Hostname: page-component-6bf8c574d5-h6jzd Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2025-02-20T19:51:26.790Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 February 2005

Keiko Kubota
Affiliation:
Keiko Kubota is Research Assistant at the World Bank. She can be reached at kkobota@worldbank.org.

Abstract

Rising international trade flows are a primary component of globalization. The liberalization of trade policy in many developing countries has helped foster the growth of these flows. Preceding and concurrent with this move to free trade, there has been a global movement toward democracy. We argue that these two trends are related: democratization of the political system reduces the ability of governments to use trade barriers as a strategy for building political support. Political leaders in labor-rich countries may prefer lower trade barriers as democracy increases. Empirical evidence supports our claim about the developing countries from 1970–99. Regime change toward democracy is associated with trade liberalization, controlling for many factors. Conventional explanations of economic reform, such as economic crises and external pressures, seem less salient. Democratization may have fostered globalization in this period.We wish to thank the editors at International Organization, David Baldwin, Jim Fearon, Geoffrey Garrett, Barbara Geddes, Tim Groseclose, Robert Kaufmann, Robert Keohane, David Laitin, Jean Leca, Edward Mansfield, Jim Morrow, Ronald Rogowski, B. Peter Rosendorff, Alex Segura, Mike Tomz, Robert Trager, Romain Wacziarg, and Greg Wawro, for their very helpful comments on versions of this article. We also received helpful comments from seminar participants at the University of Michigan, Stanford University, the University of Pennsylvania, Syracuse University, Princeton University, Rutgers University, Yale University, and the University of California at Berkeley. Ben Judkins, Robert Trager, Megumi Naoi, and Tom Kenyon provided invaluable research assistance. An earlier version was presented at the 2001 APSA meeting in San Francisco.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2005 The IO Foundation and Cambridge University Press

Since the 1970s, globalization has advanced broadly. Some four billion people, roughly two-thirds of the world's population, have joined the world economy during the past twenty-five years as part of the increasing integration of ever more countries into the world trading system. Declining trade barriers have contributed significantly to this expansion of world trade. Countries across the globe—ones as diverse as the Philippines, Zambia, Mexico, Poland, Chile, Bangladesh, Ghana, Korea, and Morocco—have all chosen to liberalize unilaterally their trade policies. In the developing countries, this “rush to free trade” gathered momentum in the mid-1980s.1

This term was coined by Rodrik 1994.

As the International Monetary Fund (IMF) pointed out in 1992, “[s]ince the mid-1980s, there has been a marked shift in the orientation of the trade and industrial policies of most developing countries away from a heavy reliance on direct intervention and inward-looking industrial policies toward less controlled and more export-oriented trade regimes.” More recent studies show that this change in policy has occurred in most regions and continued throughout the 1990s.2 Countries have chosen to integrate their economies into a global one by dismantling protectionist barriers.

This substantial change in trade policy is surprising. Over the years, many scholars have emphasized the durability of the status quo in economic policy.3

See, for example, Fernandez and Rodrik 1991.

In trade policy the status quo bias is viewed as even more significant, as the benefits of protectionism are highly concentrated while its costs are diffuse.4

A status quo bias exists if trade liberalization is welfare enhancing but policy change is not made because the political costs of liberalization outweigh the economic benefits to be gained from it.

Vested interests in protectionist sectors can be tenacious pressure groups with preferred access to policymakers. Any change in the protectionist status quo is thus unexpected. For the less-developed countries (LDCs) to abandon their protectionist, import-substituting industrialization (ISI) strategy was surprising, given existing models of the political economy of trade policy.5

As Rodrik 1994 notes.

Explanations for this change have emphasized three factors. Some scholars claim that economic crises have forced countries to reform and liberalize. Others have claimed that external pressures from the United States, Western countries in general, or international institutions, such as the World Trade Organization (WTO), IMF, and World Bank, are responsible. Finally, the spread of neoliberal policy ideas is often credited with bringing economic liberalization. We examine these claims with respect to trade policy and introduce another factor that we think is important and underappreciated.

Beginning nearly a decade before this move to free trade was a global movement toward democracy. In 1975, there were approximately thirty democracies in the world; by 1992 there were about eighty-nine, which was roughly half the total number of independent countries in the world.6

By 2002, this figure had risen to more than 120 countries.7 Are these two trends in economic and political reform related? Are democracies more likely to initiate trade liberalizing reforms than autocracies?

Many different claims about how political institutions affect trade policy exist, but systematic theory and data are lacking. Rodrik argues that any change in a political regime is likely to induce trade reforms. “Historically sharp changes in trade policy have almost always been preceded (or accompanied) by changes in the political regime. Not all political transformations result in trade reform, but sharp changes in trade policy are typically the result of such transformations.”8

The conventional wisdom, however, has been that democracy is not propitious for economic reform, and indeed that nondemocratic countries should be more likely to liberalize, as Chile in the 1970s suggests. As Geddes summarizes, “until recently, it was widely accepted that democracies, especially fragile, uninstitutionalized new democracies have difficulty carrying out economic liberalization because its costs make it unpopular and hence politically suicidal to elected officials. Consequently, it was argued, authoritarian governments should be more capable of initiating and sustaining major economic reforms.”9

Other scholars have argued that regime type makes little difference for economic reform.10

See, for example, Nelson 1990; and Remmer 1990.

Finally, Haggard and Kaufmann argue that differences within regime types (that is, among democracies and among autocracies) are likely to have more effect than is regime type itself.11 A few systematic studies of the impact of democracy on trade liberalization exist.12 But only recently have some claimed that democracy might make economic reform more likely.13 In sum, the systematic investigation of the impact of political institutions on the decision to liberalize trade merits greater attention.

In the political economy literature, the question is approached from the opposite end: what determines trade policy? A vast literature explores this issue. We point out several contributions that lay the groundwork for our argument, focusing on the Heckscher-Ohlin and Stopler-Samuelson theorems.14

The main alternative to this political economy model is the Ricardo-Viner, or specific factors, model. It postulates that sectors of the economy, not factors of production, gain or lose from trade. The more mobile agents are, the more Heckscher-Ohlin models apply. See, for example, Hiscox 2002.

Mayer explores the dependence of tariff rates on the distribution of factor ownership, the costs of voting, and the degree of factor mobility and industry diversification in the economy.15 His median voter model using the Heckscher-Ohlin framework (two factors and two sectors) has produced interesting findings about the political economy of trade. In a series of papers, for instance, Dutt and Mitra have shown that in such a framework an increase in inequality raises trade barriers in capital-rich countries and lowers them in capital-scarce ones, and that left-wing governments adopt more protectionist policies in capital-rich countries but more free trade policies in labor-rich economies than do right-wing governments.16

Dutt and Mitra 2002a, 2002b.

These cross-sectional findings are evidence that Heckscher-Ohlin models may describe the politics of trade policy well. Others using them have also been able to explain important political outcomes.17

But these models have not been used often to explain change in policy over time, such as in the recent move to free trade.18

Using a different model of trade policy, Grossman and Helpman 1994 analyze how interest groups bid for protection with their campaign support. These works show how changes in political participation, especially among interest groups, affect trade policy outcomes. These theories seem less capable of explaining how developing countries around the world were suddenly able to liberalize their trade policies.

This trade liberalization process is especially anomalous in light of the well-known tendency of countries to resist reform.19 However, many agree that an economy in crisis should facilitate reform.20

See, for example, Nelson 1994a, 11.

Few systematic tests of these hypotheses exist, and we will control for these factors in our empirical analysis.

The three main arguments explaining economic reform in the LDCs focus on external pressures, political leaders and their ideas, and economic crisis. Many scholars have argued that a variety of pressures external to the LDCs have forced them to change their policies and join the global economy. Some arguments focus on U.S. hegemony associated with the end of the Cold War, others on the role of private investors and countries' desire for foreign investment, and others on pressures from international institutions, such as the IMF, World Bank, and WTO.21

Some scholars attribute economic reform to changes either in political leaders or in the ideas that leaders hold about economic development.22

For them, economic failure (both absolute and relative) prompted leaders to give up on ISI and move toward more market-friendly economic policies; reform came from new leaders with different ideas or from old leaders with new ideas.

Other scholars emphasize economic crisis as the spur to reform.23

Crises underscore the failure of old policies and create an environment in which radical, new policies can be tried. They also increase countries' reliance on external benefactors, such as private investors or the IMF. The crisis argument is related to external pressures, as well as the claims about new ideas and wars of attrition. In order to show that regime type also plays a role, one must try to control for these factors.

This article is divided into four sections. In the next section, we present some facts about trade policy and democratization in the LDCs during the past thirty years. In the following section, we outline how democracy may be related to trade liberalization. In the third section, we present econometric evidence covering more than 100 LDCs from 1970–99. The final section concludes by arguing that regime type and changes in it affect trade policy, even when controlling for many other factors. Since the late 1970s, democracies and democratization have led to lower levels of trade barriers, ceteris paribus.

