Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dkgms Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-14T07:21:23.322Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE PHILLIPS CURVE AND AN ASSUMED UNIQUE MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM IN HISTORICAL CONTEXT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 November 2016

Richard G. Lipsey*
Affiliation:
Emeritus Professor of Economics, Simon Fraser University, rlipsey@sfu.ca.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

An early post-WWII debate concerned the most desirable demand and inflationary pressures at which to run the economy. Context was provided by Keynesian theory devoid of a full employment equilibrium and containing its mainly forgotten, but still relevant, microeconomic underpinnings. A major input came with the estimates provided by the original Phillips curve. The debate seemed to be rendered obsolete by the curve’s expectations-augmented version with its natural rate of unemployment, and associated unique equilibrium GDP, as the only values consistent with stable inflation. The current behavior of economies with the successful inflation targeting is inconsistent with this natural-rate view, but is consistent with evolutionary theory in which economies have a wide range of GDP-compatible stable inflation. Now the early post-WWII debates are seen not to be as misguided as they appeared to be when economists came to accept the assumptions implicit in the expectations-augmented Phillips curve.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2016 

I. INTRODUCTION

One important early post-WWII debate, which took place particularly in the UK, concerned the demand and inflationary pressures at which it was best to run the economy. The context for this debate was provided by early Keynesian theory with its absence of a unique full-employment equilibrium and its mainly forgotten, but still relevant, microeconomic underpinnings. The original Phillips curve was highly relevant to this debate. All this changed, however, with the introduction of the expectations-augmented version of the curve with its natural rate of unemployment, and associated unique equilibrium GDP, as the only values consistent with a stable inflation rate. This new view of the economy found easy acceptance partly because most economists seem to feel deeply in their guts—and their training predisposes them to do so—that the economy must have a unique equilibrium to which market forces inevitably propel it, even if the approach is sometimes, as some believe, painfully slow.

The current behavior of economies with successful inflation targeting is inconsistent with the existence of a unique non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) but is consistent with evolutionary theory in which the economy is constantly evolving in the face of path-dependent, endogenously generated, technological change, and has a wide range of unemployment and GDP over which the inflation rate is stable. This view explains what otherwise seems mysterious in the recent experience of many economies and makes the early post-WWII debates not seem as silly as they appeared to be when economists came to accept the assumption of a perfectly inelastic, long-run Phillips curve located at the unique equilibrium level of unemployment. One thing that stands in the way of accepting this view, however, is the tyranny of the generally accepted assumption of a unique, self-sustaining, macroeconomic equilibrium.

This paper covers some of the key events in the theory concerning, and the experience of, the economy’s behavior with respect to inflation and unemployment over the post-WWII period. The stage is set by the pressure-of-demand debate in the 1950s and the place that the simple Phillips curve came to play in it. The action begins with the introduction of the expectations-augmented Phillips curve and the acceptance by most Keynesians of its implication of a unique, self-sustaining macro equilibrium. This view seemed not inconsistent with the facts of inflation and unemployment until the mid-1990s, when the successful adoption of inflation targeting made it inconsistent with the facts. An alternative view is proposed, one that is capable of explaining current macro behavior and that reinstates the relevance of the early pressure-of-demand debate.

II. THE 1950s

During the 1950s, British economists engaged in debates over both theory and policy that were significantly different from those that occurred in period between the two world wars.

Keynes Triumphant

By the mid-1950s, Keynesian economics had been fairly well established in the profession. Critically, it contained no full-employment equilibrium. Instead, aggregate-desired expenditure could equal aggregate production at any level of GDP and employment. In modern terms, there were no natural rates of GDP, Y*, and unemployment, U*.

During the 1950s, extensive micro underpinnings had been provided for Keynesian macroeconomic theory. In particular, firms’ horizontal short-run marginal cost (SRMC) curves plus full-cost pricing explained why firms reacted to variations in demand mainly by altering output rather than prices in the short run. Numerous empirical studies had supported these two key observations. Footnote 1

Although there was strong evidence that the SRMC curve of the typical manufacturing firm was horizontal, there was confusion about how to interpret this observation. Footnote 2 The correct interpretation lies in the nature of the firm’s fixed factor. The standard textbook talks of spreading more or less of the variable factor, usually taken to be labor and materials, over a given quantity of a fixed factor, usually taken to be capital equipment in the case of manufacturing, or land in the case of agriculture. It then appeals to the law of diminishing returns to explain a U-shaped SRMC curve. But this applies only if the fixed factor is subject to a strong equality: K=K* (where K* is the fixed amount of capital available in the short run and K is the amount actually employed). In most situations, however, the fixed factor is subject to an inequality constraint: one can use less but not more than the fixed amount available in the short run, K < K*. By leaving some of its capital unemployed (e.g., by working shorter hours or closing one or more of a series of parallel production facilities), the ratio of capital to labor (and all other variable inputs) can be held constant, allowing the firm to produce at a constant marginal cost for any output up to full capacity.

