Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-lrblm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T12:02:58.584Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HISTORICISM AND NEOCLASSICISM IN THE KIEV SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS: THE CASE OF ALEKSANDER BILIMOVICH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 March 2010

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Aleksander Bilimovich (1876–1963) is often considered to have been one of the last representatives of the Kiev School of economics, which was influenced by the German Historical School as well as by the emerging neoclassical theory. After the Soviet revolution, Bilimovich continued his work in exile and was developing his theoretical and methodological views along two lines of the Kiev tradition. On the one side he maintained the historical approach, and on the other side he was inclined towards the deductivist and mathematical approach. The paper thus questions the established view among the historians of Russian economic thought of Bilimovich as a consistent adherent of marginalism. His work bears also several features of historicism.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2010

I. INTRODUCTION

The Russian-born economist Aleksander Bilimovich (1876–1963) wrote his most important economic works while living in exile, into which he was forced in 1920. The purpose of this paper is to show that his complex and multifaceted theoretical work reflects, in many aspects, the methodological dilemmas of the Russian pre-revolutionary economic theory, to which Bilimovich was exposed in his formative years at the turn of the nineteenth century. In particular, it reflects the features of the so called Kiev School of economics, whose traditional mixing up of classical liberalism with ideas of the German Historical School towards the end of the nineteenth century began manifesting itself in a methodological eclecticism (or duality), composed of German historicism and deductivist Austrian marginalism as part of the emerging neoclassical economics. Throughout the paper, we shall outline some typical features of Bilimovich’s work and compare them with the characteristics of Russian economic thought in the second half of the nineteenth century, which were thoroughly analyzed in some recent research works (Koropeckyj Reference Koropeckyj1990, Zweynert Reference Zweynert2002, Anikin Reference Anikin2002, Sheptun Reference Sheptun2005). Bilimovich’s work, although contributing to the body of economic literature in five languages (German, Russian, Slovenian, English, and Serbo-Croat), has so far not been comprehensively presented to the international audience. It was presented, however, to Russian (Korickij Reference Korickij1997) and to Slovenian readers (Sušjan Reference Sušjan2005), that is, in the environments where Bilimovich lived during the most important periods of his life and professional career.

The paper is structured in two parts. The first part is a brief outline of the characteristics of the Kiev School of economics. The second part, which begins with a biographical sketch of Aleksander Bilimovich, identifies two separate approaches that can be traced in Bilimovich’s work: the historical approach on the one side, and the neoclassical approach on the other. These two approaches in Bilimovich’s work are recognized as the legacy of the Kiev School of economics within which Bilimovich was theoretically brought up and which left a permanent impact on his economic thinking. In the last section of the second part there is an overview of Bilimovich’s work on economic dynamics, covering his studies on structural changes of agricultural sector, statistical analysis of business cycles, and his schemes of circular flow, on which he worked in the mature period of his career. Economic dynamics is an area in which his historical and neoclassical approach overlapped.

II. THE KIEV SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS WITHIN THE RUSSIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT IN THE NINETEENTH CENTURY

Aleksander Bilimovich is often considered to have been one of the last representatives of the Kiev School of economics.Footnote 1 The term “Kiev School” refers to a rather diverse group of economists in the pre-revolutionary Russia, who studied or taught at Kiev University. Since their views differed in many aspects, the label “school” is sometimes considered inappropriate for them.Footnote 2 But the works of these authors also show some common characteristics which justify their being classified together. These characteristics are several: (1) the Kiev economists were, generally speaking, considerably more liberally oriented than other Russian economists in the second half of the nineteenth century—many of them advocated the harmony doctrine of F. Bastiat and H. Carey; (2) they opposed socialist ideas (although they supported various measures of social policy performed by the state); and (3) they were strongly influenced by the German Historical School (this was to some extent in contradiction with their liberal orientation) as well as by the Methodenstreit issues (although their positions towards the methodological controversy were not uniform). The last characteristic is of special importance. Namely, while the impact of German historicism was present in almost all Russian economic theory of the nineteenth century (not only in the works of Ukrainian or Kiev authors), the dilemmas related with Methodenstreit were particularly strongly present among the Kiev economists. In fact, the ambivalent position concerning the methodological controversy between Gustav von Schmoller and Carl Menger can be viewed as the most “cohesive” feature of the Kiev School at the turn of the twentieth century.

Throughout the nineteenth century one of the main debates between the Russian economists was centered around the question of the path of Russia’s future economic development. In this debate the Kiev economists generally supported the “Westernization” of the Russian economy, that is, that Russia should develop along the path of the Western European market economies. They were opposed to the socialist ideas of Nikolaj Tschernishevsky (1828–1889), a Russian economist who viewed the traditional Russian peasant community as an authentic way into socialism. He believed that by social transformation through the peasant community Russia had a chance to avoid a capitalist path of economic development. Tschernishevsky’s ideas were further developed by the Moscow School of the so called narodniki-economists, that is, an academic circle centered around Aleksandr Tschuprov (1842–1908). They considered land community—a traditional form of collective property—to be the “cornerstone” of the Russian “social building,”Footnote 3 enabling a non-capitalist development of the Russian economy.Footnote 4 The idea of peasant socialism was in the second half of the nineteenth century also criticized by radical Russian Marxists. The Kiev economists were, of course, strongly opposed not only to socialism of the narodniki-movement but to revolutionary Marxism as well.

Russian economic theory of the nineteenth century was influenced by two traditions in economic thought. The first was classical liberalism, which was presented to Russian readers through the early translations of Adam Smith, Jean-Baptiste Say, and J. S. Mill. The second, as already indicated, was the German Historical School, whose ideas were disseminated in Russia by the translations of the works of Wilhelm Roscher and Bruno Hildebrand, later also of Gustav von Schmoller and others. It is important to note at this point, that German economic thinkers played an important role in the development of Russian economic thought from its early beginnings. Namely, western economic ideas, either in the form of classical liberalism or German cameralism, were popularized in Russia already in the first quarter of the nineteenth century by German economists teaching at Russian universities (C. Schlözer, J. Lang, L. Jacob) and also by Russian economists of German origin (“Russian Germans”).Footnote 5 Among the latter the most important was Heinrich Storch (1766–1836), who worked in St. Petersburg. He developed the theory of “inner goods” (like health, knowledge, thoughts, security), which cannot be bought or sold and have therefore no price, but are nevertheless very important in the process of utility satisfaction. Although an adherent of the classical tradition, Storch opposed the labor theory of value and criticized the materialistic concept of wealth. According to him, “national wealth” should be analyzed as a broad concept covering also non-material components, such as civilization, culture, etc.Footnote 6 This idea was popular already with early German historicists: economy is an organic whole of the material and spiritual forces of a nation, which has to be analyzed within its historical path of development. In Russia, such holistic view of the economy was later supported particularly by Ivan Kondratjevich Babst (1824–1881), who opposed any radical changes and opted for gradual social reforms. He is considered to be the first genuine representative of the historical school in Russia.

