power to illuminate business history, providing robust exemplars of studies where the historical topic under scrutiny furnishes a springboard for theorization, with theory and topic elucidating each other on a reciprocal basis. A useful example is given by Andrew Popp and Robin Holt's study of historical entrepreneurship in nineteenth-century India, conducted through examination of personal letters written by the founders of a Calcutta merchant house, which presents entrepreneurial behavior as integral to and inseparable from the historical specificities of the times in which it was enacted.Footnote 55 Here we focus instead on three cognitive lenses drawn from organization theory, whose usage in business history we believe could be advantageously expanded to contribute to more meaningful encounters with historical data.

Institutional entrepreneurship

First coined by Paul DiMaggio in the 1980s, institutional entrepreneurship was conceived as a means of bringing endogenous agency back into the study of institutional change.Footnote 56 Institutional entrepreneurship focuses on the fundamental role played by prominent individuals in reconfiguring institutional landscapes in their favor by incorporating their own interests within the ensuing institution.Footnote 57 We adopt Royston Greenwood and Roy Suddaby's definition of an institutional entrepreneur as an actor who imagines and seeks to create “new institutions as a means of advancing interests they value highly.”Footnote 58 Business history is sometimes critiqued for concentrating too overtly on the lives of great men (and they are usually men), whose stories are deemed worth recording and to whom the bulk of “ego documents” relate—documents that give “an account of, or privileged information about, the ‘self’ who produced [them].”Footnote 59 In this way the activities of business leaders are privileged over those of ordinary individuals, who are undemocratically silenced in comparison.Footnote 60 However, institutional entrepreneurship arguably provides an opportunity for business historians to turn this to their advantage, since, as Hüseyin Leblebici, Gerald R. Salancik, Anne Copay, and Tom King insist, “only institutional entrepreneurs, who are organized and possess sufficient resources, are capable of introducing institutional change.”Footnote 61 According to Kamal Munir and Nelson Phillips, however, institutional theory lacks a coherent explanation for precisely how such actors achieve institutional change aligned to their own interests, thus inviting contributions from scholars with a grasp of historical detail and an accompanying interest in conceptualization.Footnote 62 Moreover, as the work of Douglass North amply illustrates, institutional change is by its nature a protracted process that occurs over a long time frame.Footnote 63 Business historians are therefore well placed to contribute significantly to this vibrant research agenda while making explicit its “assumptive historical dynamic that goes beyond mere temporality and which, largely, remains unarticulated.”Footnote 64

In their paper on Andrew Carnegie and his pioneering role in instigating the philanthropic field, Harvey, Maclean, Jillian Gordon, and Eleanor Shaw reexamine and reinterpret Carnegie's career as a world-making entrepreneur heavily engaged in institution building.Footnote 65 While Carnegie's ruthlessness toward clients, friends, and foes alike severely dented his reputation (especially his role in the 1892 Homestead strikes), he nevertheless used his political clout as a wealthy steel magnate turned philanthropist to set agendas, drive institutional change, and promote social improvement.Footnote 66 He set out the ethics of entrepreneurial philanthropy and put these into practice through the implementation of criteria-based grants on a hitherto unparalleled scale. As Neil Fligstein remarks, institutional entrepreneurs can on occasion forge “entirely new systems of meaning.”Footnote 67 Viewed through the lens of institutional entrepreneurship, Carnegie's pledge to invest socially almost all of his accumulated fortune in the course of his life reconfigured the philanthropic field.Footnote 68 It reset expectations for other wealthy individuals to emulate (including Rockefeller and Mellon but also, more recently, Gates and Buffet) while reframing the compact between rich and poor, enhancing the legitimacy of the former, according to which wealth could be enjoyed provided it was given away in the lifetime of the holder, on the premise that “he who dies rich dies disgraced.”Footnote 69

Evolutionary theory

According to Lippmann and Aldrich, evolutionary theory integrates both narrative and social scientific modes of approaching the study of organizations, embracing the theoretical and empirical advantages of each by combining an emphasis on uniqueness, contingency, and context with an equally weighted priority accorded to universal organizational processes.Footnote 70 This perspective joins hands with institutional theory in recognizing that organizations are inevitably fashioned by the contexts in which they were formed. However, whereas institutional theory lays emphasis on organizations absorbing and exuding the “rules, norms and ideologies of the wider society,” evolutionary theory is concerned less with political norms and more with the residue of historical origins that can endure from the point of an organization's creation over its ensuing life cycle.Footnote 71 As such, embracing an evolutionary perspective allows researchers to embed organizations within their historical contexts so as to link history and social structure, enabling researchers to “scan and collect a wealth of detailed studies on unique cases and comb them for similarities and differences.”Footnote 72

Lippmann and Aldrich draw on Victoria Johnson's study of the Paris Opera, which demonstrates that the circumstances of the Opera's origins at the moment of establishment became absorbed and sedimented within the institution, exerting a powerful influence for years to come.Footnote 73 In a similar vein, James Baron, Frank Dobbin, and Devereaux Jennings trace the origins of the personnel function in the United States to the demands of the state in a wartime economy, which bureaucratized employment relations.Footnote 74 They chart the evolution of bureaucratic controls that they attribute to the major role played by governmental requirements for information, which aided the growth in personnel professionals who collected, collated, and reported this data. In a similar vein, in exploring the development of firm capabilities in American bookselling, Raff shows that capabilities can persist, influencing the development trajectories of his two case companies over several decades—albeit going hand in hand with incremental evolutionary change. He demonstrates that the divergent routes followed by the two bookstores under study are explained in part by new decisions, but also by previous choices rooted in the firms’ early histories in response to specific contexts, such that “the value of the (historically) later innovations depends on the implementation of earlier ones.”Footnote 75 In this way, Raff integrates an emphasis on the persistence of the effects of company resources and capabilities with an emphasis on evolutionary adaptation over time.