Also, a substantial amount of direct questioning showed that firms claimed to follow a full-cost pricing rule: calculating full cost, adding a markup, then selling whatever was demanded at that price. Footnote 3 This seemed implausible to those who believed in a positively sloped SRMC curve, but it was eminently plausible given a horizontal SRMC curve. All that was then required was, first, that the markup at normal capacity was at or near the profit-maximizing markup and, second, either that the elasticity of demand did not change significantly as demand varied cyclically or that the benefit gained from constantly changing price by small amounts as the profit-maximizing markup changed cyclically was less than the cost.

So these two empirically supported and theoretically defensible propositions provided strong support for the prediction that cyclical variations in demand would be met by variations in output with prices more or less constant.

An excellent illustration of the cost of not educating students in the history of our subject is the almost total loss of any knowledge of the full-cost pricing controversy and of the empirical evidence for horizontal SRMC curves among modern economics students (but not all business school students). Footnote 4 Today, the assumption of a positively sloped SRMC curve over all relevant ranges of output is ubiquitous and is a key assumption in the proofs of many propositions that would not be true if SRMC curves were horizontal up to capacity. Footnote 5

The Pressure-of-Demand Debate Footnote 6

At that time, most economists accepted that, ceteris paribus, inflation was undesirable and that if it could be manipulated independently of other economic variables, zero inflation would be the obvious goal. But such independence of the inflation rate from other real economic variables was not generally accepted at the time. Instead, the debate concerned how much inflation should be tolerated as a price of achieving two other social goals: low unemployment and high growth. It was taken for granted that the economy could be operated with varying pressures of aggregate demand, unemployment, and inflationary pressure—higher unemployment being associated with lower inflationary pressures.

With respect to unemployment, some argued that inflation had to be kept under control even if that required a moderately high rate of unemployment. In contrast, most Keynesians argued that a mild rate of inflation was an acceptable price to pay for maintaining full employment.

But what about stimulating economic growth, an issue that had been a major concern of the British government in the immediate postwar period? Although there was lack of agreement about how to determine the UK’s optimal rate of growth, there was little doubt among UK policymakers in the late 1950s and early 1960s that the current growth rate was too low. Keynesians argued that running the economy with high aggregate demand pressure would provide the profits needed to finance investment, and the demand needed to induce firms to raise productivity—albeit at the cost of some mild inflationary pressure. In contrast to this ‘carrot theory’ of growth, others, of whom professor Frank W. Paish of the London School of Economics was a key advocate, argued that running the economy with low aggregate demand pressure would provide the stick that would encourage economic growth by making it imperative for businesses to raise productivity as the main method that would then be available for sustaining profits (Paish Reference Paish1958, Reference Paish1962, Reference Paish1970).

In the late 1950s, the Phillips curve was injected into this debate. To those Keynesians who accepted Alban William Phillips’s analysis, his curve seemed to apply mainly to the range of excess aggregate demand, while, in the range of deficient aggregate demand, its relative flatness seemed to provide evidence of a downward stickiness of prices that would prevent price reductions from ending periods of unemployment over any acceptable time period. With respect to inflation and unemployment, the Phillips curve seemed to show that the rate of unemployment consistent with a stable price level was about 2.5%. Footnote 7 Although no continuous trade-off was implied, this empirical estimate came into the debate like a thunderbolt. The relatively low figure seemed to support those who would accept some higher-than-necessary unemployment as a cost of restraining inflation and encouraging growth.

III. THE 1960s Footnote 8

Sometime in the 1960s, many economists came to see the Phillips curve as providing a stable trade-off between inflation and unemployment. When Richard G. Lipsey did adopt this trade-off version, as for example in Lipsey (Reference Lipsey and Ross1965), inflationary points on the Phillips curve represented disequilibrium points that had to be maintained by monetary policy that perpetuated the disequilibrium by suitable increases in the rate of monetary expansion. In the new Classical interpretation that began with Edmund S. Phelps (Reference Phelps1967), Milton Friedman (Reference Friedman1968), and Robert E. Lucas Jr. and Leonard A. Rapping (Reference Lucas and Rapping1969), each point was an equilibrium point because demands and supplies of agents were shifted from their full-information locations when they misinterpreted the price signals. Footnote 9 There was, however, only one full-information equilibrium of GDP, Y*, and unemployment, U*.