Data on Trade Liberalization and Democracy

In the 1960s and 1970s, many LDCs had trade regimes marked by extensive, overlapping, and often prohibitive trade restrictions; ISI was the policy regime of choice. Groups that gained from these policies tended to be powerful supporters of the political leaders, and changing trade policies, it was believed, would inflict severe costs on the regime's main backers. Many scholars agree that in large parts of Latin America, Africa, and Asia, the groups that gained from ISI were urban owners of industry (that is, capitalists) and urban, higher-skilled and often unionized workers (more capital-endowed workers); the losers tended to be less-skilled, poorer workers, generally rural ones.24

Even the debt crisis of the early 1980s was unable to shake this coalition from its economically inefficient policies. Many scholars report that protection increased in the wake of the debt crisis, especially in Latin America. As Haggard and Webb point out, “if the interest group configuration does not change, it is unclear how the status quo (protection) could ever be transcended.”25

The status quo bias against liberalization is thus a key issue; something must change so that this bias can be overcome.

Beginning in the mid-1980s, the status quo was overturned. As the African Development Bank notes, “a series of reform and liberalization efforts undertaken by developing countries in the past decade and a half represents an effective shift in development strategy from an inward-oriented, import-substituting framework … to an outward-oriented export-promoting framework.”26

The data we have collected on the LDCs demonstrates a massive change from 1970–99 for five different measures of trade policy. First, a dramatic decline of about 60 percent occurred in the average tariff level for about forty LDCs from 1982–99; statutory tariff rates fell from an average of about 30 percent in the early 1980s to around 12 percent in 1999.27

World Bank 2000b compiles this data from UN Conference on Trade and Development TRAINS and the WTO's integrated database.

Tariff duties collected as a percent of imports have also fallen for a large number of LDCs. This data, available for about eighty-five to ninety countries during the 1973–97 period, shows that duties peaked in 1973 at 21 percent of imports and then fell almost 53 percent, ending at about 10 percent of the value of imports.28 This is consistent with the statutory tariff rate data; by the late 1990s, both series show that tariff rates had dropped in the LDCs to around 10 percent.

More evidence of trade liberalization comes from nontariff barriers (NTBs). While coverage is very limited (on average, thirty LDCs are sampled every few years), the data show that beginning in 1984 at around 38 percent, average NTB coverage ratios declined to around 17 percent in 1998, or about a 55 percent decrease.29

UN Conference on Trade and Development 1994 and 2000.

Falling tariffs were not compensated for by rising NTBs.

Another measure of trade policy is the dichotomous categorization of countries into open and closed trade regimes, as constructed by Sachs and Warner and updated by Horn and Wacziarg.30

Sachs and Warner 1995 define an economy as closed if any one of the following is true: NTBs cover 40 percent or more of trade; average tariff rates are 40 percent or more; the black market exchange rate depreciated by 20 percent or more relative to the official exchange rate during the 1970s or 1980s; a socialist economy existed as defined by Kornai 1992; or there was a state monopoly on exports. Updated by Horn Welch and Wacziarg 2003.

According to this data, which covers ninety LDCs per year from 1970–99, the percentage of LDCs scored as open rose from 15 percent in the early 1970s to 64 percent in 1999, with the biggest changes beginning in the mid-1980s.

Finally, using an outcome measure, trade dependence (exports plus imports as a percent of gross domestic product [GDP]), liberalization has been associated with real changes in the developing economies' exposure to international competition. From 1970, trade as a percentage of the domestic economy rose from an average of 55 percent to nearly 85 percent in 1999, or a 55 percent increase.31

All five measures of trade policy underscore the same message: since the mid-1980s, countries across the globe have decided to dramatically reduce their trade barriers and move toward freer trade.

Our central question, then, is what disturbed the historical equilibrium involving interest groups and political leaders around protectionism? Why did political leaders in many developing countries choose to lower their trade barriers? As noted before, standard political economy models predict that vested interest groups with concentrated gains from protection will strongly resist any such reduction in barriers; furthermore, the gains from freer trade will be diffuse and thus present collective action problems for groups desiring lower levels of protection. For some reason, however, political leaders decided to alter this status quo by lowering average trade barriers significantly.32

We have data on average barriers. These aggregate rates across many sectors of the economy. Within this overall average decline, it is probable that some interest groups succeeded in maintaining protection but many sectors failed to do so.

We argue that the movement toward democracy in developing countries can provide part of the answer. Democratization opened up new avenues of support for freer trade. Leaders recognized that previously disenfranchised groups had become part of the voting public; as we show later, these new groups benefited more from trade liberalization than continued high protectionism. Needing the support of these new groups in a democratic setting, leaders saw that their ability to use trade barriers as a strategy for garnering political support had declined. Democratic political competition meant that leaders were likely to liberalize trade to appeal to these new groups to ensure their political survival. We agree that “democracies possess greater capacities for promoting change and breaking free of unholy interest group coalitions than generally thought.”33

Democratic leaders in a number of developing countries chose trade liberalization as a means of gaining broader political support. In no country were trade barriers reduced to zero, and thus we are not arguing that protectionist interest groups no longer mattered. But in democratizing countries they mattered less than before, and thus leaders could liberalize more than previously.

Evidence of democratization among the LDCs is plentiful. Beginning before the move to free trade, a global movement toward democracy erupted. To measure regime type, we use the 21-point Polity index constructed by Gurr et al., Jaggers and Gurr, and Marshall and Jaggers, ranging from −10 for a highly autocratic state to 10 for a highly democratic one.34

Using data from Polity IV, the average regime score for about 110 LDCs fell from −3.4 in 1970 to a nadir of −4.71 in 1977, and then rose to a high of 1.8 in 1999.35

For more discussion, see the section on empirical analysis below.

Similarly, the dichotomous regime classification from Alvarez et al. shows how the number of democracies has increased over time.36

Alvarez et al. 1996 and Przeworski et al. 2000 developed a dichotomous measure that codes a regime as democratic if and only if high political offices are chosen through contested elections.

Starting from about 16 percent in the early 1970s, the percentage of democracies falls to a low of 14 percent among 110 LDCs in 1977, but then rises to 49 percent in 1999. Similar to the Polity data, this series shows that the percentage of democratic countries was falling in the 1970s but began a vigorous rise after 1977. Importantly, both figures show that the process of democratization among the LDCs began in the late 1970s, almost a decade before widespread trade liberalization got underway. The wave of democratization preceded that of trade liberalization.

A number of cases illustrate our claim. For instance, in 1982 Bolivia began a democratic transition. Shortly after this, in 1985, the new government launched an economic reform program called the “New Economic Policy,” which eliminated all quantitative restrictions (QRs) and lowered tariffs.37

Argentina shows a similar picture. There the democratic transition began in 1983 and substantial trade reform followed in 1988; it included tariff reductions and the elimination of import licensing.38

In other parts of the world this pattern has been repeated. For instance, in the Philippines the first parliamentary elections occurred in 1984 and were followed by presidential elections in 1986, after the ouster of the dictator Ferdinand Marcos. After this political change (1986–88), the new leaders led by Corazón Aquino began changing economic policy, replacing QRs with tariffs and then reducing tariffs.39

As the Wall Street Journal reported in 1986,

economic decline felled Ferdinand Marcos and unless Mrs. Aquino can turn the Philippine economy around, she will find it difficult to lay the foundations for enduring democracy…. What really will matter will be how much economic reform Mrs. Aquino can push through the Philippine political system…. Economic recovery still depends, however, on whether the Philippines can throw off decades of import-substitution and cronyism, and start selling its wares in the world marketplace…. For months, Mrs. Aquino has been gamely chipping away at monumental domestic trade barriers, which routinely include effective protection rates of 80 percent and 90 percent. Predictably, this liberalization is drawing sharp protests from entrenched, protected industries…. Mrs. Aquino is not giving up on this grueling liberalization process.40

Wall Street Journal, 18 September 1986, 1.

South Korea also shows a similar pattern. A democratic transition occurred during 1987–88, and the new government followed this with an economic reform program beginning in 1989 that lowered trade barriers significantly by 1992.41

WTO 1996.

Bangladesh is another interesting case. Between 1986 and 1992, the country underwent a democratic transition; beginning in 1987, President Hussain Muhammad Ershad's government introduced a slow liberalization process that only became substantial after the early 1990s when the political situation stabilized. Tariffs fell from roughly 90 percent in 1990 to 20 percent by 1996.42 The democratization of many East Central European countries, such as Poland and Hungary, was followed by economic reform, including massive trade liberalization.43

Recently, democratization in Africa has lent an impetus to trade liberalization.44

Zambia is a telling example. In 1991, a democratic transition occurred when Frederick Chiluba and his Movement for Multiparty Democracy party (MMD) overwhelmed Kenneth Kaunda in the presidential election. Chiluba's MMD campaigned for a radical change in economic policy, and this was one factor in his victory over Kaunda, who had run the country since its independence. In 1992, Chiluba then launched a massive economic reform program that featured trade liberalization; tariffs were lowered from 30 percent in the late 1980s to 13 percent by 1996.45 These cases, among others, suggest that changes in regime type may have an influence on changes in trade policy. Trade liberalization followed a change in regime type—in particular, democratization. Why did leaders choose to liberalize trade in the face of vested protectionist interests?

Trade Liberalization and Democratization: An Argument

How might democracy contribute to trade liberalization? Democratization means a movement toward majority rule with universal suffrage in contested elections. We call the group of actors who participate in the selection of political leaders “the selectorate,” following the terminology of Bueno de Mesquita et al.46

In a democracy, the selectorate is the part of the population that is eligible to vote. In a nondemocracy, the selectorate is that subset of the population upon whose political support leaders could potentially rely to remain in office. The winning coalition is the minimal set of individuals in the selectorate whose support an incumbent needs to remain in office. In a democracy, this may be a simple majority of voters, whereas in an autocracy it may be more complex. Increasing the selectorate tends to imply an increase in the size of the winning coalition; in a majority voting situation, this means a change in the median voter.