The evolutionary approach therefore implies a prospective, future-oriented outlook that gives prominence to the longue durée prized by Fernand Braudel.Footnote 76 This privileges a bottom-up perspective that reappraises consideration of firm origins and choices relative to outcomes.Footnote 77 It pays attention in this way to company failures that do not stay the course and are often overlooked.Footnote 78 At the same time, it exemplifies how “historical analysis can add value by uncovering the long-run effects of particular choices.”Footnote 79 Business historians, with a predilection for long-term, often lengthy studies featuring detailed evidence, are well equipped to contribute to the growing body of research on evolving organizations; they require only a different “way of seeing” that entails a “forward-looking perspective and close attention to the development over time of selection environments.”Footnote 80

Bourdieusian social theory

Our third suggested pathway by which business historians might embrace historical organization studies concerns Bourdieusian social theory. Pierre Bourdieu is known as a sociologist and anthropologist, not as a historian, yet as Philip Gorski observes, he has the impulses of a historical analyst.Footnote 81 In particular, Bourdieu identified as one of his most enduring objectives “the development of a unified social science, in which history would become a historical sociology of the past and sociology would become a social history of the present.”Footnote 82 Bourdieu's oeuvre provides a conceptual arsenal that equips researchers for scrutinizing historical macrosocial change along the lines of the “big questions” highlighted by Friedman and Jones.Footnote 83 His “master concepts” of capital (economic, cultural, social, and symbolic resources), field (social spaces of objective relations between positions), and habitus (internalized dispositions) have attracted much attention from organization theorists.Footnote 84 They have also attracted the interest of business historians.Footnote 85 Bourdieu's theoretical armory—comprising field theory, capital theory, reflexivity, class dispositions, doxa, homologies and the field of power, and more—provides useful tools with which to illuminate the barriers that abound in organizational and social life, past and present.Footnote 86 This theoretical armory continues to hold considerable untapped potential. Particularly underutilized is his concept of the field of power, in which both the broad expanse of history and the social microprocesses that produced it are implicated, inviting further investigation at macro and micro levels, in which business historians are well positioned to play a leading role.Footnote 87

Harvey et al.’s above-mentioned article adopts a Bourdieusian perspective that positions Carnegie as an influential actor in the field of power of his day both in the United States and further afield.Footnote 88 Through his philanthropy, and aided by the apparent disinterestedness this denoted, Carnegie acted strategically to expand his stocks of social and symbolic capital and access to prized networks: “What stands out . . . strongly is that philanthropy repaid him handsomely in terms of cultural, social, and symbolic capital, increasing, not diminishing, his overall capital stock, and securing for him a position of influence as a multi-positional actor within the field of power.”Footnote 89

Bourdieu draws comparisons between the field of power and the intellectual field, which is similarly stratified and where analogous contests for control take place. He likens the intellectual field to “a magnetic field, made up of a system of power lines,” ruled by the logic of “competition for cultural legitimacy.”Footnote 90 Viewed in this light, the projects in which scholars engage are always, for Bourdieu, studies awaiting recognition through the “consecration of success” conferred by the field.Footnote 91 Field theory concerns the positioning of individual actors vis-à-vis others in the field.Footnote 92 As Fligstein observes, incumbent groups gain the most from fields, but challengers also benefit through survival, which can prove to be a springboard to a more central positioning within the field.Footnote 93 Bourdieu's comments therefore hold relevance for business historians, who are arguably located at the periphery of the business and management field.Footnote 94 Through more meaningful engagement with organization theory, business historians might assume a more empowered and central position within the “bigger tent” evoked by Hambrick, their legitimacy enhanced as a consequence. In parallel, strengthening their voice by reconnecting with popular debates in business and management research may allow them to target the prized mainstream organization journals at the heart of the field, which aspire to publish on matters that appeal to the many rather than the few.

Embracing Theory in Business History Research

In conceptualizing historical organization studies, Maclean, Harvey, and Clegg identify five principles critical to successfully marrying together the disciplines of history and organization studies: dual integrity (historical veracity and conceptual rigor), pluralistic understanding (openness to alternatives and different ways of seeing), representational truth (congruence between evidence, logic, and interpretation), context sensitivity (attentiveness to historical specificities), and theoretical fluency (command of the conceptual terrain).Footnote 95 We pose these principles as guides to help business historians to best incorporate organization theory within their research designs and working practices. How, we ask, might these principles be used to help guide business historians in this endeavor, while recognizing that they have preexisting strengths as well as potential limitations to overcome? For example, one might expect the work of business historians to exhibit a high degree of context sensitivity, but at the same time, they might struggle to match it with a corresponding level of theoretical fluency.

Dual integrity

As an overarching principle, dual integrity signifies shared respect for and demonstrable proficiency in history and organization studies, attributing equal status to both while striving to meet appropriate standards in each. Dual integrity concerns the production of historically informed theoretical narratives whose validity resides in historical veracity and conceptual rigor alike. Viewed from a business history angle, the emphasis here is clearly on the need for scholars to exhibit a sufficient understanding of and competence in organization theory, commensurate with their mastery of history. Competence in both disciplines is necessary to achieve authenticity, which in turn impinges on scholarly legitimacy.Footnote 96 Put simply, business historians can be taken more seriously by those in the business and management field if they learn to participate actively in the organization studies milieu. Legitimacy, Mark C. Suchman argues, demands “a relationship with an audience.”Footnote 97 More robust and theoretically informed research that relates more directly to the concerns of the business and management scholarly community may attract recognition from a wider audience than business history research traditionally has reached, with attendant status implications for the positioning of business historians within the field, meriting the investment required.

