Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-v2bm5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-05T23:57:31.906Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Decline of British Manufacturing, 1973–2012: The Role of Total Factor Productivity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2020

Richard Harris*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, Durham University Business School
John Moffat*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, Durham University Business School
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper uses plant-level estimates of total factor productivity covering 40 years to examine what role, if any, productivity has played in the decline of output share and employment in British manufacturing. The results show that TFP growth in British manufacturing was negative between 1973 and 1982, marginally positive between 1982 and 1994 and strongly positive between 1994 and 2012. Poor TFP performance therefore does not appear to be the main cause of the decline of UK manufacturing. Productivity growth decompositions show that, in the latter period, the largest contributions to TFP growth come from foreign-owned plants, industries that are heavily involved in trade, and industries with high levels of intangible assets.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2019 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

1. Introduction

Manufacturing in many developed countries has been in continued and steady decline, both in terms of share of GDP and employment, over the past four decades.Footnote 1However, the decline in both measures has been particularly steep in the UK (Reference MoffatMoffat, 2013; Government Office for Science, 2013). Nevertheless, manufacturing still makes a disproportionate contribution to the UK economy: a recent report on manufacturing in the UK (Government Office for Science, 2013) notes its relatively high productivity, its accounting for half of UK exports in 2010 (despite only contributing 10 per cent to gross value added), its greater propensity to undertake R&D and introduce innovations, the strength of its inter-industry linkages and its use of highly-skilled labour. The importance of manufacturing is not new (see Reference KaldorKaldor, 1966; Reference HarrisHarris, 1987), but recognition of it now underpins a commitment by the UK Government to halt its long-run decline (BIS 2010, 2012b).Footnote 2

The aim of this paper is to consider whether the productivity performance of manufacturing has played a role in its long-run (relative) decline. Since productivity (and especially the productivity of both labour and capital inputs into the production process, i.e. total factor productivity, or TFP) is widely recognised as the key driver of long-run economic growth (e.g., Reference KrugmanKrugman, 1997; Reference BaumolBaumol, 1984; Reference O'Mahony and TimmerO'Mahony and Timmer, 2009; Reference Van ReenenVan Reenen, 2013), it is important to understand the progress of TFP in all sectors of the economy. But since part of the decline in manufacturing has historically been linked to its poor productivity performance (e.g., Reference O'MahonyO'Mahony, 1998; Reference O'Mahony and de BoerO'Mahony and de Boer, 2002), such an understanding is of particular relevance here. Therefore, in this paper, we use plant-level data from the Annual Business Survey (ABS), conducted by the UK Office for National Statistics (ONS), to provide a detailed review of the productivity performance of British manufacturing from 1973 to 2012.

The next section describes the relative decline in UK manufacturing compared to other major economies and presents TFP estimates calculated using growth accounting methods applied to industry-level data. Section 3 discusses our preferred approach for estimating TFP for each manufacturing plant in the ABS. In section 4, these estimates are used to decompose productivity growth to show whether productivity growth/decline over 1973–2012 was the result of within-plant increases in productivity or reallocations of output shares across plants. Section 5 attempts to explain trends in TFP in 1994–2012 by showing which groups of plants have contributed most to productivity growth. Groups are defined by ownership, levels of industry outsourcing, ‘openness’ to trade, labour force composition, and intangible assets. The paper concludes with a summary and brief discussion of policy options.

2. Manufacturing performance

De-industrialisation in the UK (i.e., the decline of manufacturing's share of total economy GDP) has occurred faster than in other major economies; figure 1 shows that, in 1970, the sector accounted for the second largest share of GDP among the countries considered, but by 2014 it had experienced the largest relative decline (a 20 percentage points fall). However, figure 2 suggests that this was not due to poor TFP performance (based on the growth accounting approach) since TFP in UK manufacturing saw a steady rise over the 1973–2007 period (with a major setback following the Great Recession). Moreover, UK TFP performance was comparable to that in France and Germany and much better than Italy's, although not as strong as in the USA. By contrast, British TFP growth in non-manufacturing was at best lacklustre.Footnote 3

Figure 1. Manufacturing percentage share of GDP, 1970–2014

Figure 2. Manufacturing TFP index (growth accounting approach), 1973–2009 (1997=100)