Democratization is a process involving an expansion of the selectorate. Democracies choose political leaders through popular elections, while autocrats maintain their position with the backing of small groups, such as the military elite, large landowners, or heavy industrialists. Democratization implies an expansion of the selectorate and the winning coalition, which changes the optimal policies that leaders will choose. This expansion implies a change in the composition of the selectorate, and hence a change in its preferred policies. To retain office, leaders must adjust their policies to be responsive to the preferences of the expanded selectorate.

With democratization, leaders can build new coalitions in favor of different policies because they can appeal for support to newly enfranchised groups. As Bienen and Herbst point out, “political liberalization may change constituencies and therefore promote economic reform…. Democratization would alter processes of economic decision making and the nature of economic policies…. A regime that has to take account of voters who have not previously had influence may well shift the allocation and distribution of resources.”47

Democratization is important for trade policy: the optimal level of protectionism for political leaders is a declining function of the size of the winning coalition. Even if the same political leaders remain in office, an expansion of the winning coalition reduces the amount of protection that is optimal for them. We expect that, as democratization occurs, political leaders will alter their trade policies—with or without public urging—to gain the support of this larger selectorate.

Our argument follows the logic of the Heckscher-Ohlin and Stopler-Samuelson theorems as they have been advanced by Mayer and by Yang.48

See Mayer 1984; and Yang 1995. An alternative would be a specific factors model in which sectors of the economy (import-competing versus export-oriented firms), rather than factors of production such as capital and labor, form the major coalitions. It is much debated as to which of these provides a better account of the political economy of LDCs.

In a Heckscher-Ohlin world, the Stopler-Samuelson theorem shows how individuals benefit or lose from changes in trade policy given their endowments of capital and labor. Mayer and Yang each connect this to politics by showing how political leaders respond to voters' preferences vis-à-vis trade policy. Developing countries by definition possess relatively less capital than labor.49

Almost all developing countries trade mostly with developed ones. More than 80 percent of LDC trade is with the OECD countries. Markusen and Wiggle 1990. Of total world trade, only about 6 percent is between LDCs. Hence it makes sense to consider all LDCs relatively well endowed with labor given their primary trading partners, the OECD countries.

Because the vast majority of their trade is with rich developed countries, their import-competing sectors tend to be capital-intensive, and therefore protectionism will benefit those individuals well endowed with the relatively scarce factor, capital. Liberalizing trade policy in the LDCs results in a gain in income for, and a reduction in the prices of imported goods bought by, those well endowed with the relatively abundant factor—that is, labor— in these economies.

In developing countries, workers and the poor tend to gain from trade liberalization through increases in their income and reductions in the prices they must pay (especially for import-competing goods). As an economist notes, “the protection of capital-intensive industries affected [Latin America's] ability to create employment…. In developing countries more-open trade regimes result in higher employment and in a more even distribution of income than protectionist regimes…. Export-able industries tend to be significantly more labor intensive than import-competing sectors … and the removal of external sector distortions tends to strengthen the process of employment creation in most developing countries.”50

Democratization will thus enfranchise a new group of voters with preferences for lower levels of protectionism.

As noted above, in nondemocratic countries those eligible to determine their countries' leaders are part of a very restricted selectorate. In many autocracies, either the voting that takes place does not affect the choice of leadership, or voting does not occur at all. However, even dictators must earn the support of some “majority” of the populace that has the right to determine the leadership. In many autocracies, this selectorate consists of the richest individuals, and hence those who own the most capital. Those with “voting” rights in autocracies thus own above-average levels of capital, and benefit the most from high levels of protection. In Latin America, for example, “the protective system generated large benefits to local industrialists … and urban workers. This, of course, was achieved at the cost of depressing the earnings and incomes of rural workers.”51

Ibid., 119.

The Philippines under the autocrat Marcos was another glaring example of this.

Democratization changes which groups political leaders must garner support from; political competition within democracies induces leaders to appeal to new coalitions of voters and hence offer new policies to win their support. As a country democratizes, the selectorate grows and the preferences of the enlarged selectorate will differ from before. As democracy advances to include those who own less and less capital (that is, workers and the rural poor), the median voter's capital ownership will decline, and his or her most preferred tariff rate decreases as well.52

See Milner and Kubota 2001 for a formal model demonstrating this result.

Hence political leaders in a democracy can appeal to these groups who are less well endowed with capital and whose interests may be better served by less protectionism. Leaders in this setting have new sources of support and ones that prefer lower trade barriers.

As Weyland suggests, “democratization reduces the political clout of the vested interests that benefited the most from the old development model, such as protectionist business sectors and the military. At the same time, it enhances the role of the electorate, including the large mass of poor people who received meager benefits under the old development model … Democratization weakens politically some prime beneficiaries of state interventionism…. [It] creates new cleavages that diminish the political power of business associations, which were once dominated by protectionist sectors.”53

This seems to have been the case in countries such as Bolivia, the Philippines, Bangladesh, and Zambia, where democratization preceded, and helped leaders initiate, trade liberalization.

In sum, in developing countries where autocratic governments depend on support from a small selectorate and thus are not responsive to the overall population, the governments can employ extensive protectionism. Democratization, however, may break down the old coalition supporting protectionism, and can thus lead to change in the status quo. As the selectorate grows, leaders may find it in their political interests to modify their trade policies. As the democratic selectorate in developing countries become less well endowed with capital, high levels of trade barriers no longer compensate them for their loss of income from, and the higher costs imposed by, protectionism. Thus as the political regime becomes more democratic and leaders build new coalitions of support, political competition may induce leaders to make their trade policies less restrictive. Leaders may reason that by lowering barriers, they can increase the incomes of workers and garner more of their support in future elections. Protectionist interest groups may remain powerful in these democracies, but they will be less influential than before because leaders now have new sources of support they can turn to.

Is it realistic to assume that workers and the poor gain from trade liberalization? Do they not lose from it and thus oppose it? It is important to separate trade liberalization from the other economic reforms. Different economic reforms have different distributional consequences. Many reforms, such as privatization, pension reform, and increasing labor market flexibility, may have significant negative effects (at least in the short term) for workers, and are often bitterly opposed by them.54

See, for instance, Naím 1993; and Murillo 2001.

In contrast, the distributional consequences of trade liberalization may not hurt workers or the rural poor. In the same countries where opposition to other reforms has been high, trade liberalization has often been supported—or at least not opposed—by workers and their organizations, as Murillo shows in Mexico, Argentina, and Venezuela.55 Weyland notes that public support for market reform, including trade liberalization, was actually strong in a large number of Latin American countries, and Fishlow shows that these reforms have not been visibly opposed most of the time.56

See Weyland 2002, 21–22, 35, 94; and Fishlow 1990.

Baker provides systematic evidence that trade liberalization was and has remained very popular in Latin America. As he notes, “aggregate support for free trade is much higher than support for privatization, indicating that positive orientations toward free trade are not simply a vague expression of support for economic liberalization. Instead, many citizens favorably single out free trade from the list of Latin America's recent market reforms.”57

Baker 2003, 428. Baker has a different explanation for this continued support than we do for the initial liberalization.

In Africa, as van de Walle points out, trade policy reform—although limited—has not been opposed by social groups either.58

van de Walle 2001, 168–70.

Other political scientists point out that voters may support governments even when times turn bad because they think bad times now are a signal of good times to come. As Stokes shows for a wide variety of countries, “Our most startling result is that in every country people sometimes reacted to economic deterioration by supporting the government and its economic program more strongly.”59

Polls in Mexico show that voters strongly favored trade liberalization via the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and thought it would mean more jobs and higher wages for them.60 Similarly, research on the transition economies in East Central Europe shows that in most of these countries, public support for trade liberalization was strong and never wavered.61 Political leaders do not seem to have lost support by pursuing trade liberalization; publics often are willing to keep supporting regimes that liberalize trade even if the economy slows in the short term, in the hope of future gains.62

As for whether trade liberalization actually benefits workers in LDCs, the data are mixed. Some studies show that increased openness leads to faster economic growth, which benefits workers;63

others cast doubt on claims relating trade policy to growth.64

See, for example, Rodriguez and Rodrik 2001.

At the microeconomic level, scholars have shown, surprisingly, that trade liberalization may not have important positive or negative effects for firms or workers.65 Theoretically, Heckscher-Ohlin (and Stopler-Samuelson) models suggest that workers should gain from trade liberalization in LDCs; and empirically the extant data do not reject this claim.

Empirical Analysis

According to our argument, democracies should be oriented more toward free trade than nondemocracies, and an increase in the degree of democracy should induce a move to liberalize trade. Many theories describe the relationship between political and economic reforms, but little systematic empirical work exists on trade liberalization. Part of the reason is that both political and trade regimes are difficult to measure. We test our argument while also trying to control for the leading contending propositions, relating to economic crises, changes in leaders and ideas, and external pressures. Our data set is a time-series cross-section (TSCS) one, containing 179 developing countries, territories, and dependencies from 1970–99.66

In the analysis, we have only about 100 countries represented; most small countries, territories, and dependencies are missing data.

Our central hypothesis is that more democratic countries should have fewer trade barriers, ceteris paribus; an increase in democracy should prompt a reduction in trade barriers.