Pluralistic understanding

The principle of pluralistic understanding in the present context implies a need for business historians to open their minds to different perspectives and to display interdisciplinary curiosity, boldness, and breadth. Wilkins argues that examination of the “growth and development of business as an institution” should “never [be] narrow.”Footnote 98 Yet too circumscribed an interpretation of business history—as a discipline defined by its focus on the firm, on the basis that “the firm as an entity with its changing package of attributes is what commands attention”—precludes related issues that ought properly to fall within its broad ambit.Footnote 99 As Christine Rosen observes, the future of business history is unlikely to lie within an overly narrow compass, concerned with “purely internalist ways of conceptualizing our subject matter,” but instead should embrace organizational issues with far-reaching social impact.Footnote 100 Kenneth Lipartito argues that business historians need to expand their repertoire, adding texture in this way to current debates to which they have an obligation.Footnote 101 A strict understanding of the discipline is implicated in their relinquishing responsibility for framing the field.Footnote 102 There is a need for business history to reaffirm itself as an integrative discipline that elicits connections not only within firms and between firms but, more broadly, “between systems and people, between the tangible and intangible, and, of course, between the past and the present.”Footnote 103 A relaxation of boundary assumptions allowing greater porosity may boost interdisciplinary interplay and exchange, in particular with organization studies with which business history shares many common elements, enabling reengagement with contemporary debates that affect present society.

Representational truth

A potentially strong suit for business historians concerned with “getting it right,” representational truth emphasizes the importance of accounts consistently ringing true; it privileges “the testimony of the witness that provides correspondence between representation and the event” in order to maintain “the truth of historical discourse.”Footnote 104 It joins hands with Raff's notion of “contingent truth,” which does not seek to overclaim by asserting that a proposition holds true in all possible circumstances, but rather invokes “a coherence theory of truth . . . showing how various salient bits of evidence fit together.”Footnote 105 The search for historical veracity lays stress on economic actors and their actions, linking historical explanation with an empathetic understanding of human agency reminiscent of Max Weber's notion of Verstehen.Footnote 106 The quest for representational truth does not assume that the truth sought by the researcher is readily apparent; on the contrary, it may require unearthing.Footnote 107 In this way, it promotes bottom-up perspectives that lend themselves to “a return of the repressed,” whereby material that orthodox narratives may have overlooked or camouflaged surges back to “discreetly perturb the pretty order of a line of progress or a system of interpretation.”Footnote 108

Context sensitivity

Business historians are naturally attuned to the principle of context sensitivity. As Robin Collingwood underlines, “no historical fact can be truly ascertained until we have ascertained its relations with its context.”Footnote 109 Greater interaction between history and organization theory offers business historians the opportunity to display an in-depth, contextualized understanding of the issues under scrutiny. Sensibility to particular situations matters in research pertaining inter alia to organizational evolution, entrepreneurship, and industry emergence, with which context and contingency interact. Wadhwani and Jones highlight the embeddedness of specific entrepreneurial acts or organizations in the historical and temporal context(s) in which they were formed. This emphasis on the “temporality of entrepreneurship” and the significance of time and place stands in stark contrast to the bulk of organizational research, much of which is characterized by contextual limitation and exhibits only a cursory interest in the specificities of particular historical circumstances.Footnote 110 It fails in this way to encapsulate “the rich manifestation of organizations in society.”Footnote 111 Braudel likens researchers who lack context sensitivity to travelers who see always the same thing irrespective of the variegated countries and landscapes they traverse.Footnote 112 The context sensitivity of business historians, conversely, is likely to stand them in good stead when seeking to explain and articulate the dynamics of organizational change.

Theoretical fluency

Achieving theoretical fluency is perhaps the stiffest challenge for business historians in embracing the principles of historical organization studies; hence the purpose of this paper. Nevertheless, we believe that a fluid integration of organizational theory and historical empirical data is entirely feasible and attainable, targeting the intersection of theory with robust historical empirics by drawing out what is often already implicit. Collingwood maintains that contextual uniqueness in itself is not sufficient reason to eschew abstract rules, on the grounds that “uniqueness does not exclude points of identity with other unique cases.”Footnote 113 The organizational theories outlined above are all conducive to analytically structured history, with all knowledge proceeding, according to Braudel, “from the complex to the simple.”Footnote 114 Business historians are well equipped to propose hypotheses and typologies that contain answers to fundamental questions concerning the persistence of particular organizational forms; for example, why do some firms persist while others fail? Hence, existing theory can be refined through historical study. The inclination to theorize derives from a search for patterns and frameworks that allows particular events and phenomena to be seen in conjunction with other analogous circumstances and occurrences, enabling parallels and variations to be discerned in the trajectories of organizations across time and space and conclusions to be drawn accordingly.Footnote 115 While Collingwood suggests that imposing analytic schemas and templates can prove restrictive—arguing that “you cannot think historically by playing games with any formulae”—Michel de Certeau counters this by explaining that attributing contour and shape to evidence responds to a natural impulse to elicit order and structure: “History furnishes the empty frame of a linear succession which formally answers to questions on beginnings and to the need for order.”Footnote 116 Braudel likewise argues in favor of the “constant value” offered by conceptual models that enable researchers to see events and phenomena in combination:

Models are only hypotheses, systems of explanations tied solidly together in the form of an equation, or a function. . . . The carefully constructed model will thus allow us to inquire, throughout time and space, into other social environments similar to the observed social environment on the basis of which it was originally constructed. That is its constant value.Footnote 117

Ultimately, the very nature of business history, rooted as it is in specific geographical and temporal contexts, makes it fertile terrain for bottom-up inductive theorizing that grows out of rich descriptions of particular historical examples, with the potential to give rise to the indigenous theorization anticipated by Suddaby.