In this new version, recorded unemployment was actually voluntary-arising because workers sometimes expected higher rates of inflation than actually occurred. This induced them to reject some available jobs because they thought the real wage would be lower than it turned out to be. Footnote 10 Booms in which GDP exceeded its potential level and employment was unusually high were also possible if an unexpected inflation led firms and workers to misinterpret a general rise in prices as a rise in their relative price or wage, and produce and work more. Footnote 11 If the inflation continued, firms and workers would eventually come to expect it and revert to their full-information behavior. If the central bank wished to perpetuate the boom, it would have to generate a higher rate of inflation unexpectedly, but one which agents would sooner or later come to expect, and so on with the inflation rate ever accelerating.

This led to the expectations-augmented Phillips curve and its vertical, long-run shape. Now, any level of real GDP other than Y* would cause the price level to change at a rate shown by the short-run Phillips curve, and, if the money supply was not expanded in compensation, the economy would return to its natural rates of U* and Y*.

Such is the ingrained feeling among most economists that the economy must have a unique, market-clearing equilibrium, to which it returns after any deviation, that there was no significant protest at the abandonment of the Keynesian position that the economy could persist for long periods, if not forever, at positions other than U* and Y*.

IV. SUSTAINED INFLATIONS ESTABLISHED AND ENDED: 1970–1990

The early 1970s saw a new phenomenon brought on by the OPEC-induced dramatic rise in the price of oil (and hence also the prices of its many by-products): stagflation. Footnote 12 Partly in response to the confusion caused by this period of rising unemployment combined with rising prices, Keynesians combined the IS and LM curves into an aggregate demand (AD) curve and added a short-run aggregate supply (AS) curve. Stagflation was then explained by supply-side shocks that shifted the AS curve upwards, causing prices to rise and GDP to fall along the negatively sloped AD curve. The model was closed by an expectations-augmented Phillips curve that showed the speed with which equilibrium was re-established whenever it was disturbed. Footnote 13

In contrast, many New Classical economists argued that stagflation provided a conclusive refutation of Keynesian economics. Speaking for myself, I was so intent in showing that, contrary to this view, the AD-AS construction provided a simple Keynesian explanation of stagflation that I paid too little attention to the enormous importance of the new assumption introduced into Keynesian models. The addition of an expectations-augmented Phillips curve, negatively sloped in the short run but vertical in the long run, introduced a unique macroeconomic equilibrium at Y* and U* that would be reached sooner or later, whatever macroeconomic policy was adopted.

The decade of the 1980s was a period of rapid inflations in most developed countries, but ones that seemed more normal in the sense of appearing to respond more to demand than to cost pressures. Unorthodox theories of inflation gradually fell into disrepute, and it came to be accepted that only aggressive action by central banks could curtail inflation. Footnote 14 Slowly during the 1980s, many central banks came to this view. By altering short-term interest rates, they had a direct effect on interest-sensitive expenditures and, more importantly, an indirect effect on the rate of monetary expansion.

During the late 1980s and early 1990s, many countries drove inflation down from high to relatively low levels. This did not happen, however, without serious controversy, with many economists arguing that the high temporary unemployment rates that accompanied this policy were not an acceptable price to pay for lowering the inflation rate. For a coverage of the many conflicting contemporary views on this policy, see Lipsey (Reference Lipsey, Backhouse and Salanti2000).

Once low inflation rates had been established in the early 1990s, one by one, these countries adapted regimes of inflation targeting that began an era of sustained, low, and relatively stable inflation rates. The early target rates and bands varied somewhat, but most central banks eventually settled on a target of 2% and a permissible band of one percentage point on either side of the target. By 2014, twenty-nine central banks had officially adopted inflation targets (Steve Ambler Reference Ambler2014).