Our central independent variable is the type of political regime in place in a country at time t. The political regime variable comes from Polity III and Polity IV, which collected data on the political characteristics of 177 countries between 1800 and 1999.67

To measure each state's regime type, we employ the widely used index constructed by Gurr et al. and Jaggers and Gurr.68 This index combines data on five factors that capture the institutional differences between democracies and autocracies: (1) the competitiveness of the process for selecting a country's chief executive, (2) the openness of this process, (3) the extent to which institutional constraints limit a chief executive's decision-making authority, (4) the competitiveness of political participation within a country, and (5) the degree to which binding rules govern political participation within it. Each of these five measures is directly related to our emphasis on political competition and the size of the selectorate.

Following Gurr et al. and Jaggers and Gurr, these data are used to create an 11-point index of each state's democratic characteristics (democ) and an 11-point index of its autocratic characteristics (autoc).69

Ibid.

The difference between these indices, regime = democautoc, yields a summary measure of regime type that takes on values ranging from −10 for a highly autocratic state to 10 for a highly democratic one. This measure captures the variation both within democracies and among autocracies. For instance, not all autocracies are the same. Some autocracies have a more expansive selectorate than others. Mexico, for example, is usually seen as more democratic than Saudi Arabia or China; Polity catches these differences. For instance, in 1980, Mexico scores a −3, while Saudi Arabia gets −10 and China, −7. Polity's scoring of autocracies correlates highly with a categorization of autocracies created by Geddes; countries she codes as single-party regimes, then military ones and then personalistic ones, represent a declining scale of democracy which correlates at roughly the 0.6 level with regime.70 Similarly, differences among relatively democratic countries can be discerned. Summary statistics for regime, as well as our other variables, are listed in Table 1. We use a lagged version of regime (from one to three periods) in the regressions to mitigate endogeneity issues.

Summary statistics

To increase the robustness of our analysis, we use two other measures of regime type. First, from Geddes's data on autocracies we construct a variable ranging from 1 to 8, where 8 is most democratic. Because more than two-thirds of the regimes in Polity are autocracies, it is interesting to see if their differences matter. Polity does this one way, and Geddes does it another. Geddes argues that certain autocracies are longer-lived because of their internal characteristics; she sometimes equates these differences with the nature and extent of the groups that support the autocrat.71

Ibid.

We interpret this as arguing that autocracies vary according to the size of their selectorate and winning coalition. She claims that single-party systems have the broadest selectorates, followed by military-run governments and then personalist regimes.

In personalist regimes, one individual dominates the military, state apparatus, and the ruling party if there is one. Because so much power is concentrated in the hands of one individual in personalist regimes, he generally controls the coalition-building agenda…. In contrast to single-party regimes, the leader's faction in a personalist regime may actually increase benefits to itself by excluding the rival faction from participation. Where the main benefits of participation in the government come from access to rents and illicit profit opportunities, benefits to individual members of the ruling group may be higher if they need not be shared too widely.72

Ibid., 12–14.

We code as the most autocratic regimes those with personalist elements, then those with military involvement, and least of all those with a single party. We call this variable dictator, which is supplemented with data from Przeworski et al. to add a code for democracy.73

Hence all countries not classified as autocracies by either Geddes or Alvarez et al. (for which Alvarez et al. have data) are coded as democratic.74

dictator is coded as 1 = personalist regimes; 2 = mixed regimes with some personalist element; 3 = personalist mixed with military; 4 = personalist mixed with single party; 5 = military; 6 = military mixed with single party; 7 = single party; and 8 = democracy. All countries coded as autocracies by Alvarez et al. 1996, but missing in Geddes, 1999, are coded as mixed (= 2).

Note that this measure is blunter than Polity because it does not discern among democracies. We use both a lagged version of the dictator variable and dummy variables for each category.

Our third measure of regime type is the dichotomous categorization created by Alvarez et al. and Przeworski et al.75

Their measure codes a regime as democratic if and only if high political offices are chosen through fair and free contested elections where alternation of leaders occurs. This measure, which is quite blunt since it assumes that the democratic transition occurs completely in one year, has been criticized.76

See, for example, Elkins 2000; and Collier and Adcock 1999.

It makes no distinction between types of autocracies or levels of democracy. But it is highly correlated with the other two measures (r = 0.80 with regime and r = 0.70 with dictator). We use this variable dem in lagged form.

Our central dependent variable measures a country's trade policy in year t. We want to predict the extent of protectionism, or conversely openness, of the trade regime. This is notoriously difficult to measure.77

See, for example, Leamer 1988.

Pritchett, for instance, finds little correlation among different measures of openness in the literature.78 We therefore follow Edwards, and use a variety of measures.79

Edwards 1992, 1998.

However, we face a difficult challenge in finding time-series as well as cross-sectional data, as we are interested in how openness changes over time. We use two alternative ways of measuring trade policy.

Our first measure is a country's (unweighted) average statutory tariff rate (tariff).80

See World Bank 2000b; UN Conference on Trade and Development TRAINS; and World Bank WDI. The World Bank updates its file on average tariffs annually. The current file (called tar2002) contains roughly 257 more observations for the same time period than does the file used here (tar2000). World Bank 2000b. Preliminary analysis of this new data shows that it supports the main conclusion reached in this study.

This is the most appropriate measure for our model, which predicts a decline in tariff rates in response to the shift toward democracy. But it is poorly measured. Various countries were sampled several times in the 1980s and then almost yearly from 1992 to 1999, giving 907 total observations.

Our second measure of trade liberalization is a dichotomous classification of trade regimes into open and closed ones.81

Sachs and Warner code a country as closed (sw open = 0) if any one of the following is true: NTBs cover 40 percent or more of trade; average tariff rates are 40 percent or more; the black market exchange rate depreciated by 20 percent or more relative to the official exchange rate during the 1970s or 1980s; a socialist economy existed as defined by Kornai; or there was a state monopoly on exports.82 This measure is very useful because it considers many forms of protectionism; it is much broader than tariff rates and thus more comprehensive. Others have used it, and it seems highly correlated with more precise data on trade liberalization episodes.83 It is correlated with statutory tariff rates at −0.49. Our regressions using this variable are logistic since it is dichotomous. Because trade policy is hard to measure and comes in a variety of forms, using both measures gives us a broader picture of how trade policy is changing over time and across countries. If both show that democracy is related to trade liberalization, then confidence in our claims should be enhanced.

Changes in trade policy may also arise because of factors other than changes in the political regime, and we need to control for these. Conventional wisdom as well as scholarly work suggests that three sets of factors should be included. First, we need to control for several economic variables.84

All economic data comes from World Bank WDI 2000.

It is often argued that small countries tend to be more open than large ones.85 We thus measure a country's size by its population, using the lagged value of the natural log of population as our control (lnpop). A country's level of economic development is also likely to affect its trade policy; more-developed countries tend to have smaller trade barriers.86 Hence we add the lagged value of per capita real GDP as a control (gdp pc).

The second set of control variables relates to both internal and external political factors that might affect trade policy. First among these is economic crisis. As noted above, the war of attrition models of economic reform often point out that the greater the distortions caused by the policy, the more likely reform is; economic crisis is one way to measure these distortions. Tornell, among others, claims that countries are likely to liberalize their trade regimes after an economic crisis because a crisis generates conflict among the powerful.87

He defines a country as being in crisis if either its inflation rate is skyrocketing or its real income is plummeting. We use a similar definition. Crises are either occurring or not; they are not long-continuing events by definition, and they are extreme events, not yearly changes in economic variables.

One important difficulty with this variable is defining what constitutes a crisis. Different economic problems may be more important in different countries, and different levels of those problems may trigger different evaluations of whether a crisis exists. We use two different notions of economic crisis, both of which stress that crises are unusual and extreme shocks. One notion from Tornell deems a crisis to exist if one of two conditions holds: either the country's inflation rate is 40 percent or more and it increases by 25 percent or more from the year before, or per capita GDP falls by 15 percent or more from the previous year (ec crisis = 1). Our second form of crisis involves the balance of payments. Here a crisis exists (bp crisis = 1) if a country's level of international reserves falls to less than the equivalent of three months' worth of imports. This second notion of crisis relates to a country's debt and capital flight problems.88

Although balance-of-payments crises tend to most affect countries with fixed exchange rates, most of the countries here had some form of fixed exchange rate or managed rate for the period. More than 60 percent of our total observations are for countries with fixed or managed rates. Even though countries are increasingly using more flexible rates, by the 1990s only 20 percent of our observations were for country-years with pure floating rates, and more than 60 percent had some form of fixed or managed exchange rates.

Interestingly, there is practically no correlation (r = 0.012, not significant at .10) between these two forms of crisis, yet both are cited as reasons for economic reform. We include each of these in lagged form.

A second factor seen as responsible for trade liberalization in the LDCs is external pressure—from the various international financial institutions (IFIs) that provide funds to LDCs (such as the IMF or World Bank), or from the world's hegemon, the United States. In particular, the claim is that around periods of economic crisis, LDCs are especially vulnerable to external pressure, and that in exchange for loans or aid, countries have been forced to liberalize their trade regimes—so-called conditionality. The counterfactual is that LDCs would never have made these changes without overwhelming external pressure. To control for these external forces, we include a variable indicating whether the country has just signed an IMF agreement to help bail it out of a crisis. Such a signing should represent a period of high external pressure as the country is claiming an inability to fund its own needs; IMF loans are intended to provide help for countries experiencing severe balance-of-payments or reserves crises. imf created by Przeworski and Vreeland is equal to 1 if an IMF agreement has been signed in that year; it is lagged in the models.89

Przeworski and Vreeland 2000; they also have another variable called under, which shows whether a country is subject to an IMF agreement that year. We use both, although we think imf is a superior measure of the magnitude of external pressure. In addition, we also look at the amount of total foreign aid that a country receives as a percent of its central government budget (aid). This measures the dependence of the government on foreign sources of (nonprivate) capital.