Conclusion

This article contributes to the burgeoning research promoting a fruitful synthesis between history and organization studies. Contrary to the majority of publications on this topic, however, it does so from the perspective of exploring what organization theory can contribute to business history. We revisit, nuance, and elaborate specifically for a business history readership five key principles of advancing historical organization studies—dual integrity, pluralistic understanding, representational truth, context sensitivity, and theoretical fluency—which we regard as conducive to conceptual interaction between history and organization theory. We exemplify this interplay with reference to three cognitive lenses amenable to application in business history: institutional entrepreneurship, evolutionary theory, and Bourdieusian social theory. These are intended not as exhaustive, but rather as illustrative. What, one may ask, might be lost with a tighter focus on theory? We suggest that there is no need to lose the rich contextual detail and situated understanding emblematic of many business historical studies. However, discourse is a form of capital, as de Certeau insists.Footnote 118 Like other forms of capital, it can be maintained, accrued, eroded, or forfeited. We suggest that by altering dispositions to embrace the conceptual language and analytical frameworks of organization theory, business historians can accumulate scholarly capital within this wider field by producing a more explicitly theoretically informed historical discourse. Aligning agendas and practices with the mainstream of business and management research may enhance the positioning of business historians within the scholarly community, enabling them to reclaim responsibility for framing the field while simultaneously reaching a broader audience on a route to enhanced legitimacy and impact.

For business historians to realize the promise of embracing more organization theory, two further points require emphasis. The first concerns the cultivation of greater reflexivity, as exhorted by Rowlinson, Hassard, and Decker, who specify the need for historians to locate and nurture their “own reflexive theoretical stance in relation to history.”Footnote 119 These authors echo previous calls for heightened reflexivity by Taylor, Bell, and Cooke, who view the exercise of reflexive practice by business historians as an ultimate objective, and Suddaby, Cynthia Hardy, and Quy N. Huy, who suggest that theorization requires an alert, self-reflective outlook.Footnote 120 This enhanced reflexive awareness that the production of theoretically informed historical discourse necessarily entails is implicated too in fostering the greater porosity and openness—combining rigor with flow—demanded by a pluralistic perspective.Footnote 121 Greater reflexivity can serve as a spur to creativity. It is time to break down the barriers to new theory creation erected by an overly conservative disciplinary stance. Such openness is also essential for reengagement with the bigger issues of wide-ranging contemporary debates.

The second point we wish to underline here concerns the practice of historical organization studies. Historical organization studies are fundamentally pluralistic, as stressed—concerned with bringing different approaches to history and organization studies, respectively. We contend that, after more than a decade of rumination on the need for and importance of the historic turn in organization studies, we may finally have reached the point where it is time now to practice what has been proposed. We concur with Wadhwani and Bucheli that it is timely to pursue this research agenda more vigorously by incorporating it into our actions as well as our thought processes.Footnote 122 Put differently, we suggest that the research conjuncture is now opportune for there to be less emphasis on contemplation and more on enactment, on putting historical organization studies into actual practice. It is now up to the business history community to take the necessary steps to embrace the cognitive lenses and frameworks outlined above, which, among others, enable researchers to see the general in the particular and thereby reap the benefits that an injection of organization theory can bring. We propose this as a research agenda, inviting business historians to expand their repertoire and rise to the challenge of enacting historical organization studies in their research. It is likely that the richer, more robust, theoretically imbued historical studies that may result from this endeavor, informed both by conceptual lenses and by historical and contemporary observation, will be well worth the efforts expended. Areas for further research incorporating this agenda include microhistory—in getting away from the large scale of hegemonic metanarratives to focus instead on the microhistorical processes that comprise the daily experiences of individual firms and actors—as well as prospective and historical sensemaking, in exploring how the past impinges on both the present and the future in heterogeneous aspects of organizational and institutional life.Footnote 123

References

1 Friedman, Walter A. and Jones, Geoffrey, “Business History: Time for Debate,” Business History Review 85, no. 1 (2011): 4.Google Scholar

2 Raff, Daniel M. G., “How to Do Things with Time,” Enterprise & Society 14, no. 3 (2013): 439Google Scholar. On uniqueness, see also Lippmann, Stephen and Aldrich, Howard E., “History and Evolutionary Theory,” in Organizations in Time: History, Theory, Methods, ed. Bucheli, Marcelo and Daniel, R. Wadhwani (Oxford, 2014), 124–46.Google Scholar

3 Taylor, Scott, Bell, Emma, and Cooke, Bill, “Business History and the Historiographical Operation,” Management & Organizational History 4, no. 2 (2009): 152.Google Scholar

4 Roy Suddaby, “Institutions and History: The Historic Turn in Management Theory” (keynote address, Association of Business Historians annual conference, Newcastle-upon-Tyne, U.K., 27 June 2014).

5 See Harvey, Charles and Wilson, John, “Redefining Business History: An Editorial Statement,” Business History 49, no. 1 (2007): 3Google Scholar; Harvey, Charles, “Business History: Concepts and Measurement,” Business History 31, no. 3 (1989): 1–5Google Scholar; Harvey, Charles and Jones, Geoffrey, “Business History in Britain into the 1990s,” Business History 32, no. 1 (1990): 516 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Booth, Charles and Rowlinson, Michael, “Management and Organizational History: Prospects,” Management & Organizational History 1, no. 1 (2006): 530 Google Scholar.

6 Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan, eds., The Oxford Handbook of Business History (Oxford, 2007), 1Google Scholar.

7 Friedman and Jones, “Time for Debate”; Rowlinson, Michael, Hassard, John, and Decker, Stephanie, “Research Strategies for Organizational History: A Dialogue between Historical Theory and Organization Theory,” Academy of Management Review 39, no. 3 (2014): 250–74.Google Scholar

8 Friedman and Jones, “Time for Debate,” 1. See also Steinmetz, George, “The Relations between Sociology and History in the United States: The Current State of Affairs,” Journal of Historical Sociology 20, no. 1–2 (2007): 112 Google Scholar; and Hall, John R., “Where History and Sociology Meet: Forms of Discourse and Sociohistorical Inquiry,” Sociological Theory 10, no. 2 (1992): 164–93Google Scholar.