The above TFP results based on the growth accounting approach are useful but limited since there are problems both with the methods used to construct TFP and the use of industry-level data (cf. Reference CavesCaves, 1998; Reference Restuccia and RogersonRestuccia and Rogerson, 2008). Some of the methodological issues with the standard growth accounting approach are: the typical use of gross value-added rather than gross output measures of production (see Gandhi et al., 2012, for a discussion of the limitations of the GVA approach);Footnote 4 the imposition of constant returns-to-scale; the assumption of perfect competition in factor and output markets (necessary since output elasticities are equated to factor input cost shares in total revenue); and the treatment of TFP as an unexplained residual.Footnote 5 The use of aggregate data is problematic as, for example, micro-level empirical evidence consistently indicates that plants/firms are heterogeneous with respect to productivity and industry-level data typically over-estimate measures of the capital stock, since the capital of plants that cease production usually remains in the industry-level measure of the stock.Footnote 6 Moreover, the use of aggregate data precludes an analysis of whether reallocations of output shares explain the evolution of aggregate TFP. It is therefore not possible to state whether the above trends are the result of the closure of low TFP plants (i.e. a selection effect), within-plant increases in TFP, or a more efficient allocation of output shares among surviving plants. Such an analysis is provided in the next section.

3. Plant-level estimates of TFP

In this study, we use plant-level panel data for manufacturing covering 1973–2012. The basic approach is described in the earlier analysis of Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat (2015a), that estimates TFP for market-sector plants operating in Great Britain in 1997–2008, although certain variables, such as R&D spending and whether a UK-owned plant belonged to a multinational enterprise, are only available since 1997 and are therefore omitted here. Harris and Moffat (op. cit.) describe in detail the rationale for inclusion of the variables in the model, the data (and especially the use of plants rather than firms as the unit of analysis) and the econometric methodology, and the reader is referred to the earlier article for detailed information. Below, only the core elements of the approach used are set out.Footnote 7

TFP is estimated by plant (i.e., local unit) for each year covering 1973–2012 for manufacturing sectors as defined using the 1980 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC). The first step was estimation of Cobb-Douglas log-linear production functions for each 2-digit industry (with certain industries sub-divided into 3-digit groupings – see the online appendix for details) using a system-GMM approach to address the issues of endogeneity inherent to production function estimation:Footnote 8

(1)yit=αi+αEeit+αMmit+αKkit+αXXit+αTt+εit

where yit, eit, mit and kit refer to the natural logarithms of real gross output, employment, intermediate inputsFootnote 9 and capital stock respectively in plant i in time t (i = 1, …, N; t=1, … T) and Xit is a vector of observed (proxy) variables determining TFP (as set out in table A.1). In order to calculate TFP, equation (1) is estimated providing values of the elasticities of output with respect to factor inputs (αE, αM, and αK). Logged TFP can be calculated as the level of (logged) output that is not attributable to factor inputs – i.e., TFP is due to efficiency levels and technical progress:Footnote 10

(2)lnTFP̂it=yit-αEeit-αMmit-αKkit=αi+αXXit+αTt+εit

However, equation (2) is not a proper TFP index, because the measure of input growth (αEeit+αMmit+αKkit) does not satisfy axiom X5 (proportionality)Footnote 11 in Reference O'DonnellO'Donnell (2016), except in the case of constant returns-to-scale (as discussed below, we generally find non-constant returns-to-scale prevailed when equation 1 is estimated). Proportionality is therefore restored by using a special case of the Färe-Primont (1995) input index:

(2a)lnTFP̂itFP=yit-1αE+αM+αK(αEeit+αMmit+αKkit)

Average estimates for the output elasticities used to predict TFP are provided in table 1 (the actual values are available in the online appendix, tables U.1–U.4, which shows that the estimates for all 25 models estimated are economically sensible – overall returns-to-scale across manufacturing equal 1.15Footnote 12 – and the models pass tests of the validity of the instrumentsFootnote 13 and of autocorrelation). While the parameter estimates associated with Xit in equation (1) are not the major focus of this paper, a brief commentary on the results obtained is warranted. Foreign-owned plants generally have higher TFP in high- and medium high-tech manufacturing but lower TFP in medium low- and low-tech manufacturing. Technical change was highest in high- and medium-low tech manufacturing.

In terms of spatial variables, the results suggest agglomeration (diversification) is associated with lower (higher) TFP, but there is significant variation across the different sub-groups. The results for being located in an assisted area are mostly not significant. In contrast, the effect of being located in a city is positive in all sectors apart from medium high-tech manufacturing, which is consistent with the literature on the effects of urbanisation (see Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2012, for a discussion of this literature and further evidence on city and region effects). No negative regional effects are obtained against the South-East benchmark in high-tech manufacturing whereas, with the exception of the North-West, regional effects are mostly negative in other sectors, suggesting that high-tech plants differ from other plants in that they are not disadvantaged by location in more peripheral regions.Footnote 14

Older plants are uniformly less productive. Single-plant enterprises, and plants belonging to multi-industry enterprises, tend to have lower TFP and those belonging to enterprises operating in more than one region have higher productivity. Table 2 also includes the parameter estimates for three ‘recession’ dummy variables. Generally, TFP experienced a large, negative shock during the 1980–82 recession, a smaller negative effect in 1990–92, but a large positive shock post-2007 (especially in low-tech manufacturing).