Alla Sheptun believes that the ideas of the German Historical School enabled many Russian economists to take “the ‘middle way’ between economic liberalism and socialism.”Footnote 7 This opinion could be valid also for the Kiev circle of economists, who criticized socialist ideas and argued for progressive social development which would bring the Russian economy closer to the level of the Western European countries. Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, pp. 303–304) defines the Kiev School as a combination of the views of the German Historical School, according to which economic laws depend on the socioeconomic conditions, and political liberalism based on the belief in natural order. The situation that liberal economic views were much more strongly present among the Kiev economists than elsewhere in Russia can be attributed to the fact that Ukraine was much less influenced by the Russian socialist ideas of the narodniki-economists than central Russia, and that here the traditional peasant community dissolved earlier than in other parts of the country, which led to significant increases in agricultural productivity. But this does not mean that the Kiev economists were uncritical adherents of economic liberalism. Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 169) rightly claims that Ukrainian economists rejected both pure laissez-faire doctrine and Marxian economics.Footnote 8 Unlike in Moscow and St. Petersburg, where the left-wing intellectual circles were dominant, in Kiev the view prevailed much earlier that only the capitalist path of development and free business initiative can spur economic growth and improve public welfare in Russia. At the same time, government intervention was seen necessary in order to ameliorate growing social inequalities. The Kiev School had a particularly strong influence on Russian economic policy in the last decade of the nineteenth century, when its economistsFootnote 9 influenced the governmental program, proposing several liberal measures, such as distribution of land to the farmers and reduction of tax burden for the farmers.Footnote 10 After 1890, however, also in the leftist circles of Moscow and St. Petersburg, the narodniki started losing their power. Their ideas of peasant socialism were abandoned due to the appearance of two influential Marxian-oriented economists, Petr B. Struve (1870–1944) and Mikhail I. Tugan-Baranovsky (1865–1919), who rejected the narodniki-ideology and argued for the capitalist path of Russian economic development.Footnote 11

According to Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, p. 302), one of the forerunners of the Kiev School was Ivan Vasiljevich Vernadsky (1821–1884), who promoted the classical ideas of individualism and freedom. Vernadsky studied in Kiev, taught for a short period of time at Kiev University, and became full professor of political economy at Moscow University, where he remained until 1857. Later he held various positions in civil administration and banking in St. Petersburg and Kharkov. He published many articles and participated in the heated debate concerning the traditional Russian land community, in which he severely criticized the views of Tschernishevsky. Vernadsky’s position was that communal land ownership leads to economic inefficiency.Footnote 12 Also, he disagreed with protectionist ideas of F. List and argued for internationally competitive environment, which would be conducive to the growth in productivity of Russia’s expanding industry. Vernadsky was thoroughly acquainted with Western economic literature and wrote extensively on the history of economics.Footnote 13 His favorite classical authors were Adam Smith and Frédéric Bastiat. Not surprisingly, he was critical of socialist writers who, in his view, were concerned with social conditions at the expense of the growth of output. Vernadsky was also influenced by Heinrich Storch’s theory related to inner goods and needs, so it is not surprising that while being an adherent of the labor theory of value he at the same time praised Gossen’s laws and considered important the evolution of needs.Footnote 14 Like Bastiat he was convinced that unleashed individual interests lead to social harmony and that a liberalized market system is a precondition for growth and development of the society as a whole.

The next important economist of the Kiev School was Nikolaj Christianovich Bunge (1823–1895), who began his work at the Kiev department for political economy in 1850. In his early works, Bunge like Vernadsky supported clasical liberalism (particularly the views of J. S. Mill and T. Tooke), but with time he was coming more and more under the influence of younger German Historical School and supported state interventionism in the area of social policy.Footnote 15 His most important work is considered to be Principles of Political Economy, Footnote 16 published in 1870. While rejecting absolute liberalism, Bunge was opposed even more strongly to socialism which, by eliminating private property and competition, leads to a communist society with no free expression of life possible. He criticized Marx’s economics for having several unrealistic assumptions, including the labor theory of value.Footnote 17 At the methodological level he strove for setting a demarcation line between deductive and inductive method in economics as well as between the economic theory and praxis. In the Methodenstreit, however, he clearly positioned himself on Schmoller’s side. Bunge has often been accused of being eclectic and lacking originality. But there is no doubt that his broad knowledge on various economic issues contributed to his successful work in the area of economic policy, first as minister of finance and from 1887 to his death also as president of the ministerial council. Bunge’s works laid the scientific basis for his ministerial policy, which was in essence liberally oriented, supporting economic individualism, but also introducing and extending state activities in order to reduce the negative social consequences of unlimited competition.Footnote 18

Bunge’s successor was Dmitrij Ivanovich Pichno (1853–1913). In comparison with Bunge, who favored Mill, Pichno laid more emphasis on Smith, David Ricardo, and Thomas Malthus. He considered their works to be of utmost importance for understanding the issues related with the theory of value and distribution.Footnote 19 Contrary to Vernadsky he opposed the labor theory of value and put more emphasis on Storch’s analysis of needs and utility. For Pichno, the exchange value was the result of the interplay between the supply and demand forces.Footnote 20 On the other hand he followed the ideas of the German Historical School. This can be seen in his making a strict distinction between individual and social phenomena, with national economy considered as an organic whole of both.Footnote 21 Also, in line with the German historicists, he considered cultural and historical forces of a nation as the fourth factor of production (beside land, capital, and labor). But in the Methodenstreit, Pichno supported Menger’s views, although warning at the same time about too high a level of abstraction, which would remove theoretical analysis from the firm ground of real life.Footnote 22 This position might well be considered eclectic, but at the end of the nineteenth century such methodological duality was a logical characteristic of the authors that were intellectually split between the strong tradition of the historical approach on the one side and the emerging neoclassical analysis with deductive and mathematical approach on the other.Footnote 23

As we shall see, such views of economics, characterized by the historical and evolutionary approach on the one side, and by deductive reasoning and mathematical formalism on the other, marked also the entire work of Pichno’s successor Bilimovich, who entered the Kiev circle of economists at the beginning of the twentieth century.Footnote 24 In his work on the valuation of goods and in his econometric modelling of circular flow Bilimovich came close to marginalist and neoclassical methodological views. But he nevertheless always remained convinced that economics is basically a social science and that a national economy should be analyzed within its historical—social and institutional—path of development. This means that the frequently cited views according to which Bilimovich was a consistent adherent of marginalism, who only at the end of his life became an advocate of reforms introducing social capitalism,Footnote 25 are not true. It will be shown in the next section that in his entire lifework Bilimovich was constantly swaying between the mathematical and historical approaches. Also, his explicit views about the need to introduce social reforms in capitalist economies can be already found in the early 1920s, which is forty years before the end of his life.

III. ALEKSANDER BILIMOVICH BETWEEN THE HISTORICAL SCHOOL AND NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS

A biographical outline: Kiev—Ljubljana—San Francisco

Aleksander Dmitrievich Bilimovich was born in Zhitomir (Ukraine) in 1876 as a son of a military doctor. He studied law at the University of St. Wladimir in Kiev. Already as a student he wrote an excellent statistical research work about the transportation of goods on Russian railways, for which he was awarded the first prize in the student competition. The research was later published by the university. After graduation the university offered him a scholarship to continue with postgraduate studies. In 1904 he passed the master’s exam in political economy and statistics and immediately obtained the position of Privatdozent at the Faculty of Law of Kiev University. From 1905 to 1911 he was several times abroad visiting the universities in Tübingen, Berlin, and Vienna, and collecting materials for his research work. In Tübingen he attended the lectures of professors F. J. Neumann and G. Schönberg, and in Berlin the lectures of professors G. Schmoller, A. Wagner, M. Sering, J. Böck, and L. Bortkiewicz. In the meantime, in 1909, he defended his master’s thesis in Kiev and became associate professor of economics and statistics. During the summer of 1910 he worked with Professor Böhm-Bawerk in Vienna. A year later he published an article on the valuation of economic goods, in which the influence of Böhm-Bawerk’s work is clearly present. The question of exchange values and prices was also the main subject of his doctoral dissertation, which he successfully defended in St. Petersburg in 1915.Footnote 26 After that he became a professor of political economy and statistics at Kiev University.

Bilimovich’s academic career in Kiev ended abruptly with the arrival of the Bolsheviks in 1918. He moved to the south and for a short time taught economics in Odesa and Simferopol. In 1919 he joined the counter-revolutionary forces, serving briefly as a minister in the government of General A. Denikin. Early in 1920 he emigrated with his wife and daughter to Yugoslavia,Footnote 27 where he was appointed professor of political economy at the newly established University of Ljubljana.Footnote 28 He settled in Ljubljana and became a respected citizen. During the next twenty-five years he wrote his best economic works, dealing with price and monetary theory, cycle analysis, statistics, methodological issues, circular flow analysis, agricultural development, questions of economic legislation, etc. His articles and book reviews were appearing regularly in the Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, published by Julius Springer in Vienna,Footnote 29 in scientific proceedings of the Faculty of Law in Ljubljana, and in many other German, Austrian, and Yugoslav economic periodicals of the time. Beside numerous articles, book reviews, and statistical studies, in this period he also wrote three monographs.Footnote 30 In 1933 he became a member of Econometric Society.Footnote 31

However, with the arrival of communism in Yugoslavia at the end of the second World War, Bilimovich was once again forced into exile. In 1945, at the age of 69, he moved to Germany. He was appointed professor of economics and statistics at the UNRRA University in Munich.Footnote 32 Due to several organizational problems the UNRRA University was closed down in 1947, after which Bilimovich went to the United States. At the University of California, Berkeley, he organized a seminar on five-year plans in socialist economies.Footnote 33 According to the university regulations he had to abandon teaching at the age of 73, but he remained actively involved in research work, publishing articles on economic theory and critically analyzing the situation in the Soviet economy.Footnote 34 He lived in San Francisco until his death in 1963.