9 See Steinmetz, George, “Transdisciplinarity as a Nonimperial Encounter: For an Open Sociology,” Thesis Eleven 91, no. 1 (2007): 4865 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Phelan, James, “Who's Here? Thoughts on Narrative Identity and Narrative Imperialism,” Narrative 13, no. 3 (2005): 205–10Google Scholar.

10 For useful exceptions, see Decker, Stephanie, “Corporate Legitimacy and Advertising: British Companies and the Rhetoric of Development in West Africa, 1950–1970,” Business History Review 81, no. 1 (2007): 59–86Google Scholar; Jones, Geoffrey and Miskell, Peter, “Acquisitions and Firm Growth: Creating Unilever's Ice Cream and Tea Business,” Business History 49, no. 1 (2007): 828 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Mairi Maclean, Charles Harvey, and Lindsay Stringfellow, “Narrative, Metaphor and the Subjective Understanding of Historic Identity Transition,” Business History 59 (published electronically 7 Sept. 2016), doi: 10.1080/00076791.2016.1223048.

11 Certeau, Michel de, The Writing of History (New York, 1988), 3.Google Scholar

12 See Jones, Geoffrey and Khanna, Tarun, “Bringing History (Back) into International Business,” Journal of International Business Studies 37, no. 4 (2006): 453–68Google Scholar; Keulen, Sjoerd and Kroeze, Ronald, “Understanding Management Gurus and Historical Narratives: The Benefits of a Historic Turn in Management and Organization Studies,” Management & Organizational History 7, no. 2 (2012): 171–89Google Scholar; Mills, Albert J., Weatherbee, Terrance G., and Durepos, Gabrielle, “Reassembling Weber to Reveal the Past-as-History in Management and Organization Studies,” Organization 21, no. 2 (2014): 225–43Google Scholar; Rowlinson, Michael, Booth, Charles, Clark, Peter, Delahaye, Agnès, and Procter, Stephen, “Social Remembering and Organizational Memory,” Organization Studies 31, no. 1 (2010): 6987 Google Scholar; Rowlinson, Michael and Carter, Chris, “Foucault and History in Organization Studies,” Organization 9, no. 4 (2002): 527–47Google Scholar; and Rowlinson, Michael and Hassard, John S., “Historical Neo-Institutionalism or Neo-Institutionalist History? Historical Research in Management and Organizational Studies,” Management & Organizational History 8, no. 2 (2013): 111–26Google Scholar.

13 Maclean, Mairi, Harvey, Charles, and Clegg, Stewart R., “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies,” Academy of Management Review 41, no. 4 (2016): 609–32Google Scholar.

14 Tsoukas, Haridimos and Knudsen, Christian, “Introduction: The Need for Meta-Theoretical Reflection in Organization Theory,” in The Oxford Handbook of Organization Theory, ed. Tsoukas, Haridimos and Knudsen, Christian (Oxford, 2003), 2Google Scholar.

15 Raff, “How to Do Things,” 435; Scranton, Philip and Fridenson, Patrick, Reimagining Business History (Baltimore, 2013), 205Google Scholar.

16 Maclean, Harvey, and Clegg, “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies.”

17 See, in particular, Kieser, Alfred, “Why Organization Theory Needs Historical Analyses—and How This Should Be Performed,” Organization Science 5, no. 4 (1994): 608–20Google Scholar; and Clark, Peter and Rowlinson, Michael, “The Treatment of History in Organisation Studies: Towards an ‘Historic Turn’?Business History 46, no. 3 (2004): 331–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 Zald, Mayer N., “More Fragmentation? Unfinished Business in Linking the Social Sciences and the Humanities,” Administrative Science Quarterly 41, no. 2 (1996): 256Google Scholar.

19 See Bucheli, Marcelo and Wadhwani, R. Daniel, eds., Organizations in Time: History, Theory, Methods (Oxford, 2014)Google Scholar; Greenwood, Anna and Bernardi, Andrea, “Understanding the Rift, the (Still) Uneasy Bedfellows of History and Organization Studies,” Organization 21, no. 6 (2014): 907–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Kipping, Matthias and Üsdiken, Behlül, “History in Organization and Management Theory: More Than Meets the Eye,” Academy of Management Annals 8, no. 1 (2014): 535–88Google Scholar.

20 Rowlinson, Hassard, and Decker, “Strategies for Organizational History.”

21 Maclean, Harvey, and Clegg, “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies.”

22 R. Daniel Wadhwani and Marcelo Bucheli, “The Future of the Past in Management and Organization Studies,” in Bucheli and Wadhwani, Organizations in Time, 23.

23 Hambrick, Donald C., “The Field of Management's Devotion to Theory: Too Much of a Good Thing?Academy of Management Journal 50, no. 6 (2007): 1346Google Scholar.

24 Wilkins, Mira, “Business History as a Discipline,” Business and Economic History, vol. 17 (1988): 1Google Scholar.

25 Raff, “How to Do Things,” 439.

26 Davis, Gerald C., “Do Theories of Organizations Progress?Organizational Research Methods 13, no. 4 (2010): 690709 Google Scholar.

27 Ibid., 707.

28 Hambrick, “Management's Devotion to Theory.”

29 White, Hayden, The Content of the Form: Narrative Discourse and Historical Representation (Baltimore, 1987)Google Scholar.

30 Maclean, Harvey, and Clegg, “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies”; Lippmann and Aldrich, “History and Evolutionary Theory.”

31 Hüseyin Leblebici, “History and Organization Theory: Potential for a Transdisciplinary Convergence,” in Bucheli and Wadhwani, Organizations in Time, 72.