More external pressure of any sort should be related to lower trade barriers.90

See, for example, Nelson 1990; and Kahler 1986.

We include several variables designed to capture the impact of other external pressures. A measure of U.S. hegemony captures the widespread claim that American power is responsible for economic reform. Given our interest in trade, hegemony (us heg) is measured as the sum of U.S. exports and imports as a percent of world trade.91

As Mansfield and Bronson 1997, among others, do.

If Hegemonic Stability Theory is correct, greater U.S. influence should induce trade liberalization.92

See, for example, Krasner 1976.

We also examine the impact of the GATT/WTO. Joining the GATT/WTO should induce countries to lower their trade barriers. Recent work by Rose, however, suggests that it might have no impact; moreover, given the exceptions that LDCs were allowed in the GATT regime, it may be that GATT membership had a negative impact on them.93

Rose 2002a, 2002b.

Recent research suggests that the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) in the GATT may also have induced developing country members to maintain higher trade barriers than otherwise.94 We include a lagged variable (gatt) indicating whether a country is in the GATT/WTO (=1) or not.

Finally, some scholars argue that competitive pressures among states may drive policy changes around the world.95

See, for example, Simmons 2000.

In order to control for this, we create a variable that indicates the average tariff level for all LDCs in that year (av tariff) and the average level of openness (according to Sachs and Warner) for all countries in that year (av open). We use the lagged version of these to test for strategic competition among LDCs.

A third factor involves the ideas that leaders possess about the best policies available to them. Many claim that the turnabout in trade policy was caused by a change in the ideas that leaders held about the policies that would best promote economic development. Whether these new ideas resulted from policy failure or external pressure is debated. But the claim is that in their search for better development strategies, leaders decided that an open trade regime was preferred to the ISI one. It is difficult to find measures of such ideational change, and the measures we use are not ideal. One measure we employ is the number of years a government has been in office (office). A new government might indicate a change in leadership and hence a change in ideas. Others have examined whether governments in their first year of office are more likely to reform; we considered this (first = 1 if office < 2; 0 otherwise), but it was never significant in the regressions.96

See, for example, Abiad and Mody 2003.

Finding measures of how policy ideas have changed throughout the world is difficult. Quinn has developed an indicator of changing global ideas about economic policy.97

He uses a measure of the degree to which the top five advanced industrial countries have opened their capital markets (five open) to suggest how, globally, changes in ideas about the ideal set of foreign economic policies are evolving. Increases in this measure indicate that anticapitalist sentiment is waning worldwide. This variable captures both changes in ideas about optimal policies and the potential contagion of those ideas from powerful developed states to the LDCs. This measure has many problems, and if it is not related to our outcomes it can hardly be seen as a fair test of the ideas claims. We include it in some models to try to control for all of the main alternative explanations for trade liberalization in the LDCs.

The basic equation estimating the relationship between democracy and trade policy is:

We also include us heg, gatt, and five open in some equations to check for robustness. TSCS data have numerous problems that violate the standard assumptions necessary for ordinary least squares (OLS) to be unbiased and efficient. We try to correct for these in the standard ways. We use panel-corrected standard errors to mitigate problems caused by various forms of heteroskedasticity, as recommended by Beck and Katz.98

We include country fixed effects and a time trend or decade fixed effects to deal with problems of omitted variable bias. The use of a time trend allows us to address concerns about whether the relationship between democracy and trade policy is solely related to their both trending in one direction over time.

The use of country fixed effects is particularly interesting in this model.99

In all the regressions, a Hausman test rejects the suitability of using random effects, not surprisingly.

The fixed effects—or “within”—estimator exploits the time-series component of the data around the country averages. The within estimator examines variation over time and thus addresses the question of the impact on trade policy of a change in regime type within a country over time. We address problems of serial correlation by using an AR1 correction. In the logistic model, we estimate a natural spline function with three knots; we use the count variable and three splines generated by this procedure to handle temporal dependence, as recommended by Beck, Katz, and Tucker.100

Regime Type

In almost all of the regressions, regime type is correctly signed and significant. The regressions on tariff rates are the most direct test of our argument. As Tables 2 and 3 show, more democratic regimes tend to have lower tariff rates. Setting all the other variables at their means in equation (3) in Table 3, a one standard deviation increase in democracy from its mean leads to a 12.2 percent decrease in tariff rates. Tariff rates drop from about 19 percent to about 16.5 percent. Moving from an absolute autocracy (−10) to a perfect democracy (10) induces a 31 percent decline in tariffs. Rates fall from close to 22 percent to about 15 percent. These results are robust to a wide variety of controls.

Tariff rates

Tariff rates

Table 3 also shows that using other measures of regime type does not undermine our result. The dictator variable is negative and quite significant, indicating again that systems with larger selectorates tend to have lower trade barriers. An increase in dictator by one standard deviation from its mean leads to roughly a 17 percent reduction of tariff rates, from about 16 percent to roughly 13 percent. The dichotomous dem variable is also negative, but it is not significant at conventional levels.

When we include the regime variable from Polity with dummy variables for the three major types of autocracies, the type of autocracy matters, even when controlling for overall regime type. More democratic countries still tend to have lower barriers. But compared to personalistic regimes (which is the excluded category), single-party ones (sgl pty) are much less prone to protectionism. This finding also supports our argument because selectorates are larger in single-party autocracies than in personalistic ones. This suggests that variations within both democracies and autocracies may help explain the choice of trade policy.101

We also turned Polity's regime variable into a dichotomous variable with countries scoring below 6 as autocracies (= 0) and those at or above 6 as democracies (= 1). Using equation (3) in Table 3, we found that once again, the regime coefficient is negative and very significant; more democratic countries have lower trade barriers.

To assess the robustness of our results, we address concerns about multicolinearity. (The use of panel-corrected standard errors helps assuage problems with various types of heteroskedasticity; and the inclusion of country fixed effects, decade fixed effects, and a time trend should address concerns about omitted variable biases.) In Table 4, we lag the regime variable by two and then three periods. This did not affect our results greatly. The regime variable either by itself or jointly with all of the lags was correctly signed and significant for all the tariff regressions. We also lagged the main alternatives to our argument: the crisis variables (ec crisis and bp crisis) and an external pressure variable (imf) for two and three periods for both dependent variables. They were never significant and did not affect the regime variable. This suggests that multicolinearity (at least among the main alternative hypotheses) is not driving these results. Moreover, it suggests that the effect of regime on trade policy is fairly long lasting.102

We also dropped the outliers from equation (3) in Table 3 and reran the regressions, which did not change the regime variable's sign or significance. This entailed dropping observations whose residuals were more than 2, 3, or 5 standard deviations from the mean.

Tariff rates

Table 5 shows that increasing democracy also increases the likelihood of a country opening its trade regime. A one-unit increase in democracy in equation (1) raises the probability of a change to openness by 0.523. Equivalently, holding all other variables constant, each additional unit of increase in democracy multiplies the log odds of openness occurring by 1.69. Using alternative measures of regime type yields similar results. As above, we created a dichotomous version of Polity's regime score, with countries at or above 6 scoring as democracy. This variable is also positive and significantly related to trade liberalization. When we lag the regime variable, it remains positively related to trade liberalization, but it is only significant when considered jointly with all three lags. Entering the lags of the crisis and external pressure variables does not change the results materially either.

Sachs-Warner trade liberalization

As Table 6 shows, the dictator variable is also positive and statistically significantly related to trade policy liberalization. The same is true for the dichotomous dem variable. More-democratic countries are more likely to liberalize their trade policies. As before, we also get interesting results when using both the Polity measure and the dummy variables for autocratic regime types. The regime measures are all jointly significant (p > .05) with regime still having a positive relationship. The broad Sachs-Warner measure of trade policy yields similar results to the narrower tariff measure. For the two different measures of trade policy, movement toward democracy is positively associated with more openness, even when we account for many other influences.

Sachs-Warner trade liberalization

To further test the robustness of our results, we also address concerns about endogeneity. To explore whether trade policy itself promotes regime change, we regressed all the independent variables in equation (1) of Table 3—including the two trade policy measures lagged (each independently) and excluding the average level of tariffs in the world—on our measure of regime type. None of the variables, except GDP per capita, the time trend, and the log of population, was near statistical significance, implying again that colinearity is not a major problem. Most importantly, the trade policy measures never reached conventional levels of significance, suggesting that they are not causing regime change.

In addition, several tests examined endogeneity problems with the regime variable. First, following Wooldridge, we took the residuals from two fixed effects regressions of our independent variables on regime and included them in regressions identical to those in equation (3) in Table 3 and equation (1) in Table 5.103

Wooldridge 2002, 118–22.

We then checked whether the coefficients on the residuals were significant; they were not at the .10 level. This test indicates that endogeneity is not acute.