An Historicist and Mathematical Economist

Bilimovich was strongly influenced by the Kiev tradition in economic thought. The alleged eclecticism of the Kiev School in the form of a split between two different methodological approaches can be traced already in the works that Bilimovich wrote in the pre-revolutionary period. His early contributions were related with Russian railways, dealing either with railway transportation costs or with issues concerning the social status of the railway personnel.Footnote 35 In his master’s thesis (Bilimovič 1907) he analyzed in depth the legislative issues related with Russian land settlement, particularly stressing the importance of the institution of property rights. Bilimovich referred mostly to German authors, such as W. Roscher, A. Wagner, G. Krafft, A. Glatzel, and G. Schmoller, and to Schmoller’s Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung und Verwaltung.Footnote 36 Also, he surveyed the controversies concerning the transformation of land community into various forms of private ownership in agrarian societies.Footnote 37 All these works are written in the spirit of the historical school; they include statistical data and describe several institutional features of economic life in tsarist Russia, concerning social classes, infrastructure, evolution of ownership and legislation, etc. But in this period Bilimovich also tackled a completely different subject. In 1911 he published his first article in the German language, dealing with the valuation of goods (Bilimowitsch Reference Bilimowitsch1911). This article is by its form and contents close to the marginalist tradition of the Austrian school and to the subjective theory of value. There is no doubt that it was written under the impact of Bilimovich’s visit to Vienna University in 1910.

The coexistence of the historical approach on the one side and the marginalist-mathematical approach on the other side (although applied to different issues) remained characteristic for Bilimovich throughout his entire lifework. If we consider the interwar period, when Bilimovich reached the peak of his professional career, his publications can be classified into two groups. First, there are the essays written in the methodological tradition of the German Historical School. In these essays Bilimovich presented, using comprehensive statistical materials, the structural and institutional characteristics of the Yugoslav economy or its sectors between the two wars (e.g. Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1927, Reference Bilimovič1935a, Reference Bilimovič1939a) and the position of workers in the Yugoslav economy (Bilimovič, 1926). He analyzed labor law (Bilimovič 1929c) and market regulations (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1936). To this group also belongs his detailed analysis of agricultural reforms in Russia at the beginning of the twentieth century (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1930), stressing the importance of the institutional background of the reforms. It should also be mentioned that a significant part of Bilimovich’s introductory textbook to economics (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933a) deals with the historical evolution of the economy, presenting various schemes of developmental phases, typically proposed by German historicists (F. List, B. Hildebrand, K. Bücher).Footnote 38 All these works show Bilimovich as inclined to the use of historical approach. On the other hand, there are, from the same time period, several articles in which Bilimovich discussed typical neoclassical issues of the time, like the subjectivist theory of value (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1930b, Reference Bilimovič1931b), the problem of utility measurement (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1929a, Reference Bilimovič1933b, Reference Bilimovič1934), and the role of money (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1931c, Reference Bilimovič1935b). It is on the basis of this part of his work,Footnote 39 which was written in the methodological tradition of Austrian marginalism, that Bilimovich is often categorized as a neoclassical economist. What distinguishes him from the Austrian marginalist tradition of Menger and Böhm-Bawerk is his extensive use of mathematics, which brings him closer to the tradition of English marginalists and to the representatives of the Lausanne mathematical school. Bilimovich’s work in the interwar period thus represents an interesting juxtaposition of historicism and neoclassicism in economic thinking.

However, there is one segment of Bilimovich’s work in which he obviously found the possibility to fruitfully combine the historical approach with his inclination towards mathematical formalism. In the 1920s he started with the statistical analysis of business fluctuations which resulted in an excellent textbook type monograph on the analysis of business cycles (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1931a). Although technical in method, this segment of his work indirectly relates Bilimovich with the institutionalist economic theory of the time. Namely, it was American institutionalism (e.g. W. Mitchell) which initiated a detailed statistical analysis of business cycles. But even here the methodological thread goes back to German economic thought, since, as is well known, many American institutionalists had been influenced by the German Historical School.Footnote 40

Bilimovich made a further step in this field in the 1940s when, inspired by Quesnay’s Tableau, he began designing the so-called “dynamic schemes of economic process”—an econometric representation of economic circular flow (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1943, Reference Bilimovič1944b). This line of research, probably also encouraged by his membership in the Econometric Society, eventually led him to a very specific way of simulating business cycles in the form of sequential “shots” of circular flow (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1953). Judging from this part of his work, we can again characterize Bilimovich as a mathematical and neoclassical economist.

Views about Economics

In his 1933 textbook on economics Bilimovich defined economics as a social science dealing with social relations which emerge between people as a result of their economic activities.Footnote 41 It is interesting that only one year earlier Lionel Robbins in his famous essay proposed a completely different definition, which became a manifesto of modern neoclassical economics. According to Robbins (Reference Robbins1932), economics is a science of how to apply scarce means to alternative ends. Although Bilimovich was familiar with Robbins’s definition,Footnote 42 his views remained closer to the German authors who claimed, like for example Werner Sombart, that all economic categories have a social dimension and that economics (Nationalökonomie) is in fact “economic sociology.”Footnote 43 So in spite of his inclination towards mathematical formalism and deductive reasoning and his support of subjectivist theory of value, which are all typical for the neoclassical theory, Bilimovich, by emphasizing the social dimensions of economics, maintained the tradition of the German historicism, characterized by a broad holistic approach to economics.

These “two souls” of Bilimovich are also discernible from his systematization of economic science.Footnote 44 Here, again in the manner of German authors (G. Mayr, A. Voigt, W. Sombart), Bilimovich insisted on the distinction between “economic ontology” and “economic deontology.”Footnote 45 The former is positivist in nature, based on the observation of reality and on the analysis which is value-free. The latter is normative and practical. It deals with economic policy and is based on subjective ideas about the desired state of the economy. Economic ontology was further divided into “economic idiography” and “economic nomography.” Economic idiography describes particular economies with their macro- and microeconomic phenomena (according to Bilimovich it included economic statistics, economic history, and economic geography). Economic nomography searches for general laws of economic processes (it refers either to the economy as a whole or to particular industries—agriculture, manufacturing, etc.). Practical economic processes (the subject of economic deontology), on the other hand, can be analyzed either from a micro or macro perspective. Therefore economic deontology covers the analysis of the policy of the firm (Betriebswirtschaftslehre) (either general or specific concerning firms in particular industries) and of the household (Haushaltungskunde), as well as of various macroeconomic policies (financial, industrial, etc.).

Because of the changing social characteristics of the economic systems and historical relativity of economic laws, Bilimovich was convinced that economics belongs to the social, historical, and cultural sciences. This caused him some problems in interpreting the neo-Kantian ideas about idiography and nomography, which he applied in his systematization of economic science. Namely, the neo-Kantian philosophers, especially W. Windelband and H. Rickert, originally introduced these terms to set a demarcation line between natural sciences and historical (or cultural) sciences, with the former being strictly nomothetic (using general phenomena and value-free analysis, and setting general laws) and the latter being idiographic (analysing individual and non-repeating phenomena, and also applying value judgements). Bilimovich believed that economics, although belonging to the historical and cultural sciences, deals not only with individual phenomena but also searches for general laws and is therefore also nomothetic in character. He was very clear about this: “Therefore the difference between economic science (as well as other cultural sciences) and natural sciences lies not in the method of research (Forschungsweise), as believed by W. Windelband and H. Rickert, but in the subject of research (Forschungsbereich). The methodological distinction, made by these two authors, does not set a demarcation line between economic science and natural sciences but rather . . . between various parts of economics itself” (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933a, pp. 122–123n). With this Bilimovich pointed to his distinguishing between economic nomographyFootnote 46 and economic idiography as two parts of economic ontology.