V. SUCCESSFUL INFLATION RATE TARGETING

Figures 1 to 3 provide scatters of unemployment against the inflation rate as measured by the index that the relevant central bank is targeting—the CPI for Canada and the UK, and the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index for the Federal Reserve System. The charts show some interesting common behavior, with the high inflation rates of the 1980s continuing into the early 1990s but then being followed by two decades of much lower average rates. Although the inflation rates have varied since then, none of the countries have shown any clear, systematic tendency for its inflation rate to be negatively related to its unemployment rate—a rate that ranged over the period from 9.6% to 4.0% in the USA, from 10.2% to 4.7% in the UK, and from 11.4% to 6.0% in Canada).

Figure 1. CPI Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, Canada 1990–2014.

OECD (2013). “Main Economic Indicators – complete database,” Main Economic Indicators (database). doi: 10.1781/data-00052-en (accessed 15 October 2015).

Figure 2. PCE Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, USA 1990–2014.

US Bureau of Economic Analysis (2015). Personal Consumption Expenditures: Chain-type Price Index,” FRED (database), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/PCEPI/ (accessed 14 October 2015).

US Bureau of Labor Statistics (2015). “Employment Status of the Civilian Noninstitutional Population, 1944 to date,” Household Data Annual Averages, Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey. http://www.bls.gov/cps/cpsaat01.htm (accessed 14 October 2015).

Figure 3. CPI Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, UK 1990–2014.

OECD (2013). “Main Economic Indicators – complete database,” Main Economic Indicators (database). doi: 10.1781/data-00052-en (accessed 15 October 2015).

UK Office of National Statistics (2015). “People by economic activity by age (seasonally adjusted),” Reference Table A01: Summary of labour market statistics. https://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/lms/labour-market-statistics/october-2015/table-a01.xls (accessed 15 October 2015).

Within those broad similarities, there have been differences. In Canada, the rate has been within the Bank of Canada’s target band of ± 1% on either side of 2%, except when it fell below it in 1998, 2009, and 2013. In the US, the inflation rate was within the target band in every year except for 2008, when it was marginally above the upper bound, and 2009, when it was marginally below the lower bound. In the UK, inflation did not fall below 3% until 1993, one year behind the USA and Canada. Then, from 1993 until 2001, unemployment fell steadily from 8.5% to 5.0% while inflation fell from 2.7% to 1.3%. Inflation and unemployment stayed fairly constant from 2001 to 2004. Then, unemployment rose slightly while inflation rose dramatically from 1.3% to 3.6% in 2008 while unemployment fell slightly until 2008. With unemployment staying within the range 7.6%–8.0%, inflation rose from 2.1% in 2009 to 4.4% in 2011 and then fell back to 2.8% in 2012. Lipsey and Alec Chrystal (Reference Lipsey and Chrystal2015, p. 536) deal in some detail with the UK experience and show, among other things, that when core rather than full CPI inflation is considered, the inflation rate fell only once below the target band (1999) and rose only once above it (2010), the later breach being accounted for by a sharp increase in the UK’s value-added tax.

Simple inspection of these scatters suggests that these data are not consistent with a negative relation between the rate of inflation and unemployment, which is required if there is a unique Y* and U*, deviations from which set up inflationary or deflationary pressures to push the economy towards these values.

In a more detailed investigation of this type of data, Kenneth Carlaw and Lipsey (Reference Carlaw and Lipsey2012) correlate the inflation rate and unemployment for five countries: France, Italy, Spain, the UK, and the US. They also relate the acceleration of these countries’ inflations to their GDP gaps, defined as the difference between their actual unemployment rates and their NAIRUs, estimated using a Kalman filter. They conclude that starting in the early 1990s, the data for these countries are not consistent with either a negative relation between unemployment and the rate of inflation or a unique NAIRU below which inflation accelerates and above which inflation decelerates. Footnote 15

VI. SOME OLD IDEAS REHABILITATED AND NEW ONES ADDED

In the study just referred to, Carlaw and Lipsey distinguish three main types of macroeconomic theories. The first type they term “equilibrium with deviations (EWD) theories.” These are theories in which a full-information, unique equilibrium exists but can be deviated from due to such transitory forces as errors in perception or lagged reactions to random fluctuations in tastes and technology. They can be expressed in terms of the static concept of a general equilibrium to which the economy returns after a transitory disturbance or the textbook unique-equilibrium, balanced-growth path, along which agents wish to do the same thing, period by period, and to which the economy will return if disturbed. This class includes most New Keynesian and earlier New Classical theories. In all EWD theories, the past is repeatable and disturbances leave no trace once their effects have been worked out.

