Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-grxwn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-10T11:13:25.632Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

TERM LIMITS AND AUTHORITARIAN POWER SHARING: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM CHINA

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 May 2016

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Term limits that effectively govern leadership transition play an important role in authoritarian power sharing. A fixed term and a pre-appointed successor – two crucial components of term limits – credibly commit the incumbent ruler to share power with other elites, and also allow the elites to monitor and coordinate against the ruler's transgression of the power-sharing agreement. While the successful adoption of term limits often requires an even balance of power among the ruling elites in the first place, once adopted it initiates an evolving bargain over allocation of political power among multiple generations of leaders that further keeps any one faction from dominating the others. I corroborate this argument using a biographical dataset of elite members of the Chinese Communist Party from 1982 to 2012. The findings suggest that the Party's incumbent leaders and their rivals (i.e., predecessor and heir-apparent) shared equal chances in promoting their associates—which proxy their political influence—and this pattern has become more salient since the 16th party congress, when the term limits that currently govern China's leadership transition became fully fledged. This result also sheds light on the role of informal, patronage-based promotion in the institutionalization of authoritarian politics.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © East Asia Institute 2016 

1 INTRODUCTION

Authoritarian survival relies critically on a stable ruler–elite coalition. Between 1946 and 2008, 68% of non-constitutional exits of authoritarian leaders from office were caused by internal break-ups among the ruling elites (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 5). The root of such instability rests on an inherent problem of authoritarian rule: that a ruler's promise to share power with his allies is often incredible (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Myerson Reference Myerson2008). Extant studies have identified various formal and informal institutions—such as legislatures (Gandhi and Przeworksi Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2006; Malesky Reference Malesky2009; Malesky and Schuler Reference Malesky and Schuler2010), constitutions (Myerson Reference Myerson2008; Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2012), political party (Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008), organizational proliferation (Haber Reference Haber, Weingast and Wittman2007), or hereditary succession (Brownlee Reference Brownlee2007; Kokkonen and Sundell Reference Kokkonen and Sundell2014)—to facilitate credible power sharing between the ruler and his allies.

The resilient rule of China Communist Party (CCP) poses a theoretical challenge to the received wisdom on credible power sharing in one-party regimes. Whereas elites in a typical one-party regime could credibly threaten the incumbent by defecting from the ruling party and by forming oppositions in periodic elections (Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008), there are no periodic, mass, multi-party elections under the CCP regime. The influence of the CCP is so encompassing that there is little independent political space beyond the Party itself. The Party organization is equivalent to the regime, and being a member of the Party is the only way to powerful positions. Inside this “regime-party,” no open, observable factions are allowed to exist, by which elites could coordinate collective action against the ruler's transgression. Despite all these inconsistencies with the conditions that would facilitate power sharing in a typical one-party state, the post-Mao CCP has nonetheless demonstrated a considerable degree of resilience in sustaining its authoritarian rule (Nathan Reference Nathan2003). Why and how is power sharing possible in the CCP?

Term limits that effectively govern leadership transitions might serve as an important institution that facilitates power sharing in regime parties like CCP (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 2013). Drawing from the case of China, a functioning term limits institution should have two characteristics: a fixed term for political leaders and the emergence of a pre-appointed successor (i.e., heir apparent) prior to the turnover. The term limits institution mitigates rulers’ commitment problems by placing the incumbent ruler under the shadow of potential post-tenure punishment, and by allowing the elites who face the risk of being abused to preemptively invest their loyalty in the incoming leader who can deliver such punishment. A fixed term and a pre-appointed successor also alleviates the monitoring problem faced by elites, making the ruler's intention to transgress the term limits easily detectable, and providing a focal point for the elites to coordinate collective actions when the ruler fails to commit to the power sharing agreement.

While the effective adoption of term limits often requires a rather even balance of power among the ruling elites in the first place, once effectively adopted, the term limits generate expectations of future leadership turnover that in turn reinforce such balance of power. An incumbent leader bound by the term limits would appoint his close associates to important positions prior to his retirement, in order to tie the hands of his successor and continue to exert influence after retirement. Lower-ranked elites will also preemptively signal their loyalty to the incoming leader. If the incumbent leader intended to overstay in office, he would face opposition not only from the heir apparent, but also from those elites who have already invested their loyalty in the heir apparent (Svolik Reference Svolik2013). The incoming leader, on the other hand, wants to secure important positions for his followers beforehand, so that he can have a group of elites who he can rely on to carry out his policies already in important positions when he assumes the office. This evolving bargain over allocation of political power among multiple generations of leaders further keeps any one faction from dominating the others.

This theory generates two testable hypotheses on elite interactions within a dictatorship. The first hypothesis predicts a rather equal balance of power among the ruling elites when the dictator's tenure is governed by term limits. I use CCP top leaders’ capability in promoting their close associates to measure their power. Such even balance of power is a critical initial condition for the effective adoption of term limits, as the first ruler who resigned in accordance with term limits would only do so when his power was under sufficient check. Once adopted, term limits further reinforce this balance of power by placing the incumbent ruler under the shadow of post-tenure punishment and by allowing the elites to organize collective actions against the transgression of the ruler. The second hypothesis predicts that the effective adoption of term limits would initiate a series of actions by top-level elites in anticipation of future leadership turnover—such as active promotion of factional influence among multiple generations of leaders—that in turn keep the power of the incumbent ruler in check.

I test these hypotheses by looking at an important aspect of power sharing within the CCP—how opportunities to appoint close followers to the central committee are distributed among the top-level leaders. Unlike other institutionalized dictatorships, where elections are held periodically, there is no similar venue in the CCP regime through which people can observe the public displays of intra-elite competition. As a result, it becomes difficult to directly measure the power of individual leader, or to determine whether each leader's actions are constrained by a particular institution. The appointment of top-level CCP cadres—especially those at the central committee level and the above—is one of the very few institutionalized channels through which we can observe the allocation of power among top party leaders (e.g., Shih, Shan, and Liu Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010). The promotions of cadres into the central committee, which take place concurrently with leadership turnover during the National Party Congress, provide a rare opportunity to examine whether the actions of the party leaders are consistent with the theorized manners.

I use an original dataset of 631 CCP's Alternate Central Committee members in the post-Mao period (from 1982 to 2012). Alternate Central Committee (ACC) members, by definition, are officials who are “wait-listed” for the more powerful Central Committee—the selectorate of the CCP regime (Shirk Reference Shirk1993; Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003). Despite being the official “candidates” for the Central Committee, not all alternate members get promoted into the Central Committee. Among those who are promoted, substantial variations also exist in terms of the amount of time they spend waiting for the advancement. I exploit such variations and examine whether being connected with the past, present, and incoming top leaders affects one's chance of promotion into the Central Committee.

Following Shih, Shan, and Liu (Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010) and Shih, Adolph, and Liu (Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012), I measure an official's connection with top leaders based on whether they were born in the same province, went to the same institution of higher education, and have worked together in the same bureaucratic unit within two administrative steps of one another. Following the recent discussions on alternative ways of measuring factional ties (e.g., Keller Reference Keller2015 and article in this issue; Meyer, Shih, and Lee Reference Meyer, Shih and Lee2015), I also create two additional measures based on officials’ shared work experience to check the robustness of the most broadly defined measure of connection.

The result suggests that in the post-Mao CCP, connection with either the party's incumbent paramount leader or his rivals (the past and incoming general secretaries) increases an ACC member's chance of promotion. Neither the incumbent paramount leaders nor their rivals have enjoyed a decisive advantage over the other in promoting their followers either before or after the 16th party congress (2002)—when the term limits institution that currently governs the leadership transition in China became fully fledged. Top leaders (present, past and incoming general secretaries), however, have exerted more effort in promoting their followers since the 16th party congress. Connection with either incumbent or rival leaders has a more pronounced and significant effect on an alternate member's chance of promotion in this period (compared to the period before), especially during the two party congresses when the leadership transitions took place (the 16th and 18th congress, respectively). The result is robust to alternative ways of measuring elite connections, and after holding various personal idiosyncrasies—such as gender, ethnicity, education, princeling status, and the voting rank each ACC member received in the last party congress—constant.

This study is related to several important strands of literature in comparative and Chinese politics. Recent theoretical inquires in authoritarian politics have emphasized the role of formal political institutions in facilitating credible power sharing among the ruling elites (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013; Myerson Reference Myerson2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2009, 2012). The argument of this study embraces such perspectives and examines the role of term limits in authoritarian power sharing. While term limits that effectively bind top leaders is rarely seen among dictatorships as their adoption often requires even distribution of power among the ruling elites in the first place, once adopted, they generates expectations of future leadership turnover that in turn keep the power of the ruler in check (Svolik Reference Svolik2013). This study provides micro-level empirical evidence that lends strong support to this argument. In the meantime, at the macro-level, it also furthers our understanding on why the CCP regime, despite of lacking some commonly seen institutions that could facilitate credible power sharing (such as multi-party election), has been able to maintain a rather stable intra-elite relationship like many other one-party states (Brownlee Reference Brownlee2008; Geddes Reference Geddes1999; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2006, 2008; Smith Reference Smith2005).