32 Ibid.

33 Ricoeur, Paul, “Explanation and Understanding,” in The Philosophy of Paul Ricoeur: An Anthology of His Work, ed. Reagan, Charles E. and Stewart, David (Boston, 1978), 149–66Google Scholar.

34 Wilkins, “Business History,” 5.

35 R. Daniel Wadhwani, “Re-imagining History in Unsettled Times” (plenary session, European Group for Organizational Studies annual conference, Rotterdam, 4 July 2014).

36 Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American Industrial Enterprise (Cambridge, Mass., 1962)Google Scholar, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, Mass., 1977)Google Scholar, and Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism (Cambridge, Mass., 1990)Google Scholar.

37 Chandler, Strategy and Structure.

38 Chandler, Visible Hand; Chandler, Scale and Scope.

39 Maclean, Mairi, Harvey, Charles, and Press, Jon, “Managerialism and the Postwar Evolution of the French National Business System,” Business History 49, no. 4 (2007): 531–51Google Scholar.

40 Ericson, Mona, Melin, Leif, and Popp, Andrew, “Studying Strategy as Practice through Historical Methods,” in Strategy as Practice, 2nd ed., ed. Golsorkhi, Damon, Rouleau, Linda, Seidl, David, and Vaara, Eero (Cambridge, U.K., 2015), 507Google Scholar.

41 Harvey and Wilson, “Redefining Business History.”

42 Raff, “How to Do Things,” 444. See Bucheli, Marcelo, Mahoney, Joseph T., and Vaaler, Paul M., “Chandler's Living History: The Visible Hand of Vertical Integration in Nineteenth Century America Viewed under a Twenty-First Century Transaction Cost Lens,” Journal of Management Studies 47, no. 5 (2010): 859–83Google Scholar; and Lipartito, Kenneth J., “The Future of Alfred Chandler,” Enterprise & Society 9, no. 3 (2008): 430–32Google Scholar.

43 Jones, Geoffrey, Multinationals and Global Capitalism: From the Nineteenth to the Twenty-First Century (Oxford, 2005)Google Scholar.

44 Friedman and Jones, “Time for Debate,” 8.

45 See Hannan, Michael T. and Freeman, John, “The Population Ecology of Organizations,” American Journal of Sociology 82, no. 5 (1977): 929–64Google Scholar; and Aldrich, Howard E. and Ruef, Martin, Organizations Evolving, 2nd ed. (London, 2006)Google Scholar.

46 Suddaby, “Institutions and History.” See also Suddaby, Roy, Hardy, Cynthia, and Huy, Quy N., “Introduction to Special Topic Forum: Where Are the New Theories of Organization?Academy of Management Review 36, no. 2 (2011): 236Google Scholar.

47 Braudel, Fernand, On History (Chicago, 1980)Google Scholar.

48 Lippmann and Aldrich, “History and Evolutionary Theory,” 142

49 Judt, Tony, Thinking the Twentieth Century, with Timothy Snyder (London, 1992), 272Google Scholar.

50 On path dependence, see David, Paul A., “Clio and the Economics of QWERTY,” American Economic Review 75, no. 2 (1985): 332–37Google Scholar; and Sydow, Jörg, Schreyögg, Georg, and Koch, Jochan, “Organizational Path Dependence: Opening the Black Box,” Academy of Management Review 34, no. 4 (2009): 689709 Google Scholar. With respect to structural inertia, see Hannan, Michael T. and Freeman, John, “Structural Inertia and Organizational Change,” American Sociological Review 49, no. 2 (1984): 149–64Google Scholar. On imprinting, see Stinchcombe, Arthur L., “Social Structure and Organizations,” in Handbook of Organizations, ed. March, James G. (Chicago, 1965), 142–93Google Scholar; and Marquis, Christopher, “The Pressure of the Past: Network Imprinting in Intercorporate Communities,” Administrative Science Quarterly 48, no. 4 (2003): 655–89Google Scholar.

51 See Wernerfelt, Birger, “A Resource-Based View of the Firm,” Strategic Management Journal 5, no. 2 (1984): 171–80Google Scholar; and Raff, Daniel M. G., “Superstores and the Evolution of Firm Capabilities in American Bookselling,” Strategic Management Journal 21, no. 10–11 (2000): 1043–59Google Scholar. On organizational ecology, see Ruef, Martin, “The Demise of an Organizational Form: Emancipation and Plantation Agriculture in the American South, 1860–1880,” American Journal of Sociology 109, no. 6 (2004): 1365–410Google Scholar. On organizational emergence, see Forbes, Daniel P. and Kirsch, David A., “The Study of Emerging Industries: Recognizing and Responding to Some Central Problems,” Journal of Business Venturing 26, no. 5 (2011): 589602 Google Scholar.

52 See Leblebici, Hüseyin, Salancik, Gerald R., Copay, Anne, and King, Tom, “Institutional Change and the Transformation of Interorganizational Fields: An Organizational History of the US Radio Broadcasting Industry,” Administrative Science Quarterly 36, no. 3 (1991): 333–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Roy Suddaby, William M. Foster, and Albert J. Mills, “Historical Institutionalism,” in Bucheli and Wadhwani, Organizations in Time, 100–23.