The second class may be termed “equilibrium always (EA) theories.” Theories in this class include some recent versions of New Classical models, which contain neither GDP gaps nor Phillips curves of any form. Instead, since all markets always clear, and all agents are farsighted and rational, all realized levels of GDP are equilibrium levels, representing optimal adjustments to the long-term growth path and the disturbances around it. Theories in these first two classes are all stationary (either in levels or first differences), in which history does not matter.

Theories in the third class my co-authors and I call “evolutionary” to draw a contrast between the unique, self-sustaining equilibrium concepts employed in both the EWD and EA classes and the path-dependent, evolving, historical processes that model the economy as constantly changing. Footnote 16 Because of the path dependency produced by endogenous technological change—new advances build on old advances—a disturbance that affects the immediate path of technological development can have lasting effects in the sense that the economy will never return to the path that it would have taken in the absence of that disturbance: history matters. These changes are continually altering the structure of the economy, causing waves of serially correlated investment expenditure that are a major cause of cycles, as well as driving the long-term growth that continually transforms our economic, social, and political structures. Footnote 17 Because agents operating in the evolutionary context typically make research and development decisions under conditions of genuine uncertainty, there is no objective way to decide in advance which of two alternative actions with respect to invention or innovation is the best one until the results are known. As a result, there is no unique line of behavior that maximizes agents’ expected profits. Footnote 18 Thus, there is no unique equilibrium, either static or dynamic, in the evolutionary world, so no adjustment mechanism is required to maintain it. Instead, the constantly changing economy can exist over a wide range of GDP, employment, and unemployment values, without behaving as it would if its inflation rate were determined by an expectations-augmented Phillips curve or any similar construct centered on unique general equilibrium values of Y and U. Thus, there is no stable, long-run vertical Phillips curve or aggregate supply curve. Although the economy clearly does cycle, there has never been any serious evidence that it cycles around a stable equilibrium GDP, Y*, such that whenever current Y does not equal Y*, pressures will be clearly operating to return the economy to Y*. Footnote 19

Given the evidence in Figures 1 to 3, which was discussed in the previous section, and the more detailed evidence given in the study by Carlaw and Lipsey (Reference Carlaw and Lipsey2012), I suggest that the explanation of the current behavior of inflation, output, and unemployment in modern industrial economies is provided not by any EWD theory but by evolutionary theories. Instead of the Phillips curve, there is a band, as shown in Figure 4. Its midpoint is at the expected rate of inflation. If the central bank has a credible inflation target that it sticks to, the expected rate will be that target rate, shown as πe in the figure. The actual rate will vary around the expected rate, depending on a number of influences, such as changes in productivity, or the price of oil and food, but not systematically on short-term variations in U or Y. At either end of this band, there may be something closer to a conventional Phillips curve, with prices and wages falling in the face of major depressions and rising in the face of a major booms financed by monetary expansion. Also, the whole band will be shifted up or down by anything that changes the expected rate of inflation.

Figure 4. The Band of Non-accelerating Inflation (NAIBU).

All Unemployment Rates Between U l and U u are NAIRUs.

One way of describing this behavior is to say that the Phillips curve has disappeared. Another way is to say that the perfectly elastic Phillips curve raised on Y* and its associated NAIRU, points on which were consistent with various, fully expected rates of inflation, has been rotated through 90o to become a NAIBU, a non-inflationary band of unemployment (and Y) located at the constant expected inflation rate, points on which are consistent with various levels of Y and U. (This is all short-term analysis in which full-capacity GDP can be regarded as roughly constant so that variations in Y mainly represent variations in the GDP gap.)

The change in policy implied by this change in how the economy is viewed is dramatic. In EWD theories, there is only one level of GDP and unemployment Y* and U* that the natural forces of the economy will sustain over the long run. Given fully rational expectations, no other levels of GDP and unemployment can persist. If expectations are less than fully rational, such as being adaptive or based on less than a perfect understanding of how the economy works, other levels of Y and U can be sustained by policy for some time, but will sooner or later be met by either accelerating inflation (if Y > Y* and U < U*) or deflation (if Y < Y* and U > U*). In contrast, evolutionary theories imply that policymakers have a range of Ys and Us on which they can target. Footnote 20 On the one hand, they could try to minimize unemployment consistent with staying within the NAIBU. They would do this by expanding the economy until inflation threatened to accelerate. On the other hand, they could seek to hold the economy near the high unemployment end of the NAIBU range. They could do this by depressing it until the inflation rate showed signs of falling persistently below the NAIBU’s lower band. Since the economy will cycle whatever the authorities do, these policies would have the effect of making the economy cycle within the area marked K (for Keynesian) in the former case and the area marked P (for Pashian) in the latter case.