Figure 3 plots aggregate labour productivity and TFP obtained using equation (2a) in manufacturing for 1973–2012. Comparison of figures 2 and 3Footnote 15 shows that the growth accounting measure of TFP is less cyclically sensitive (to the early recessions), has sustained growth in TFP between 1981 and 1994, and shows a major dip post-2007. The finding that manufacturing productivity did not experience a large fall in the latter period is consistent with recent evidence from micro-data (Reference Field and FranklinField and Franklin, 2013; Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2016)Footnote 16 showing that falls in the level of aggregate TFP since the Great Recession were mainly driven by services. However, table 3 also confirms that TFP growth in manufacturing stalled between 2008 and 2012 after rapid increases in the preceding period. Manufacturing therefore conforms to the pattern that productivity growth has tended to decline significantly in sectors that experienced rapid growth prior to the financial crisis (Reference Mason, O'Mahony and RileyRiley et al., 2018). Overall, the correlation between the TFP series in figures 2 and 3 is 0.96, indicating that both follow similar time-paths. This again suggests that TFP performance did not play a major role in the relative decline of UK manufacturing.

Figure 3. Manufacturing TFP, labour productivity, real gross output and employment indices, 1973–2012 (1973=1)

Three sub-periods for TFP are suggested by figure 3 covering decline between 1973 and 1982, recovery from 1982 until 1994, and substantial improvement post-1994. In contrast, labour productivity increased throughout the period, reflecting in part the continued substitution of capital and intermediate inputs for labour at a time when manufacturing output was largely unchanged.Footnote 17

4. Productivity growth decompositions

Having obtained an index of TFP at the plant-level, this section considers the sources of productivity growth over the three sub-periods identified in figure 3. Then in Section V we focus on 1994–2012, and consider the contribution of different sub-groups of plants in an attempt to explain the rapid productivity growth in this period. Individual plant-level TFP is aggregated as follows:

(3)lnTFP̂t=ΣiθitlnTFP̂it

θit is the share of (real) gross output for plant i at time t. The growth of aggregate TFP is therefore given by:

(4)Δln̂t=ln̂t-ln̂t-k

Following Reference Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan, Hulten, Dean and HarperFoster et al. (2001), TFP can be decomposed into five components as follows:

(5)ΔlnTFP̂t=iSθit-kΔlnTFP̂it+iSΔθit(lnTFP̂it-k-lnTFP̂t-k)+iSΔθit(ΔlnTFP̂it)+iSθit(lnTFP̂it-lnTFP̂t-k)-iSθit-k(lnTFP̂it-k-lnTFP̂t-k)

The first component shows the contribution from improvements in TFP within plants that survived from t–k to t (denoted by S), the second term shows the contribution from reallocations of output shares between plants that were open in t–k and t and the third term shows the contribution from the coincidence of increases in productivity and increases in output shares in plants open in t–k to t. The final two terms capture the contribution from plants that entered between t–k and t (denoted E) and plants that exited between t–k and t (denoted by X). If the observed growth in TFP is the result of the closure of low productivity plants, this term should be positive.

As discussed by Reference Melitz and PolanecMelitz and Polanec (2015), a weakness of this approach is that the contribution of entrants will be overstated (and the contribution of survivors understated) if there is productivity growth between t–k and t among survivors because the contribution of entrants is calculated relative to the productivity of all plants at t–k. A plant that opens at t (or any time after t–k), that has lower productivity than surviving plants at time t, need only have higher productivity than the weighted average of productivity at time t–k in order to contribute positively to the entrants’ term.

They therefore suggest an alternative decomposition method, based on the static decomposition of Reference Olley and PakesOlley and Pakes (1996), that does not have this feature:

(6)ΔlnTFP̂t=1ntiSΔlnTFP̂it+ΔiS(θit-θ¯t)(lnTFP̂it-1ntiSlnTFP̂it)+iEθit(iEθitElnTFP̂it-iSθitSlnTFP̂it)-iXθit-k(iXθitXlnTFP̂it-k-iSθitSlnTFP̂it-k)

where nt is the number of survivors in manufacturing. The first term is the change in the unweighted mean of plant TFP among surviving plants between t–k and t. The second term is the change in the covariance between output shares and TFP among surviving plants. A positive value of this term therefore indicates reallocations of output shares towards more productive surviving plants. The third term is the difference in weighted TFP between entrants and survivors at time t. This differs from the approach of Reference Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan, Hulten, Dean and HarperFoster et al. (2001) for whom the entrants term is calculated relative to the weighted average of productivity across all plants at t–k. The final ‘exiters’ term is measured relative to the weighted average of survivors’ TFP at t–k.