Another way to deal with endogeneity is to instrument for the variable in question. Finding useful instruments for regime type is not a trivial matter. In our case, they must be measures that predict regime type well and are not related to either trade policy or the errors. We used two instruments for regime: the average age of the party system in a country year (ptyage variable from Beck et al.) and the level of secondary school completion among the population over fifteen years (sschool variable from Barro and Lee).104

We expect both variables to be positively related to democracy. Using these two instruments, we estimate the impact of regime type on statutory tariff rates in Table 7. The regime variable remains negative and quite significant.105

A test devised by Davidson and MacKinnon 1993, which is similar to the (Durbin-Wu-) Hausman test, reveals that the null hypothesis that an OLS version of the same equation would be consistent can be rejected at the .01 level, suggesting that the instrumental variables are useful. A Sargan-like test for overidentification does not allow rejection of the null hypothesis that the instruments are useful and uncorrelated with the error term at the .05 level.

These results give some confidence that even correcting for possible endogeneity, regime type still affects trade policy.

Instrumental variable regression: Tariff rates

The Political Control Variables

Our first set of control variables explored the impact of economic crisis on a country's decision to liberalize. We included two distinct variables, ec crisis and bp crisis, to capture the pressures from such crises. These variables do not seem to matter significantly, either independently or jointly. Countries may respond differently to crises, sometimes raising trade barriers and other times lowering them. These results are not unexpected. Many claims about the role of crises come from case studies that often select on the dependent variable; that is, they explore cases of economic reform and often find that crises (of varying types) existed as well. But they rarely look at the cases where countries experienced crises and did not reform.106

A simple cross-tabulation of our data shows that in 3 percent of the cases, liberalization according to Sachs and Warner occurred just after a bout of economic crisis; in 3 percent of cases, such crises occurred with no trade liberalization; and in 30 percent of them liberalization occurred with no crisis beforehand. For balance-of-payments crises, 40 percent of the cases had crises but no trade policy reform, compared to 16 percent with crises preceding the reforms.

As noted earlier, the debt crisis of the early 1980s did not lead to trade liberalization, but to greater closure. The effects of crises may be highly contingent on the environment. Sorting through the myriad types of economic crises and their various political effects is an important area for future research.

The second set of external political factors involves external pressures. The main way we measured this was to look at whether countries had signed an agreement with the IMF in the previous period (we explored up to three lags). This variable (imf) was never significant. Increases in external pressure via the IMF have little measurable effect on trade policy, and when they do (in the regressions on Sachs-Warner openness), their effect is to increase the closure of the economy, not to open it. We also tried using whether a country was under any IMF agreement (in one to three previous periods), and this was never significant either. These results may not be that surprising given the findings of Przeworski and Vreeland and Vreeland, among others, which show that countries do not receive IMF loans when they are most vulnerable and in crisis, and that conditionality rarely seems to have much impact on policy.107

We also employed a variable measuring the amount of foreign aid a country received relative to its government budget. While this measure has many fewer observations, it was not significant either. We concur with Weyland, who argues that “economic-structural arguments alone cannot provide a complete explanation for the enactment of market reform…. ‘Markets’ and ‘leverage’ did not determine governmental decisions; political leaders retained a margin of choice.”108

Other measures of external influence show greater impact. Whether a country is in the GATT/WTO has a significant influence on both tariff rates and on Sachs-Warner openness. But the relationship is surprising. Being a member keeps one's tariff rates higher than otherwise and lowers the probability that a country opens its trading regime. This finding is consistent with recent research by Rose, which shows that being a member of the GATT/WTO does not increase a country's trade flows, nor does it lead them to reduce their trade barriers.109

Rose 2002a and 2000b. Subramanian and Wei 2003 also show that for the LDCs, the GATT/WTO has not mattered much.

Many countries, it seems, choose to reduce their barriers before they enter the GATT or even if they have no plans for entering it. Furthermore, countries that are already in the international organization are much less likely to become more open, ceteris paribus. In part, this results from the myriad exceptions in GATT rules (some tightened by the WTO) to reducing barriers. Among these exceptions, the GSP scheme was very important for the LDCs; it allowed them to maintain their barriers while still gaining access to developed countries' markets. Moreover, it is very consistent with Ozden and Reinhardt, who show that the GSP system in the GATT encouraged many LDCs to maintain higher trade barriers than otherwise.110 In part, this finding may reflect the fact that many of these countries decided to lower their trade barriers unilaterally before joining the GATT/WTO. Once in the organization, further liberalization might be quite slow given the glacial pace of recent multilateral trade negotiations.

Our final set of political controls looked at the change in ideas around the globe. Our measures are weak indicators for this factor; hence, our results should be interpreted cautiously. We examined governments' tenure in office to see whether new governments were more likely to undertake trade policy reform. This variable was only significant in the case of tariff rates, and here the findings were surprising. The longer governments had been in office, the lower were their tariff rates, ceteris paribus. Trade policy reform may require political stability and a government with a firm hold on power.111

For example, Bermeo 1994.

A variable for whether the government was in its first year or not was never significant, suggesting that in general, new governments either did not have new ideas about trade policy or could not implement them.112

Our measure of the global spread of procapitalist ideas, five open, has weak and inconsistent results. This measure is a poor substitute for more direct evidence about the global spread of ideas, but few alternatives exist.

Existing data do not allow us to conclude much about the role of ideas in the change in trade policy. We have tried to control for them simply to give greater credibility to our claim about democracy. But our research should not be interpreted as concluding that the spread of new ideas about trade policy did not matter.

We looked at several other, less obvious factors that might affect economic reform. We included a variable for a government's relative political capacity.113

This measures a government's ability to extract resources from its society. One might expect a more capable government to need to use trade taxes less, and hence be more likely to liberalize. It was not significant in regressions on either dependent variable—equation (3) in Table 3 and equation (1) in Table 5—and did not affect the sign or significance of the regime variable. We also included a variable indicating whether a country was involved in a war that year or previously.114

war was coded from the latest Correlates of War data set and includes all three types of war.

War is expected to make protectionism more likely and to reduce the chances of trade liberalization. Its effect on tariff rates was positive but not near conventional levels of significance. Its effect on liberalization was negative, as expected, and significant in some cases. It did not alter the sign or significance of the regime variable, however. In addition, we employed a variable intended to show the similarity between the foreign policy interests of an LDC and the United States by measuring the overlap in UN voting.115 Such similarity should be associated with a more open economy and hence with lower trade barriers. This variable had no statistically significant impact on Sachs-Warner liberalization, but it sometimes had a modestly negative impact on tariff rates. It did not materially affect the regime variable. Finally, we added data on inequality.116 These data are few and of low quality (some are imputed), so results should be regarded with low confidence. But for neither dependent variable was inequality near conventional levels of significance, nor did it affect the sign or significance of the regime variable.

The Economic Factors

We included several obvious economic controls for trade policy. Our variable measuring country size, logpop, is always significant, but not as expected. Big countries tend to have higher tariff rates, as often suggested, but they tend to be more likely to liberalize, ceteris paribus. The level of economic development (gdp pc) seems to matter at times. But among the LDCs, more-developed countries have more restrictive trade regimes, ceteris paribus. Finally, we looked at a country's flows of direct foreign investment as a percentage of gross national product (GNP), which is represented by variable fdi.117

For the tariff variable, these flows were always positive and significant, indicating that foreign investment flows earlier may have built up a constituency for continued protection of the host market.

We looked at a number of other economic factors that might have some relationship to trade policy. First, we controlled for countries with heavy dependence on oil and fuel exports. Unfortunately, given the use of country fixed effects, and given that the oil producers change little over time, we were unable to address this point. Second, we included a measure of a country's exchange-rate regime, measured along a continuum of fixed to floating.118

This variable had no statistically significant relationship to tariff rates, and a mildly negative impact on trade liberalization à la Sachs-Warner; its inclusion did not affect the sign or significance of regime. Finally, we also looked at (lagged) yearly changes in GNP per capita, GDP, exchange rates, and inflation.119

Data from World Bank WDI and Penn World Tables. See Summers and Heston 1991.

These variables had no statistically significant relationship to tariff rates, sometimes a positive impact on the Sachs-Warner measure of trade liberalization, and no effect on the sign or significance of regime.

In sum, these results support our claim that democratization is one force that leads to a more open trade regime. This finding is robust to three different measures of regime type; it also withstands a variety of robustness checks. Moreover, this influence was never negligible, even when controlling for many alternative explanations. Conventional wisdom about economic reform depending on crises and external pressures is not supported by this study, while the impact of regime change appears more important than previously thought.

Conclusion

Why countries that long pursued protectionism should suddenly liberalize their trade regimes is an important and underexplored question. While economists have long preached the benefits of free trade, developing countries have only recently begun to heed their advice. Indeed, much of the extant literature argues that economic reforms, such as trade liberalization, rarely occur. However, many developing countries began liberalizing trade in the mid-1980s, and the move to free trade since has been remarkable.

Our argument is that a change in the political regime toward more democracy should be followed by a move to liberalize trade. Autocratic political leaders in LDCs can cater to the capital-rich segment of the population because the “selectorate” that picks them is limited. Trade barriers are then imposed on capital-intensive imports so that wealth is redistributed from those who are not part of the selectorate to those who are. Democratization, which implies an increase in the selectorate's size, changes the calculations of political leaders about the optimal level of trade barriers; it induces the adoption of trade policies that better promote the welfare of consumers/voters at large, which implies trade liberalization in this context. While protectionist interest groups remain important in developing democracies, other groups preferring lower trade barriers become more important for political leaders because they are now part of the selectorate upon which leaders depend for their political survival.