53 See Marshall, David R. and Novicevic, Milorad M., “Legitimizing the Social Enterprise: Development of a Conformance Framework Based on a Genealogical Pragmatic Analysis,” Management & Organizational History 11, no. 2 (2016): 99122 Google Scholar. On organizational memory, see Anteby, Michel and Molnár, Virág, “Collective Memory Meets Organizational Identity: Remembering to Forget in a Firm's Rhetorical History,” Academy of Management Journal 55, no. 3 (2012): 515–40Google Scholar. On historical entrepreneurship, see R. Daniel Wadhwani and Geoffrey Jones, “Schumpeter's Plea: Historical Reasoning in Entrepreneurship Theory and Research,” in Bucheli and Wadhwani, Organizations in Time, 192–216; and Popp, Andrew and Holt, Robin, “The Presence of Entrepreneurial Opportunity,” Business History 55, no. 1 (2013): 928 Google Scholar. On process theory, see Schultz, Majken and Hernes, Tor, “A Temporal Perspective on Organizational Identity,” Organization Science 24, no. 1 (2012): 121 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On strategic change and strategy as practice, see Ericson, Mona, “Exploring the Future Exploiting the Past,” Journal of Management History 12, no. 2 (2006): 121–36Google Scholar; and Ericson, Melin, and Popp, “Studying Strategy as Practice.”

54 Weick, Karl E., Sensemaking in Organizations (Thousand Oaks, Calif., 1995)Google Scholar; Maclean, Mairi, Harvey, Charles, Sillince, John A. A., and Golant, Benjamin D., “Living Up to the Past? Ideological Sensemaking in Organizational Transition,” Organization 21, no. 4 (2014): 543–67Google Scholar; Suddaby, Roy, Foster, William M., and Trank, Christine Quinn, “Rhetorical History as a Source of Competitive Advantage,” in The Globalization of Strategy Research, ed. Baum, Joel A. C. and Lampel, Joseph (Bingley, U.K., 2010), 147–73Google Scholar.

55 Popp and Holt, “Presence of Entrepreneurial Opportunity.”

56 DiMaggio, Paul J., “Interest and Agency in Institutional Theory,” in Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Environment, ed. Zucker, Lynne G. (Cambridge, Mass., 1988), 322 Google Scholar; Battilana, Julie, Leca, Bernard, and Boxenbaum, Eva, “How Actors Change Institutions: Towards a Theory of Institutional Entrepreneurship,” Academy of Management Annals 3, no. 1 (2009): 65107 Google Scholar.

57 Munir, Kamal A. and Phillips, Nelson, “The Birth of the ‘Kodak Moment’: Institutional Entrepreneurship and the Adoption of New Technologies,” Organization Studies 26, no. 11 (2005): 1165–87Google Scholar.

58 Greenwood, Royston and Suddaby, Roy, “Institutional Entrepreneurship in Mature Fields: The Big Five Accounting Firms,” Academy of Management Journal 49, no. 1 (2006): 29Google Scholar.

59 Fulbrook, Mary and Rublack, Ulinka, “In Relation: The ‘Social Self’ and Ego-Documents,” German History 28, no. 3 (2010): 236Google Scholar.

60 See Collingwood, R. G., The Idea of History (Oxford, 1993)Google Scholar; Sewell, William H. Jr., Logics of History: Social Theory and Social Transformation (Chicago, 2005)Google Scholar; and de Certeau, The Writing of History.

61 Leblebici et al., “Institutional Change,” 336.

62 Munir and Phillips, “Birth of the ‘Kodak Moment.’”

63 See North, Douglass C., Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge, U.K., 1990)Google Scholar. This point is made by Dacin, M. Tina, Goodstein, Jerry, and Scott, W. Richard in “Institutional Theory and Institutional Change: An Introduction to the Special Research Forum,” Academy of Management Journal 45, no. 1 (2002): 4557 Google Scholar.

64 Suddaby, Foster, and Mills, “Historical Institutionalism,” 100.

65 Harvey, Charles, Maclean, Mairi, Gordon, Jillian, and Shaw, Eleanor, “Andrew Carnegie and the Foundations of Contemporary Entrepreneurial Philanthropy,” Business History 53, no. 3 (2011): 424–48Google Scholar. See also Nasaw, David, Andrew Carnegie (New York, 2006)Google Scholar.

66 Hutner, Gordon, introduction to The Autobiography of Andrew Carnegie, by Carnegie, Andrew (1920; New York, 2006), viixvi Google Scholar.

67 Fligstein, Neil, “Social Skill and the Theory of Fields,” Sociological Theory 19, no. 2 (2001): 105–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

68 Maclean, Mairi and Harvey, Charles, “‘Give It Back, George’: Network Dynamics in the Philanthropic Field,” Organization Studies 37, no. 3 (2016): 399423 Google Scholar.

69 Carnegie, Andrew, The Gospel of Wealth Essays and Other Writings (Harmondsworth, U.K., 2006), 7Google Scholar; Bishop, Matthew and Green, Michael, Philanthrocapitalism (London, 2008)Google Scholar.

70 Lippmann and Aldrich, “History and Evolutionary Theory”; Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G., An Evolution Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, Mass., 1982)Google Scholar.

71 Meyer, John W. and Rowan, Brian, “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony,” American Journal of Sociology 83, no. 2 (1977): 333–63Google Scholar.

72 Lippmann and Aldrich, “History and Evolutionary Theory,” 129.

73 Ibid., 132; Johnson, Victoria, “What Is Organizational Imprinting? Cultural Entrepreneurship in the Founding of the Paris Opera,” American Journal of Sociology 113, no. 1 (2007): 97127 Google Scholar.

74 Baron, James N., Dobbin, Frank R., and Jennings, P. Devereaux, “War and Peace: The Evolution of Modern Personnel Administration in U.S. Industry,” American Journal of Sociology 92, no. 2 (1986): 350–83Google Scholar.

75 Raff, “Superstores,” 1055.

76 Braudel, On History, 27.

77 Raff, “How to Do Things,” 445–46.

78 Naomi R. Lamoreaux, Daniel M. G. Raff, and Peter Temin, “Economic Theory and Business History,” in Jones and Zeitlin, Oxford Handbook of Business History, 37–66.

79 Jones and Khanna, “Bringing History (Back),” 462; Casson, Mark and Casson, Catherine, The Entrepreneur in History: From Medieval Merchant to Modern Business Leader (Basingstoke, 2013)Google Scholar.