This article is also built on a rich literature exploring the underlying logic of career advancement within the authoritarian bureaucracy. The empirical results speak to the important role of clientelistic networks in elite selection (e.g., Nathan Reference Nathan1973; Pye Reference Pye1980, Reference Pye1992; Dittmer Reference Dittmer1995; Shih Reference Shih2008a, Reference Shih2008b; Shih, Shan, and Liu Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010; Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012): officials connected with powerful patrons at the top tend to be rewarded with higher ranks. This study goes a step further and suggests a potential link between such informal, patronage-based selection and the institutionalization of leadership succession within CCP. Under the term limits, leaders appoint loyal associates into higher positions not only to advance their own factional influence, but also to limit the power of their rivals and to protect their interest in anticipation of leadership turnover. Thus, it behooves us to think about patronage-based promotion—which has been generally perceived as corruptive and distorting efficient allocation of talents—as an important mechanism through which balance of power might be maintained in a one-party state.

The remainder of the article proceeds as follows. Section 2 introduces some distinctive features of the CCP regime as a one-party state and the necessity to seek an alternative explanation for its stable inter-elite relations. It then introduces the theoretical framework of authoritarian power sharing under the term limits institution. Section 3 provides background information on the subject of the empirical analysis—CCP's Central Committee and its Alternate Committee. Section 4 details the data, the variables, and the estimation strategy. Section 5 presents estimation results. Section 6 concludes the paper with additional discussions.

2 THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

2.1 ONE-PARTY REGIME AND THE REGIME PARTY

One-party autocracies are in general more stable than other types of authoritarian regimes (Geddes Reference Geddes1999; Magaloni and Kricheli Reference Magaloni and Kricheli2010). The key mechanism, as Magaloni (Reference Magaloni2008) argues, is that authoritarian parties facilitate credible power sharing among the ruling elites. Authoritarian rulers, enjoying unchecked power, are unable to credibly commit to not abuse other members of the ruling coalition. Fearing the possibility of being exploited by the incumbent dictator, members of the ruling coalition tend to invest their loyalty in the subversion, not the survival, of the dictator. This commitment problem is mitigated when the incumbent dictator delegates his power of selecting ruling elite members to a parallel political organization, namely a political party, so that the ruling elites can also enjoy a share of power and spoils of office and without worrying too much about the changing whims of the ruler. Moreover, multi-party election also provides a potential exit option for the aggrieved ruling coalition members. Although most of these elections are restrictive and manipulated, defection of the ruling elites from the party would undermine the party's “image of invincibility (i.e., winning supermajority in the election to signal to the masses that the party is the “only game in town”),” and therefore constitutes a credible threat to the incumbent ruler who intends to exploit other elites. Cuauhtémoc Cárdenas’ defection from Mexico's long-time ruling Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI) in 1987—just one year before the presidential election—was a vivid real-life demonstration of such a mechanism.

The theory of credible power sharing through an authoritarian party assumes the following conditions. The authoritarian party operates in a rather independent manner from the incumbent executive. It exists as a political organization in which career advancement within its hierarchies is sufficient to ensure the long-term loyalty of the rank-and-file. It also assumes that powerful elites have the option to defect from the party, and once they have left the party they can still maintain their political influence and impose a credible threat to the incumbent ruler (e.g., through multi-party elections). While these assumptions are reasonable and can explain a wide range of variance across the world of one-party regimes, there is a small, yet important group of one-party regimes which are not consistent with these assumptions.

In these regimes, the boundary between the incumbent executive and the political party is often blurred or even does not exist. Government positions are made into a part of the party hierarchy, and the ranks within the party determine access to government resources. The incumbent rulers concurrently hold the position of party leaders, and control the distribution of political offices both within the government and the party. It is unlikely for an elite to escape from the influence of the ruler by situating himself only within the party. More crucially, no mass elections—even nominal ones—are held in these regimes, and only the ruling party can legitimately appoint political offices. Under such circumstances, the ruling party is truly “the only game in town” and there are no exit options for elites who are facing the risk of being exploited by the incumbent. Not only are there no popular elections in which rival elites could potentially form (or join) an opposition party and challenge the incumbent rulers, publically defecting from the ruling party is a serious crime in these regimes. The ruling party itself is equivalent to the regime, and there is no independent political sphere (either in government or in opposition parties) beyond the organization of the ruling party.

The Chinese Communist Party (CCP) is a typical example of such “regime party.”Footnote 1 The formation of CCP far predated that of the People's Republic of China. The party's leader is also the paramount leader of the regime. The Party rules the country with a nomenklatura system through which the Party not only makes government posts a part of the party hierachy, but also extends its reach into various public and private organizations (Burns Reference Burns1994; McGregor 2009). No competive, popular election exits in China, and the non-direct, carefully orchestrated elections of the people's congress delegates do nothing more than approving the candidates handpicked by the party committees at different levels (Manion Reference Manion2014; Truex Reference Truex2014). There are a handful, state-endorsed “democratic parties” under the close tutulage of CCP, serving as window dressings for the “CCP led multi-party collaboration” stipulated in the Chinese constitution. Forming independent political parties is outlawed in China, however, and unlike many other one-party states, the CCP even does not allow publically observable factions within the party, through which the elites could have organized collective actions against the ruler.Footnote 2 Despite all these inconsistencies with the conditions under which power sharing is made possible in one-party regimes, CCP has steadily ruled China in the past several decades, and has achieved an impressive record of economic growth (Nathan Reference Nathan2003). Why and how is credible power sharing possible within the CCP?

2.2 TERM LIMITS AND POWER SHARING IN A REGIME PARTY

Term limits that effectively govern the leadership transitions serve as an important alternative institution that facilitates power sharing in regime parties like CCP (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 2013). Studies of power sharing within one-party regime has recognized the role of institutionalized leadership turnovers (e.g., Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008), but have had less to say about how and under what conditions term limits matter. I define term limits explicitly in two dimensions, based on the features of CCP's leadership turnovers in the past decades. First, a well-established term limit system is one in which the leadership is subject to peaceful turnover following a fixed, periodic schedule. Second, the successor to the incumbent leader should be announced well before the turnover takes place.Footnote 3 Leadership turnovers lacking either of the two features are not sufficient to facilitate credible power sharing.

The term limits institution facilitates power sharing by mitigating the commitment problem between the ruler and the elites. Dictators worry about the security of their life and assets once they leave office (e.g., Debs Reference Debs2010; Escribà-Folch Reference Escribà-Folch2013; Albertus and Menaldo Reference Albertus and Menaldo2012), and such concern becomes more salient if they face a fixed schedule for stepping down. The term limit places the incumbent ruler who intends to exploit other elites under the shadow of future retaliation once his term ends. Elites who face the risk of being expropriated, on the other hand, can invest their loyalty and resources preemptively in the heir apparent who is capable of delivering such post-tenure punishment. These elites, meanwhile, will also enjoy a share of the power as a reward to their loyalty when the new leader assumes his office, and the political power these elites gain under the new leader could also impose a threat to the outgoing leader. A pre-appointed successor, combining with the fact that the ruler will have to step down in a future point, provides the elites an “exit option” from the incumbent ruler alternative to defection from the party. The threat of post-tenure punishment makes the ruler's commitment to share power with other elites more credible.