Concerning the question of value judgements, Bilimovich was very explicit about the need for strictly differentiating between the value-free formation of economic theory (economic ontology) on one side and economic pragmatism (economic deontology), based on normative value judgements, on the other. Only the value judgements made by economizing economic agents (related with self-interest and profit motives) can be taken as facts and as such belong to the positivist part of economics.Footnote 47 However, an economic theoretician should never subordinate economic theory to his own subjective values and normative ideas about the economy. A typical example of such methodological error was Marx’s distinction between “bourgeois” and “proletarian” economic theory, a distinction which for Bilimovich was “as senseless as would be a distinction between bourgeois and proletarian mathematics, chemistry, physics or astronomy.”Footnote 48 For Bilimovich, an economic theoretician should act like an anatomist; the formation of economic theory requires a value-free “anatomical” approach. Economics as a science should be independent of practical issues and absolutely autonomous. As in all other scientific disciplines, looking for scientific truth should be the main objective of a scientist and should not be mixed with any pragmatic aims. This is strictly in line with neoclassical methodological views. In his inaugural lecture at the University of Ljubljana in 1920 he referred to the words of D. Mendelejev, that if the scientific work is independent, then practical usefulness of science comes by itself. Taking into account that Mendelejev invented the (very useful) periodic table of elements, Bilimovich lucidly concluded that thus “even practical interests support the need for a completely independent and autonomous position of science.”Footnote 49 Bilimovich’s econometric modelling of economic processes in the form of “dynamic schemes,” with which he began in early 1940s, was a clear example of this “anatomical” and value-free approach.

But once formed, economic theory should be applied also to practical issues. In his studies Bilimovich therefore often proposed various policy measures. He was critical of negative social effects of the functioning of the market, which can be eliminated or at least mitigated by social policy measures and social reforms.Footnote 50, Footnote 51 This was clearly an impact of the German Historical School, especially of the representatives of its younger generation, who enthusiastically discussed the distributional and social issues in the economy (G. Schmoller and Verein für Sozialpolitik).

By referring to his systematization of economic science Bilimovich’s work can be described as an interesting combination of economic ontology (“idiographic” statistical studies, “nomographic” econometrics, and studies on value), paralleled by mild social activism (economic deontology). The legacy of the eclecticism of the Kiev School can be framed within the “ontological” part of Bilimovich’s work with his idiographic studies exhibiting the historical approach and his nomographic studies representing the neoclassical-mathematical approach.

Idiographic and Nomographic Studies on Economic Dynamics

If we judge from his work as a whole, then understanding economic dynamics seems to have been one of the most intriguing issues for Bilimovich as an economist. In fact, he was often critical about using the term “statics” in economics.Footnote 52 For him the functioning of an economy is a process that never stops, not even under conditions of equilibrium. So by making an analogy with the science of mechanics where “dynamics” is divided into “statics,” which analyzes only still bodies, and “kinetics,” which deals with moving bodies, Bilimovich argued that only the term “kinetics” is appropriate for economic dynamics, while “statics” is completely irrelevant (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1924a).

Using his own terminology, Bilimovich’s studies on economic dynamics can be classified into “idiographic” and “nomographic” ones. His idiographic studies were mostly centered around two subjects: (1) developments in the agricultural sector and (2) business fluctuations in the economy as a whole. In these studies he was applying an historical approach. In his nomographic studies on economic dynamics Bilimovich attempted to design the so-called “dynamic schemes of economic process” formalizing the idea of circular flow. Here his approach was mathematical.

Developments in agriculture and the analysis of business cycles. Already in his early works Bilimovich analyzed the problems of Russian agriculture and land legislation in historical context (e.g. Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1907). Later, in the interwar period, he was the co-author of an extensive monograph on Russian agriculture in the first two decades of the twentieth century, published by Yale University in 1930 (Antsiferov et al. Reference Antsiferov, Bilimovich, Batshev and Ivantsov1930, Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1930). Here Bilimovich gave a comprehensive and systematic overview of Russian agricultural reforms in the period 1906–1913. He analyzed the role of the relevant institutions (e.g. the establishing and the reorganization of the state agricultural bank) and presented the demise of the agricultural system after the revolution in 1917. In the early 1950s, Bilimovich took part in a research, supported by Stanford University, analyzing the evolution of agriculture in some of the Eastern European economies in the period 1935–1945. He presented the Yugoslav agriculture and food industry before and during the Second World War, and in the immediate aftermath of the establishment of the communist regime in Yugoslavia (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich, Zagoroff, Végh and Bilimovich1955). Bilimovich was well acquainted with this subject, because he had already carried out two comprehensive studies on Yugoslav agriculture in 1939, when he statistically analyzed its structural dynamics (concerning the size of farms) (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1939a) and compared this dynamics with agricultural sectors in selected European economies (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1939b).Footnote 53 The conclusions of these studies pointed out the need for extending the cultivation areas (e.g. by irrigation) and for the growth of industrialization, which would reduce the problem of rural overpopulation and poverty in Yugoslavia.Footnote 54

Bilimovich became interested in statistical analysis of business cycles in the mid 1920s under the influence of works of H. L. Moore and W. Mitchell.Footnote 55 In the interwar period he was one of the few economists in Yugoslavia who strongly advocated an institution which would systematically collect and analyze statistical data about economic fluctuations and use these data for economic forecasting (e.g. Bilimovič 1928).Footnote 56, Footnote 57 Like many economists in the interwar period, Bilimovich suggested a number of indicators from various economic sectors (employment, production, prices, capital markets, etc.) which combined could serve as an economic barometer. This was a pragmatic line of economic research which flourished in the United States and Europe in the first three decades of the century and was aimed to instrumentalize statistical surveying for the purpose of (anti-recessionary) economic policies. It is interesting that Bilimovich did not criticize the old, descriptive theories of business crises which had been put forward by theoreticians such as A. Spiethoff, A. Aftalion, J. Schumpeter, and Tugan-Baranovsky. He was inclined towards a compromise, stating that there was in this area in the long run a need for “a broad synthesis” of “logical theory” on one side and “statistical symptomatics” on the other.Footnote 58 Based on his lectures on the statistical analysis of cycles Bilimovich’s monograph was published in the middle of the Great Depression (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1931a).

Schemes of economic circular flow. In the early 1940s Bilimovich started working on a subject which later became one of the main pillars of his economic “nomography.” Bilimovich’s interest in circular flow analysis evolved from his fascination with Quesnay’s Tableau Economique. His excellent exposition of the physiocratic table (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1942)Footnote 59 was duly appraised by Woog (Reference Woog1950) and Holý (Reference Holý1957). Bilimovich designed an innovative graphical representation of the Tableau. For this purpose he analyzed separately the monetary and the real aspects of the table and then brought them together in a comprehensive aggregate flow chart. Bilimovich was thus among the first theoreticians to transform the original Quesnay “zig-zags” into a modern schematic chart of aggregate flows.Footnote 60 In the same study Bilimovich also attempted to construct a Quesnayian picture of a modern capitalist economy.Footnote 61 He replaced the physiocratic social structure (composed of three classes: farmers, sterile class, and landowners) with producers, traders, workers, landowners, the banking sector, and the state as the main participants in the contemporary market economic process. By assuming the real and monetary flows between the participants to be reproduced from year to year in an unchanged form, Bilimovich managed to design a comprehensive model of a stationary circular flow (stationäre Wirtschaft).

In his subsequent studies in this area (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1943; Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1944b) Bilimovich worked on the “dynamization” of the stationary circular-flow model. His idea was to present the dynamic process of economic change “in a cinema-like manner,”Footnote 62 that is, as a series of “shots” of the changing economy. In Bilimovich’s presentation, the initial shock in a particular year is assumed to come from increased investments by producers, which disrupts the stationary equilibrium and causes the changes of macroeconomic flows in the following years. An important element of the analysis, which Bilimovich introduced into his “dynamic schemes of economic process,” was the entrepreneurial reactions (Unternehmerreaktionen). According to these, growth of investment in particular year depends on the ratio between achieved and expected profits in the previous year.Footnote 63 Due to the volatility of profits and profit expectations the growth path of the economy follows a cyclical pattern.