Tables 2 and 3 show that over 1973–2012 aggregate TFP increased by 0.68 per cent per annum and that this was almost entirely due to the contribution of plants that entered. In the first sub-period, 1973–82, TFP declined by 1.1 per cent per annum on average. This was largely the result of a negative contribution from falls in TFP within plants, offset to some extent by reallocations of output share in surviving plants towards more productive plants. TFP recovered between 1982 and 1994, increasing by 0.9 per cent per annum. The larger contribution of entrants was mainly responsible for this better performance, which was sufficient to offset the negative contribution from within plant deteriorations in productivity and the closure of relatively productive plants.

In contrast, TFP increased by 1.5 per cent per annum on average between 1994 and 2012. The primary source of this increase differs according to the decomposition method used: the Reference Foster, Haltiwanger, Krizan, Hulten, Dean and HarperFoster et al. (2001) approach attributes 1.1 per cent per annum to entrants and 0.5 per cent per annum to reallocations of output shares across surviving plants. By contrast, the Reference Melitz and PolanecMelitz and Polanec (2015) approach attributes 1.3 per cent per annum to a higher covariance between output shares and productivity among surviving plants and only 0.5 per cent to entrants. As discussed above, this is the pattern that would be expected since there was productivity growth among survivors in 1994–2012.

Table 2 also shows that in 1973–82 and 1982–94, TFP growth was lowered by the negative contribution of the closure of more productive plants. In 1994–2012, regardless of the decomposition method used, exiting plants made a positive but small contribution to productivity growth. The finding that TFP in manufacturing has increased over the past forty years is therefore not primarily due to the closure of low productivity plants.

5. Sources of productivity growth post-1994

Studies that have analysed the evolution of UK manufacturing productivity until the end of the 1980s (for example, Reference CameronCameron, 2003) tended to concentrate on the structural changes that were taking place during this period. According to Cameron (2003, p. 122), “In the 1970s … institutional rigidities, strong trade unions, lax competition policies, corporatist government interventions and a slowdown in technological advance led to a growth slowdown…. Growth rose in the 1980s because of the weakening of trade union power, withdrawal of state subsidies, the shedding of below average labour and capital, increasing subcontracting, the widespread adoption of ‘microchip’ technologies.”18,19

In order to explain high productivity growth in 1994–2012, we consider the role of globalisation, the composition of the workforce and intangible assets. In relation to the former, the continued opening up of the UK economy is likely to have played a role in raising manufacturing TFP in 1994–2012. As Reference Griffith, Redding and SimpsonGriffith et al. (2005) note: “deregulation and the opening of markets to international trade and investment has been widely recognised as a major driver of growth. (The) main effects of liberalisation. (are) the replacement of low productivity plants with high productivity entrants. increased competition or entry (inducing) incumbent firms to organise work more effectively, (while) the contribution of. multinationals to domestic productivity growth (advances) the U.K.'s technological frontier” (Griffith et al., op. cit., pp. 2–3).

We consider three dimensions of globalisation: trade, foreign direct investment and offshoring. There is evidence for the UK that foreign-owned firms have higher productivity (Reference Girma, Greenaway and WakelinGirma et al., 2001; Reference Harris and RobinsonHarris and Robinson, 2003; Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2015a). Similarly, many studies have found that involvement in trade increases productivity (see Reference WagnerWagner, 2012, for a review of the recent evidence and Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2015b for a recent study on the UK). Alongside the opening of markets has been increased material and service outsourcing, and especially offshoring, in manufacturing worldwide, which a number of studies have found increases productivity (e.g. Reference Amiti and WeiAmiti and Wei, 2009). The latter can arise for a number of reasons: static efficiency gains as firms focus on core competencies and offshore less productive activities; interaction with foreign suppliers, which can enhance learning externalities; the higher quality or better fit of imported input varieties; and general equilibrium effects if productivity gains spill over to other firms or induce tougher competition (cf. Reference Criscuolo and LeaverCriscuolo and Leaver, 2005; Reference SchwörerSchwörer, 2013; Reference Fariñas, López and Martín-MarcosFariñas et al., 2011).