Not a single CCP paramount leader in the post-Mao era has been subject to post-tenure punishment so far. The absence of such punishment, however, does not mean that the institution is not working. In many cases, we see few consequences associated with deviations from the institutions, precisely because the relevant actors are behaving in accordance with the incentive structure induced by the institutions. Had the rulers (say Jiang Zemin or Hu Jintao) not been subject to term limits, they might have acted very differently from how they actually did. The recent fall of Zhou Yongkang also suggests that post-tenure punishment of top leaders is not an empty threat. Zhou is accused of “undermining party's solidarity and engaging in political activities not approved by the party” during his tenure as China's domestic security chief.Footnote 4 His continued support of Bo Xilai—his political ally—even when the party decided to take Bo down, caused the perhaps the most severe rift among the party's leadership since the Tiananmen Square incident. Although Zhou's activities raised concerns among other members of the party leadership and led to countermeasures even when he was still in power,Footnote 5 he was not formally arrested until two years after his retirement from the Politburo Standing Committee.Footnote 6

The term limits institution also facilitates power sharing by alleviating the monitoring problem faced by the elites. The secretive nature of authoritarian politics gives the ruler certain advantages in exploiting the elites: the elites often do not know for certain whether the ruler is transgressing the power-sharing agreement, and the ambiguity caused by such information scarcity incapacitates the elites from organizing successful collective actions against the ruler (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013). A fixed term and a pre-appointed successor place the ruler under a situation in which whether he complies with the institution is easily observable. A dictator's attempt to overstay in office would immediately send a clear signal to the elites that is not committed to power sharing. The heir apparent, who has the single largest share of interest in the succession, also provides a focal point around which the elites could coordinate collective oppositions against the ruler. This becomes particularly crucial if there is no other alternative mechanism, such as a public and organized faction, by which the elites could have devised collective actions. Imagine during the CCP's 16th Party Congress, if Jiang Zemin was not subject to a two-term limits as the head of the state and if the party did not already have a well-prepared successor (Hu Jintao), it would have been much more difficult for Jiang's opponent to organize collective effort to demand that he step down (Miller Reference Miller, Lin and Shirk2002; Shirk Reference Shirk, Lin and Shirk2002). Jiang's decision to stay as the chairman of the Central Military Commission in the same congress also sent a clear signal of his intention to overstay in power, making himself a target of criticisms both within and outside the party, which eventually forced him to resign completely two years later (Mulvenon Reference Mulvenon2005).

Term limits that effectively bind top leaders are rarely seen among dictatorships, however. The successful institutionalization of leadership turnover in the CCP should be attributed to several historical and political factors. First, the resignation of revolutionary veterans in the early 1980s set up a norm of retirement among the CCP top leaders (Manion Reference Manion1993). This norm was later reinforced through the introduction of the age-based mandatory retirement (Nathan Reference Nathan2003; Huang Reference Huang and Li2008; Shirk Reference Shirk2012). Second, the 1982 constitution of the CCP regime—the one currently in effect—stipulates a two-term limit for major political positions of the state, including the president, the prime minister, and the chairman of the National People's Congress Standing Committee. Since 1992, the paramount leaders of the CCP regime have been concurrently holding the position as the President of the state (Huang Reference Huang and Li2008), and are forced to relinquish other powerful positions (most notably, the General Party Secretary of the Central Committee) when his second term as the President ends (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, Chapter 4).Footnote 7

More importantly, the distribution of power was not highly skewed towards the incumbent leader even before the term limits were fully adopted. Deng, despite being a powerful leader, used his personal charisma to push forward a system that prevents over-concentration of party power in individuals. He reinforced the norm of retirement by voluntarily resigning from the chairmanship of the Central Military Commission. He also emphasized collective decision-making within party's top leadership, particularly in the Politburo Standing Committee, in order to weaken the role of individual leaders (Deng Reference Deng1993). He handpicked Hu as Jiang's successor and placed a number of his protégés (e.g., Zhu Rongji, Qiao Shi) into the Politburo Standing Committee to further keep Jiang's power in check. As a consequence, Jiang—Deng's chosen successor, did not enjoy the same level of personal authority as Mao and Deng, and was only “first among equals” (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 8) during his tenure as the party's paramount leader. Such a condition is important, as the first leader whose tenure was governed by the term limits—Jiang in the case of CCP—would only comply with the institution when his personal power was sufficiently confined.

Once the term limit is in place (i.e., when a leader is expected to step down in accordance with term limits), it generates expectations about the leadership turnover, and such expectations lead to an evolving bargain over allocation of power among multiple generations of leaders who in turn keep the ruler's power in check.Footnote 8 A leader who intends to overstay in office will face opposition not only from the heir apparent, but also from those aspiring elites who have preemptively invested their loyalty in the incoming leader (Svolik Reference Svolik2013).Footnote 9 An incumbent leader who is about to leave office also has the incentive to appoint close associates to powerful positions to ensure the hands of the succeeding ruler will be sufficiently tied. Jiang Zemin, for example, publicly announced the promotion of Jia Qinglin and Huang Jü several weeks before he handed over the CCP general secretaryship to Hu Jintao in November 2002. Jia and Huang, along with Jiang's other allies, significantly confined the influence of Hu Jintao within the Politburo Standing Committee and allowed Jiang, who already retired, to continue to exert influence on important decisions (Fewsmith Reference Fewsmith2003; Miller Reference Miller2004, Reference Miller2011). Similar to what Jiang did, immediately before his retirement in November 2012, Hu Jintao promoted two generals into the Central Military Commission as the Vice Chairmen, a move considered to limit the influence of Xi Jinping—Hu's successor—within the military (Mulvenon Reference Mulvenon2013). The incoming leader, knowing that his influence would be limited by his predecessor, will also try to secure important positions for his followers beforehand, so that he has a legion of elites that he can rely on to carry out his policies when he assumes the office.Footnote 10

As noted in the introduction, the theory allows us to derive two testable hypotheses regarding elite interactions under the constraints of term limits. The first hypothesis predicts that there is a rather equal distribution of power among the ruling elites when the dictator's tenure is governed by term limits. The second hypothesis predicts that the effective adoption of term limits would initiate a series of actions by top-level elites in anticipation of future leadership turnover—such as active promotion of factional influence among multiple generations of leaders—that in turn keep the power of the incumbent ruler in check.

I test these hypotheses by exploring an important aspect of elite politics within CCP—how the opportunities to appoint close followers into higher ranks are distributed among the top party leaders. Specifically, I look at the selection of CCP's Alternate Central Committee members into the Central Committee between 1982 and 2012. The appointment of top-level cadres associated with the party leaders—especially those at the central committee level and above—is one of the very few institutionalized channels through which we can observe the allocation of power among top party leaders (e.g., Shih, Shan, and Liu Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010). The promotions of elites into the Central Committee, which take place concurrently with leadership turnover during the National Party Congress, also provide a rare opportunity to examine whether the actions of the party leaders are consistent with the theorized manners. For this particular empirical exercise, we should expect a relatively equal distribution of the chances of promoting close associates between the incumbent paramount leader and his rivals during the entire period of observation, even before the term limits was fully effective (16th party congress). We also expect top leaders to exert more effort in promoting their followers as a result of power bargaining among multiple generations of leaders (i.e., “past, present, and future general secretaries (Shirk Reference Shirk2012)”) after the term limits was fully adopted. In the next section, I provide background information on the subject of the empirical analysis—CCP's Central Committee and its Alternate Committee.

3 CCP CENTRAL COMMITTEE AND ITS ALTERNATE COMMITTEE

There are several advantages in using CCP's Central Committee and its Alternate Committee as the subject of the empirical analysis. First, the Central Committee (hereafter CC) resides at the top of CCP regime's political structure. The CC, according to CCP's party constitution, assumes the highest authority in electing the Politburo and its Standing Committee (PSC)—the Party's top decision making body, and approves important platforms and resolutions proposed by the Politburo. The CC is by far the closest approximation of the concept of “selectorate” in an authoritarian regime (Shirk Reference Shirk1993; Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003), and has received a growing amount of scholarly attention (e.g., Li Reference Li2001; Kung and Chen Reference Kung and Chen2011; Sheng Reference Sheng2005; Shih, Shan, and Liu Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010; Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012). The appointment of CC members, a group of nearly 200 high-ranking officials, is where genuine political bargains among the top leaders are likely to take place. To what extent can a top leader place his followers into the central committee serves as a good proxy for his political power.

An idealistic (and methodologically impeccable) way to answer who will be appointed as a CC member would be obtaining the biographical profiles of all past and present members of CCP—the universe of the potential candidates for CC, which currently has 85 million party members, and looking at if the selection is patterned on particular individual attributes. For obvious reason, such strategy is infeasible, and thus I resort to a second-best approach—by looking at the advancement of the Alternate Central Committee members into CC. Alternate Central Committee (hereafter ACC) members, as is evidenced in its name, are those who are “wait-listed” for the CC. In each National Party's Congress, around 150 to 170 ACC members are elected along with the CC members. Accodring to Kung and Chen (Reference Kung and Chen2011), ACC members are different from the full CC members in three important aspects: full CC members hold (concurrently) more official positions in the party, the military, and the government than the ACC members; Full CC members occupy more strategic positions, whereas the appointments of ACC members were confined to positions of lesser political significance. Finally, although ACC members are allowed to sit in the plenary meetings of CC and voice their opinions, they are ineligible to vote on resolutions. These differenes provide strong incentives for ACC members to want to become full CC members.

Although being the official “candidates” for CC membership, not all ACC members eventually became CC members. Among the ACC members who were first elected since the 12th Party Congress (1982), 42% of them eventually got into the CC. The remaining 58% either retired from politics with the ACC being the highest position they have ever reached, or are still waiting to be promoted. Even among those who were promoted into CC, subtantial variation exists in terms of the speed of advancement: while it only took one congress (i.e., 5 years) for some ACC members to be promoted, others had to wait three (15 years) or even four congresses (20 years) to be promoted (see the data section below for more details). Such variations provide a rare opportunity to examine the determinants of their career advancement.