In the United States Bilimovich returned to the modelling of economic circular flow. In the early 1950s he extended the concept of entrepreneurial reactions, which can be optimistic, pessimistic, or neutral, causing the fluctuations of the economy to be accordingly more or less explicit (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1951). Assuming an initial rise in investments in the production of capital goods and a sequence of optimistic and pessimistic entrepreneurial reactions, Bilimovich made a simulation of the dynamic circular flow covering a period of 24 years (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1953). The simulation showed that after a sharp oscillation in the first five years, the economy levels off into a regular cyclical pattern with a 10-year period.Footnote 64 In his last paper on this subject (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1954), Bilimovich emphasized the role of psychological factors (through entrepreneurial behaviour) in business cycles and considered the possibility of state intervention in case of extreme fluctuations.Footnote 65

It is interesting that, with the exception of his innovative presentation of the Tableau, Bilimovich’s schemes of circular flow and his illustration of cyclical fluctuations did not cause any reactions in the academic circles. There were at least three reasons for this. First, in the 1950s economics was already strongly under the influence of Keynesian theory and policy, on the basis of which many economists (wrongly) concluded that business cycles belonged to the past.Footnote 66 Also, Keynesian models that started developing in that period (L. Klein) were useful for economic forecasting, while the usefulness of Bilimovich’s schemes for economic policy was limited. Even Bilimovich himself stated that his dynamic schemes had exclusively “a descriptive and illustrative character.”Footnote 67 The second reason could be found in the developments within mathematical economics and pure theory, to which Bilimovich’s schemes actually belonged (they were part of his economic “nomography”). Here, in the 1950s, the prominent position was taken by the general equilibrium theory, which formed the theoretical core of neoclassical economics. John Hicks, Kenneth Arrow, Gerard Debreu, and other general equilibrium theorists aimed at continuing the original Walrasian tradition. Bilimovich’s schemes, although similar in spirit to general equilibrium models (comparative statics), were thus left on the sidetrack of theoretical developments. And thirdly, after the war Bilimovich’s work was already overshadowed by the achievements of the next generation of Russian emigrant economists, such as W. Leontief and S. Kuznets. Especially Leontief’s input-output analysis was a great success, particularly because of its practical implications for economic planning. It is not insignificant that, like Bilimovich’s schemes of circular flow, Leontief’s intersectoral analysis was initially inspired by Quesnay’s Tableau.Footnote 68

IV. CONCLUSION

Aleksander Bilimovich is considered to have been one of the last representatives of the Kiev School of economics, which reached its peak at the end of the nineteenth century and then disappeared in the wave of the 1917 Revolution. Bilimovich, who continued his work in exile, developed his theoretical and methodological views along two lines of the Kiev tradition. On the one side he maintained the historical approach, which he applied especially in his analysis of agricultural development and business cycles. On the other hand, he showed increasing inclination towards a deductivist and mathematical approach, particularly in his econometric modelling of circular flow. In our view, this juxtaposition of two methodological approaches in Bilimovich’s work can be understood as a legacy of his formative years in the Kiev circle of economists, influenced by the German Historical School as well as by the early Austrian marginalism and emerging neoclassical economics. Also, Bilimovich remained a strong opponent of socialist views and Marxism; such opposition was another typical feature of the Kiev economists.

An implication that follows from the paper is that the received view among historians of Russian economic thought about Bilimovich as having been a typical marginalist, who only in his last years put more stress on some social aspects of economics, is one-sided. It is based mostly on his German papers on value, published in Austrian economic journals in the interwar period. That view neglects a number of Bilimovich’s works written in English, Slovenian, and Serbo-Croat languages, including his Slovenian economic textbook (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933a), from which one can see that he retained several methodological features of the German Historical School.

The ambivalent position of the Kiev School towards historicism and neoclassicism was normal in the decades around the end of the nineteenth century when the Kuhnian paradigmatic shift was taking place in economics. We should not forget that in this period even Alfred Marshall exhibited in his work two completely different approaches: marginalist-neoclassical in his Principles and historical with institutional features in Industry and Trade.Footnote 69 Bilimovich was aware of the positive aspects of both of these two approaches. In his work he therefore maintained both neoclassical and historical analysis, thus extending the legacy of the Kiev School far into the twentieth century.

Footnotes

1 See Anikin (Reference Anikin2002, p. 150).

2 Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 168). For the opposite view see Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, pp. 300–305).

3 A. I. Tschuprov, cited in Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, p. 274). Methodologically, Tschuprov was looking for a compromise between classical economics (he was particularly fond of J. S. Mill), Marxism, and German Historical School. This eclectic combination was absorbed into the ideology of the narodniki-economists at the Moscow University (Zweynert Reference Zweynert2002, pp. 268–269).

4 That the Kiev School of economists has to be distinguished from the Moscow School was argued also by Bilimovich in his memorial paper to D. I. Pichno (whom he considered as a typical representative of the Kiev School). For Bilimovich the theory of the Moscow School was Marxian while in economic policy the school followed the proposals of the narodniki (see Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1915, p. xi). Also, in an unpublished (and later probably lost) manuscript titled “The Kiev School of Russian National Economists,” written (in Russian) in Ljubljana in 1925, whose content is reported by Seraphim (Reference Seraphim1925, pp. 38–47), Bilimovich considers the rejection of the labor theory of value and strong opposition to all forms of socialism to be the most distinctive features of the Kiev economists as compared with the Moscow School. Besides, he emphasizes the distinctive view of the Kiev economists, taken from the German historicists, that negative social consequences of capitalism can be overcome by active social policies of the state. Here we can add that the last point was not so distinctive if we consider Tschuprov’s enthusiasm about Schmoller’s views on social policy (cf. Zweynert Reference Zweynert2002, p. 277).

5 Sheptun (Reference Sheptun2005, p. 352).

6 On this issue see also Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2004).

7 Sheptun (Reference Sheptun2005, p. 354).

8 Among the Kiev economists the exceptions were I. Vernadsky, who was “a staunch admirer of the laissez-faire” (Koropeckyj Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 187), and M. Ziber, who was a Marxist.

9 Especially N. Bunge and D. Pichno.

10 See Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, pp. 304–305) and Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 176).

11 Contrary to orthodox Marxists of the time, such as V. Lenin and G. Plechanov, Struve and Tugan-Baranovsky together with S. N. Bulgakov (1871–1944) formed the so called “legal” Marxists, who attempted, in various ways, to revise the methodological and theoretical foundations of Marx’s theory. Struve criticized Marx’s views on class struggle and social revolution. Tugan-Baranovsky, who was a Ukrainian (born near Kharkov), worked in St. Petersburg and achieved international appraisal for his book on industrial crises in England (see also Koropeckyj Reference Koropeckyj1991 and Screpanti and Zamagni Reference Screpanti and Zamagni2005, pp. 239–240). The work of Tugan-Baranovsky expresses a methodological duality similar to the one that we find later in the work of Bilimovich. While he believed that the dominant method in economics should be deduction, in his works on crises in England and on the Russian factory he “attemped to combine an analysis of historical evolution with an account of economic structures, the formation of economic policy, and a concern for social consequences, and both were illustrated with statistical data” (Barnett Reference Barnett2004, pp. 88–89). Barnett (ibid.) considers this part of Tugan-Baranovsky’s work to use the institutional approach, and sees parallels with the approach of the German Historical School and institutionalism in general.

12 Cf. Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 223).

13 Among his works is the outline of the history of economics (Ocherk istorii politicheskoi ekonomii, St. Petersburg, 1858), where he critically analyzed various schools of thought from the point of view of a convinced laissez-faire economist (see Koropeckyj Reference Koropeckyj1990, pp. 184–187).