Since the UK workforce became better qualified during this period (Reference Mason, O'Mahony and RileyMason et al., 2018), a second major source of productivity gains since 1994 is likely to have been an up-skilling of the workforce employed in manufacturing. Raising the quality of labour input has a direct effect on productivity, which has been demonstrated in a large number of studies (e.g. Reference Sianesi and Van ReenenSianesi and Van Reenen, 2003; Reference Bosworth, Jones and WilsonBosworth et al., 2008; Reference Oesch and Rodríguez MenésOesch and Menés, 2011; Reference MadsenMadsen, 2013). Using a decomposition approach, Reference Rincon-Aznar, Forth, Mason, O'Mahony and BerniniRincon-Aznar et al. (2015) estimate that up-skilling contributed 0.47 and 0.54 percentage points to aggregate UK labour productivity growth in 2002–7 and 2008–13 respectively. If higher human capital causes innovation, this will strengthen the impact of human capital on TFP (e.g. Reference Gennaioli, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and ShleiferGennaioli et al., 2013). In recent decades the evidence for affluent countries is that high skill occupations have been expanding at the expense of low skilled ones, and this is especially true in Britain (Reference Felstead, Gallie, Green and ZhouFelstead et al., 2007). This can be explained by growth in manufacturing imports from newly industrialising economies, skill-biased technical change associated with a growth in ICT and the demise of collective-bargaining for unskilled workers (Reference Peng and KangPeng and Kang, 2013).Footnote 20 Empirical evidence from Reference Gregory, Zissimos and GreenhalghGregory et al. (2001) shows that over the period 1979–90 in the UK, technological change had a major influence on the relative demand for skills, while the effect of trade was relatively small.

Lastly, intangible assets (which can be defined as complimentary knowledge embodied in intellectual assets and thus comprise more than just formal R&D)Footnote 21 are widely recognised as a key driver of enterprise performance and thus productivity (e.g., Reference Corrado, Hulten and SichelCorrado et al., 2006, Reference Corrado, Haskel and Jona-Lasinio2012; Reference Van Ark, Hao, Corrado and HultenVan Ark et al., 2009; Reference Dal Borgo, Goodridge, Haskel and PesoleDal Borgo et al., 2013) especially by proponents of a ‘resource-based’ perspective of the firm (e.g., Reference PenrosePenrose, 1959; Reference BarneyBarney, 1991; Reference Kogut and ZanderKogut and Zander, 1996; Reference Teece, Pisano, Dosi, Teece and ChytryTeece and Pisano, 1998; Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2013b). Their increased usage may also have played a role in increasing TFP growth.

Figure 4 presents the available information for UK manufacturing on changes in the (real) ‘openness’ of the sector, the composition of employment, trade union density and the relative importance of intangible (to tangible) investment for 1973–2007. ‘Openness’ (the ratio of exports and imports to GVA) was increasing in the 1970s, accelerated after the 1980–82 recession, and continued to grow post-1994. A similar pattern is shown for labour composition, with the largest increase occurring post-1994. As discussed in footnote 18, unionisation in manufacturing had seen the largest decline in the 1980s, followed by continued decline after 1992. Lastly, figure 4 indicates the very rapid growth in intangible asset building that occurred after 1997 (information is not available before this date). Thus plants have been grouped into categories reflecting high-to-low levels of change in openness, offshoring, labour composition, and total innovation spending (the latter proxying for investments in intangible assets) in order to show whether the industries most involved in these activities did indeed contribute more to productivity growth.Footnote 22

Figure 4. Factors affecting productivity 1973–2007 in UK manufacturing (1997=1)

Table 4 presents the results from decomposing TFP growth using the Reference Melitz and PolanecMelitz and Polanec (2015) approach for 1994–2012 by ownership sub-groups and by industries with differing levels of trade, offshoring, labour force composition and intangible assets. The ownership classification is done at the plant-level since the ABS contains the necessary information at the plant-level on ownership status. However, the other classifications are done at the industry level, as the ABS does not include the required variables measuring exporting/importing, offshoring, labour composition or intangible assets at the plant level. Plants are therefore allocated using their SIC code to industries with high, medium-high, medium-low and low levels of the relevant activity, with the classification of industries based on data from outside sources (see the online appendix for details). This therefore creates the likelihood that some plants are misclassified (for example, a plant that does no exporting or importing will be included in the high level of openness group if all other plants in its industry are heavily involved in trade) but, in our view, this represents the best possible approach with the data at our disposal.