So we seem to have gone full circle from the early Keynesian view in which there was no unique level of GDP to which the economy was inevitably drawn, through a simple Phillips curve with its implied trade-off, to an expectations-augmented Phillips curve (or any of its more modern equivalents) with its associated unique level of GDP, and finally back to the early Keynesian view in which policymakers had an option as to the average pressure of aggregate demand at which economic activity could be sustained. However, the modern debate about whether to aim for the K or P area is not a debate about inflation versus growth, as it was in the 1950s, but between those who would risk an occasional rise of inflation above the target band as the price of getting unemployment as low as possible and those who would risk letting unemployment fall below that indicated by the lower boundary of the NAIBU as the price of never risking an acceleration of inflation above the target rate.

Perhaps [then] Keynesians were too hasty in following the New Classical economists in accepting the view that follows from static [and all EWD] models that stable rates of wage and price inflation are poised on the razor’s edge of a unique NAIRU and its accompanying Y*. The alternative does not require a long term Phillips curve trade off, nor does it deny the possibility of accelerating inflations of the kind that have bedeviled many third world countries. It merely states that industrialized economies with low expected inflation rates may be less precisely responsive than current theory assumes because they are subject to many lags and inertias, and are operating in an ever-changing and uncertain world of endogenous technological change, which has no unique long term static equilibrium. If so, the economy may not be similar to the smoothly functioning mechanical world of Newtonian mechanics but rather to the imperfectly evolving world of evolutionary biology. The Phillips relation then changes from being a precise curve to being a band within which various combinations of inflation and unemployment are possible but outside of which inflation tends to accelerate or decelerate. Perhaps then the great [pre-Phillips curve] debates of the 1940s and 1950s that assumed that there was a range within which the economy could be run with varying pressures of demand, and varying amounts of unemployment and inflation[ary pressure], were not as silly as they were made to seem when both Keynesian and New Classical economists accepted the assumption of a perfectly inelastic, one-dimensional, long run Phillips curve located at a unique equilibrium Y* and NAIRU. (Lipsey Reference Lipsey, Blaug and Lloyd2011, p. 389)

Footnotes

1 For a fuller discussion of these underpinnings, and relevant references, see Lipsey (Reference Lipsey, Backhouse and Salanti2000, pp. 72–76).

2 For a contemporary review of the evidence on cost curves, see John Johnston (Reference Johnston1960), and for a discussion of its significance in the traditional Keynesian IS-LM-type models, see Lipsey (Reference Lipsey1981, pp. 274–276).

3 Many studies of full cost pricing followed the seminal article by Robert L. Hall and Charles J. Hitch (Reference Hall and Hitch1939).

4 This controversy was rediscovered by Barattieri and Basu (Reference Altomonte, Barattieri and Basu2015), who have produced some interesting evidence for its existence and some theory concerning its importance.

5 For one illustration, see Mankiw’s “proof” (Gregory Mankiw and William Scarth Reference Mankiw and Scarth2001, pp. 554–555) that the Phillips curve and the aggregate supply curve are just two different ways of looking at a single relation, and Lipsey’s argument (2010, pp. 161–162 ) that this is not so if the SRMC curve is horizontal.

6 For an excellent review of this debate, see Schwarzer (Reference Schwarzer2014). However, much of the debate took place in the oral tradition in the 1950s before it occurred in writing and hence became available to Schwarzer.

7 This figure is exceedingly low by current standards of both the experiences and methods of measuring unemployment. But it seemed high to Keynesians in the 1950s when both experience and methods of measurement led to much lower rates of perceived unemployment.

8 For a more detailed study of the Phillips curve debate during this period, see Schwarzer (Reference Schwarzer2012 and Reference Schwarzer2013).

9 At various places in his 1968 presidential address, Friedman takes both a disequilibrium and an equilibrium view, although by the time of Friedman (Reference Friedman1975), he was clearly in the equilibrium camp.