Another advantage of using ACC (as to using a random sample of all party members) is that a large number of ACC members have close connections with the top leaders. ACC members, despite being at the lower half of the party's central leadership, are nontheless high-ranking officials. For the ACC members being examined in this study (1982–2012), the average party experience when they were first elected as ACC members is 23.3 years. Most of these members are already serving major positions in the provincial government, the central bureaucracy, or in the military. There is a high chance that these officials have a shared working experience with the top ruling elites (the incumbent, the incoming or the retired leaders) during their long time party service, which many studies have used as a proxy for political connections (e.g., Shih, Shan and Liu Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2008; Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012; Jia, Kudamatsu, and Seim Reference Jia, Kudamatsu and Seim2014).

While the mechanism suggested in my argument—that term limits enhances the balance of power—might well apply at other levels of the CCP regime, espcially at the higher Politburo and Politburo Standing Committee (PSC), I choose to limit my analysis on ACC member's advancement into CC for two empirical reasons. First, the relative large sample size and a reasonable portion of ACC members being selected into the CC (48%) are ideal for us to uncover any systematic patterns of promotion. In contrast, the advancement into the much smaller sized Politburo or PSC leaves little space for making systematic inference—the difference in two or three observations might completely change the overall pattern. Second, the small and fixed sizes of the Politburo (around 20) and PSC (7 to 9) may also raise the concern on the violation of the independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) assumption for most statistical inference approaches. The chance of someone getting promoted into Politburo or PSC is not completely independent from other's chance of being promoted. In fact, one's promotion into the Politburo or PSC might well reduce other's chances of being promoted, given the extremely limited seats in these institutions. Although I fully recognize that the implication of my argument should also apply at other levels, I limit my empirical analysis to ACC's advancement into CC for these practical reasons.

4 DATA, METHOD, AND VARIABLES

4.1 DATA AND METHOD

I use an original dataset of CCP central committee members (Lu and Ma Reference Lu and Ma2015), which contains detailed biographical and career information of 1973 ACC and CC members from the 1st party congress (1921) to the 18th (2012).Footnote 11 For this project, I use those observations that entered ACC in any of the seven party congresses during China's reform era (1982–2012), among which I delete a handful that were already ACC members before this period but entered the sample as a result of reelection. I also do not include those who were newly elected ACC members in the 18th party congress, since they have not been exposed to a period of risk for promotion.

The resulting sample contains 631 ACC members. Among these members, sixty two are female (9.8%), seventy seven are ethnic minorities (12.2%), 370 have college degrees (58.6%), 200 have graduate degrees (31.7%), and sixteen are so called princelings (i.e., whose parents are cadres at or above the ministerial level). The mean age of first-time ACC members is 52.8, and the average party experience (i.e., time since joining the Communist Party) for the first-time ACC members is 23.3 years.

The mean length that these ACC members have stayed as observations is 1.38 party congresses (the congress is held every five year). 265 of them (42%) eventually experienced the event of interest (i.e., promotion to CC membership), and the remaining 58% are right censored. For those who were eventually promoted, the mean time to promotion is 1.24 congresses, and for those right-censored observations, the mean time they have stayed as ACC members is 1.48 congresses. Figure 1 provides a visual display of the data. The left bands of each column represent the cumulative percentages of ACC members being promoted into the CC in each of the congress since they were first elected, and the bands at the right represents the cumulative percentages of those who were not re-elected as ACC members. The “residuals” are the ones who are re-elected as ACC members. The two lines should eventually add up to 100%. We see that for ACC elected in each congress, no more than 50% of them eventually got into CC, and such pattern remains relatively stable during the entire observational period.

FIGURE 1 Visualizing the Dependent Variable (promotion and dropout in each congress, in %)

I organize the data into the person-congress format, which allows me to accommodate time-varying covariates. The unit of analysis is ACC member-congress in which he experienced the risk of promotion. For example, if person A is elected as an ACC member in the 12th congress, reelected as the ACC member in the 13th and 14th, and promoted into the CC in the 15th, the observations would be A-13, A-14, and A-15. I code the observation as 1 if the ACC was promoted into the CC, and 0 otherwise. Because I am interested in the effect of covariates, I apply piece-wise logistic survival model to analyze the data. The point estimates can be interpreted as the marginal effect of the covariates on the odds of the outcome—promotion into CC in each congress.

4.2 COVARIATES

My key covariates measure official's connections with the top leaders. For the theoretical purposes discussed earlier, I divided connections into two categories: connection with the incumbent paramount leader, and connection with the main political rivals of the incumbent—the past and incoming general party secretaries (for example, Jiang Zemin and Xi Jinping are rivals to Hu Jintao at the 18th Party Congress).Footnote 12 It is worth noting that we shall not take the word “rivals” in its literal sense, that the rival leaders necessarily have competing political objectives with the incumbent. Instead, as stated in my argument, the notion of “rivalry” tries to capture the political tension created in anticipation of leadership turnovers under the term limits. The” rivals” (the retired and incoming leaders) are the ones who have the genuine interest in and are also most capable of subjecting the incumbent to effective checks and balances.Footnote 13 Because of such categorization, the status of an ACC member's connection might change over time. For example, an official's connection to Jiang Zemin qualifies “connection to the incumbent” at 16th Party Congress (2002), but since Jiang stepped down after the 16th Party Congress, this connection changes to “connections to rival leaders” in the 17th and 18th Party Congresses. Later when I limit my analysis to observations in the 16th and 18th party congress—when the two peaceful leadership transitions took place--I further divide the rival leader category into past and incoming leaders.

Having known the classification of connections, a practical question then arises: how do we measure an official's connection with the top leaders? Like many other authoritarian regimes, elites politics in China is a black box, and personal relations between elite politicians are seldom reported publically. There are also no open and observable political factions within CCP like those in LDP or PRI that can provide a basis for coding elite connections. Arbitrary coding of connections based on already well-known patron-client relations (e.g., Cheng Liangyu, the former Party Secretary of Shanghai and an ACC member of the 15th Congress, is known to be a close associate of Jiang Zemin) would result in serious selection issues: we can only handpick those we know, but would miss a large number of potential connections we do not know. Estimation based on such selected sample would produce seemingly desirable yet largely biased results.

The probabilistic approach suggested by Shih, Shan, and Liu (Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2010) and Shih, Adolph, and Liu (Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012) provides a reasonable solution to this problem. It measures an official's connection with a top leader based on the following criteria: whether the two were born in the same province, graduated from the same institution, or worked in a same bureaucratic agency within two ranks at a given period of time. Although officials who have shared birthplace, education or workplace experience might not necessarily be connected, such probabilistic measure mitigates concerns for selection bias. I therefore follow this strategy and code ACC official's connection with the top leaders.

This approach is not without pitfalls, of course. Because China is a fairly large and populous country, being born in the same province or graduating from the same university might not be very informative criteria to determine connections. Following the suggestions in recent work that explore more accurate measures of factional ties (e.g., Keller Reference Keller2015 and article in this issue; Meyer, Shih, and Lee Reference Meyer, Shih and Lee2015), I pay additional attention to shared workplace experience between officials. I create two additional variables that are based on whether the official has a shared workplace experience with the top leaders (incumbent and rival), and whether the official shares 10% or more of his/her career with the top leaders. The rationale for the latter is that since top CCP cadres are career bureaucrats, they rarely stay in the same position or locale for an extended period of time,Footnote 14 and a 10% or more shared work experience (or more than three or four years) suggests that the two have worked together for an extended period of time, or might have worked as colleagues in multiple places—which is a strong indicator that the two are closely connected.Footnote 15 Results based on each of the three connection measures will be presented and compared in the estimation section.

The first control variable is the average provincial fiscal revenue relative growth during the four-year interim when the congress is not held as proxies for performance.Footnote 16 Fiscal revenue data has been considered a more credible indicator of local economic performance than the noisy GDP figures reported by local officials (Lü and Landry Reference Lü and Landry2014).Footnote 17 Following Shih, Adolph, and Liu (Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012), the relative growth is calculated by subtracting rest-of-China growth from each province's growth rate. Intuitively, this measure reflects how better (or worse) a province's revenue performance is relative to the average of all other provinces. It has several advantages. First, it allows the inclusion of ACC members who did not have provincial administrator experience, such as central government bureaucrats, military officials, university administrators, or star athletes into the analysis. Because provincial governor and party secretary account for less than 20% of all ACC members, using absolute growth data will result in list-wise deletion of more than 80% of the observations. These observations are assigned a score of zero under the relative growth calculation, assuming they are doing neither better nor worse than their peers in terms of generating revenue growth. Second, it makes comparison of growth rates over time feasible. The substantive meaning of absolute growth might change over time. For example, a 10% provincial revenue growth rate might have been only mediocre in the early 1990s, but it would be quite impressive in the late 2000s. The relative growth measure assumes the promotion is a zero-sum game (Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012), and mitigates the inconsistency problem of absolute growth rate over time.