14 I. Vernadsky, Ocherk teorii potrebnostej (An outline of the theory of needs), St. Petersburg, 1857.

15 In 1869, because of his strong interest in practical policy issues, Bunge even moved to the department of state administration studies, which, similarly to German cameralist tradition (Polizeiwissenschaften), researched the problems related with law, state administration, public finance, and economic policy. His lectures from that period appeared in Policejskoe pravo (2 Vols., Kiev, 1869, 1877) (see Zweynert Reference Zweynert2002, p. 284).

16 Osnovanija političeskoj ekonomii.

17 Cf. Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, p. 192).

18 As a minister he introduced various reforms aimed at shifting the tax burden from the poorer to the richer groups of the society, and pioneered factory legislation (see Koropeckyj Reference Koropeckyj1990, pp. 190–191).

19 D. Pichno, Osnovanija političeskoj ekonomii, Vol. 1, cited in Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, pp. 297). Volume 1 of Pichno’s Osnovanija (Principles) was published in Kiev in 1890. Volume 2 did not appear.

20 The issue of value was a dominant subject in his above-mentioned textbook as well as in his monograph Zakon sprosa i predloženija. K teorii cennosti (The law of supply and demand. Towards a theory of value), published in Kiev in 1886.

21 According to Sheptun (Reference Sheptun2005), Russian economic theory of the nineteenth and early twentieth century, including the pro-western oriented Kiev School, never really abandoned the influential methodological tradition of the German Historical School. Indeed, some Russian authors did criticize the “descriptive” approach of the German Historical School and its lack of “solid theoretical generalizations,” thus pointing to the validity of Menger’s arguments in the Methodenstreit (see Sheptun Reference Sheptun2005, p. 359). But Sheptun also convincingly argues that, on the whole, “(t)he Historical School’s ideas conformed to Russian spiritual and intellectual traditions of the primacy of the social, ‘the communal,’ instead of ‘the individual’ and selfish, as the constituent element of economic life” (p. 360) and that it was therefore “natural for Russian economists to view political economy as a social science aimed at studying national economy as an integral whole in its historical development” (p. 356). Subjectivism and methodological individualism of the emerging marginalist schools, although taken positively by some authors in their researches on value, were in Russia never accepted on a larger scale.

22 Zweynert (Reference Zweynert2002, p. 297).

23 It is interesting that Konstantin Hattenberger (1844–1893), an Ukrainian economist of Kharkov University, already in the early 1880s compared the methodology of the German Historical School with the methodology of the Austrian School, and argued for the need of their mutual coexistence and complementarity in economics (see Sheptun (Reference Sheptun2005, pp. 359–360) referring to the work of N. Balabkins and I. Koropeckyj). Tugan-Baranovsky was another Ukrainian economist who was searching for complementarity (particularly in the theory of value) between classical and neoclassical views.

24 At that time the Kiev circle was represented by economists such as D. Pichno, A. Antonovich, N. Cytovich, M. Iasnopolsky, V. Zheleznov, and others. Zheleznov doesn’t fit completely into this group because of his interest in labor theory of value and Marxism. Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990) reports that while other Kiev economics professors “generally preferred to omit Marxian theory from class lectures, Zheleznov discussed it, albeit critically” (p. 177).

25 Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj1990, pp. 168, 177) or Koropeckyj (Reference Koropeckyj and Koropeckyj1984, pp. 168, 180). Such interpretation of his work is probably due to the fact that Bilimovich’s papers with a marginalist approach appeared mostly in Austrian and German economic journals and in the German language, and are therefore easier accessible than his papers in Slovenian and Serbo-Croat periodicals, in which his approach was mainly historical.

26 His opponent was P. Struve, a versatile economist and together with Tugan-Baranovsky one of the first social democratic Marxists in Russia.

27 In 1920 still officially named the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenians.

28 His younger brother Anton (b. 1879), a mathematician, who followed him into emigration, became professor of mathematics at the University of Belgrade. He died in Belgrade in 1970.

29 A forerunner of today’s Journal of Economics. Rothschild (Reference Rothschild and Barens2004) provides a comprehensive evaluation of the editorial policy of the journal in the 1930s, when Bilimovich was a regular contributor with articles and book reviews. Among the latter see, for example, his favorable review of Keynes’s Treatise on Money (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933c).

30 For a detailed list of Bilimovich’s published works after 1920 see references in Sušjan (Reference Sušjan2005). For some additional documents related with his work and life see also Sušjan (Reference Sušjan2004).

31 See Econometrica (1934, Vol. 4). Bilimovich lectured at the annual meeting of the Econometric society in Stresa in 1934. See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1937b, p. 297n).

32 The UNRRA University in Munich was established at the end of the war (by the United Nations Rehabilitation and Relief Administration) with the purpose of providing higher education for a number of displaced persons from Eastern Europe. See more in Zittel (Reference Zittel1979).

33 E. Korickij, D. Šetov (web).

34 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1955, Reference Bilimovič1956, Reference Bilimovič1959, Reference Bilimovič1960). For his critique of Marxism see Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1954). Bilimovich’s position in these works is often emotional, which is understandable, if we know that communist revolutions deeply affected his private life and professional career. Cf. Boettcher (Reference Boettcher1957). From the philosophical standpoint Bilimovich based his critique of Marx on the work of Nikolai O. Lossky (1870–1965), a Russian philosopher and student of Windelband, who lived in exile since 1922 (see Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1954, pp. 20 ff.). Lossky was an intuitivist and particularly critical of dialectical materialism as the philosophical foundation of Marxism as well as of the Soviet regime (see Lossky Reference Lossky1951, pp. 345–377).

35 Tovarnoe dviženie na russkih željeznih dorogah, Kiev, 1902; Položenije služaščih na gosudarstvenih željeznih dorogah Germanii i Rosii, Kiev, 1906.

36 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1907, e.g. pp. 7, 9, 21, 41). Significant is also the motto of the book (taken from a German author and printed on the title page) obviously expressing Bilimovich’s belief that the clear institutional arrangement of ownership was a crucial precondition for further development of Russian agricultural production: “Was helfen die Förderungsmittel für landwirtschaftliche Production (sic!), wenn es am Segen eines geordneten Besitzes fehlt” (Stimulating agricultural production is futile if there is no order in ownership).

37 Germanskoe zemleustroiteljnoe zakonodateljstvo, Kiev, 1908 (cf. Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 63).

38 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, pp. 44–88).

39 Most of these articles appeared in the Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie.

40 See for example Spiegel (1991, p. 628).

41 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 23).

42 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 20n).

43 E.g. Sombart (Reference Sombart1929, p. 6).

44 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, pp. 125–136).

45 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 126).

46 The original term, introduced by Windelband, was nomothetics. But due to the etymology of the term (in Greek: setting laws) Bilimovich considered it to be too normative in character and thus inappropriate for economic ontology, which is positivist and explicative in nature. He therefore decided to use Tschuprov’s term nomography, which Bilimovich found more adequate, since the subject of this part of economic ontology “is not setting laws, but searching for economic laws . . . and describing them” (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 130n).

47 Cf. Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 123n). It should be noted at this point, that Bilimovich also disagreed with the view (originally proposed by R. Stammler) that the main difference between natural and cultural sciences lies in the fact that the former belong to causal sciences, analysing the “cause-consequence” relationships, while the latter (including economics) belong to teleological sciences, dealing only with the “aim-means” relations. This view was further developed by K. Engliš in his book Begründung der Teleologie als Form des empirischen Erkenns (published in Brno in 1930). Bilimovich’s critical review of this book (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1932) sparked a polemic exchange between the two (Englis Reference Englis1933, Bilimovič 1933d), in which Bilimovich argued that in spite of teleological character of economic activities of people it is wrong to claim that economics is not a causal science. According to him, human economic behavior is guided by psychological reasons, which can be the subject of positivist analysis. The practical part of economics (economic deontology), which analyzes policy measures needed to attain targets set by policy makers, is, of course, different in character.

48 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1921, pp. 16–17) and Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1933a, p. 129).

49 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1921, p. 20).