10 This alleged behavior called out for a survey of the unemployed, asking such questions as: Did you have any job opportunities that you turned down or did not pursue? If so, what were they? Do you have any expectation of the behavior of the price level over the near future? If so, what was it? If you were told that the price level was going to fall by 1% over the next few months, would you accept a job with the following specifications … ? What if you were offered a job with the same specifications but were told that the price level was going to rise by 5% … ? The answers to these, and other more carefully defined, questions would very probably have revealed that, almost without exception, the unemployed did not have the expectations or behavioral incentives that were assumed in the theory. Of course, this would not refute the then-prevailing version of New Classical theory, but it would pose a problem to its proponents. It would be up to them to explain how workers could act as if they had the assumed motivation and behavior and yet report totally different motives and behavior. The possible Friedmanesque retort that only predictions, not assumptions, should be tested has been dismissed as bad methodology by many writers. See, for example, Mark Blaug (Reference Blaug1992) and Lipsey (Reference Lipsey, Boumans and Klaes2013).

11 Although relative prices appear in the supply equations of a Walrasian general equilibrium model, the theory of the firm makes it clear that price-taking, profit-maximizing firms need only to know the money prices of their outputs and inputs and not other prices or their average, the general price level.

12 For an excellent contemporary study of this period, see Alan Blinder (Reference Blinder1979).

13 Models of this sort entered the elementary textbooks in the late 1970s and early 1980s. For an early empirical model of a similar sort, see Otto Eckstein (Reference Eckstein1981).

14 Because it is not relevant to the present discussion, I have not surveyed here the other great macroeconomic debate of the 1950s and 1960s: cost-push versus demand-pull theories of inflation.

15 Of course, in some New Classical models, the acceleration of inflation is the cause and not the outcome of a lower rate of unemployment. If the economy is shocked and hence not at the natural rate, there will be no true acceleration of inflation in such models. There might be a temporarily higher or lower rate of inflation, but in the end, the economy will move back to the natural rate and to the rate of inflation given by the money growth rate.

16 Lipsey (Reference Lipsey, Boumans and Klaes2013) provides many examples of the changes that need to be made to many currently accepted propositions when endogenous technological change and uncertainty replace exogenous technological change and risk.

17 In their important book As Time Goes By, Christopher Freeman and Francisco Louçã (Reference Freeman and Louçã2001) trace these processes as they have operated since the beginnings of the First Industrial Revolution.

18 Risk is easily handled in neoclassical economics, while uncertainty is largely ignored, except to pay it lip service. In risky situations, agents with the same objective function and identical knowledge will choose the same alternative: the one that maximizes the expected value of their profits or utility. This gives rise to unique predictable behavior of agents acting under specified conditions. In contrast, in uncertain situations, two identically situated and motivated agents can, and observably do, choose different alternatives, and there is no way to tell in advance of knowing the results which is the better choice.

19 Although Arrow and Debreu proved the existence of a unique equilibrium in a world of universal perfect competition (and with many other restrictive conditions), no one has even tried, let alone succeeded, to prove the existence of an economy-wide equilibrium for the kind of economy that we actually experience, with its plethora of price-setting monopolists, oligopolists, and monopolistic competitors, and its intuitional constraints on many aspects of economic behavior originating from both public policy and private-sector activities.

20 Some might raise the Lucas critique here, arguing that one finds the NAIBU in the data because policymakers are credibly concerned only with inflation. As soon as policymakers made use of the NAIBU, the whole unemployment–inflation relation that has been seen since the mid-1990s might change or break. For example, unions, particularly in the European Union, where they are typically more powerful than in North America, might alter their behavior once they became aware that the central bank was actually targeting employment levels directly and appeared to have the power to do so. If so, the Bank would have to establish that its priorities were lexicographically ordered with control of inflation paramount so that any level-of-activity target would be quickly dropped whenever inflation threatened to go outside of the target bands. For example, instructions to this effect are laid down in the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, Article 127 (1), and also by both the Bank of England and Bank of Canada.