The second set of control variables is a series of personal characteristics. They include ACC member's gender (1 if female), ethnicity (1 if ethnic minority), princeling status (1 if parents are cadres at the ministerial level or above), and education attainment (two dummy variables for college and graduate degree). I also include a dummy variable for whether the official is above the age of 60 at the time of congress, since the majority of the ACC members are at deputy ministerial/governor level or below, and the mandatory retirement age for officials at this level is 60.

The last covariate is the ACC voting rank. In each party congress, ACC members are ranked based on the number of votes they received during the election in National Party Congress. Extant studies suggest the voting rank being an indicator of ACC member's latent political strength (e.g., Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012), but whether the voting rank would affect the prospect of an ACC member's promotion into CC remains unclear. I take a one-congress lag of the ACC rank, in the spirit of using the voting rank one receives in the last congress to predict the probability of promotion in the current congress. All ACC ranks are standardized into percentiles (a score ranging from 0 to 1, with 1 denoting rank at the last in each congress).

5 RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS

5.1 POOLED SAMPLE ANALYSIS

I first estimate the result using pooled dataset for the entire observational period. Table 1 (in Online Appendix) presents models with the measures for connections only. In model 1 I use the original probabilistic measure for connection in Shih, Adolph, and Liu (Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012) with three components (shared birthplace, education institution, and workplace experience). In model 2 I use a more conservative measure that looks only at job overlaps, and in model 3 I further constrain the criteria by looking at whether an official shares 10% or more of his career with the top leaders. In all of the three models, connections with the incumbent and rival leaders have positive and statistically significant coefficients. Because the coefficients from logistic model are notoriously hard to interpret, following King, Tomz and Wittenberg (Reference King, Tomz and Wittenberg2000), I present a visual display of the covariates effect in Figure 2. Connection with the incumbent leader increases one's chance of promotion by about 12% to 15%, whereas connection with the rival leaders increases the chance by 7% to 9%.

FIGURE 2 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (Without Other Covariates)

I now turn to examine if the associations observed above are sensitive to potential confounders. The comparison of the effects of three measures after including the complete set of control variables is presented in Figure 3. It is evident that the positive effects of incumbent and rival connections remain largely similar as to the ones presented in the baseline models.Footnote 18 Because we are using the pooled data, the results lend strong support to the first hypothesis, that the opportunities to promote followers are distributed rather equally between the incumbent and the rival under the term limits. Neither the incumbent nor the rivals enjoy a decisive advantage (or disadvantage) in promoting their close associates during the entire observational period.

FIGURE 3 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates)

5.2. SPLIT SAMPLE ANALYSIS

As noted in the theory section, the expectation of future leadership turnover under the established term limits institution will stir a series of elite actions—i.e., active promotion of factional influence—that in turn keep any one faction from dominating the others. This leads to the second hypothesis: that we should observe the party leaders exerting more effort to promote their followers following the establishment of the term limits. Although several important elements of the term limits institution already emerged in the 1980s and 1990s (e.g., retirement of revolutionary veterans in 1980s, transition of leadership from Deng to Jiang in early 1990s, selection of Hu Jintao as the heir-apparent in the late 1990s), the term limits were not fully adopted until 2002—when Jiang stepped down as the general party secretary in the 16th party congress. Our analyses so far used the pooled data during the entire post-Mao period, which might have lumped together the dynamics of promotion under various degrees of institutional constraint. To explore such dynamics, I create two sub-samples of the data. The first sample includes only those observations since the 16th party congress (2002). The second sample includes those observations until the 15th party congress (1997). I run the full model with all control variables on the two samples and present the estimated marginal effects of the key covariates in Figures 4 and 5 (See Tables 2 and 3 in Online Appendix for the complete regression results). We need to bear in mind that the number of observations in each sub-sample is only half of that of the full sample. We should expect the degree of uncertainty (i.e., standard errors) to increase as the sample size reduces.

FIGURE 4 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates, Since 2002)

FIGURE 5 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates, until 1997)

Despite of having a much smaller sample size, the effects of the two key covariates still remain positive and statistically significant across all three different measures for the period since 2002 (Figure 4). Moreover, the connection to the rival leader increases one's chance of promotion by about 10% to 16% during this period, which is larger than the effect we observe in the aggregated sample (7%–9%).

In contrast, the marginal effects of connection with either the incumbent leader or the rivals, although both are positive, are not statistically significant for the period until the 15th party congress (Figure 5). There are several interpretations for this. First, as noted earlier, the increased uncertainty might just be a result of the reduced sample size. Second, as term limits were not fully adopted during this period, top-level leaders were not subject to the expectation of imminent leadership turnover, and thus were less engaged in promoting their followers to place other leaders under check and balance. Third, several members in the rival category in this period (Hu Yaobang in the 13th party congress, Zhao Ziyang in the 14th party congress) did not fit perfectly with the account of power sharing. Although both Hu and Zhao had held the position of general secretary, neither were paramount leaders. In addition, they did not leave office as a result of the binding term limits, but were instead forcefully removed from office due to their failure in the party's internal struggle, which suggests that their ability to promote factional members after they stepped down was very much limited. This also explains why the effect of connection with rivals is smaller than that of the incumbent during this period. However, the positive sign of the coefficients indicates that the rivals and their factions were not completely precluded from promoting their followers during this period, suggesting some informal elements of the term limits might already at work during this period.

Finally, I further restrict my analysis to observations in the 16th and 18th Party congress, when the two peaceful leadership turnovers (Jiang to Hu, and Hu to Xi, respectively) took place under the current term limits institution. I am able to code top leaders into three categories for these two congresses: the incumbent paramount leader who is about to step down (Jiang Zemin, Hu Jintao), the heir apparent who is about to succeed the office (Hu Jintao, Xi Jinping), and the past/retired paramount leader (Deng Xiaoping, Jiang Zemin). As discussed in the theory section, we should expect more intensive bargains over allocation of power among the present, past and future paramount leaders during the time of transition. I run the full model with all the control variables, and present the marginal effects of the three key covariates in Figure 6 (for full regression result, see Table 4 in Online Appendix). The effects of connections with the outgoing incumbent leader and incoming leader are both positive and statistically significant across all three measures. The substantive effects (around 25% to 35%) are much larger than the one we observe from the aggregated data. The effect of connection with retired leader is not statistically significant for the most broadly defined measure, but is significant for the two stricter measures. This uncertainty might be explained by a potential “cohort effect” (Meyer, Shih, and Lee Reference Meyer, Shih and Lee2015): as the influence of the retired (past) leader's factions declines over time, they tend to focus on promoting a handful of core factional members, instead of trying to send anyone that is vaguely connected into higher ranks.

FIGURE 6 The Two Transitioning Congresses (16th and 18th)

Results from these split sample analyses further shed lights on our understanding of the relationship between term limits and power sharing within the CCP. The evidence suggests that there was already a substantial degree of power sharing among the Party's top leadership before term limits were fully adopted. Neither the incumbent leader nor his rivals enjoyed a systematic edge over each other in promoting their close followers during this period. This is an important initial condition, as Svolik (Reference Svolik2013, 9) points out, that the effective adoption of the term limits relies on the even balance of power among the ruling elites. The first leader whose tenure is governed by term limits (Jiang Zemin in the case of CCP) would only comply with the institution when there is a relatively even balance of power among the elites. Once adopted, the term limits initiates expectation of leadership turnover among the elites that in turn enhances power sharing. Both the incumbent ruler and his rivals have clearly exerted more effort in promoting their close followers in the two transitioning congresses to ensure the hands of the future party leader would be tied. Patronage-based promotion, in this case, not only helps to advance leader's own factional interest, but also serves to place leaders under the checks by each other.

5.3. OTHER INDIVIDUAL ATTRIBUTES

Although the control variables are not the primary focus of this study, it is worth discussing their effects to better our understanding on the selection mechanism within the Central Committee. I run the model with full specification and present the simulated effects of all covariates in Figure 7 (for full regression result, see Table 5 in Online Appendix).

FIGURE 7 Effects of All Covariates

Two variables that show significantly negative effects are female and ethnic minority. Being a female or ethnic minority ACC member reduces the chance of promotion to CC by almost 20%. This is consistent with the intuition that ACC plays a partial “window dressing” function for the Party.Footnote 19 Women and ethnic minorities are appointed as ACC members to showcase the Party's commitment in promoting equality along the gender and ethnicity lines. Yet once it comes to the competition into more powerful positions like CC, these members are hugely disadvantaged or are even not considered for promotion at all.