The first three decompositions are intended to measure different dimensions of globalisation. In relation to ownership, disproportionately large contributions came from the foreign-owned sub-groups, largely due to reallocations of output shares towards relatively productive plants. Foreign-owned plants have therefore played an important role in productivity growth in 1994–2012. The industries most ‘open’ to international trade contributed the most to TFP growth, largely due to reallocations of output shares towards more productive surviving plants. While the first two panels suggest increased globalisation has had an important role in driving productivity growth in 1994–2012, industries involved in offshoring have tended to contribute less to aggregate TFP growth, vis-à-vis those with low levels of offshoring. Interestingly, one of the reasons for the relatively poor performance of the industries most involved in offshoring was a tendency to close relatively productive plants. This shows that, while offshoring may have reduced costs and boosted profits, the plants that closed were not necessarily unproductive.

Industries with more highly paid labour forces made a significant contribution to aggregate productivity growth (0.6 per cent per annum), mostly due to the entry of relatively productive plants and exit of less productive plants. However, industries belonging to the low-level sub-group provided the largest contribution, indicating the relationship between highly skilled labour forces and TFP growth is not as clear-cut as that between openness and TFP growth. The final panel of figure 3 shows that, as expected, industries with the highest level of intangible assets had the fastest TFP growth in 1994–2012, again because of reallocations of output share to more productive plants.

6. Conclusion

As is acknowledged by the UK government, the manufacturing sector makes a far larger contribution to the UK economy (to exports, innovation, other sectors through inter-industry linkages and the employment of highly skilled labour) than would be expected given its output share. This paper has calculated estimates of TFP for all manufacturing plants in the ABS between 1973 and 2012 to see what role, if any, TFP may have played in manufacturing's continuing relative decline. These show that TFP fell between 1973 and 1982 but had recovered by 1994. Since this date, TFP has increased rapidly. Only a small proportion of the growth since 1994 can be explained by a selection effect, whereby low productivity plants exited the market. The continued relative decline of UK manufacturing cannot therefore be attributed to poor TFP performance. Aggregate TFP growth was then decomposed to show the contribution of different sectors. This showed that much of the growth in this latter period comes from foreign-owned plants, industries that are involved in trade and industries with high levels of intangible assets.

Since the UK government is committed to increasing the role of manufacturing in the economy, it is useful to discuss the policy implications of our results. First, the results support efforts to encourage activities that allow firms to build up intangible assets. R&D tax credits, which have operated in the UK since 2000, are an example of such a policy although a recent meta-analysis finds these have been less effective in manufacturing than services (Reference Castellacci and LieCastellacci and Lie, 2015). Similarly, the results support assistance such as that offered by UK Trade and Investment to increase exporting, particularly since previous research using micro-data has found that such policies can be effective (Reference Gorg, Henry and StroblGorg et al., 2008; Reference Van Biesebroeck, Yu and ChenVan Biesebrock et al., 2016). We also find that the industries that are most involved in offshoring contribute positively to productivity growth but to a relatively small extent due to the closure of productive plants. This suggests that these firms are moving capacity in order to lower costs, rather than to increase productivity. Whether slowing the rate of offshoring is feasible, given the UK's high wage costs, is debatable but recent reductions in the main rate of UK corporation tax (from 28 per cent to 20 per cent between 2008 and 2015, declining to 19 per cent in 2017) may help at the margin. Such a policy may also attract foreign-owned plants that were also shown to have contributed positively to productivity growth.

More broadly, we confirm the results of earlier papers (Reference Disney, Haskel and HedenDisney et al., 2003; Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat, 2013a) which emphasise the importance of reallocations of output shares both among surviving plants and most especially the opening of new plants as a source of productivity growth. Policy measures to increase competition and thus facilitate the transfer of resources between firms would therefore improve aggregate productivity. By contrast, the government should resist pressures to support unproductive plants in areas where resources are likely to be re-employed quickly, since this will impede the process of ‘creative destruction’ necessary to generate productivity growth.

Appendix A

Footnotes

This work contains statistical data from ONS which is Crown copyright and reproduced with the permission of the controller of HMSO and Queen's Printer for Scotland. The use of the ONS statistical data in this work does not imply the endorsement of the ONS in relation to the interpretation of analysis of the statistical data. This work uses research datasets which may not exactly reproduce National Statistics aggregates. Supplementary material for this article is available online.

1 As will be shown later, manufacturing output in 2012 was 97% of the level achieved in 1973, and 16 percentage points lower than its peak in 2001. In terms of employment, only some 36% of the 7.3 million employed in 1973 were employed in the sector in 2012 (peak post-war employment in manufacturing was close to 9 million in 1966).