References

REFERENCES

Ambler, Steven. 2014. Price-Level Targeting: A post Mortem? Commentary No 400. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.Google Scholar
Altomonte, Carlo, Barattieri, Alessandro, and Basu, Susanto. 2015. “Average-Cost Pricing: Some Evidence and Implications.” European Economic Review 79: 281296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1992. The Methodology of Economics. Second edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blinder, Alan S. 1979. Economic Policy and the Great Stagflation. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Carlaw, Kenneth I., and Lipsey, Richard G.. 2012. “Does History Matter?: Empirical Analysis of Evolutionary versus Stationary Views of the Economy.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 22 (4): 735766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Otto. 1981. Core Inflation. Englewood: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Freeman, Christopher, and Louçã, Francisco. 2001. As Time Goes By: From the Industrial Revolutions to the Information Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1968. “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review 58: 117.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1975. Unemployment Versus Inflation. London: Institute for Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Hall, Robert L., and Hitch, Charles J.. 1939. “Price Theory and Business Behaviour.” Oxford Economic Papers 2: 1245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, John. 1960. Statistical Cost Analysis. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1965. “Structural and Deficient Demand Unemployment Reconsidered.” In Ross, Arthur M., ed., Employment Policy and the Labor Market. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 210255.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1981. “The Understanding and Control of Inflation and Unemployment: Is There a Crisis in Macro-Economics?” Canadian Journal of Economics 14: 545576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G, ed. 1990. Zero Inflation: The Goal of Price Stability. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute. Policy Study 8.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2000. “IS-LM, Keynesianism and the New Classicism.” In Backhouse, Roger E. and Salanti, Andrea, eds., Macroeconomics and the Real World. Volume 2: Keynesian Economics, Unemployment, and Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 5782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2010. “Evolutionary Economics and the Disappearing NAIRU and Phillips Curve.” In Hanusch, Horst, Kurz, Heinz D., and Seidl, Christian, eds., Schumpeter for Our Century: Homo Oeconomicus Special Issue 27 (1/2): 145176.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2011. “The Phillips Curve.” In Blaug, Mark and Lloyd, Peter, eds., Famous Figures and Diagrams in Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 377392.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2013. “Some Contentious Issues in Theory and Policy in Memory of Mark Blaug.” In Boumans, Marcell and Klaes, Matthias, eds., Mark Blaug: Rebel with Many Causes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 3162.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., Carlaw, Kenneth I., and Bekar, Clifford T.. 2005. Economic Transformations: General Purpose Technologies and Long-Term Economic Growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Chrystal, Alec. 2015. Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Scarth, William. 2011. “The History, Significance and Policy Context of the Phillips Curve.” In Lipsey, Richard G. and Scarth, William, eds., Inflation and Unemployment: The Evolution of the Phillips Curve. Volume 1. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr., and Rapping, Leonard A.. 1969. “Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation.” Journal of Political Economy 77 (5): 721754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Scarth, William. 2001. Macroeconomics. Sixth edition. New York: Worth Publishers.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1958. “Inflation in the United Kingdom, 1948–1957.” Economica 25 (98): 94105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1962. Studies in an Inflationary Economy: The United Kingdom 1948–1961. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1970. How the Economy Works and Other Essays. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. 1967. “Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation and Optimal Unemployment over Time.” Economica NS 34: 254281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2012. “A. W. Phillips and His Curve: Stabilisation Policies, Inflation Expectations and the ‘Menu of Choice.’” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (6): 9761003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2013. “Samuelson and Solow on the Phillips Curve and the ‘Menu of Choice’: A Retrospective.” Œconomia 3 (3): 359388.Google Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2014. “Growth as an objective of economic policy in the early 1960s: the role of aggregate demand.” Cahiers d’économie politique/ Papers in Political Economy 67 (2): 175206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. CPI Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, Canada 1990–2014.OECD (2013). “Main Economic Indicators – complete database,” Main Economic Indicators (database). doi: 10.1781/data-00052-en (accessed 15 October 2015).

Figure 1

Figure 2. PCE Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, USA 1990–2014.US Bureau of Economic Analysis (2015). Personal Consumption Expenditures: Chain-type Price Index,” FRED (database), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/PCEPI/ (accessed 14 October 2015).US Bureau of Labor Statistics (2015). “Employment Status of the Civilian Noninstitutional Population, 1944 to date,” Household Data Annual Averages, Labor Force Statistics from the Current Population Survey. http://www.bls.gov/cps/cpsaat01.htm (accessed 14 October 2015).

Figure 2

Figure 3. CPI Inflation Rate and Percentage of the Labor Force Unemployed, UK 1990–2014.OECD (2013). “Main Economic Indicators – complete database,” Main Economic Indicators (database). doi: 10.1781/data-00052-en (accessed 15 October 2015).UK Office of National Statistics (2015). “People by economic activity by age (seasonally adjusted),” Reference Table A01: Summary of labour market statistics. https://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/lms/labour-market-statistics/october-2015/table-a01.xls (accessed 15 October 2015).

Figure 3

Figure 4. The Band of Non-accelerating Inflation (NAIBU).All Unemployment Rates Between Ul and Uu are NAIRUs.