We think that future research should try to disaggregate regime type further. Our data suggest that autocracies may vary in the likelihood of choosing economic reform, with single-party and military-controlled systems being more likely than personalistic ones. The two former types of regimes rely on a broader selectorate and are not as able to use protectionism to garner political support. The likelihood of reform may also depend on the type of democratic institutions in place. Examining the impact of different political institutions on trade policy is an unexplored area of great potential interest.

We view democratization as exogenous. However, trade policy could exert an impact on political regimes. Although we lag all of our independent variables (from one to three periods) and include tests for endogeneity, this could be a much longer-term effect. Most models predicting regime type, however, do not include trade policy or even the extent of openness of the economy as a predictor.120

See, for example, Przeworski et al. 2000; and Barro 1997.

Moreover, we found no evidence of such an impact in our data; trade policy did not predict democracy. Even after instrumenting for democracy, regime type still played an important role in explaining the move to free trade. Democracies choose lower levels of trade barriers, even when holding many other factors constant.

Our results cast some doubt on the leading alternative theories of trade policy reform. Although much discussion exists of the role of economic crises, external pressures, and the role of ideas on economic reform, little systematic research has been done. To the extent that our measures adequately control for these factors, they did not seem to play a consistent role in explaining trade policy. Neither crises, nor international pressures, nor new leaders seem to account very well for the move to free trade. We concur with Jenkins, who points out that “the existence of a crisis is no guarantee that a government will respond, and more importantly, that it will be successful in convincing interest groups that ‘something must be done.’”121

Moreover, international institutions that were supposed to foster trade liberalization, such as the GATT/WTO and the IMF, do not appear to be playing that role. As Rose has argued, the GATT does not seem to promote a more liberal trade policy for most countries; and as Ozden and Reinhardt show, the GSP in the WTO has slowed down liberalization in LDCs.122 Our research certainly does not rule out any of these factors, especially the spread of neoliberal ideas. Our measures of the rise of new ideas are very crude, and better research into this topic requires more and different data.

Our argument does not explain all cases or all pressures for liberalization. No single variable can possibly account for the dramatic change in economic policies in the LDCs during the past twenty years. Changes in domestic political institutions, however, have been an underappreciated factor. Hence we highlight their role. Additionally, we cannot explain all countries. India, for instance, remains a puzzle; long a democracy, the government has only recently chosen to lower trade barriers. Although a large number of cases seem to fit our claim, as discussed in the first section of this article, no single variable can possibly account for this move to free trade in all countries.

In general, more-democratic countries are more willing to open their markets to the international economy, even when holding many other factors constant. Democratization thus may have promoted the globalization of the past two decades. As we show vis-à-vis trade, and as Quinn shows relative to capital controls, democracies in the late twentieth century may have been more likely to join the global economy by eliminating the barriers protecting their markets.123

Democratization may have fostered the increasing globalization of the past two decades. Whether the new democracies in the developing world will survive and thrive in a globalized world is a separate issue that should command future research.