50 See e.g. Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1924b, p. 6).

51 While criticizing the central planning system, Bilimovich supported the view that some degree of state regulation was necessary if the market economy is to function efficiently: “Optimal ist also eine Kompromiβform, eine gemischte, dualistische Form, . . . eine Verbindung individueller Freiheit mit sozialer Regulierung” (The optimum form is a compromise, a mixed, dualistic form, . . . a combination of individual freedom and social regulation) (Bilimovič 1938, p. 166).

52 E.g. Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1937a, p. 222).

53 A revised version of this study was published in Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1939c).

54 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1939b, pp. 32–33). Bilimovich also concluded that contrary to the manufacturing sectors, which were experiencing the process of concentration, in the agricultural sectors of the European economies there was a gradual tendency of deconcentration exhibiting itself in the reduction of the share of extremely large farms and in the increasing number of farms of medium size (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1944a). Later he came to a different conclusion in his analysis of the concentration of agriculture in the United States (Bilimovich Reference Bilimovich1959). He found out that in the period 1900–1954 the concentration of farm land had been significantly increased in all parts of the United States. The process was obviously related with technical improvements in farm production, increasing mechanization, etc.

55 As a versatile statistician Bilimovich liked their idea of the need for a statistical analysis of the “symptomatics” of business cycles (see Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1931a, p. 13)—rather than dealing with “causal” theories of crises, which was the domain of older theoreticians.

56 The paper was also published in Russian (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1929e).

57 He strongly supported the pioneering work in this area carried out by the brilliant Slovenian mathematician Ivo Lah (1896–1979), who used the statistics of social insurance of workers as the basis for evaluating macroeconomic trends (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1930a).

58 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1928, p. 3); cf. Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1931a, pp. 14–15).

59 The Tableau is analyzed in the first part of his 1942 study on the economic circular flow (Bilimovič Reference Bilimovič1942, pp. 200–206). In Slovenian the table is analyzed in Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1941).

60 For Bilimovich’s graphical presentation of the Tableau see Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1941, p. 16) and Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1942, p. 205). Bilimovich was probably inspired by the schemes of Denis (Reference Denis1897), which, however, contained no quantities. Cf. Rieter (1983, pp. 66–67).

61 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1942, pp. 219 ff).

62 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1943, p. 12).

63 Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1944b, pp. 74–76).