80 Aldrich and Ruef, Organizations Evolving, xiv; Raff, “How to Do Things,” 435.

81 Gorski, Philip S., “Bourdieu as a Theorist of Change,” in Bourdieu and Historical Analysis, ed. Gorski, Philip S. (Durham, N.C., 2013), 1Google Scholar. See also Bourdieu, Pierre and Chartier, Roger, The Sociologist and the Historian (Cambridge, U.K., 2015)Google Scholar.

82 Bourdieu, Pierre and Raphael, Lutz, “Sur les rapports entre l'histoire et la sociologie en Allemagne et en France,” Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales 106–7, no. 1 (1995): 108–22Google Scholar, quoted in Calhoun, Craig, “For the Social History of the Present,” in Bourdieu and Historical Analysis, ed. Gorski, Philip S. (Durham, 2013), 37Google Scholar.

83 Friedman and Jones, “Time for Debate,” 4.

84 See, for example, Swartz, David L., “Bringing Bourdieu's Master Concepts into Organizational Analysis,” Theory and Society 37, no. 1 (2008): 45–52Google Scholar; and Oakes, Leslie S., Townley, Barbara, and Cooper, David J., “Business Planning as Pedagogy: Language and Control in a Changing Institutional Field,” Administrative Science Quarterly 43, no. 2 (1998): 257–92Google Scholar.

85 See Mutch, Alistair, “Communities of Practice and Habitus: A Critique,” Organization Studies 24, no. 3 (2003): 383–401Google Scholar; Maclean, Mairi, “New rules – old games? Social capital and privatisation in France, 1986–1998, Business History 50, no. 6 (2008): 795810 Google Scholar; Maclean, Mairi, Harvey, Charles, and Chia, Robert, “Dominant Corporate Agents and the Power Elite in France and Britain,” Organization Studies 31, no. 3 (2010): 327–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

86 See, for example, Bourdieu, Pierre, “Intellectual Field and Creative Project,” Social Science Information 8, no. 2 (1969): 89119 Google Scholar; Bourdieu, Pierre, “The Forms of Capital,” in Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education, ed. G., John Richardson (New York, 1986), 241–58Google Scholar; Bourdieu, Pierre, “Champ du pouvoir et division du travail de domination,” Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales 190, no. 5 (2011): 126–93Google Scholar.

87 Bourdieu's work has been used by business historians to explore the creative industries, in particular the mechanisms of taste formation and dissemination across a broad swath of society, eventually becoming institutionalized. See Harvey, Charles, Press, Jon, and Maclean, Mairi, “William Morris, Cultural Leadership, and the Dynamics of Taste,” Business History Review 85, no. 2 (2011): 245–71Google Scholar.

88 Bourdieu, Pierre, The State Nobility: Elite Schools in the Field of Power (Cambridge, U.K., 1996)Google Scholar.

89 Harvey et al., “Andrew Carnegie,” 436.

90 Bourdieu, “Intellectual Field,” 89, 91.

91 Ibid., 96.

92 Martin, John Levi, “What Is Field Theory?American Journal of Sociology 109, no. 1 (2003): 149 Google Scholar.

93 Fligstein, “Social Skill.”

94 Taylor, Bell, and Cooke, “Business History.”

95 Maclean, Harvey, and Clegg, “Conceptualizing Historical Organization Studies.”

96 Suchman, Mark C., “Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches,” Academy of Management Review 20, no. 3 (1995): 571610 Google Scholar.

97 Ibid., 594.

98 Wilkins, “Business History,” 1.

99 Ibid., 5.

100 Rosen, Christine M., “What Is Business History?Enterprise & Society 14, no. 3 (2013): 476Google Scholar.

101 Lipartito, “Future of Alfred Chandler,” 432; Judt, Thinking the Twentieth Century, 267.

102 Friedman and Jones, “Time for Debate,” 6.

103 Harvey and Wilson, “Redefining Business History,” 4.

104 Judt, Thinking the Twentieth Century, 268; Taylor, Bell, and Cooke, “Business History,” 158.

105 Raff, “How to Do Things,” 458, 447.

106 Weber, Max, The Theory of Social and Economic Organization (New York, 1947)Google Scholar.

107 Collingwood, The Idea of History, 377.

108 De Certeau, The Writing of History, 4.

109 Collingwood, The Idea of History, 419.

110 Wadhwani and Jones, “Schumpeter's Plea,” 195; Jones and Khanna, “Bringing History (Back).”

111 Suddaby, Hardy, and Huy, “New Theories of Organization,” 236.

112 Braudel, On History, 48.

113 Collingwood, The Idea of History, 383.

114 Braudel, On History, 51.

115 Morck, Randall and Yeung, Bernard, “History in Perspective: Comment on Jones and Khanna ‘Bringing History (Back) into International Business,’Journal of International Business Studies 38, no. 2 (2007): 357–60Google Scholar.

116 Collingwood, The Idea of History, 417; de Certeau, The Writing of History, 12.

117 Braudel, On History, 40.

118 De Certeau, The Writing of History, 13.

119 Rowlinson, Hassard, and Decker, “Strategies for Organizational History,” 269.

120 Taylor, Bell, and Cooke, “Business History,” 162; Suddaby, Hardy, and Huy, “New Theories of Organization,” 236.

121 De Certeau, The Writing of History, xxii.

122 Wadhwani and Bucheli, “The Future of the Past,” 23.

123 See, for example, Ulrich, Laurel Thatcher, A Midwife's Tale: The Life of Martha Ballard, based on Her Diary, 1785–1812 (New York, 1991)Google Scholar; and Popp and Holt, “Presence of Entrepreneurial Opportunity.”

Figure 0

Table 1 Business History: Perceived Failings and Recommended Solutions