References

REFERENCES

Abiad, Abdul, and Ashoka Mody. 2003. Financial Reform: What Shakes It? What Shapes It? Working Paper 03/70. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
African Development Bank. 2003. African Development Report 2003. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Alesina, Alberto, and Allan Drazen. 1991. Why Are Stabilizations Delayed? American Economic Review 81 (5):117088.Google Scholar
Alvarez, Mike, José Antonio Cheibub, Fernando Limongi, and Adam Przeworski. 1996. Classifying Political Regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development 31 (2):336.Google Scholar
Andriamananjara, Shuby, and John Nash. 1997. Have Trade Policy Reforms Led to Greater Openness in Developing Countries? Policy Research Working Paper 1730. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Aslund, Anders, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson. 1996. How to Stabilize? Lessons from Post-Communist Countries. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1996 (1):217313.Google Scholar
Baker, Andy. 2003. Why Is Trade Reform so Popular in Latin America? A Consumption-Based Theory of Trade Policy Preferences. World Politics 55 (3):42355.Google Scholar
Balistreri, Edward. 1997. The Performance of the Heckscher-Ohlin-Vanik Model in Predicting Endogenous Policy Forces at the Individual Level. Canadian Journal of Economics 30 (1):117.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Barro, Robert. 2001. Human Capital and Growth. American Economic Review 91 (2):1217.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert, and Jong-Wha Lee. 2001. International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications. Working Paper 42. Cambridge, Mass.: Center for International Development, Harvard University.
Bates, Robert H. 1981. Markets and States in Tropical Africa. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Beaulieu, Eugene. 2002. The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem Faces Congress. Review of International Economics 10 (2):34360.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Jonathan Katz. 1995. What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series-Cross-Section Data. American Political Science Review 89 (3):63447.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, Jonathan Katz, and Richard Tucker. 1998. Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable. American Journal of Political Science 42 (4):126088.Google Scholar
Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, and Patrick Walsh. 2001. New Tools in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank Economic Review 15 (1):16576.Google Scholar
Bermeo, Nancy. 1994. Sacrifice, Sequence, and Strength in Successful Dual Transitions: The Case of Spain. Journal of Politics 56 (3):60127.Google Scholar
Bienen, Henry, and Jeffrey Herbst. 1996. The Relationship Between Political and Economic Reform in Africa. Comparative Politics 29 (1):2342.Google Scholar
Bierstecker, Thomas. 1995. The ‘Triumph’ of Liberal Economic Ideas in the Developing World. In Global Change, Regional Response, edited by Barbara Stallings, 17496. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, James D. Morrow, Randolph M. Siverson, and Alastair Smith. 1999. An Institutional Explanation of the Democratic Peace. American Political Science Review 93 (4):791807.Google Scholar
Collier, David, and Robert Adcock. 1999. Democracy and Dichotomies: A Pragmatic Approach to Choices about Concepts. Annual Review of Political Science 2:53765.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul, and Jan Willem Gunning. 1999. Explaining African Economic Performance. Journal of Economic Literature 37 (1):64111.Google Scholar
Cordoba, Jose. 1994. Mexico. In The Political Economy of Policy Reform, edited by John Williamson, 23284. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Davidson, Russell, and James MacKinnon, eds. 1993. Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press.
Diamond, Larry, and Marc Plattner, eds. 1993. The Global Resurgence of Democracy. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Dollar, David. 1992. Outward Oriented Developing Economies Do Really Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976–85. Economic Development and Cultural Change 40 (3):52344.Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan. 1996. The Political Economy of Delayed Reform. Journal of Policy Reform 1 (1):2546.Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan, and William Easterly. 2001. Do Crises Induce Reform? Economics and Politics 13 (2):12957.Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan, and Victorio Grilli. 1993. The Benefit of Crises for Economic Reforms. American Economic Review 83 (3):598607.Google Scholar
Dutt, Pushan, and Devashish Mitra. 2002a. Endogenous Trade Policy Through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of International Economics 58 (1):10733.Google Scholar
Dutt, Pushan, and Devashish Mitra. 2002b. Political Ideology and Endogenous Trade Policy: An Empirical Investigation. Working Paper 9239. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo. 1993. Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 32 (3):41758.Google Scholar
Edwards, Sebastian. 1992. Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 39 (1):3158.Google Scholar
Edwards, Sebastian. 1995. Crisis and Reform in Latin America. New York: Oxford University Press.
Edwards, Sebastian. 1998. Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know? Economic Journal 108 (447):38398.Google Scholar
Elkins, Zachary. 2000. Gradations of Democracy?: Empirical Tests of Alternative Conceptualizations. American Journal of Political Science 44 (2):293300.Google Scholar
Feng, Yi, Jacek Kugler, and Paul Zak. 2000. The Politics of Fertility and Economic Development. International Studies Quarterly 44 (4):66793.Google Scholar
Fernandez, Raquel, and Dani Rodrik. 1991. Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual Specific Uncertainty. American Economic Review 81 (5):114655.Google Scholar
Fishlow, Albert. 1990. The Latin American State. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4 (3):6174.Google Scholar
Frankel, Jeffrey, and David Romer. 1999. Does Trade Cause Growth? American Economic Review 89 (3):37999.Google Scholar
Frye, Timothy, and Edward Mansfield. 2001. Voting for Openness: Elections and Trade Liberalization in the Post-Communist World. Paper presented at the 97th Annual Conference of the American Political Science Association, August 30–September 2, San Francisco.
Gartzke, Erik, and Dong-Joon Jo. 2002. The Affinity of Nations Index, 1946–1996. Version 3.0: Codebook. New York: Columbia University.
Geddes, Barbara. 1995. Challenging the Conventional Wisdom. In Economic Reform and Democracy, edited by Larry Diamond and Marc Plattner, 5973. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Geddes, Barbara. 1999. The Effect of Regime Type on Authoritarian Breakdown: The Empirical Test of a Game Theoretic Argument. Paper presented at the 95th Annual Conference of the American Political Science Association, September, Atlanta, Ga.
Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1994. Protection for Sale. American Economic Review 84 (4):83350.Google Scholar
Gurr, Ted Robert, Keith Jaggers, and Will H. Moore. 1990. Polity II: Political Structures and Regime Change, 1800–1986. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.
Haggard, Stephan. 1990. The Political Economy of the Philippines Debt Crisis. In Economic Crisis and Policy Choice: The Politics of Adjustment in the Third World, edited by Joan Nelson. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Haggard, Stephan, and Robert Kaufmann, eds. 1992. The Politics of Economic Adjustment. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Haggard, Stephan, and Robert Kaufmann, eds. 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Haggard, Stephan, and Steven Webb, eds. 1994. Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization, Distributive Conflicts, and Economic Adjustment. New York: Oxford University Press.
Harrison, Ann. 1994. Productivity, Imperfect Competition, and Trade Reform: Theory and Evidence. Journal of International Economics 36 (1/2):5374.Google Scholar
Harrison, Ann. 1996. Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Country Analysis for Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 48 (2):41947.Google Scholar
Hiscox, Michael J. 2002. International Trade and Political Conflict: Commerce, Coalitions, and Mobility. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Horn Welch, Karen, and Romain Wacziarg. 2003. Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence. Working Paper 10152. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1992. Issues and Developments in International Trade Policy. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). Various years. Government Finance Statistics (IMF GFS). Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.
Jaggers, Keith, and Ted Robert Gurr. 1995. Tracking Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data. Journal of Peace Research 32 (4):46982.Google Scholar
Jenkins, Rob. 1999. Democratic Politics and Economic Reform in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kahler, Miles. 1986. The Politics of International Debt. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kahler, Miles. 1989. International Financial Institutions and the Politics of Adjustment. In Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment, edited by Joan Nelson, 13959. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books.
Katzenstein, Peter. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kornai, János. 1992. The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Kotwal, Ashok, and Bharat Ramaswami. 1999. Economic Reforms in Agriculture and Rural Growth. In India in the Era of Economic Reforms, edited by Jeffrey Sachs, Ashutosh Varshney, and Nirupam Bajpai, 12159. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Krasner, Stephen. 1976. State Power and the Structure of International Trade. World Politics 28 (3):31747.Google Scholar
Krueger, Anne. 1997. Trade Policy and Economic Development: How We Learn. American Economic Review 87 (1):122.Google Scholar
Leamer, Edward. 1988. Measures of Openness. In Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis, edited by Robert Baldwin, 147200. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Levinsohn, James. 1999. Employment Responses to International Liberalization in Chile. Journal of International Economics 47 (2):32144.Google Scholar
Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, and Federico Sturzenegger. Forthcoming. Classifying Exchange-Rate Regimes: Deeds vs. Words. European Economic Review.
Little, I. M. D., Richard N. Cooper, W. Max Corden, and Sarath Rajapatirana. 1993. Boom, Crisis and Adjustment: The Macroeconomic Experiences of Developing Countries. New York: Oxford University Press.
Mansfield, Edward, and Rachel Bronson. 1997. Alliances, Preferential Trading Arrangements, and International Trade. American Political Science Review 91 (1):94107.Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward, Helen V. Milner, and B. Peter Rosendorff. 2000. Free to Trade: Democracies, Autocracies, and International Trade. American Political Science Review 94 (2):30522.Google Scholar
Markusen, James R., and Randall M. Wiggle. 1990. Explaining the Volume of North-South Trade. Economic Journal 100 (403):120615.Google Scholar
Marshall, Monty, and Keith Jaggers. 2001. Polity IV: Political Regime Change and Transitions, 1800–2001. College Park, Md.: Integrated Network for Societal Conflict Research (INSCR) Program, University of Maryland. Available at 〈http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/〉. Accessed 15 September 2004.
Mayer, Wolfgang. 1984. Endogenous Tariff Formation. American Economic Review 74 (5):97085.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V., and Keiko Kubota. 2001. Why the Rush to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Liberalization in the Developing World, 1970–1999. Paper presented at the 97th Annual Conference of the American Political Science Association, September, San Francisco.
Munoz, Oscar. 1994. Toward Trade Opening. In Intricate Links: Democratization and Market Reforms in Latin America and Eastern Europe, edited by Joan Nelson, 61104. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Murillo, Maria. 2001. Labor Unions, Partisan Coalitions and Market Reform in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Naím, Moisés. 1993. Paper Tigers and Minotaurs: The Politics of Venezuela's Economic Reforms. Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Nelson, Joan. 1990. Economic Crisis and Policy Choice: The Politics of Adjustment in the Third World. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Nelson, Joan, ed. 1994a. Intricate Links: Democratization and Market Reforms in Latin America and Eastern Europe. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Nelson, Joan, ed. 1994b. A Precarious Balance: Democracy and Economic Reform in Eastern Europe. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press.
Ozden, Caglar, and Eric Reinhardt. 2002. The Perversity of Preferences: The Generalized System of Preferences and Developing Country Trade Policies, 1976–2000. Working Paper 2955. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Pritchett, Lant. 1996. Measuring Outward Orientation in LDCs: Can It Be Done? Journal of Development Economics 49 (2):30735.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and James Vreeland. 2000. The Effect of IMF Programs on Economic Growth. Journal of Development Economics 62 (2):385421.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, Michael F. Alvarez, José Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge University Press. Updated data to 2000 available from José Cheibub.
Quinn, Dennis. 2001. Democracy and International Financial Liberalization. Paper presented at the 97th Annual Conference of the American Political Science Association, September, San Francisco.
Remmer, Karen. 1990. Democracy and Economic Crisis: The Latin American Experience. World Politics 42 (3):31535.Google Scholar
Rodriguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik. 2001. Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, edited by B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff, 261325. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Rodrik, Dani. 1992. The Limits of Trade Policy Reform in Developing Countries. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 6 (1):87105.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1994. The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World: Why So Late? Why Now? Will It Last? In Voting For Reform, edited by Stephan Haggard and Steven Webb, 145794. New York: Oxford University Press.
Rodrik, Dani. 1995. Political Economy of Trade Policy. In Handbook of International Economics, edited by Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff, 145794. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science Press.
Rodrik, Dani. 1996. Understanding Economic Policy Reform. Journal of Economic Literature 34 (1):941.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Rogowski, Ronald. 1987. Political Cleavages and Changing Exposure to Trade. American Political Science Review 81 (4):112137.Google Scholar
Rose, Andrew. 2002a. Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade? Working Paper 9273. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Rose, Andrew. 2002b. Do WTO Members Have More Liberal Trade Policy? Working Paper 9347. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner. 1995. Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (1):1118.Google Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth, and Matthew Slaughter. 2001. What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences? Journal of International Economics 54 (2):26792.Google Scholar
Seddon, Jessica, and Romain Wacziarg. 2004. Trade Liberalization and Intersectoral Labor Movements. Journal of International Economics 64 (4):41139.Google Scholar
Sharer, Robert, Piritta Sorsa, and IMF staff. 1998. Trade Liberalization in IMF-Supported Programs. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
Sikkink, Kathryn. 1997. Development Ideas in Latin America: Paradigm Shift and the Economic Commission for Latin America. In International Development and the Social Sciences: Essays in the History and Politics of Knowledge, edited by Frederick Cooper and Randall Packard, 22856. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Simmons, Beth. 2000. International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs. American Political Science Review 94 (4):81936.Google Scholar
Stallings, Barbara, ed. 1995. Global Change, Regional Response: A New International Context of Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Stallings, Barbara, and Robert Kaufmann, eds. 1989. Debt and Democracy in Latin America. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Stokes, Susan, ed. 2001. Public Support for Market Reforms in New Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Subramanian, Arvind, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2003. The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly but Unevenly. Working Paper 10024. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Subramanian, Arvind, Enrique Gelbard, Richard Harmsen, Katrin Elborgh-Woytek, and Piroska Nagy. 2000. Trade and Trade Policies in Eastern and Southern Africa. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.
Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston. 1991. The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950–1988. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2):32768. Version 6.0, updated to 2000, available at <http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/pwt_index.php>. Accessed 15 September 2004.Google Scholar
Tornell, Aaron. 1998. Reform from Within. Working Paper 6497. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Tybout, James, and Daniel Westbrook. 1995. Trade Liberalization and the Dimensions of Efficiency Change in Mexican Manufacturing Industries. Journal of International Economics 39 (1–2):5378.Google Scholar
UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). 1994. Directory of Import Regimes. Geneva: UN Conference on Trade and Development.
UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). 2000. Trade Analysis and Information Systems (TRAINS). Geneva: UN Conference on Trade and Development. CD-ROM.
UN Development Program. 2002. Human Development Report 2002: Deepening Democracy in a Fragmented World. New York: Oxford University Press.
van de Walle, Nicolas. 2001. African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979–1999. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Vreeland, James. 2003. The IMF and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Weyland, Kurt. 2002. The Politics of Market Reform in Fragile Democracies: Argentina, Brazil, Peru and Venezuela. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
World Bank. 2000a. Global Development Finance. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
World Bank. 2000b. File: tar2000.xcl. Washington, D.C. Updated file tar2002.xcl available at <http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/TRADE/0,,contentMDK:20103740∼menuPK:167374∼pagePK:148956∼piPK:216618∼theSitePK:239071,00.html>. Accessed 15 September 2004.
World Bank. Various years. World Development Indicators. (WB WDI). Washington, D.C.: World Bank. CD-ROM.
World Trade Organization (WTO). Various years. Trade Policy Review. Geneva: WTO.
Yang, C. C. 1995. Endogenous Tariff Formation under Representative Democracy: A Probabilistic Voting Model. The American Economic Review 85 (4):95663.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Summary statistics

Figure 1

Tariff rates

Figure 2

Tariff rates

Figure 3

Tariff rates

Figure 4

Sachs-Warner trade liberalization

Figure 5

Sachs-Warner trade liberalization

Figure 6

Instrumental variable regression: Tariff rates