64 See Bilimovich (Reference Bilimovich1953, pp. 22–23).

65 See Bilimovich (Reference Bilimovich1954, p. 306).

66 Cf. Backhouse (Reference Backhouse2002, p. 236).

67 See Bilimovič (Reference Bilimovič1943, p. 12).

68 For Bilimovich’s (positive) opinion about Leontief’s work see Bilimovich (Reference Bilimovich1958, p. 207).

69 Marshall’s positive views on historicism are presented in Hodgson (Reference Hodgson2005).

References

REFERENCES

Anikin, A. 2002. “Russian Economic Science: Enlightenment and First Schools.” Problems of Economic Transition 44 (9/10): 148154.Google Scholar
Antsiferov, Alexis N., Bilimovich, Alexander D., Batshev, Michael O., and Ivantsov, Dimitry N. 1930. “Rural Economy.” In Russian Agriculture during the War. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 1300.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2002. The Penguin History of Economics. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Barnett, Vincent. 2004. “Tugan-Baranovsky, the Methodology of Political Economy, and the ‘Russian Historical School’.” History of Political Economy 36 (1): 79101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander. 1930. “The Land Settlement.” In Russian Agriculture during the War. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 301388.Google Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1951. “Investment and Employer’s Reactions.” Economia Internazionale 4 (4): 847866.Google Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1953. “A Model of the Undulatory Economic Process.” Economia Internazionale 6 (3): 131.Google Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1954. “Einige Schemata der fortschreitenden Wirtschaft.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 14 (2–4): 273306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1955. “Agriculture and Food in Yugoslavia before, during, and after World War II.” In Zagoroff, S. D., Végh, Jenö, and Bilimovich, Alexander D., The Agricultural Economy of the Danubian Countries 1935–45. A Publication of the Food Research Institute, Stanford University, pp. 289366.Google Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1958. “Kommentare zu einem neuen kreislauftheoretischen Buch.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 18 (1–2): 201207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovich, Alexander D. 1959. “Concentration of Agriculture in the United States (Trends and Consequences).” Economia Internazionale 12 (3): 495527.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1907. Zemleustroiteljnyja zadači i zemleustroiteljnoje zakonodateljstvo Rossii. Kiev: Tipografija Imperatorskago Univerziteta sv. Vladimira.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, A. D. 1915. “Pamjati D.I. Pihno.” In Trudy Kievskago juridičeskago obščestva sostojaščago pri Imperatorskom Univeritetu Sv. Vladimira (Za 1911, 1912, 1913 i 1914 gody). Kiev: Tipografija Imperatorskago Univerziteta Sv. Vladimira, pp. ixiv.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1921. “Nekoliko misli o narodno-gospodarski vedi [Some thoughts about economic science].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav I. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 121.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1924a. “Pojem ‘statike’ in ‘dinamike’ v narodno-gospodarski vedi [‘Statics’ and ‘dynamics’ in economics].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav III. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 151161.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1924b. “Družba, država in gospodarstvo [Society, state and economy].” Slovenski pravnik 38 (5–6): 136147.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1926. “Položaj delavcev v Jugoslaviji po poročilih inspekcije dela [The position of workers in Yugoslavia according to the reports of work inspectors].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav. V. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 1851.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1927. Jugoslavien (Königreich der Serben, Kroaten u. Slovenen) (Einzelheft aus dem Band II der “Osteuropäischen Länderberichte”). Breslau: Verlag von M. & H. Marcus.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1928. “Nove metode proučevanja konjunktur in gospodarska prognoza [New methods in the analysis of cycles and economic forecasting].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav. VI. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 121. (Cf. Bilimovič 1929e.)Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1929a. “Irving Fishers statistische Methode für die Bemessung des Grenznutzens.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 1 (1): 114128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1929b. “Grenzkosten und Preis.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 1 (3): 368386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1929c. Arbeitsrecht des Königreichs der Serben, Kroaten und Slovenen (Jugoslavien) (Sonderdruck aus Zeitschrift für Ostrecht, III. Jahrgang, Heft 3, 369–388). Berlin: Carl Heymanns Verlag [1929].Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksandr. 1929d. Očerk Narodnago Chozjajstva Korolevstva Serbov, Horvatov i Slovencev [An outline of the national economy of the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenians]. Belgrad: Izdanje Russkago Naučnago Instituta v Belgrade (Offprint from Trudy IV Suezda Russkih Akademičeskih Organizacij za granicej, pp. 363370).Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksandr. 1929e. Novyje metody izučenija konjunktur i ekonomičeskij prognoz [New methods in the analysis of cycles and economic forecasting]. Belgrad: Izdanje Russkago Naučnago Instituta v Belgrade (Offprint from Trudy IV Suezda Russkih Akademičeskih Organizacij za granicej, pp. 371376).Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1930a. “Matematična obdelava statističnih podatkov Okrožnega urada za zavarovanje delavcev v Ljubljani [Mathematical analysis of statistical data of the Bureau for the insurance of workers in Ljubljana].” Slovenski Pravnik 44 (11–12): 282289.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1930b. Die Preislehre von Othmar Spann (Sonderabzug aus Schmollers Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reiche, Jahrgang 54, Heft 4, pp. 57–82). München: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1931a. Nauk o konjunkturah [Business cycles]. In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav VIII (1930–31). Ljubljana: Samozaložba prof. zbora Juridične fakulteta, pp. 1184.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1931b. Die Preis- und Wertlehre (Sonderabdruck aus Die Wirtschaftstheorie der Gegenwart, pp. 94113). Wien: Verlag von Julius Springer.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1931c. “Kritische und positive Bemerkungen zur Geldwerttheorie.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 2 (3, 5): 353375, 695732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, A. 1932. “Karel Engliš. Begründung der Teleologie als Form des empirischen Erkenns.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 3 (2): 296301.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1933a. Uvod v ekonomsko vedo [An introduction to economics]. Ljubljana: Jugoslovanska knjigarna v Ljubljani.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1933b. “Ein neuer Versuch der Bemessung des Grenznutzens.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4 (2): 161187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, A. 1933c. “John Maynard Keynes: A Treatise on Money.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4 (2): 267273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1933d. “Meine Antwort an Herrn Prof. Dr. Karel Engliš.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4 (4): 521526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1934. “Wie können unmessbare psychische Grössen in das Gleichungs-system der wirtschaftlichen Gleichgewichts eingeführt?” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 5 (2): 145184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1935a. “Oblike obrtnih in industrijskih obratov (Odlomek iz gospodarske morfologije) [The forms of craft- and industry-plants (A fragment from economic morphology)].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav XI. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 126.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1935b. “Zum Problem des ‘neutralen’ Geldes.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 6 (1): 5384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1936. Das Kartellrecht Jugoslawiens (Sonderdruck aus Zeitschrift für Osteuropäisches Recht, N.F. 3. Jahrgang, Heft 2, pp. 6780). Berlin: Carl Heymanns Verlag.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1937a. “Zur Verteidigung der Gleichgewichtsidee.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 8 (2): 220228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1937b. “Zins und Unternehmergewinn im Gleichungssystem der stationären Wirtschaft.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 8 (3): 297326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1938. “Einige Bemerkungen zur Theorie der Planwirtschaft.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 9 (2): 147166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1939a. “Agrarna struktura Jugoslavije [The structure of Yugoslavian agriculture].” In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav XV. Ljubljana: Juridična fakulteta, pp. 135.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1939b. Agrarna struktura Jugoslavije in Slovenije v primeri z agrarno strukturo nekaterih drugih dežel [The structure of agriculture in Yugoslavia and Slovenia in comparison to the structure of agriculture in some other countries]. Ljubljana: Socialno ekonomski institut v Ljubljani (Zbirka študij št. 4).Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1939c. “Die vergleichende Untersuchung von Agrarstrukturen.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 50 (3): 493522.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1941. Ekonomska tabela Françoisa Quesnaya [Economic Table of François Quesnay]. Ljubljana: Akademija znanosti in umetnosti v Ljubljani.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1942. “Das allgemeine Schema des wirtschaftlichen Kreislaufes.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 10 (2): 199241. (This article is often (e.g. in Woog 1950) cited under the year 1944, when volume 10 of the journal was republished.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1943. Nekoliko dinamičnih shem gospodarskega procesa [Some dynamic schemes of economic process]. Ljubljana: Akademija znanosti in umetnosti v Ljubljani.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksander. 1944a. “Razvojna tendenca kmetijstva [The developmental tendency of agriculture].”In Zbornik znanstvenih razprav XX. Ljubljana: Pravna fakulteta, pp. 3957.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Alexander. 1944b. “Dynamische Wirtschaft und ihre schematische Darstellung.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 11 (1): 4595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksandr D. 1954. Marksizm (Izloženie i kritika) [Marxism (Exposition and Critique)]. San Francisko (San Francisco): Tipografija Luč (Looch Printing and Publishing Co.).Google Scholar
Bilimovič, A. D. 1955. Kooperacija v Rosii do, vo vreme i posle boljševikov [Cooperative in Russia before, during and after bolsheviks]. Frankfurt am Main: Posev.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksandr D. 1956. Sovetskaja kooperacija posle vtoroj mirovoj vojny [Soviet cooperative after the Second World War]. Issledovanija i materiali (Serija 2, No. 40). München: Institut zur Erforschung der UdSSR.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, Aleksandr D. 1959. Era pjatiletnich planov v chozjajstve SSSR [Five-year plans in the Soviet economy]. Issledovanija i materiali (Serija 2, No. 71). München: Institut zur Erforschung der UdSSR.Google Scholar
Bilimovič, A. D. 1960. Ekonomičeskij stroj osvoboždennoj Rosii [The economic system of Russia]. München: Izdateljstvo Centralnogo Objedinenija Političeskih Emigrantov iz SSSR (COPE) – Verlag ZOPE.Google Scholar
Bilimowitsch, A. 1911. “Zur Frage der Bewertung der wirtschaftlichen Güter.” Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung XX: 623698.Google Scholar
Boettcher, Erik. 1957. “Bilimovich, Alexander D., Marxism. (Exposition and Critique.)Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 78 (1): 70*.Google Scholar
Denis, H. 1897. “Die physiokratische Schule und die erste Darstellung der Wirtschafts-gesellschaft als Organismus.” Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung VI: 8999.Google Scholar
Englis, Karel. 1933. “Zum Problem der teleologischen Theorie der Wirtschaft.” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4 (2): 220242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2005. “Alfred Marshall versus the Historical School?” Journal of Economic Studies 32 (4): 331348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holý, Václav L. 1957. Über die Zeitgebundenheit der Kreislauftheorien von Quesnay, Marx und Keynes. Zürich: Polygraphischer Verlag A.G.Google Scholar
Korickij, E. B. 1997. Mir idej A. D. Bilimoviča [The world of ideas of A. D. Bilimovič], 2 Vols. St. Petersburg.Google Scholar
Koropeckyj, I. S. 1984. “Academic Economics in the Nineteenth-Century Ukraine.” In Koropeckyj, I. S., ed., Selected Contributions of Ukrainian Scholars to Economics. Harvard Ukrainian Research Institute. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 163222.Google Scholar
Koropeckyj, I. S. 1990. Development in the Shadow: Studies in Ukrainian Economics. Edmonton: Canadian Institute of Ukrainian Studies Press, University of Alberta.Google Scholar
Koropeckyj, I. S. 1991. “The Contribution of Mykhailo Tuhan-Baranovsky to Monetary Economics.” History of Political Economy 23 (1): 6178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lossky, N. O. 1951. History of Russian Philosophy. New York: International Universities Press.Google Scholar
Rieter, Heinz von. 1983. “Zur Rezeption der physiokratischen Kreislaufanalogie in der Wirtschaftswissenschaft.” In Scherf, Harald, ed., Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie III. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot, pp. 5599.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rothschild, K. W. 2004. “The End of an Era: The Austrian Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie in the Interwar Period.” In Barens, I. et al. , eds., Political Events and Economic Ideas. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 247260.Google Scholar
Screpanti, Ernesto and Zamagni, Stefano. 2005. An Outline of the History of Economic Thought, 2nd edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seraphim, Hans-Jürgen. 1925. “Neuere russische Wert- und Kapitalzinstheorien.” Sozialwissenschaftliche Forschungen (Herausgegeben von der Sozialwissenschaftlichen Arbeitsgemeinschaft), Abteilung I, Heft 4. Berlin und Leipzig: Walter de Gruyter & Co.Google Scholar
Sheptun, Alla. 2005. “The German Historical School and Russian Economic Thought.” Journal of Economic Studies 32 (4): 349374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sombart, Werner. 1929. “Nationalökonomie: Ein Überblick.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 30 (1): 118.Google Scholar
Spiegel, Henry William. 1991. The Growth of Economic Thought, 3rd edition. Durham and London: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Sušjan, Andrej. 2004. “Ljubljansko obdobje v življenju in delu ekonomista Aleksandra Bilimoviča [The Ljubljana period in the life and work of the economist Aleksander Bilimovič].” Kronika 52 (1): 5572.Google Scholar
Sušjan, Andrej. 2005. “Nekatere značilnosti ekonomskega opusa Aleksandra Bilimoviča [Some characteristics of the economic works of Aleksander Bilimovič].” Economic and Business Review for Central and South-Eastern Europe 7 (sp. issue): 533.Google Scholar
Woog, Henri. 1950. The Tableau Economique of François Quesnay: An Essay in the Explanation of its Mechanism and a Critical Review of the Interpretations of Marx, Bilimovic and Oncken. Bern: A. Francke A. G. Verlag.Google Scholar
Zittel, Bernhard. 1979. “Die UNRRA-Universität in München 1945–1947.” Archivalische Zeitschrift (Böhlau Verlag, Köln, Wien) 75. Band: 281301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim. 2002. Eine Geschichte des ökonomischen Denkens in Ruβland 1805–1905. Marburg: Metropolis Verlag.Google Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim. 2004. “The Theory of Internal Goods in the Nineteenth-century Russian Classical Economic Thought.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 11 (4): 525554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar