Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-s22k5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-09T08:53:21.779Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bourbon Intervention in the Peruvian Tobacco Industry, 1752–1813*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 July 2007

CATALINA VIZCARRA
Affiliation:
Catalina Vizcarra is Assistant Professor in the Department of Economics, University of Vermont.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

During the second half of the eighteenth century the Spanish Crown monopolised the tobacco industry in its American colonies, creating vertically integrated organisations which included factories for the production of cigars and cigarettes. A detailed analysis of the regulations, organisation and policies applied during the Peruvian viceroyalty suggests that Bourbon officials were effective managers. The monopoly was successful at curbing contraband and extracting rents. The evolution of monopoly policies, however, reflected political constraints on the Crown's efforts to raise revenues. The archival evidence suggests that Bourbon officials closed the tobacco factories in Peru in 1791 as a result of public opposition.

Resumen: Durante la segunda mitad del siglo XVIII la Corona española monopolizó la industria tabacalera en sus colonias americanas, creando organizaciones integradas verticalmente con fábricas para la producción de puros y cigarros. Este artículo es el primero que estudia el Estanco peruano a profundidad. Un análisis detallado de las regulaciones, la organización y las políticas aplicadas en este caso sugiere que los oficiales borbónicos fueron efectivamente sus gerentes. El monopolio tuvo éxito en frenar el contrabando y extraer rentas. La evolución de las políticas monopólicas, sin embargo, mostró los límites políticos sobre los esfuerzos de la Corona por elevar sus ingresos. Los archivos sugieren que los oficiales borbónicos cerraron las fábricas de tabaco en Perú en 1791 como resultado de la oposición pública hacia ellos y no por razones económicas.

Palabras clave: tabaco, reformas borbónica, Virreinato de Perú, ingresos fiscales, contrabando.

Resumo: Durante a segunda metade do século dezoito a Coroa espanhola monopolizou a indústria de fumo de suas colônias americanas, criando organizações verticalmente integradas que incluíam fábricas para a produção de charutos e cigarros. Este é o primeiro artigo a estudar o estanco peruano a fundo. Uma análise detalhada do regulamento, organização e diretrizes aplicados sugere que neste caso funcionários bourbons eram administradores eficazes. O monopólio obteve sucesso em frear o contrabando e na extração de rendas. Porém, a evolução das diretrizes do monopólio refletia restrições políticas sobre os esforços da Coroa para aumentar receitas. Evidências arquivais sugerem que funcionários bourbons fecharam fábricas de tabaco no Peru em 1791 mais propriamente como resultado da oposição pública do que por motivos econômicos.

Palavras-chave: tabaco, reformas Bourbons, vice-realeza do Peru, receitas fiscais, contrabando

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2007

Recent studies on the economic history of Latin America argue that the burdensome legacy of Spanish colonial institutions affected the path of growth in the region. John Coatsworth, for example, discusses how a wide array of institutional constraints, including the poor protection of property rights, oppressive regulatory systems, and the unpredictability of economic policies restricted Spanish America's potential for economic growth.Footnote 1 Despite these suggestive works, we are far from understanding the precise mechanisms by which colonial institutions affected the newly independent states. This is partially due to the fact that, to this day, we lack a comprehensive picture of the Spanish American colonial economies. One of our major limitations in this respect is the relatively small number of works on the Andean region. John Fisher's work on Bourbon Peru, for example, calls for further research on several important industries of the Peruvian economy that have been neglected.Footnote 2

One such industry is the tobacco trade. Few economic activities were more vital to the development of the Spanish American economies than the cultivation, manufacture and commercialisation of tobacco. Tobacco was the second most important export industry in Spanish America at the time.Footnote 3 The decision of the Bourbon monarchs to monopolise the industry was a critical component of their plan to increase government revenues through a renewed contract with the colonists.Footnote 4 The economic significance of the industry was certainly critical for the establishment of the Estanco, but there were other considerations that made tobacco an ideal source of government income. Since it was viewed as a luxury good, a tax on tobacco was perceived as a ‘voluntary’ contribution, which was consistent with the Bourbon view that in order to build a prosperous empire the Crown had to promote the wellbeing of the population at large.Footnote 5

The monopoly was first instituted in Cuba in 1717. Later, it was established in Peru, Chile, La Plata, New Spain, Costa Rica, New Granada, Paraguay and Venezuela.Footnote 6 The literature overall focuses on the institutional evolution of the monopoly and pays little attention to its economic rationale and microeconomic aspects.Footnote 7 In particular, the historiography on the Peruvian tobacco industry addresses only partial aspects of the trade and is rarely based on data that go beyond a few scattered years. This article aims to fill these lacunae by reconstructing and analysing state intervention in the Peruvian tobacco industry between 1752 and 1813.Footnote 8

One aspect of the monopoly that has been relatively well documented for significant parts of the empire is its economic importance as a revenue-collection agency. In the Iberian Peninsula, for example, the Estanco yielded about 28 per cent of fiscal income, and in New Spain it became the second source of revenues for the Crown after silver, producing over 20 per cent of revenues in its best years.Footnote 9 In the Peruvian viceroyalty, as noted below, the magnitude of tobacco income was also impressive, especially when compared with traditional sources of revenues, like mining. Table 1 presents the distribution of Crown revenues in the Peruvian viceroyalty from 1750 to 1810.Footnote 10 Gross revenues from the tobacco monopoly surpassed silver for a good portion of the period under study. Net revenues represented around 15 per cent of fiscal income for most of the period. This result challenges the widely held view that the Peruvian Estanco produced meagre revenues, and was, overall, a failure.Footnote 11

Table 1. Fiscal Revenues in the Viceroyalty of Peru, 1750–1809 (annual averages, pesos)

* Head tax levied on the Indian population.

Sources: Data for the Peruvian tobacco monopoly compiled from the Estados del Estanco, AGI, Lima 704, 766, 1102, 1112, 1228, 1229, 1230, 1231, 1232, 1233, 1234, 1236, 1237, 1238, 1242, 1243, 1245 and Chile: 368, 369. The data have been adjusted by changes in inventories. The remaining columns come from Klein, The American Finances of the Spanish Empire: Royal Income and Expenditures in Colonial Mexico, Peru, and Bolivia, 1680–1809 (Albuquerque, 1998), chap. 3.

Notwithstanding, the explanation of how the Bourbons managed to control such a dynamic industry remains elusive. In particular, the dispersion of tobacco production and its great significance for domestic markets underscore the challenges of controlling smugglers and illegal producers. How did Bourbon bureaucrats manage to enforce regulations in such a large and varied industry and generate sizeable rents? Based on an analysis of monopoly policies, this article suggests that Bourbon officials had a good understanding of the managerial challenges of the industry and developed sensible strategies to address them. The success of the Peruvian monopoly owed as much to the firm political will of José de Gálvez (Minister of the Indies from 1776 to 1787) as to the skilful handling of contraband.Footnote 12

It took a number of years for the Peruvian monopoly to achieve its peak. Soon after its institution in 1752, the monopoly took control of tobacco production and distribution, thus assuming the power to determine output quotas and prices. In these years, however, the Estanco did not provide the fiscal bonanza that was anticipated. It was only later, under Gálvez, that the monopoly was reformed with the introduction of a number of policies aimed at increasing revenues and controlling contraband, including the centralisation of manufacture. As Figure 1 shows, the years of the Gálvez reforms (1780–1791) were the most successful in the extraction of revenues. However, the rise in revenues was not the product of centralisation per se (the establishment of factories did not imply major changes in transformation costs), but rather resulted from a more effective control of illegal markets in combination with higher prices.Footnote 13

Fig. 1. Net Revenues of the Peruvian Tobacco Monopoly, 1770–1813. Source: The data comes from the Estados del Estanco (see Table 1). Revenues were adjusted by changes in inventories and administrative changes in the viceroyalty in order to be able to compare with more accuracy the yields in the different phases pre-factory, factory, and post-factory periods. The data have been corrected for the separation of the viceroyalty of Río de la Plata and the captaincy-general of Chile in 1776 and 1786 respectively, and the addition of Guayaquil in 1807. Guayaquil revenues have been subtracted from the total for the years 1807–10, but they are included thereafter because they were no longer separately distinguished. Between 1807 and 1810 these revenues averaged around 20,000 pesos annually. Adjustments have been made for Chile by subtracting revenues from the Chilean administration and adding to the Peruvian accounts the revenues received by the Peruvian viceroyalty from tobacco sales to Chile. Starting in 1794, there is no data on Chilean consumption, so the revenue figures include the tobacco sent to Chile rather than that consumed. This implies that from 1794 Peruvian revenues are overestimated.

The archival evidence, including correspondence among high-ranking officials, indicates that the Bourbons viewed the centralisation of manufacture as a means to exert better control over the flow of tobacco and tobacco products, and to economise on the costs involved in monitoring the daily activities of workshop managers and final retailers.Footnote 14 The state's anti-contraband policies, however, went well beyond the centralisation of manufacture, affecting the industry at all levels, including tobacco production and distribution. The monopoly introduced higher purchase prices for tobacco leaf and made production quotas conditional on planters' performance. It also increased the severity of punishments for smugglers and added to the number of monopoly police in the provinces, making contraband trade more costly. The result was higher revenues.

The reforms, however, were short-lived. The evolution of monopoly policies demonstrates important limits to the Crown's revenue-raising efforts from the 1790s onwards. In particular, the Peruvian tobacco factories were closed, in spite of their financial success, as a result of Charles IV's cautious approach to colonial administration in the turbulent years that followed the death of Gálvez and Charles III. Although this article cannot claim to provide a definitive account of the rationale of the counter-reform, it does present evidence that suggests that political considerations explain, at least in part, the dramatic change in policies regarding Crown monopolies that occurred in the last decades of the empire.

The origins of the Estanco

The Royal Order that authorised the creation of the Real Estanco in Peru granted Viceroy José Antonio Manso de Velasco full discretion over the design of policies. As a result, the Viceroy requested Tomás Chavaquey Herreros, a prominent accountant of the Tribunal de Cuentas in Lima, to undertake a study of the industry and to formulate a plan with alternative regulatory options.Footnote 15

Chavaque reported that tobacco consumption was extensive among the white population at the time. An important proportion of tobacco leaf consumed in the Peruvian realm, approximately 800,000 mazos a year, was produced in the northern coastal province of Saña.Footnote 16 Nonetheless, tobacco of better quality was produced in the Andean provinces of Jaen de Bracamoros and Chachapoyas, which had an estimated annual production of about 380,000 mazos. As described in Table 2, the viceroyalty also consumed large quantities of snuff tobacco imported from Havana and Mexico, as well as tobacco leaf from Havana and Guayaquil.

Table 2. Tobacco Industry and Colonial State Revenues in the Viceroyalty of Peru, 1725–1743 (Annual Averages)

Source: Based on Tomás Chavaque y Herreros' report, 1746, AGI, Lima 1229.

(1) Tobacco of this kind was also produced in Luya and Chillaos (Chachapoyas). In the records any tobacco brought from either area was recorded as from Jaen de Bracamoros. Total production in Chachapoyas (Luya and Chillaos) was 80,000 and in Jaen de Bracamoros 200,000. Tobacco was also produced in the nearby province of Moyobamba. This area produced approximately 100,000 mazos. Legal consumption from Moyobamba was only 1,956, and total taxes were 58.68 pesos. The figures include data of the three areas.

(2) These are Chavaque's estimates.

(3) 8 reales is equivalent to a peso.

Tobacco was generally consumed in the form of cigarettes, cigars and limpiones. Footnote 17 The most important consumption centres were Lima and the Gobernación de Chile. Lima accounted for about 40 per cent of the market, followed by Chile (Santiago and Concepción), which took around 35 per cent. Other important centres were Arequipa, with a market share of about 7 per cent, and Potosí and Cuzco with 5 per cent each.Footnote 18 Chileans consumed Saña tobacco and snuff exclusively. All the other regions consumed tobacco from Chachapoyas, Guayaquil and Havana.Footnote 19 This consumption pattern was maintained, with slight variations, throughout the monopoly period.

Chavaque's account of the industry also drew attention to the high level of contraband. The colonial state charged both the alcabala and the almojarifazgo on the tobacco trade in these years. By comparing the amount of legal trade with Chavaque's estimates of total tobacco consumption, it seems that around 70 per cent of tobacco was traded illegally. As shown in Table 2, the average amount of taxes collected annually between 1725 and 1743 was no more than 11,000 pesos in total.Footnote 20 Chavaque believed that a monopoly over the tobacco industry would increase revenues because it would enable the state to exert better control of contraband and charge a higher tax rate, commenting that it would provide:

… a tool with which it will be possible to deter the defrauding of the Royal Rights and at the same time achieve a sizeable increase to the Real Hacienda. This can be achieved through the establishment, at the expense of His Majesty, of a Royal Monopoly of all types of tobacco that this Realm produces including the imports of tobacco from Mexico and from the island of Havana, inasmuch leaf as snuff. This will result in annual revenues for His Majesty equal to 1,088,664 pesos 6¼ reales.Footnote 21

Chavaque presented his report to the Viceroy in 1746, but the institution of the Real Estanco came six years later, on 24 April 1752. According to the viceroy its establishment was delayed due to the disruption caused by an earthquake in Lima in the same year as the report was completed. Footnote 22

The early years

The first Administración General for the monopoly was instituted in Lima. Shortly afterwards, the monopoly established the Administraciones Generales of Santiago, Trujillo, Cuzco, Arequipa, Huamanga, Concepción, Alto Perú and Río de La Plata.Footnote 23 All spheres of the industry were tightly regulated. The regulations followed those of the Spanish tobacco industry closely. The highest administrative agency was the Real Junta de Tabaco. Its permanent members comprised the viceroy, who presided over it, a member of the Church, and the director of the Estanco. The Tribunal de la Dirección General (analogous to an executive committee) was formed by the Estanco's director, its general accountant, and the treasurer.Footnote 24

The state determined all prices and fixed agricultural production quotas. Licensed planters were compelled to sell all their production to the monopoly. The tobacco leaf was later transported by licensed mule drivers from the production areas to the main consumption centres and stored at monopoly warehouses. The final sales of tobacco leaf and snuff were entrusted to licensed retailers (estanqueros) who earned a commission of between 5 and 10 per cent of total sales. At this early stage the manufacture of tobacco products was left in the hands of artisans, who traditionally produced cigars, cigarettes and limpiones for domestic consumption.Footnote 25

Initially, tobacco planters remained in the industry and for the most part maintained their pre-monopoly market shares. In addition, the colonial state set purchase prices higher than pre-monopoly levels. In 1756, for example, the average purchase prices for bracamoro tobacco and for Saña leaf were around 0.3 and 0.28 reales per mazo respectively.Footnote 26 There were differences in the administration of the two producing areas, which were to a great extent shaped by their contrasting factor endowments. In the province of Saña, which was located on the Peruvian coast about 700 kilometres north of the capital, the planters included hacendados who owned large extensions of lands, medium-size planters who either produced on their own lands or rented lands from the hacendados, and small farmers, Indians and poor mestizos who cultivated their land by themselves. The largest production quota in Saña in the 1760s was 20,571 mazos.Footnote 27 In Chachapoyas, on the other hand, which was also located in the northern region, but on the tropical eastern side of the Andes, approximately 1,200 kilometres from Lima, most planters were Indians and poor mestizos, who rarely had production quotas exceeding 2,000 mazos. Tobacco cultivation in Saña was not only concentrated in a much smaller geographical area than in Chachapoyas, but it was far closer to reliable and well frequented transport arteries. Marine transport was a viable means of transporting tobacco from Saña to Lima and farther south to Chile, whereas this was not an alternative in Chachapoyas. From Chachapoyas, mules were the only practical means of carrying large quantities of tobacco over the mountain passes and the several dangerous river crossings.Footnote 28

In Saña the factoría originally had only one employee, the factor who, together with planters' representatives, was in charge of monitoring production in the region. They organised the remittances of tobacco leaf to Lima, distributing ‘receipts’ among legal producers, which entitled the planters to sell their product to the Dirección General. The Administración General paid them in cash shortly after their quota of tobacco was deposited at the warehouse in Lima. In Chachapoyas, in contrast, the contract between the cosecheros and the colonial state was much more hierarchical. There was no role for planters' representatives, leaving the factor in charge of most administrative decisions. The factor decided production quotas and organised transportation of the plant to Lima.Footnote 29

The monopoly expanded considerably in the years of Viceroy Amat (1761–1776), especially under the direction of Feijoo de Sosa (1767–1774). In these years, the administration was strengthened by the expansion of the bureaucracy in the production areas and new estanquillos (final retailers) in Lima and other provinces. In 1767, for example, seven new employees (one guarda mayor and six guarda veedores) were hired to control the production process in Saña. There were also a number of institutional changes in Chachapoyas, where new officials were employed to supervise four areas of production in the region: Sesuya, Chillaos, Sipasbamba and Guayabamba.Footnote 30 By the end of Amat's administration the Estanco had established two Juntas Generales (one in Lima, and the other in Chile), ten Administraciones Generales, 35 Administraciones Particulares, 160 estanquillos and 2 factorías.Footnote 31

In spite of the improved administration, legal production did not change significantly in the period. Net revenues for the Crown increased only marginally. The latter fluctuated from an average of 141,246 pesos in the first decade of the Estanco to an average of 183,069 pesos in the 1770s.Footnote 32 Nonetheless, the net revenues of the monopoly constituted a good portion of the value added of the industry even at this early stage, which, as shown in Table 1, was the least profitable for the Crown. On the basis of Chavaque's figures it can be estimated that the industry's value added was about 652,817 pesos annually in the late 1740s. Net monopoly revenues were equivalent to around 21.6 per cent of this figure, which signals a relatively effective administration.Footnote 33

Gálvez's reform and the battle against contraband

A critical turning point in the administration of the Estanco came in 1776, with the appointment of José de Gálvez as Minister of the Indies. Shortly after taking office, Gálvez sent visitador José Antonio de Areche to Lima to evaluate the Peruvian Real Hacienda and other revenue-generating agencies. The viceroyalty was facing a deep financial crisis at the time due, among other reasons, to the administrative separation of the viceroyalty of Río de la Plata. Public officials were thus understandably eager to increase revenues from any available sources.

Under the auspices of Gálvez a major reform of the monopoly took place, which strongly endorsed the adoption of the Mexican system.Footnote 34 Not surprisingly, one of the two directors of the Mexican monopoly, José de la Riva Aguero, was assigned the mission of reforming the Peruvian Estanco. Footnote 35 De la Riva and two other monopoly officials arrived in Peru in 1779. Their early reports expressed concerns about the high levels of contraband in the viceroyalty and their hope that, with the correct policy adjustments, the Peruvian monopoly would produce revenues comparable to those in Mexico.Footnote 36

The reform of the Estanco, which took the commissioners' assessments as its point of departure, consisted of sweeping changes that included the centralisation of manufacture and a fully renewed administration of the production areas. The centralisation of manufacture was conceived of as the cornerstone in the state's battle against contraband.Footnote 37 In a letter to José de Gálvez, a Spanish public official discussed how ‘… tobacco allowances to producers of limpiones and cigarettes will always serve as a cloak for the growth of contraband'.Footnote 38 The director of the Peruvian monopoly, Alfonso Santa de Ortega, agreed entirely with this argument. In a letter to the viceroy he sustained that the solution for the ‘uncontrollable’ level of contraband in the Peruvian viceroyalty was to expand the monopoly to the manufacture of tobacco products.Footnote 39 In addition, Miguel de Otermín, like Santa de Ortega, took the position that state manufacture of cigars and cigarettes was essential because of the difficulties of monitoring the workshops and retailers' stores.Footnote 40

Before centralisation, there were 86 licensed cigarreros (workshop managers), and a larger number of licensed retailers, who were required to buy tobacco leaf at monopoly warehouses. The job of monopoly supervisors, who visited the workshops and retailers' stores regularly, consisted of checking accounts and inventories against the monopoly warehouses' books (which recorded sales to all workshop owners and tobacco allowances to all retailers in the viceroyalty). Monitoring costs were quite high because it was impossible to distinguish between legal and illegal tobacco at the workshops and retailer stores. Under the new system, the private workshops were banned and licensed retailers were only allowed to sell manufactured products. Packs of cigars and cigarettes were stamped with a seal of origin at the state factories. Illegal manufacturers thus faced a higher risk of detection. Smugglers could attempt to disguise their products, but this would be costly.Footnote 41

Monitoring costs at the state manufactories

Despite the improvement in the control of the flow of tobacco and tobacco products, the factories created new challenges. Factory workers had to be monitored closely and offered the right incentives in order to assure good and faithful performance. Monopoly officials who were aware of these monitoring problems instituted a number of incentives to reduce the costs of supervision.

The monopoly established two factories, one in Lima and another in Trujillo. The latter was created in order to manufacture tobacco products for the Diocese of Trujillo, where the production areas were located, so as to save in transportation costs.Footnote 42 The factory in Lima produced cigars, cigarettes and limpiones for the rest of the Peruvian viceroyalty.Footnote 43 Production was organised in five offices: grinding (labor del picado), manufacture of cigarettes, manufacture of cigars, manufacture of limpiones, and the women's office (which produced cigarettes). An additional office was in charge of packing and stamping. There was a chief supervisor (fiel) for each major office, who supervised the work of the foremen/women (sobrestantes). Each sobrestante organised and monitored his own group of workers, most of whom were piece-workers. A certain degree of division of labour took place in the production of cigarettes, but not in the production of cigars and limpiones. The production of cigarettes started in the grinding office, where leaves were selected and then ground in order to prepare them for the rollers. The cigarette rollers were in charge of cutting the paper and rolling the cigarettes. The stamping and packing office was the last stop in the production chain.

Discipline was an important feature of the organisation of work within the tobacco factories. A critical point to stress here is that discipline was not instituted for coordination purposes or as a means to extract greater levels of work effort, but to improve the administration's capacities to control quality and contraband.Footnote 44 All workers, including top employees, had to comply with a relatively strict schedule. Work started every morning at 7 a.m.. Tobacco and paper were distributed to chief supervisors by the fiel of the grinding office before 7:30 a.m.. Afterwards, chief supervisors distributed the raw material to their foremen, who in turn gave them to the piece-workers in accordance with their quotas. At 10 a.m. the foremen reported to the chief supervisor on the final allocation of the raw material, and returned all the tobacco that would not be utilised that day to the grinding office.Footnote 45 The rationale for such a strict schedule was to control tobacco circulation. It was difficult, under such a system, for an employee to embezzle raw material, or to assign tobacco of better quality – or greater quantity – to a particular worker or group of workers, for distribution took place simultaneously across offices and workers. In this way, the monopoly sought to prevent fraud:

Neither in the office of cigars, nor in the office of cigarettes, will the administrator permit any reservation of paper or tobacco for workers who were not present at the time of the distribution; not following this regulation would permit fraud and abuse from the chief supervisors and foremen …Footnote 46

Sanctions for employees and piece-workers who did not comply with these regulations were severe. For example, chief supervisors and foremen who were late, with no good excuse, paid a fee equivalent to their daily salary. However, the administrator was responsible for informing the director when an employee committed this fault for the third time, in which case the director punished the employee either with suspension or permanent exclusion from the state manufactories. Piece-workers lost their tareas, and risked being erased from the roster of tobacco workers.Footnote 47

Behaviour at work was heavily regulated as well: drinking, gambling and even minor distractions were prohibited. In the eyes of the colonial state, good order was essential to control fraud and maintain the quality of tobacco products. There were a number of regulations preventing any kind of intimacy, or familiarity, between factory employees and operarios who could generate conspiracies against the state manufactories:

Being useful and convenient the transference of the fieles and sobrestantes, not permitting them to stay in the same offices for any significant length of time so as to avoid any close links with the workers and other prejudices from being inflicted on the Estanco … , the administrator will take close care of these modifications, considering the type of responsibilities of each of these offices, and the capacities of the employees …Footnote 48

Guards controlled the exit from the factory building and searched all workers for any possible signs of fraud. Sanctions imposed on tobacco workers for these cases were harsh. Stealing tobacco and/or paper – regardless of the amount – was punished with a large monetary fee, and permanent expulsion from the state manufactories.Footnote 49 Archival records and secondary sources suggest that these regulations were repeatedly enforced.Footnote 50

Beyond discipline and sanctions, did the colonial state institute any positive incentives in order to reduce monitoring efforts? According to documentary evidence, monetary incentives, the most common means used to enhance performance elsewhere, were not significant. Even though De la Riva recognised the importance of a well paid bureaucracy, the budget constraints faced in the early 1780s due to local upheavals (the Túpac Amaru rebellion) and the wars of American Independence put restrictions on the use of high salary policies.Footnote 51 Factory workers were thus paid the same wage rates that they had received at the artisanal workshops.Footnote 52 Managerial jobs did not fare any better. The majority of individuals hired for these posts were quite experienced in the tobacco business, but most of them received lower annual incomes at the factories than they had as independent cigarreros.Footnote 53 Overall, factory managers and tobacco workers had limited monetary incentives to develop vested interests in the state manufactories.

The colonial state, however, provided a number of non-market goods that compensated somewhat for the lack of such incentives. Principal among these were job stability and security. Indeed, in practice, bureaucrats were admitted to an exclusive club that could guarantee lifetime employment. Stability and promotions were generally based on performance, and according to the roster of factory employees these principles were religiously applied.Footnote 54 Another, though more subtle, mechanism that might have helped reduce monitoring efforts was the discourse that nurtured labour relations within the factories, in effect an informal system of control. Deans-Smith, in her work on the Mexican tobacco monopoly, illustrates how paternalism functioned as a constraint on the work force:

Manufactory authority was presented in the guise of paternalism. The informal name given to the manufactory in Mexico City was the House of the King; in response the workers used the term El Rey Padre (the Father-King) when referring to their ‘employer.’ The manufactory functioned as a microcosm of colonial Spanish hegemony, in which the ideals of political authority and religious orthodoxy were constantly promoted and upheld. Supervisors at all levels were instructed that the administrator as well as the dirección general would consider workers' petitions or grievances. Grievances were channeled from workers to supervisors, the administrator, the dirección general, and ultimately the viceroy and monarch. In so doing, guided by its ‘unwritten constitution,’ the colonial state encouraged negotiation and compromise and created a channel through which to absorb conflict.Footnote 55

This system created a sort of ‘family atmosphere’ within the factories, which is generally considered to be very effective in increasing the costs of opportunism.Footnote 56

The reforms upstream

None of these reforms, however, would have sufficed in the battle against contraband without modifying the organisation and regulations of the production areas. De la Riva stated that the latter was essential because registered planters were heavily involved in contraband:

It will only be possible to control the planters, who are so embroiled in contraband as to be smuggling half or more of their crop, with the resguardo (monopoly police) … In order to emphasise even more the necessity of these expenses, I remind your lordship of the considerable expenditures made in New Spain to combat the illicit extraction of the crops of Cordova, Orizaba, and Zongolica …Footnote 57

Beginning in 1780, the monopoly heavily monitored all aspects of the production process including the location and timing of planting and harvest.Footnote 58 But, most importantly, it introduced a number of built-in incentives in the contracts with the tobacco planters that increased the opportunity cost of engaging in contraband. One of the most important modifications in this respect was the increase in the purchase price for good quality bracamoro tobacco from 0.4 to 1 real per mazo, and for Saña leaf from around 0.3 to 0.6 reales.Footnote 59 Another important change was the conditioning of future quotas on planters' performance.Footnote 60

In addition, the monopoly established much harsher penalties for illegal activities. According to the regulations that predated the reforms, each planter was required to put forward some collateral, which is typical of contracting systems where there is no effective third party enforcement. Under the new regulations, however, the collateral was eliminated and the planters faced much higher penalties and a fully renovated enforcement system. An important new clause detailed harsher punishments for smuggling: four years of incarceration for any fraud that involved more than twelve mazos.Footnote 61

Effective enforcement, however, depended not only on the matrix of incentives, but also on the efficacy of the administration. Consequently, the monopoly modified the administration of the production areas. At the time of the reforms, for example, Chachapoyas had a total of four officials: the factor and three monopoly guards, with a total budget of 900 pesos.Footnote 62 In addition to higher wages for current positions, the monopoly created several new offices. Total expenditures for the new administration in Chachapoyas rose from 900 to 9,750 pesos annually.Footnote 63 In Saña, the Administración General of Trujillo was dissolved and merged with the factoría in Lambayeque, which was at the centre of the production areas: the partidos of Lambayeque, Saña, and Chiclayo. Total expenditures in the area increased from 60 to 6,740 pesos a year.Footnote 64

In addition, the monopoly concentrated production quotas in fewer hands. Before the reforms the number of planters in Saña was approximately 87, which contrasts with only 37 planters in the early 1780s. According to the roster of registered planters the top three had quotas of 100,000 mazos, and the next three had quotas between 30,000 and 50,000 mazos. Footnote 65 The top six planters, therefore, had legal rights to produce 60 per cent of Saña's output.Footnote 66 There were also attempts to concentrate production in Chachapoyas. In Sipasbamba, for example, there were around 72 planters registered in 1781. In 1788 we find only 45, in spite of the fact that total legal production in the area was about four times larger than in 1781. In the other partidos the archival evidence also suggests increasing concentration throughout the decade.Footnote 67

The monopoly also instituted the rondas volantes, which consisted of groups of guards who inspected the areas suspected of heavy contraband, the most important of which was the one controlling the Marañón, a river that passes through Chachapoyas and connects with consumer centres in the Andean region. In the 1780s, the colonial state spent 11,400 pesos a year to police this route. Moreover, the monopoly hired employees to patrol transportation routes that connected the production areas to Lima. Before the reforms, only five employees took care of these routes, with a total expenditure of 2,400 pesos a year. In 1780, fifteen new employees were added with total salaries of 10,000 pesos.Footnote 68

Overall, the anti-contraband reforms could be summarised as follows. First, the monopoly vertically integrated downstream into tobacco manufacture, which allowed for better control over the flow of tobacco products. In addition, the factory's regulations included a complex system of incentives and sanctions directed to the control of fraud. Second, the state instituted a series of organisational changes in the production areas. Prominent among these were the incentives directed to tobacco planters such as a higher purchase price for the tobacco leaf, quotas based on planters' performance, and penalties for those planters who provided poor quality tobacco and engaged in contraband. In addition, the state improved its administration by concentrating tobacco production in the hands of a few planters, and significantly increasing the number of monopoly police in the provinces. Each of these changes acted to make smuggling activity riskier and more costly. The net effect of the state's reforms, both upstream and downstream, was to provide much more effective deterrence to smugglers than had been the case in earlier years.

The evidence on contraband

There is substantial evidence in support of the thesis that the reforms of 1780 led to a reduction in contraband. As mentioned above, accounts of the prevalence of contraband prior to the establishment of the factories are abundant. De la Riva's commission encountered widespread smuggling, especially of bracamoro tobacco. We can infer contraband levels by comparing estimates of cigarette and cigar sales before and after 1780, which are illustrated in Figure 2.Footnote 69 Estimates of ‘legal’ cigarette sales increased substantially during the 1780s, in spite of the rise in the final price of tobacco products. Interestingly, the Administración de Cajamarca, which was the nearest to the production centre of Chachapoyas, saw the value of legal consumption rise from 14,177 pesos for the period between 1771 and 1778 to 159,527 pesos for the period from 1781 until 1788, which constitutes strong evidence of a decrease in contraband of bracamoro-variety tobacco.

Fig. 2. Legal Consumption of Bracamoro Tobacco (mazos) and Tobacco from Guayaquil and Havana (manojos). Source: Estados del Estanco (doc. cit. in Table 1). Estimations since 1780 based on data on consumption of cigars and cigarettes.

This increase in legal sales was accompanied by an increase in final prices. De la Riva raised the price of bracamoro tobacco from an average of four to sixteen reales per mazo (in Lima), and the price of Saña leaf from two to four reales.Footnote 70 The price of manufactured products, on the other hand, was nominally unchanged, at half a real a package of 24 cigarettes, although they increased somewhat in real terms since the Estanco occasionally manufactured cigarettes with lower tobacco content than artisans.Footnote 71 An increase in final prices of tobacco and tobacco products should theoretically have produced a reduction in total tobacco consumption. The increase in legal sales is therefore indicative of a reduction of contraband.Footnote 72

Nonetheless, as Figure 2 illustrates, smugglers posed new challenges in the late 1780s. The graph shows that after a substantial increase in the early 1780s legal sales of cigars made from Guayaquil and Havana tobacco decreased to pre-factory levels in the second half of the decade. Archival evidence suggests that merchants turned to smuggling tobacco coastwise from Guayaquil.Footnote 73 Overall, however, Figure 2 provides strong evidence of a relative success in the fight against contraband. The total volume of legal sales of both cigars and cigarettes combined was undoubtedly greater in the factory years than in the pre-factory period.

The cost advantages of factory organisation

In order to assess the impact of the anti-contraband reforms on monopoly revenues we need to discuss one additional factor, which is whether there were any changes in the cost of producing tobacco products when the state vertically integrated into the manufacturing process. This amounts to explaining whether the factory system achieved scale economies that were not achieved by the artisan manufacturers and why. In other words, were there technical reasons for the higher revenues under the factory system? Or can we really assert that much of the change in revenues was due to the reduction in contraband in combination with higher prices?

The discussion of the existence of scale effects is critical to evaluating changes in transformation costs that could have occurred when the colonial state integrated into the manufacture of tobacco products.Footnote 74 A full resolution of this issue, however, requires a comparison of the average total cost functions for the production of cigarettes under the two different systems: state manufactories and artisanal production. If the average total cost of the monopoly at its level of production was less than the minimum point on the average total cost curve of the artisanal producer, one can assert that the monopoly did represent a technical improvement over the prior (and subsequent) systems. Unfortunately, no data is available on artisanal production that would allow us to test this hypothesis. However, it is possible to utilise reliable estimates of returns to scale based on the factory's production function, which suggests constant returns to scale at approximately 0.23 reales per pack of puros (cigars) and 0.21 reales per pack of cigarettes.Footnote 75 As noted above, the factory achieved greater division of labour than the workshops. It is likely, however, that the improvements in costs resulting from this were exhausted at relatively low levels of production, below the normal output of the Lima factory.Footnote 76 If there were any effects of factory organisation on transformation costs, they were likely to have been minimal.

The closure of the tobacco factories and the political economy of the counter-reform

For all their accomplishments, the factories were closed after only eleven years of operation, in 1791. This major modification in the organisation of the Estanco, which took place only a few years after the institution of Gálvez's reforms, signified the relative stagnation of revenues from the monopoly, as can be seen in Figure 1.Footnote 77 Interestingly, however, legal sales did not return to pre-factory levels after the factory system ended, which explains, at least in part, why revenues in the 1790s and beyond were higher than in the pre-factory period.Footnote 78 It is likely that contraband was higher in the 1770s than in the 1790s and 1800s because although the expected benefits of smuggling were higher in the 1790s (the post-1790 price of tobacco leaf was above the pre-1780), the expected costs were still high relative to the pre-factory period. A total dismantling of the reforms that De la Riva made to police the trade did not occur, particularly in Chachapoyas.Footnote 79

This unexpected turn of events requires a discussion of some of the policy changes that took place in the metropolis after the disappearance of José de Gálvez, the death of Charles III in 1788, and the tumultuous events in Europe at the time. The latter certainly affected the attitudes and policies towards the Indies.

Under Charles IV, the Crown took a number of measures that illustrated its concerns with the security of the empire, especially its fears of upheavals in the colonies. Primary and secondary sources suggest that the Crown relaxed monopoly policies in those areas where conflicts with local elites were most apparent. The tobacco monopoly in Paraguay, for example, experienced a marked relaxation in its policies. As Cooney puts it:

Shortly before the death of the Minister of the Indies, José de Gálvez, and the subsequent termination of his ‘revenue-producing reforms’, Paula Sanz was removed from the Superintendencia of Buenos Aires … Now with a greater willingness among officials to appease the local elites and with less zeal displayed for law enforcement, the war against contraband on the rivers noticeably slackened. Thus by 1790 those former obstacles to the contraband traffic had disappeared. In 1790–91 the apprehension of downriver smugglers by the Resguardo (revenue police) had vanished …Footnote 80

But this is not the only example of drastic changes in policies in the region. In 1792 Charles IV ordered the abolition of the Estanco in Venezuela, conceding that since its institution several demands for its termination had been introduced before the Crown, and that, ‘in all justice’, the monopoly should be brought to an end. The Royal Order stated that the Ayuntamiento had to commit itself to taxing the tobacco industry either through the encabezamiento (head tax to be paid by tobacco producers) or through any other system that the local authorities deemed appropriate. According to Arcila Farias, a heated argument ensued, following the royal order, between those farmers excluded from the monopoly and those defending old privileges. In the end, those lobbying for the status quo won the battle and the Estanco continued functioning, mostly unchanged, until the wars of independence.Footnote 81

In New Spain, the monopoly lost its relative autonomy with respect to the Tribunal de Cuentas, although no other major administrative changes followed. As Deans-Smith argues, after the early 1790s attempts to reform the monopoly to adjust it to economic and political changes were silenced. Although this is merely speculative, it is likely that what lay behind the relative rigidity of Mexican regulations was the important economic role of the monopoly as collateral for government loans (the monopoly in New Spain was mortgaged for 15 million pesos by 1797). The latter generated the support that the monopoly enjoyed from leading merchants and miners.Footnote 82

The Peruvian case illustrates well the politics of Charles IV and his new ministers. The arrival, in 1790, of Viceroy Gil de Taboada y Lemos (1790–96) was crucial for the evolution of the Estanco. Viceroy Gil had strong ties with newly appointed officials in Madrid, especially with Antonio Valdés, who was in charge of the Ministry of Finance. He was appointed first as viceroy of New Granada in 1788, and then, shortly afterwards, as viceroy of Peru.Footnote 83 Allan Kuethe, in his article on the culmination of the Bourbon reforms in New Granada, gives a suggestive picture of Gil's politics. Kuethe argues that Gil fought the huge financial crisis in New Granada with the same views he would apply in Peru a few months later: reducing expenditures instead of increasing taxes and expanding the bureaucracy. Kuethe finds Viceroy Gil's policies to be consistent with Barbier's interpretation of the new regime: the Crown became more cautious under Charles IV, advancing the Bourbon programme as long as it did not threaten local vested interests.Footnote 84 Gil, for example, as viceroy of New Granada, supported the policy towards modernisation of the mining industry, whereas in Lima, where opposition from Lima's mercantile oligarchy was apparent, Gil visibly opposed those same policies.Footnote 85

Viceroy Gil's stand on the tobacco industry is consistent with this interpretation. Soon after his arrival to Lima, honouring his duties as maximum authority of the Royal Treasury, Gil sent a letter to the Crown discussing the performance of the Estanco.Footnote 86 He informed the Crown of pervasive complaints from consumers about the quality of manufactured products, and stated that the monopoly had enormous bureaucratic expenses, which had to be reduced to improve performance.Footnote 87 This was the view of members of the local elite. Hipólito Unanue, writing for the Mercurio Peruano, a publication of the Sociedad de Amantes del País, an enlightened and progressive organisation in Peru, strongly criticised the state manufactures.Footnote 88

Gil's diagnosis of the Estanco's performance was also consistent with the Crown decrees of 1787, which ‘implicitly condemned some of Minister Gálvez's policies by stressing the need to economise’.Footnote 89 The Viceroy manifested his views more extensively in a subsequent letter to the Crown:

Selling the leaf cheaply and thereby increasing the quantity sold is the most advantageous step for the people and it is that which Your Majesty should take throughout the entire monopoly if Your Majesty wishes it to flourish without the need of hiring as many monopoly police. In order to accomplish this successfully, it is indispensable to achieve economy, good order, and simplicity.Footnote 90

Finally Gil ordered a visita (audit and investigation) of the monopoly in April 1790.Footnote 91 Soon afterwards, in July of the same year, he reported to the Crown that the visita, which had been conducted by former director of the monopoly Feijoo de Sosa, was not favourable to the Estanco. According to Feijoo, the factories presented a number of challenges. The main problem was the excess of inventories that caused the deterioration of a great quantity of tobacco in the Lima's factory warehouse, which, in his view, was at the root of the low quality of tobacco manufactures.Footnote 92 According to Feijoo's report, there were other problems including the relatively low weight of the mazos of bracamoro tobacco.Footnote 93 But Feijoo's report overlooked a key issue that was at the heart of consumers' complaints against the state manufactories. The inadequate quality of manufactured products was not only related to the excessive inventories of tobacco leaf at the factory's warehouse, but also, and principally, to the substitution of domestic tobacco for imports. As a result of the disruption of commerce during the War of American Independence, the colonial state had engaged in an ‘import-substitution’ strategy experimenting with new tobacco fields that tried to reproduce Guayaquil and Havana tobacco. However, the Peruvian Estanco failed to produce tobacco that could compete with the best quality imports.Footnote 94 In the end, on the basis of the report of the visita, and arguing that the public outcry was for the closure, Viceroy Gil abolished the tobacco factories. The Crown approved the judgment of the visita, the closure of the factories, and the destitution of Director Otermín on 24 May 1791.Footnote 95

Conclusions

The historiography argues, convincingly, that the Bourbons failed to construct the absolutist state envisioned by the reformers, but there is no consensus on the nature of the organisation they actually created.Footnote 96 The reconstruction and analysis of tobacco monopoly policies sheds new light on the nature of the Bourbon administration. One of the main findings of this article, which is consistent with a good portion of the literature, is that Bourbon officials were effective in the extraction of rents.Footnote 97 The literature, however, for the most part inferred competent administration from fiscal results without directly linking policies and outcomes. Building on a detailed economic analysis of monopoly policies and performance, this study of the Peruvian tobacco monopoly has suggested that Bourbon officials had a thorough understanding of the importance of transaction costs for the formation and support of a successful bureaucracy. Indeed, the factory system was devised as a means to reduce the costs associated with the control of illegal markets, and judging by the available evidence, it was effective in doing so. Overall, the evolution of monopoly policies suggests that Bourbon officials were in no way ‘backward’ managers. They were certainly aware of the organisational problems that afflict hierarchies.

The limitations to Bourbon policies are to be found in the political economy of colonialism. The tobacco factories were closed in 1791, partly in response to public outcry. Their closure should be understood in light of the major policy changes emanating from Madrid after the tumultuous events in Europe at the time. Under Charles IV, the crown took a number of measures that illustrate its concerns with the security of the Empire. Primary and secondary sources suggest that the Crown relaxed monopoly policies in those areas where conflicts related to monopoly operations were most apparent. That, seemingly, was the case in the Peruvian viceroyalty, where the tobacco factories were closed in spite of their financial success.

References

1  The last decade has witnessed an upsurge in the publication of works that address the role of institutions in shaping the region's path of growth. The latter is the result of the major influence that the New Institutional Economics (NIE) has had in the field of economic history. Coatsworth, John H. has pioneered the application of this framework to Latin America. See, for example, his ‘Economic and Institutional Trajectories in Nineteenth-Century Latin America’, in Coatsworth, John and Taylor, Alan (eds.), Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800 (Cambridge MA, 1998), pp. 2354Google Scholar. For a discussion of the latest research in Latin American economic history and the influence of the NIE see Coatsworth, , ‘Structures, Endowments, and Institutions in the Economic History of Latin America’, Latin American Research Review, vol. 40, no. 3 (2005), pp. 126–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2  Fisher, John, El Perú borbónico 1750–1824 (Lima, 2000)Google Scholar.

3  Total tobacco exports were behind silver with 13.6 per cent of the total during the ‘free-trade’ period between 1782 and 1796. Tobacco was followed by cacao with 7.8 per cent and sugar with 5.5 per cent: see Fisher, John, The Economic Aspects of Spanish Imperialism in America, 1492–1810 (Liverpool, 1997), p. 168Google Scholar.

4  The Bourbons sought to transform the colonial ‘consensus’ of the Habsburg period into a stronger state capable of extracting higher rents: see Lynch, John, ‘The Institutional Framework of Colonial Spanish America’, Journal of Latin American Studies, vol. 24, Quincentenary Supplement (1992), pp. 6981CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5  See MacLachlan, Colin, Spain's Empire in the New World: the Role of Ideas in Institutional and Social Change (Berkeley, 1988)Google Scholar.

6  The Cuban industry, with the tobacco of best quality, was monopolised early on with the explicit goal of assuring enough imports of Cuban tobacco leaf for the factories in Seville. In all other areas the main goal was to increase fiscal revenues.

7  The most important study of the tobacco monopoly is the work of Susan Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers: the Making of the Tobacco Monopoly in Bourbon Mexico (Austin, 1992). In addition, see Eduardo Arcila Farías, Historia de un monopolio: el estanco del tabaco en Venezuela (1779–1833) (Caracas, 1977). For a collection of essays on the tobacco industry in the eighteenth century see Agustín González Enciso and Rafael Torres Sánchez (eds.), Tabaco y economía en el siglo XVIII (Pamplona, 1991).

8  The earliest article on Peru is Castillo, Guillermo Céspedes del, ‘La renta del tabaco en el virreinato del Perú’, Revista Histórica vol. 21 (1954), pp. 138–63Google Scholar. Mauro Escobar Gamboa wrote his bachelor's thesis on aspects of tobacco production in Saña: ‘El tabaco en el Perú colonial 1752–1796’, unpubl. Bach thesis, Universidad Nacional Mayor de San Marcos, 1973. Christine Hünefeldt addresses some aspects of production and distribution in Chachapoyas in ‘Etapa final del monopolio en el virreinato del Perú: el tabaco en Chachapoyas’, in Nils Jacobsen and Hans-Jürgen Puhle (eds.), The Economies of Mexico and Peru During the Late Colonial Period (Berlin, 1986), pp. 388–417. John Fisher gives a general overview of the monopoly enterprise in ‘El estanco del tabaco en el Perú borbónico’, in González Enciso and Torres Sánchez (eds.), Tabaco y economía, pp. 35–53. Additional secondary sources include Pimentel, Carlos Deustua, ‘Aspectos de la economía peruana a fines del siglo XVIII (1790–1796)’, Boletín del Instituto Riva Agüero, vol. 8 (Lima, 1969–1971), pp. 135308Google Scholar; Alonso, Serena Fernández, ‘Un caso de represión del fraude en la Real Renta de Tabacos de Lima durante el período reformista’, Boletín del Instituto Riva Agüero, vol. 17 (Lima, 1990), pp. 401–10Google Scholar; Catalina Vizcarra, ‘Markets and Hierarchies in Late Colonial Spanish America: The Royal Tobacco Monopoly in the Viceroyalty of Peru, 1752–1813’, unpubl. PhD diss., University of Illinois, 2001; and Vizcarra, Catalina and Sicotte, Richard, ‘El control del contrabando en el Perú colonial: el caso del monopolio del tabaco, 1752–1813’, in Contreras, Carlos and Glave, Manuel (eds.), Estado y mercado en la historia del Perú (Lima, 2002), pp. 184211Google Scholar.

9  For an overview of its importance as a source of revenues see Vizcarra, Catalina, ‘El monopolio del tabaco en hispanoamérica colonial’, in Alvarez, Luis Alonso, Muñoz, Lina Gálvez and Luxan, Santiago (eds.), Tabaco e historia económica: estudios sobre fiscalidad consumo y empresa (siglos XVII–XX) (Madrid, 2006), pp. 231–44Google Scholar.

10  The data employed in these estimates were gathered from extensive records at the Archivo General de Indias (AGI) in Seville and the Archivo General de la Nación (AGN) in Lima. Most of the primary sources used for this work cover the monopoly period until 1813. Some data from 1814 onwards are available at Biblioteca Nacional and AGN, but they are quite disperse and incomplete.

11  The net revenue figures underestimate the importance of tobacco income. We should keep in mind that all other revenues listed in Table 1 are presented in gross terms. In neither case have bureaucratic costs been subtracted. See Jacobsen and Puhle (eds.), The Economies of Mexico and Peru, p. 23, for an alternative assessment of the Peruvian monopoly.

12  Gálvez's enterprise led to the extension of state intervention in the industry in terms of geographical location (it is in these years that the Estanco became omnipresent in the region), and to a higher degree of control. For a discussion see Vizcarra, ‘El monopolio del tabaco.’

13  This finding is significant for the historiography because an important portion of our knowledge about the Spanish American economies is based, in one way or another, on the Treasury accounts. If contraband had been as pervasive as so many scholars suggest, it would be necessary to be quite suspicious of some of the general conclusions drawn from the official records. Nonetheless, this result should be treated with some caution. It refers exclusively to the Gálvez era. As noted later, archival evidence suggests that in the early eighteenth century tax evasion was rampant.

14  The costs of monitoring employees and protecting property are viewed by some scholars as being lower in a factory environment than under an alternative sub-contracting or system of ‘putting-out’ to artisans. The case of the Peruvian tobacco factories is consistent with this view. See Williamson, Oliver, ‘The Organisation of Work: A Comparative Institutional Assessment’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organisation, vol. 1, no. 1 (1980), pp. 538CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For alternative points of view, see Marglin, Stephen, ‘What do Bosses Do? The Origins and Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production’, in Gorz, André (ed.), The Division of Labour: The Labour Process and Class-Struggle in Modern Capitalism (London, 1976)Google Scholar, and Landes, David, ‘What Do Bosses Really Do?’, Journal of Economic History, vol. 46, no. 3 (1986), pp. 585623CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15  Report of Thomas Chavaque y Herreros, AGI, Lima 1229.

16  Mazos were small rolls of tobacco leaf, typically weighing between 15 and 24 ounces.

17  Limpiones were small bundles of chewing tobacco, about one inch long.

18  Estimated from ‘Extracto que demuestra’, AGI, Lima 1236-B.

19  Slaves in Peru consumed tobacco produced in Saña.

20  Tax rates did not exceed 0.05 reales per mazo and did not change throughout the period. As a way of comparison, from 1746 to 1750, the total revenues of the Royal Treasury in Lima were 8,283,468 pesos: see Paske, John Te, ‘General Tendencies and Secular Trends in the Economies of Mexico and Peru, 1750–1810: The View From the Cajas of Mexico and Lima’, in Jacobsen, and Puhle, (eds.), The Economies of Mexico and Peru, p. 337Google Scholar.

21  Chavaque's estimations were overly optimistic. During the monopoly period net revenues for the Crown were rarely greater than 500,000 pesos. There were three main flaws in his calculations. First, he assumed that tobacco smuggling would vanish with the creation of the Estanco. Second, the final prices he considered in his calculations were much greater than pre-monopoly prices, yet his estimates assumed the same level of consumption as before the establishment of the monopoly. Finally, he did not account for bureaucratic costs. Report of Tomás Chavaque y Herreros, p. 3.

22  See Fuentes, Manuel A. (ed.), Memoria de los virreyes que han gobernado el Perú, vol. 4 (Lima, 1859), p. 239Google Scholar.

23  Céspedes del Castillo, ‘La renta del tabaco’, p. 139.

24  The ordenanzas of 1759 are in AGI, Lima 1229.

25  Ibid.

26  As described in Table 2, costs in production areas were 0.2 reales per mazo for Saña leaf and 0.24 reales per mazo for Bracamoro tobacco in the pre-monopoly period.

27  See Escobar, ‘El tabaco en el Perú’, appendix, p. XII.

28  Factor of Chachapoyas to Dirección de la Renta, July 1787, AGN, C-14, legajo 18. Also see, ‘Reparos que resultan de las listas de sembradores de tabacos remitidas por el factor de Chachapoyas Dn. Baltasar Collantes’, 1771, AGN, C-14, legajo 617.

29  Otermín's report to Gil, July 1790, AGI, Lima 1228..

30  Ibid

31  See Céspedes del Castillo, ‘La renta del tabaco’, pp. 147–51.

32  See Table 1.

33  These figures are derived from Table 2, using average final prices for each product. These are the best estimates that can be obtained, although they are clearly contingent on the precision of Chavaque's assessments, and on the assumption that the industry did not grow substantially during the early years of the monopoly.

34  Gálvez himself had played a significant role in the evolution of monopoly policies in New Spain. As visitador general of Mexico, in the 1760s, he had been responsible for several important policy measures, including the move toward centralisation of manufacture: see Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, chapter 1.

35  De la Riva to Gardoqui, March 1796, AGI, Lima 1242. See also Otermín's report to Gil, July 1790, AGI, Lima 1228.

36  His companions were Miguel de Otermín (who became director of the Peruvian Estanco in 1783) and Marcos Alonso Gamero. Both worked for the Mexican monopoly prior to their appointment as De la Riva's assistants.

37  Deans-Smith argues that there were two reasons for centralisation in Mexico: ‘profitability’, and provision of employment for the urban poor. In the Peruvian documents there are a number of references to profitability, but social considerations do not figure prominently. Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, p. 144.

38  Ortiz de Landazuri to Gálvez, Madrid, 23 April 1776, AGI, Chile 369.

39  Otermín's report to Gil, July 1790, AGI, Lima 1228.

40  Ibid.

41  These monitoring problems were in some respects analogous to those faced under the putting-out system in eighteenth-century England. Travelling from station to station to supervise workers implied high monitoring costs. According to Oliver Williamson, hierarchy (the centralised ownership of equipment and inventories, together with close supervision and discipline) displaced other forms of organisation because it economised on transaction costs. In Williamson's view, the putting-out system was gradually replaced by a more efficient system based on a greater degree of control: the reduction of embezzlement and shirking are crucial to improve performance, and under greater discipline illegal markets are less likely to expand. As mentioned above, it was precisely the reduction of monitoring costs that monopoly officials had in mind when they decided to integrate into the manufacture of cigars and cigarettes: see Williamson, ‘The Organisation of Work’.

42  Nonetheless, this factory was quite small. This area produced no more than 7 to 8 per cent of the monopoly's revenues at the time. In its first year it had only five employees. De la Riva to Superintendente General de la Real Hacienda, Nov. 1781, AGN, C-14, legajo 621.

43  By 1788, the Lima factory employed 622 workers, 472 of whom rolled cigarettes, while 121 manufactured cigars, and 29 limpiones. Otermín's reports to Gil, No. 16–21, AGI, Lima 1229.

44  Piece-workers have good incentives to comply with production quotas, but poor incentives to produce good quality products. As a legal monopoly, the Estanco considered necessary to produce good quality products which were perceived as essential for the state to be able to compete with contraband tobacco.

45  ‘Expediente sobre las instrucciones que deven guardar los elavorantes de la fabrica de tavacos’, 1787, AGN, C-14, Administrativo (Adm.) 11.

46  In ‘Instruccion que debe obserbar el administrador y demas empleados en la real fabrica de puros cigarros y limpiones de Lima’, 1790, AGN, C-14, Adm. 15.

47  Ibid.

48  Ibid.

49  Ibid.

50  Fernández Alonso, in ‘Un caso de represión del fraude’, p. 405, cites a number of cases and sources related to the enforcement of anti-contraband regulations. Documents on expulsion and other penalties imposed on factory workers can also be found in AGN C-14, Contencioso, 9–11.

51  ‘El visitador general Escobedo’, Jan. 1783, AGI, Lima 1231. Monopoly officials argued that high salaries were critically important to achieve their objectives. This finding challenges Linda Salvucci's view of Bourbon administration. According to Salvucci, the changes introduced by José de Gálvez in Mexico reflected very limited perspectives on the part of Bourbon officials on how to build an effective bureaucracy. In particular, she refers to the salaries of employees and managers as the foremost example of Gálvez's ineptitude. As she puts it: ‘In spite of the fact that his explicit objective was to improve the Crown's control of the local government, he did not envision bureaucratic salaries as an important incentive to increase productivity or the willingness to serve the Crown … ’ Indeed, Salvucci extends this view to the entire administration: ‘As a consequence of the Bourbon reformers’ conceptual mistake, the bureaucrats continued immersed in corruption … ' See Salvucci, Linda, ‘Costumbres viejas, hombre nuevos: José de Gálvez y la burocracia fiscal Novohispana (1754–1800)’, Historia Mexicana, vol. 33, no. 2 (1983), pp. 249 and 252Google Scholar.

52  Cigarette rollers earned, on the average, five reales a day, and cigar manufacturers six.

53  Official reports discuss the income of some of these workshop managers. For example, former workshop manager Dn. Andrés Zavala earned an average annual income of 2,587 pesos as an independent cigarrero, and Dn. Manuel De la Rocha 1,935 pesos. As employees of the factory they earned only 300 and 700 pesos respectively. Escobedo to Gálvez, Feb. 1784, AGI, Lima 1231, and ‘El visitador general Escobedo’, Jan. 1783, AGI, Lima 1231.

54  Evidence for the Peruvian monopoly can be found in ‘Reyno del Peru’, 1811, which gives the history of all monopoly employees in great detail, AGN, C-14, Adm. 42. See also ‘Nomina de hoja de servicios reales rentas estancadas’, 1806, AGN, C-14, Adm. 37; and ‘Nomina de empleados mayores y menores que en esta fecha sirben en la renta del tabaco de los reynos de Peru y Chile con expresion de sus oficios, nombramientos y sueldos fijos … ’, 1780, AGN, C-14, Adm. 5. For Mexico, see Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, p. 42. Secondary sources suggest that this was the case for the bureaucracy in general. For Buenos Aires, for example, see Susan Migden Socolow, The Bureaucrats of Buenos Aires, 1769–1810: Amor al Real Servicio (Durham and London, 1987).

55  It can be assumed that the Peruvian factories experienced similar mechanisms given that they followed closely the Mexican organisation in most respects. It must be emphasised, however, that no direct evidence of the use of such means of informal controls was found in Peruvian documents. On Mexico, see Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, p. 204.

56  Ann Carlos and Stephen Nicholas, for example, in their work on the Hudson's Bay Company, argue that one of the most effective mechanisms in dealing with agency problems was the institution of an ‘informal system of control’ that adapted employees’ values to the company's goals. See their ‘Agency Problems in Early Chartered Companies: The Case of the Hudson's Bay Company’, Journal of Economic History vol. 50, no. 4 (1990), pp. 853–75.

57  De la Riva to Areche, no. 190, 1781, AGI, Lima 1230.

58  The tenientes reconocedores (newly appointed officials) were in charge of supervising all aspects of cultivation: the suitability of the land for tobacco production, its preparation, planting of the seedbeds, transplanting, etc. until the mazos were deposited in the factoría. All details about the production process are in ‘Circular anexa comunicada a los tenientes reconocedores de los cinco partidos de Chachapoyas’, signed by Gregorio Zuñiga, September 1787, AGN, C-14, legajo 620.

59  The opportunity cost of selling the leaf in the black market is the official purchase price. Thus this measure increased the opportunity cost of engaging in contraband. Also, the Estanco reserved to itself the right to decide ex-post the price for tobacco that did not comply with monopoly standards.

60  This rule implied that planters who engaged in illegal activities or who did not produce tobacco according to the instrucciones, risked losing their production quotas. See ‘Condiciones de la nueva contrata’, and ‘Instrucción que han de observar los cosecheros de tabacos de la provincia de Saña para el cumplimiento de la contrata con la Real Hacienda, 1779’, reproduced in Escobar Gamboa, ‘El tabaco en el Perú colonial, 1752–1796’, appendix, pp. VIII and XXIII.

61  Ibid.

62  600 pesos for the factor and 100 pesos for each guarda veedor.

63  De la Riva to Areche no. 190, 1781, AGI, Lima 1230.

64  Ibid.

65  Dn. Fernando Pantoja in Chiclayo, Dn. Miguel Paredes in Ferreñafe, and Dn. Benito Antonio Caldas in Saña. The sise of quotas rose substantially. The maximum quota in the pre-factory period was 20,571 mazos. See Escobar Gamboa, ‘El tabaco en el Perú colonial’, pp. 103–5.

66  Although all of them had been tobacco producers in the 1770s, many of the old ‘prominent’ planters were not registered in the 1780s.

67  The roster of tobacco planters and their respective quotas of production for the 1780s can be found in AGN C-14, legajo 619.

68  Areche to Gálvez, July 1780, AGI, Lima 1230.

69  These figures for the pre-factory years were derived by calculating the amount of tobacco necessary to produce a pack of cigarettes or cigars and dividing the amount of tobacco leaf sales by that figure. For example, cigarettes were made exclusively with bracamoro tobacco and approximately 41.12 packs of cigarettes were made from one mazo. In the pre-factory years, the number of mazos of bracamoro sold was multiplied by 41.12 in order to estimate ‘legal’ cigarette sales. There is only a scattered series of legal sales of bracamoro tobacco in this early period, which explains the breaks in the graph. During the factory years, there are actual figures on cigarette and cigar sales, plus sales of tobacco leaf. Assuming that all of this leaf was converted ‘legally’ into cigarettes and cigars (for home consumption only), an estimate of product consumption can be derived.

70  As mentioned earlier, the sale of the leaf was prohibited in many areas. For the few cases in which it was allowed, retailers were not permitted to sell it by weight but only by mazos. As a consequence, lower income groups abstained from buying the tobacco leaf. Bear in mind that a mazo cost almost three times as much as the typical daily salary earned by common labourers.

71  Expediente sobre la reforma de la renta de tabaco, no. 230, AGI, Lima 1230.

72  The exact dimension of this change depends on the elasticity of the demand. But the impact of a price increase is unequivocally to reduce the quantity demanded, unless there were any meaningful exogenous shifts in the demand or supply of tobacco products. Vizcarra and Sicotte showed that such exogenous shocks were marginal, see their ‘El control del contrabando’, pp. 193–6.

73  Escobedo to Marqués de Sonora, Sept. 1787, AGI, Lima 1112. See also Document no. 982, AGI, Lima 1112.

74  Economic theory has shown that the monopolist of an input used in fixed proportions with other inputs could obtain full monopoly rents without vertically integrating. This was precisely the case of the tobacco monopoly where tobacco and paper were used in fixed proportions to produce manufactured products. So the argument that vertical integration in, and of itself, implied larger rents is questionable. Nevertheless, Quirmbach showed that integration might be profitable in such a scenario if there are ‘scale distortions’. Scale distortions can occur if downstream firms face U-shaped average costs, because the monopoly price of the intermediate good will induce downstream firms to adopt a scale that is not equal to the lowest possible unit cost. The central idea here is that monopoly pricing upstream distorts the incentives of firms downstream when they decide about the appropriate scale of manufacture. In this case the upstream monopolist can increase total profits through integration by lowering industry costs. See Vernon, Johnand Graham, Daniel, ‘Profitability of Monopolisation by Vertical Integration’, Journal of Political Economy vol. 79, no. 4 (1971), pp. 924–5;CrossRefGoogle Scholar and Quirmbach, Herman, ‘Vertical Integration: Scale Distortions, Partial Integration, and the Direction of Price Change’, Quarterly Journal of Economics vol. 100, no. 1 (1986), pp. 131–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75  This is on the basis of figures for costs of production for 1788 and 1789. Even when quantities vary by tens of thousands of units, average total cost remains nearly constant for cigars and cigarettes. One fixed cost, that of the factory buildings themselves, is not included. Checking total costs of production divided by production of each item, a very rough estimate of returns of scale indeed, is consistent with the supposition of constant returns as well.

76  Economies of scale were also quite limited in the Mexican case. See Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, pp. 143–73.

77  Data available for the years after 1813 confirm this trend. See for example, Fisher, ‘El estanco del tabaco en el Perú borbónico’, pp. 45 and 51–3.

78  Data on sales can be found in the Estados del Estanco (doc. cit., table 1).

79  Among other documents see letter Marqués de San Felipe to Gardoqui, Aug. 1793; AGI, Lima 1242.

80  Cooney, Jerry, ‘La Dirección General de la Renta de Tabacos and the Decline of the Royal Tobacco Monopoly in Paraguay, 1779–1800’, Colonial Latin American Historical Review, vol. 1, no. 1 (1992), p. 108Google Scholar.

81  The tobacco monopoly in New Granada also experienced serious opposition. It occurred much earlier, however, in 1780, as part of the Comunero rebellion. Secondary sources indicate that monopoly revenues in New Granada increased in the 1790s and beyond, but there is no detailed study of the political economy of monopoly policies in the period. See Anthony McFarlane, Colombia before Independence: Economy, Society and Politics under Bourbon Rule (Cambridge, 1993), p. 223. Also, see John P. Harrison, ‘The Colombian Tobacco Industry from Government Monopoly to Free Trade, 1778–1870’, unpubl. PhD diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1951. For Venezuela, see Arcila Farías, Historia de un monopolio, chap. 12.

82  Deans-Smith, Bureaucrats, Planters and Workers, pp. 52 and 65.

83  In 1787 the Ministry of the Indies was divided into two offices, one in charge of war, finance and commerce, under Antonio Valdés, and the other in charge of grace and justice under Antonio Porlier. In 1790, a Junta de Estado was formed to oversee policies in Spain and America. The colonial portfolios were abolished and the newly nominated peninsular ministers gained authority over the Indies in their own sphere. The Junta de Estado was composed of five office-holders: Florida Blanca was in charge of the Ministry of State, Campo Alegre of War, Valdés of the Navy, Lerena of Finance and Porlier of Justice. This evolution, according to Barbier, was ‘the logical culmination of nearly nine decades of administrative development’, whose principal problem was the coordination of policies. The Junta de Estado was meant to guarantee ‘union and equality’ between Spain and America. See Barbier, Jacques, ‘The Culmination of the Bourbon Reforms, 1787–1792’, Hispanic American Historical Review, vol. 57, no. 1 (1977), pp. 5168CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84  See Kuethe, Allan, ‘More on the Culmination of the Bourbon Reforms: A Perspective from New Granada’, Hispanic American Historical Review, vol. 58, no. 3 (1978), pp. 477–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

85  Ibid., p. 480.

86  In 1787, as part of the administrative changes that followed the death of Gálvez, the viceroys regained power over economic matters, which had been taken away from them in the early 1780s.

87  Opposition to the state manufactories thrived in spite of the fact that the state did not change the nominal prices of manufactured products: Areche to Gálvez, no. 230, Sept. 1780; AGI, Lima 1230. See also ‘Indice de los extractos que por la intervención de visita del Real Estanco de Tabacos de Lima, se han deducido de las actuaciones originales de ella por lo respectivo a cuenta y razon se pasan al excelentisimo Sr. Virrey de estos reynos. Anexo 3: Resumen de las sumarias informaciones recibidas por los señores intendentes de Tarma, Cuzco, Huamanga, Huancavelica y Trujillo, acerca del estado calidad peso y precio de los tabacos que se expenden en las capitales de sus distritos y en sus subdelegaciones, con arreglo a la comisión conferida por este superior gobierno en 27 de diciembre, 1790’, AGI, Lima 704.

88  See Unanue, Hipólito, ‘Disertación sobre la naturaleza y efecto del tabaco, orígen y progresos del Real Estanco de Lima’, Mercurio Peruano vol. 4, no. 109 (1792), pp. 4351Google Scholar.

89  Barbier, ‘The culmination of the Bourbon Reforms’, p. 59.

90  Gil to the Crown, June 1790, AGI, Lima 1243.

91  Gil to the Crown, April 1790, AGI, Lima 1243.

92  Tobacco leaf was accumulating at a much higher pace than expected. This was an unintended effect of the state's success in controlling contraband in the production areas. The excessive accumulation of tobacco leaf in the factory's warehouse is consistent with S. R. H. Jones' view on the relatively poor responsiveness to changes in market conditions of the factory as opposed to the putting-out system. Jones' work focuses on British entrepreneurs in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. We should not expect any better from a state controlled monopoly. See Jones, S. R. H., ‘The Organisation of Work: A Historical Dimension’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organisation, vol. 3, no. 2–3 (1982), pp. 117–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

93  ‘Indice de los extractos que por la intervención de visita del Real Estanco de Tabacos de Lima, se han deducido de las actuaciones originales de ella por lo respectivo a cuenta y razon y se pasan al excelentisimo sr. virrey de estos reynos’, 1791, AGI, Lima 704.

94  Otermín to Escobedo, Aug. 1785, AGI, Lima 1231.

95  Crown to Viceroy Gil, May 1791, AGI, Lima 1243.

96  For an account of this transition see John Lynch, ‘The Institutional Framework’, pp. 69–81.

97  See Marichal, Carlos, ‘Money, Taxes and Finance’, in Coatsworth, John, Conde, Roberto Cortés and Bulmer-Thomas, Victor (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Latin America (Cambridge, 2006), vol. 1, pp. 423–60Google Scholar.

Figure 0

Table 1. Fiscal Revenues in the Viceroyalty of Peru, 1750–1809 (annual averages, pesos)

Figure 1

Fig. 1. Net Revenues of the Peruvian Tobacco Monopoly, 1770–1813. Source: The data comes from the Estados del Estanco (see Table 1). Revenues were adjusted by changes in inventories and administrative changes in the viceroyalty in order to be able to compare with more accuracy the yields in the different phases pre-factory, factory, and post-factory periods. The data have been corrected for the separation of the viceroyalty of Río de la Plata and the captaincy-general of Chile in 1776 and 1786 respectively, and the addition of Guayaquil in 1807. Guayaquil revenues have been subtracted from the total for the years 1807–10, but they are included thereafter because they were no longer separately distinguished. Between 1807 and 1810 these revenues averaged around 20,000 pesos annually. Adjustments have been made for Chile by subtracting revenues from the Chilean administration and adding to the Peruvian accounts the revenues received by the Peruvian viceroyalty from tobacco sales to Chile. Starting in 1794, there is no data on Chilean consumption, so the revenue figures include the tobacco sent to Chile rather than that consumed. This implies that from 1794 Peruvian revenues are overestimated.

Figure 2

Table 2. Tobacco Industry and Colonial State Revenues in the Viceroyalty of Peru, 1725–1743 (Annual Averages)

Figure 3

Fig. 2. Legal Consumption of Bracamoro Tobacco (mazos) and Tobacco from Guayaquil and Havana (manojos). Source: Estados del Estanco (doc. cit. in Table 1). Estimations since 1780 based on data on consumption of cigars and cigarettes.