A higher relative fiscal revenue growth does not contribute to one's chance of advancement. Despite ample evidence suggesting that the CCP tends to reward officials who can bring in more rents, especially at the lower tiers of government (Whiting Reference Whiting, Naughton and Yang2004; Lü and Landry Reference Lü and Landry2014), such logic seems to not apply at a higher level. This is consistent with what Lü, Landry, and Duan (Reference Lü, Landry and Duan2014) find, that the ability of an official to claim the credit for better economic performance becomes weaker and weaker as one climbs up the administrative ladder. At a level as high as Alternate Central Committee member, loyalty becomes the dominant concern when determining an official's further advancement into the inner circle (Egorov and Sonin Reference Egorov and Sonin2011; Jia, Kudamatsu, and Seim Reference Jia, Kudamatsu and Seim2014).

One's chance of promotion is reduced significantly if he is above the age of 60 at the time of party congress. This age is also the mandatory retirement age for cadres at the deputy minster/governor level—the ones that constitute the majority of ACC members. The negative and significant effect of age suggests the end of lifelong tenure among the CCP elites during the reform era (Manion Reference Manion1992, 1993). The adoption of age-based retirement ensures important party positions routinely become available, which is critical to “create an enduring stake in the regime's survival (Svolik Reference Svolik2012, 193)” among those rank-and-file with strong career aspirations.

College and post-graduate degrees do not bring advantage to ACC member's promotion, as suggested in Model 6 of Table 2. This result seems counterintuitive, as many other studies have found a positive correlation between political ranks and educational attainment (e.g., Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012). Yet in the case of ACC's promotion into CC, education qualification might work in opposite directions. Higher level in education might indeed accelerate the speed of those career bureaucrats’ promotion into the CC. But for those social elites with very high education qualifications (e.g., intellectuals, entrepreneurs), ACC is perhaps the highest rank they can make, or more precisely, the Party co-opted them into the ACC but with no intention to further promote them into more powerful positions. Zhang Yanzhong, who holds a Ph.D. from Oxford and is one of China's leading aeronautical scientists, was elected an ACC member in the 13th (1987) and 14th (1992) Party congress, but he never made it to the more powerful CC. Zhang Ruimin, CEO of Haier Group and a former master student at Chinese University of Science and Technology, has been elected ACC member for consecutively three congresses (16th, 17th, and 18th). Such examples again suggest the dual function of the ACC. On the one hand, ACC is a career step stone for those who arise within the regime and are potential candidates for the selectorate. On the other hand, ACC performs the role of co-opting influential non-regime elites into the high ranks of the Party, providing them with considerable political status but little substance in power sharing.

Princelings, who have long enjoyed unmatched political and economic privileges in China, do not seem to have a systematic edge in terms of promotion from an ACC member to a full CC member. While the sign of the coefficient suggests a positive effect (see Figure 3), such effect is not salient at the 90% level. One potential explanation for the large uncertainty is perhaps there are so few princelings in the sample (16 out of 631).

ACC voting rank is positively associated with the prospect of promotion at a marginally significant level. Although ACC election is largely orchestrated and follows the order from the top leaders, it does not mean the voting rank reflects accurately the potential strength of each individual ACC member. The central leader's order can safely manipulate who will be selected into the ACC, but is unlikely to control precisely how many votes each ACC member would receive from close to 3000 National Party Congress delegates (Lu and Ma Reference Lu and Ma2015). The relative large uncertainty could also be driven by that fact that several ACC members who were at the bottom of the rank have performed surprisingly well. Xi Jinping, who ranked the last in the 15th ACC, was promoted to the CC in the 16th Party Congress, entered the most powerful Politburo Standing Committee in the 17th Party Congress, and ascended to the position of General Party Secretary—China's paramount leader—in the 18th Party Congress. Jia Tingan, former general party secretary Jiang Zemin's personal associate, ranked the last in the 17th ACC. He was promoted to the CC in the 18th Party Congress.

6 CONCLUDING REMARKS

Fearing the possibility of internal breakup, Deng Xiaoping warned his colleagues during his famous “Southern Tour” that “if there is going to be a problem (in the future), it is probably from within the Party.”Footnote 20 The CCP however has achieved a rather stable intra-party elite relationship despite its departure from a typical model of one-party state that could facilitate credible power sharing among the elites. This paper argues that term limits that bind the top leaders, which the CCP has institutionalized over the past three decades, serve as an alternative institution under which power sharing becomes possible.

Although the empirical part of the paper focuses on patronage-based promotion under term limits, the overall argument might also help us to understand promotions based on merit. An influential line of empirical studies on the Chinese bureaucracy has argued for a merit-based promotion model.Footnote 21 Yet few have questioned why few other authoritarian regimes have adopted a similar bureaucratic selection system. The strong growth orientation of the CCP bureaucracy is likely a result of credible power sharing within the party: economic growth becomes the common pursuit of the top-level elites under effective power sharing, as they all would be more or less well off with increased economic rents (Geddes Reference Geddes1999).

Finally, it is noteworthy that the scope of the analysis in this article is limited to the relationship between the term limits that binds CCP's paramount leader and the power sharing among the party elites. This naturally leaves many important questions unanswered. For example, this article does not address the potential policy implications of term limits. The adoption of term limits might be a double-edge sword from a policy perspective. On the one hand, the institutionalization of elite politics reduces the tremendous uncertainties associated with the successions, therefore increasing the credibility of the policies by the regime.Footnote 22 On the other hand, the resulting power decentralization among the party leaders could also produce policy paralysis, making reforms in key policy areas more difficult for the leaders (such as the policy stagnation during Hu Jintao's tenure).

In recent years, the CCP has also institutionalized term limits at lower levels of the party and government. Together with age-based mandatory retirement, term limits continuously create vacancies at various positions that pave the way for the party to purchase the loyalty of some of its most competent and aspiring cadres (Geddes Reference Geddes1999; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2012, Chapter 6). Recent empirical studies on local officials in China (e.g., Guo Reference Guo2009; Pan Reference Pan2013; Wallace Reference Wallace2016), however find that the manipulation of local cadre's career aspirations through term limits might also lead to perverse consequences that could undermine the overall accountability of the regime (e.g., data manipulation before the turnover). The role of the institution of term limits in authoritarian survival is yet to be fully explored and will continue to be an interesting subject of future scholarly inquires.

Footnotes

1 I borrow this term from Svolik's discussion (2012, Chapter 6) on authoritarian parties.

2 The CCP has repetitively cracked down attempts to form organized factions within the Party. For a recent move in this regard, see People.com, December 29, 2014, “Politburo: Zero Tolerance to Forming Factions and Pursuing Individual Interest within the Party.” http://politics.people.com.cn/n/2014/1229/c70731-26295927.html (last accessed Feb 2, 2015). The absence of open, organized factions also propels the elites to signal their loyalty to the top leaders via unconventional approach (see for example, Shih Reference Shih2008a).

3 This characteristic is based on the experience of CCP's leadership turnover in recent decades. For example, Hu Jintao emerged as the heir apparent after the 15th Party Congress (1997), five years before he succeeded Jiang Zemin; Xi Jinping became the heir apparent after the 17th Party Congress (Reference Xi2007), five years before he succeeded Hu Jintao.

4 See Nectar Gan, 2015. “China's Supreme Court takes aim at disgraced Zhou Yongkang and Bo Xilai.” South China Morning Post, 19 March 2015. http://www.scmp.com/news/china/article/1741522/supreme-court-report-takes-aim-zhou-and-bo (last accessed, March 20, 2015).

5 For media reference, see also Reuters.com, 2012. “Exclusive: China considers downgrading domestic security tsar in next line-up,” August 29, 2012. http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/08/29/uschina-politics-security-idUSBRE87S1F020120829 (last accessed, January 22, 2015).

6 Xinhua.net, 2014. “Zhou Yongkang investigated for serious disciplinary violation.” July 29, 2014. http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2014–07/29/c_133518450.htm (last accessed, January 22, 2015).

7 Jiang Zemin tried to maintain his political influence even after relinquished his position as the President of the state and the General Party Secretary of the Central Committee, by staying as the Chairman of the Central Military Commission for two additional years. As noted earlier, such behavior constitutes a clear signal of the ruler's intention to transgress the power sharing agreement, making the ruler an easy target of collective opposition. Jiang's successor, Hu Jintao, relinquished all positions when his term ended in 2012.

8 This insight is consistent with an important line of work on how institutions initiate mutual expectations among political actors and impose self-enforcing limits on executive authority (see for example, Carey Reference Carey2000; Hardin Reference Hardin, Grofman and Wittman1989; Myerson Reference Myerson2008; Weingast Reference Weingast1997).

9 A notable example of such “preemptive investment of loyalty” is that after Xi Jinping was rumored to be considered as the heir apparent in the summer 2007—several months before the 17th Party Congress, Zhejiang People's Press published a collection of Xi's speeches during his tenure as the provincial party secretary in Zhejiang, a rare move by a provincial mouth-piece for an ex-provincial party secretary. See Xi Jinping, August 2007, Zhijiang Xinyu [in Chinese, New Words from Zhejiang], Zhejiang People's Press.

10 An example is that Li Zhanshu, Xi's friend from his early years in Hebei province, was appointed to the important position as the director of the general office of CCP in July 2012, several months before Xi succeeded Hu Jintao (Li Reference Li2014). In a recent study, Meyer, Shih, and Lee (2015) also find that Hu Jintao and Xi Jinping promoted a large number of their followers into the central committee at the party congress when they each assumed the office as the general party secretary (16th and 18th, respectively).

11 This dataset is an extension of the original dataset collected by Shih, Shan and Liu (Reference Shih, Shan and Liu2008), which document the biographical information of all CC and ACC members until the 16th party congress. Lu and Ma (Reference Lu and Ma2015) follow the strategy suggested by Adolph (Reference Adolph2003, Reference Adolph2013) to code the official vitas for officials entered the data in the 17th and 18th party congress. It allows us to preserve every piece of information appears on an official's CV, not just those that are pertinent to this particular study. The official vitas of the 17th and 18th CC and ACC member are obtained from the officially endorsed Xinhuanet.com, with only a handful of exceptions.

12 The incumbent leaders are Deng Xiaoping (13th Party Congress), Jiang Zemin (14th, 15th, and 16th Party Congress), and Hu Jintao (17th and 18th Party Congress). The 12th party congress is included in the sample but does not generate any observations, because it is the first congress in the observational period, and no ACC member in the data experienced the risk of being promoted (i.e., the ones elected in the 12th congress experienced the risk of promotion in the 13th congress for the first time).

13 For the 13th and 14th Party Congress (when the term limits was not fully established), I code Hu Yaobang (13th) and Zhao Ziyang (13th and 14th) as the rival leaders. Both Hu and Zhao were once considered hopeful successors to Deng Xiaoping, and held the general party secretaryship—the nominally highest position within the party. They were later purged during the internal political struggles of the party. Hu and Zhao's factions nonetheless were able to promote some of their members into higher positions even after their purge from the top leadership (e.g., Shih, Adolph, and Liu Reference Shih, Adolph and Liu2012).

14 For example, Xi Jinping served 12 different positions (not including those concurrent positions) from 1979—the year he graduated from college—to 2007, the year he was appointed the heir apparent. He spent on average 2.33 years in each position. For the official vita of Xi, see Xinhuanet.com, http://news.xinhuanet.com/rwk/2013-02/01/c_114586554.htm (last accessed, January 29, 2015).

15 Keller further uses whether an officials received a promotion when working under the party leader as an additional criterion to identity connection (see her article in this issue). This method, as Meyer, Shih, and Lee (2015) notes, would result in too few observable connections among the ACC members.

16 Revenue growth data from the year party congress is held is not included in the average measure, because the economic data will not be released until the first quarter of the next year and therefore should not be a basis of promotion judgment. For the remaining four-year period, if an official served as the provincial party secretary or governor for all four years, a four-year average is calculated. If only three years, then the average is calculated on a three-year basis, and so on. The determinant of year follows a “three-month rule”: if an official ends a job before the end of March, then the job is coded as ending in the previous year; if an official starts a job after September 30, then the job is coded as starting in the next year.

17 For problems of Chinese local GDP data, see for example Rawski (Reference Rawski2001); for recent efforts in exploring alternative measures for local economic performance, see for example Lorentzen, Landry, and Yasuda (Reference Lorentzen, Landry and Yasuda2014), and Wallace (Reference Wallace2016).

18 The strictest measure for rival connection, as demonstrated in Figure 4, is no longer significant at the 90% level, but it only crosses the borderline by a tiny margin.

19 The claim that ACC plays a partial “window dressing” role is also backed by the fact the portion of ethnic minority members in ACC is close to ethnic minority's population portion (around 10%). Yet the portion shrinks dramatically in the more powerful CC and politburo. There has been no ethnic minority (or female) member in the most powerful Politburo Standing Committee throughout CCP's history.

20 People.com. May 2012, “Deng Xiaoping: If China are to have problem, it is probably from within the Party.” May 2, 2012, http://history.people.com.cn/GB/198454/17794010.html (last accessed, January 29, 2015).

21 Extant studies have examined this hypothesis at various levels of the Chinese bureaucracy, including at the levels of township (Whiting Reference Whiting2001, 2004; Edin Reference Edin2003), county (Kung and Chen Reference Kung and Chen2013), municipality (Landry Reference Landry2008), and province (Bo Reference Bo1996; Li and Zhou Reference Li and Zhou2005). For a recent survey of this subject, see Lü, Landry, and Duan (2014).

22 I thank the journal editor Stephan Haggard for suggesting this important point.

References

REFERENCES

Adolph, Christopher. 2003. Paper autonomy, private ambition: Theory and evidence linking central bankers’ careers and economic performance. In Annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia.Google Scholar
Adolph, Christopher. 2013. Bankers, Bureaucrats, and Central Bank Politics: The Myth of Neutrality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Albertus, Michael, and Menaldo, Victor. 2012. “Dictators as Founding Fathers? The Role of Constitutions under Autocracy.” Economics & Politics 24 (3): 279306.Google Scholar
Bo, Zhiyue. 1996. “Economic Performance and Political Mobility: Chinese Provincial Leaders.” Journal of Contemporary China 5 (12): 135154.Google Scholar
Boix, Carles, and Svolik, Milan. 2013. “The Foundations of Limited Authoritarian Government: Institutions, Commitment, and Power-Sharing in Dictatorships.” The Journal of Politics 75 (2): 300316.Google Scholar
Brownlee, Jason. 2007. “Hereditary Succession in Modern Autocracies.” World Politics 59 (4): 595628.Google Scholar
Brownlee, Jason. 2008. “Bound to Rule: Party Institutions and Regime Trajectories in Malaysia and the Philippines.” Journal of East Asian Studies 8 (1): 89118.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph M., and Morrow, James D.. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, John. P. 1994. “Strengthening Central CCP Control of Leadership Selection: the 1990 Nomenklatura.” The China Quarterly 138: 458491.Google Scholar
Carey, John. M. 2000. “Parchment, Equilibria, and Institutions.” Comparative Political Studies 33 (6–7): 735761.Google Scholar
Debs, Alexander. 2010. “Living by the Sword and Dying by the Sword? Leadership Transitions in and out of Dictatorships.” Unpublished manuscript at Yale University.Google Scholar
Deng, Xiaopig. 1993. The Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping, Vol. 3. Beijing: People's Publisher.Google Scholar
Dittmer, Lowell. 1995. “Chinese Informal Politics.” China Journal 34: 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edin, Maria. 2003. “State Capacity and Local Agent Control in China: CCP Cadre Management from a Township Perspective.” The China Quarterly 173: 3552.Google Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2011. “Dictators and their Viziers: Endogenizing the Loyalty–Competence Trade-Off.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (5): 903930.Google Scholar
Escribà-Folch, Abel. 2013. “Accountable for what? Regime types, performance, and the fate of outgoing dictators, 1946–2004.” Democratization 20 (1): 160185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fewsmith, Joseph. 2003. “The 16th Party Congress: Implications for Understanding Chinese Politics.” China Leadership Monitor 5.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Przeworski, Adam. 2006. “Cooperation, Cooptation, and Rebellion under Dictatorships.” Economics & Politics 18 (1): 126.Google Scholar
Geddes, Barbara. 1999. “What do we Know about Democratization after Twenty Years?Annual Review of Political Science 2 (1): 115144.Google Scholar
Guo, Gang. 2009. “China's Local Political Budget Cycles.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (3): 621632.Google Scholar
Haber, Stephan. (2007). “Authoritarian Government.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by Weingast, Barry and Wittman, Donald, 693707. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. (1989). “Why a Constitution.” In The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism, edited by Grofman, Bernard and Wittman, Donald, 100120. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Huang, Jing. (2008). “Institutionalization of Political Succession in China: Progress and Implications.” in China's Changing Political Landscape: Prospectus for Democracy, edited by Li, Cheng, 8097. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Jia, Ruixue, Kudamatsu, Masayuki, and Seim, David. 2014. “Political Selection in China: The Complementary Roles of Connections and Performance.” IFN Working Paper No. 1003.Google Scholar
Keller, Franziska. 2015. Moving beyond factions: using Social Network Analysis to uncover patronage networks among Chinese elites. Paper presented at the Conference of Quantitative Studies of Chinese Elites, February 2015 University of California, San Diego.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Tomz, Michael, and Wittenberg, Jason. 2000. “Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (2): 347361.Google Scholar
Kokkonen, Andrej, and Sundell, Anders. 2014. “Delivering Stability—Primogeniture and Autocratic Survival in European Monarchies 1000–1800.” American Political Science Review 108 (2): 438453.Google Scholar
Kung, James, and Chen, Shuo. 2011. “The Tragedy of the Nomenklatura: Career Incentives and Political Radicalism during China's Great Leap Famine.” American Political Science Review 105 (1): 2745.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kung, James, and Chen, Ting. 2013. “The Mystery of Authoritarian Growth: Land Revenue and the Career Concerns of China's Local Leaders.” Working paper, HKUST.Google Scholar
Landry, Pierre. 2008. Decentralized Authoritarianism in China. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Li, Cheng. 2001. China's Leaders: The New Generation. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.Google Scholar
Li, Cheng. (2014). “Xi Jinping's Inner Circle (Part 2: Friends from Xi's Formative Years).” China Leadership Monitor 44.Google Scholar
Li, Hongbin, and Zhou, Li-An. 2005. “Political Turnover and Economic Performance: the Incentive Role of Personnel Control in China.” Journal of Public Economics 89 (9): 17431762.Google Scholar
Lorentzen, Peter, Landry, Pierre, and Yasuda, John. 2014. “Undermining Authoritarian Innovation: The Power of China's Industrial Giants.” The Journal of Politics 76 (1): 195214.Google Scholar
Lu, Fengming, and Ma, Xiao. 2015. “Keep Silent and Make a Big Fortune: How Appearances in Partially Free Media Affect an Authoritarian Intra-Elite Election.” Paper presented at the 2015 Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meeting, Chicago, April 2015.Google Scholar
, Xiaobo and Landry, Pierre F.. 2014. “Show Me the Money: Interjurisdiction, Political Competition and Fiscal Extraction in China.” American Political Science Review 108 (3): 706722.Google Scholar
, Xiaobo, Landry, Pierre and Duan, Haiyan. 2014. “Does Performance Matter? Evaluating the Institution of Political Selection along the Chinese Administrative Ladder.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 2014.Google Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and its Demise in Mexico. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. “Credible Power-Sharing and the Longevity of Authoritarian Rule.” Comparative Political Studies 41 (4–5): 715741.Google Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz, and Kricheli, Ruth. 2010. “Political Order and One-Party Rule.” Annual Review of Political Science 13: 123143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund. 2009. “Gerrymandering—Vietnamese style: Escaping The Partial Reform Equilibrium in a Nondemocratic Regime.” The Journal of Politics 71 (1): 132159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malesky, Edmund, and Schuler, Paul. 2010. “Nodding or Needling: Analyzing Delegate Responsiveness in an Authoritarian Parliament.” American Political Science Review 104 (3): 482502.Google Scholar
Manion, Melanie. 1992. “Politics and Policy in Post-Mao Cadre Retirement.” The China Quarterly 129: 125.Google Scholar
Manion, Melanie. 1993. Retirement of revolutionaries in China: Public policies, Social Norms, Private Interests. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Manion, Melanie. 2014. “Authoritarian Parochialism: Local Congressional Representation in China.” The China Quarterly 218: 311338.Google Scholar
Meyer, David, Shih, Victor, and Lee, Jonghkyuk. 2015. “The Performance of Various Factions Indicators.” Paper presented at the Conference of Quantitative Studies of Chinese Elites, University of California, San Diego, February 2015.Google Scholar
Miller, Alice. 2004. “Hu Jintao and the Party Politburo.” China Leadership Monitor 9.Google Scholar
Miller, Alice. (2011). “The Politburo Standing Committee under Hu Jintao.” China Leadership Monitor 35.Google Scholar
Miller, Lyman. 2002. “The 16th Party Congress and China's Political Processes.” In The 16th CCP Congress and Leadership Transition in China, edited by Lin, Gang and Shirk, Susan, 1014. Washington, DC: The Woodrow Wilson Center Asia Program.Google Scholar
Mulvenon, James. (2005). “The King Is Dead! Long Live the King! The CMC Leadership Transition from Jiang to Hu.” China Leadership Monitor 13.Google Scholar
Mulvenon, James. 2013. “The New Central Military Commission.” China Leadership Monitor 40.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger. 2008. “The Autocrat's Credibility Problem and Foundations of the Constitutional State.” American Political Science Review 102 (1): 125139.Google Scholar
Nathan, Andrew. 1973. “A Factionalism Model for CCP Politics.” China Quarterly 53: 3466.Google Scholar
Nathan, Andrew. 2003. “Authoritarian resilience.” Journal of Democracy 14 (1): 617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pan, Jennifer. 2013. “Measuring the Goals and Incentives of Local Chinese Officials.” Harvard University Working Paper.Google Scholar
Pye, Lucian. 1980. The Dynamics of Factions and Consensus in Chinese Politics. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
Pye, Lucian. 1992. The Spirit of Chinese Politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rawski, Thomas. 2001. “What is happening to China's GDP statistics?China Economic Review 12 (4): 347354.Google Scholar
Sheng, Yumin. 2005. “Central–Provincial Relations at the CCP Central Committees: Institutions, Measurement and Empirical Trends, 1978–2002.” The China Quarterly 182: 338355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shih, Victor. 2008a. “‘Nauseating’ Displays of Loyalty: Monitoring the Factional Bargain Through Ideological Campaigns in China.” The Journal of Politics 70 (4): 11771192.Google Scholar
Shih, Victor. 2008b. Factions and Finance in China: Elite Conflict and Inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shih, Victor, Adolph, Christopher, Liu, Mingxing. 2012. “Getting Ahead in the Communist Party: Explaining the Advancement of Central Committee Members in China.” American Political Science Review 106 (1): 166187.Google Scholar
Shih, Victor, Shan, Wei, Liu, Mingxing. 2008. “Biographical Data of Central Committee Members: First to Sixteenth Party Congress” [Dataset]. Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Shih, Victor, Shan, Wei, Liu, Mingxing. 2010. “Gauging the Elite Political Equilibrium in the CCP: A Quantitative Approach Using Biographical Data. The China Quarterly 201: 79103.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shirk, Susan. 2002. “The Succession Game.” in The 16th CCP Congress and Leadership Transition in China, edited by Lin, Gang and Shirk, Susan, 59. Washington, DC: The Woodrow Wilson Center Asia Program.Google Scholar
Shirk, Susan. 2012. “Age of China's New Leaders May Have Been Key to Their Selection.” China File, November 15, 2012. http://www.chinafile.com/reporting-opinion/viewpoint/age-chinas-new-leaders-may-have-been-key-their-selection (accessed March 25, 2015).Google Scholar
Smith, Benjamin. 2005. “Life of the Party: The Origins of Regime Breakdown and Persistence under Single-Party Rule.” World Politics 57 (3): 421451.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2009. “Power Sharing and Leadership Dynamics in Authoritarian Regimes.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (2): 477494.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2013. “Incentives, Institutions, and the Challenges to Research on Authoritarian Politics.” APSA Comparative Democratization Newsletter.Google Scholar
Truex, Rory. 2014. “Representation within Bounds.” PhD diss., Yale University.Google Scholar
Wallace, Jeremy. 2016. “Juking the Stats? Authoritarian Information Problems in China.” British Journal of Political Science 46: 1129.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of the Law.” American Political Science Review 91 (2): 245263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whiting, Susan. 2001. Power and Wealth In Rural China: The Political Economy of Institutional Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Whiting, Susan. 2004. “The Cadre Evaluation System at the Grass Roots: The Paradox of Party Rule.” In Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era, edited by Naughton, Barry J. and Yang, Dali L., 101119. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Xi, Jinping. 2007. Zhijiang Xinyu [in Chinese, New Words from Zhejiang]. Hangzhou: Zhejiang People's Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

FIGURE 1 Visualizing the Dependent Variable (promotion and dropout in each congress, in %)

Figure 1

FIGURE 2 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (Without Other Covariates)

Figure 2

FIGURE 3 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates)

Figure 3

FIGURE 4 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates, Since 2002)

Figure 4

FIGURE 5 Comparison Between Three Coding Strategies of Connections (With All Covariates, until 1997)

Figure 5

FIGURE 6 The Two Transitioning Congresses (16th and 18th)

Figure 6

FIGURE 7 Effects of All Covariates