2 In 2011, the Chancellor of the Exchequer called for a ‘march of the makers’ (Reference OsborneOsborne, 2011) and this theme remained recurrent in post-2011 Budgets. The most recent initiative has been the creation of the Industrial Strategy Council by BEIS to help improve low productivity.

3 The peak level of non-manufacturing TFP was only slightly higher in 2007 when compared to 1973, whereas in manufacturing it was 55 percentage points higher. Put another way, average TFP growth p.a. in non-manufacturing 1973–2007 was less than 0.1% compared to 2.3% in manufacturing.

4 See also Sudit and Finger (1981, p. 15) who discuss gross output versus value-added measures of the production function, referring particularly to the work of Reference Diewert, Fuss and McFaddenDiewert (1978) and Reference Bruno, Fuss and McFaddenBruno (1978), both of whom were early proponents of a gross output approach. Diewert (op. cit., p.42) went as far as saying: “one is … led to wonder about how much of the ‘unexplained residual’ in growth studies … is due to the unjustified use of a real value-added framework”.

5 That is, factors that shift plants towards the ‘best-practice’ current technological frontier, together with those that influence technological progress, are not explicitly included or modelled in the growth accounting approach. This leads to bias in the output-elasticities relating factor inputs to output, given there are ‘omitted variables’ in the growth-accounting equation.

6 Note, the growth accounting approach has its own merits – it is a strong descriptive method and so is most useful when the objective is to measure the relative contributions of input growth and ‘other influences’ on output growth. It typically only requires data on real output, capital and labour, total revenue and the total cost of labour; no econometric estimation is needed; it is easy to construct and interpret; and the aggregate data sources used mean that factor inputs can often be adjusted for ‘quality’ (see Reference O'Mahony and TimmerO'Mahony and Timmer, 2009, for a discussion).

7 Further details about the variables included and the data are provided in an online appendix.

8 Estimators (such as Reference Olley and PakesOlley and Pakes, 1996; Reference Levinsohn and PetrinLevinsohn and Petrin, 2003) that purport to overcome these endogeneity issues are based on assumptions we believe are more restrictive than those implied by system-GMM (Reference Ackerberg, Caves and FrazerAckerberg et al., 2015). In particular, these estimators do not allow for fixed effects, which are important as empirical evidence shows that the distribution of productivity has both a large variance and is persistent over time (see, for instance, Reference Bartelsman and DhrymesBartelsman and Dhrymes, 1998; Reference MartinMartin, 2008). Note, like the Olley-Pakes approach, system-GMM is used to overcome the bias that would arise from OLS estimation if firms make decisions on factor inputs based on the value of the TFP shock (error term), which is unobservable to the researcher.

9 Intermediate inputs cover materials, fuels, semi- and finished-goods and (especially business) services used in the production of new goods and services. We are not estimating a gross valued-added function because we do not want to impose weak separability (capital and labour are separable from intermediate inputs in production) and thus homogeneity with respect to αM – see Reference Gandhi, Navarro and RiversGandhi et al. (2012) for a discussion.

10 TFP here comprises those factors contained in X that influence efficiency and technological progress. It also comprises an error term (ε∘it), which will pick up any measurement error, unobserved inputs (e.g., intangibles not captured by the R&D variable, the use of outsourcing, increased quality of labour inputs, etc.), and changes in the level of utilisation of factor inputs.

11 Reference O'DonnellO'Donnell (2016) characterises a TFP index as ‘proper’ if it can be written as the ratio of a proper output quantity index to a proper input quantity index. To be a proper input quantity index, the proportionality axiom requires that if a plant increases its use of all inputs by a factor of λ, its input quantity index should also increase by a factor of λ. Without constant returns to scale, the use of the estimated coefficients on the inputs to create the input quantity index (as is done in equation 2) leads to a violation of this axiom since increasing all inputs by a factor of λ leads to a less (more) than proportionate increase in the input quantity index in the presence of decreasing (increasing) returns to scale.

12 Table 7 in Reference Harris and MoffatHarris and Moffat (2015a) shows that this result is consistent with most recent studies.

13 Factor inputs (e, m and k) and brownfield foreign-ownership are treated as endogenous. In all cases endogenous variables are instrumented by their lagged values (in first differences for the levels equation and levels for the first differenced equation). The validity of the instruments is assessed using the Hansen test of over-identification. In all 25 industries, the null of valid instruments is not rejected at the 10% level.

14 This suggests that the development of high-tech manufacturing would be a good target for regional policy. However, the difficulty of identifying the precise source of these productivity differences limits our ability to make such recommendations.

15 Figure U.1 in the online appendix jointly plots the TFP indices reported in Figures 2 and 3, to allow comparison.

16 Like others, Harris and Moffat (op. cit.) show that labour productivity fell sharply in manufacturing post-2008, but this was not due to a fall in TFP (rather changes to factor mix).

17 Figure U.1 in the online appendix also plots the index of real gross output shown in Figure 3 and the ONS's index of manufacturing production; the series are broadly similar with a correlation of 0.9.

18 Cameron himself explained the higher productivity growth of the 1980s as being due to large and significant returns to business R&D, to decreasing unionisation, and to an increase in white-collar employment vis-a-vis manual employment.

19 While it is generally accepted that unions in the 1970s were a drag on productivity (Reference Metcalf, Addison and SchnabelMetcalf, 2003), leading to productivity gains in the 1980s (Reference CameronCameron, 2003; Reference Bryson, Forth and KirbyBryson et al., 2005), Reference Van ReenenVan Reenen (2013) argues that it “seems improbable that antiunion laws would have a permanent effect on productivity growth. Unions would have to have had a seriously negative effect on innovation and there is no compelling evidence of this” (p. 127). Reference Doucouliagos and LarocheDoucouliagos and Laroche (2003) conclude “that if all the available evidence is pooled together, measures of central tendency indicate a near zero association between unions and productivity … (although) a negative association appears for the United Kingdom and Japan” (p. 682). Figure 4 below shows that in manufacturing most of the decline in unionisation had occurred by 1990, such that unionism per se had a negligible impact on productivity by the late 1990s (Reference OsbornePencavel, 2003; Reference Bryson and ForthBryson and Forth, 2010; Reference Wright and BrownWright and Brown, 2014). Further falls after this period were against a backdrop of much lower unionisation, with trade union density below 19% in 2012.

20 Peng and Kang (op. cit.) are arguing that collective bargaining power is a decisive factor in accounting for disparities in skill premiums; given the way labour composition is measured, weighting employment in occupational groups by the associated wage for that group, this will have an impact.

21 In concrete terms, intangible assets have been classified by some “. into economic competencies (i.e., invest in skills, advertising and branding and organizational structure), scientific and creative property (i.e., R&D and ‘innovation’ more generally) and Information and Communications Technology” (BIS, 2012a; emphasis in original).

22 Details are provided in the online appendix (tables U.5 – U.9) on how industries were categorised into sub-groups experiencing high-to-low levels of change.

References

Ackerberg, D., Caves, K. and Frazer, G. (2015), ‘Identification properties of recent production function estimators’, Econometrica, 83(6), pp. 2411–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amiti, M. and Wei, S.-J. (2009), ‘Service offshoring and productivity: evidence from the US’, World Economy, 32(2), pp. 203–20.10.1111/j.1467-9701.2008.01149.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. (1991), ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage’, Journal of Management, 17(1), pp. 99120.10.1177/014920639101700108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartelsman, E. and Dhrymes, P. (1998), ‘Productivity dynamics: US manufacturing plants, 1972–1986’, Journal of Productivity Analysis, 9(1), pp. 534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. (1984), ‘On productivity growth in the long run’, Atlantic Economic Journal, 12(3), pp. 410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
BIS (2010), ‘Manufacturing in the UK: an economic analysis of the sector’, BIS Occasional Paper 10A, Department for Business, Innovation and Skills.Google Scholar
BIS (2012a), ‘The impact of investment in intangible assets on productivity’, BIS Research Paper 75, Department for Business, Innovation and Skills.Google Scholar
BIS (2012b), ‘Industrial strategy: UK sector analysis’, BIS Economics Paper 18, Department for Business, Innovation and Skills.Google Scholar
Bosworth, D., Jones, P. and Wilson, R. (2008), ‘The transition to a highly qualified workforce’, Education Economics, 16(2), pp. 127–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruno, M. (1978), ‘Duality, intermediate inputs and value-added’, in Fuss, M. and McFadden, D. (eds), Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications, pp. 416, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Bryson, A. and Forth, J. (2010), ‘Trade union membership and influence 1999–2009’, CEP Discussion Paper 1003, Centre for Economic Performance.Google Scholar
Bryson, A., Forth, J. and Kirby, S. (2005), ‘High-involvement management practices, trade union representation and workplace performance in Britain’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52(3), pp. 451–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, G. (2003), ‘Why did UK manufacturing productivity growth slow down in the 1970s and speed up in the 1980s?’, Economica, 70(277), pp. 121–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castellacci, F. and Lie, C.M. (2015), ‘Do the effects of R&D tax credits vary across industries? A meta-regression analysis’, Research Policy, 44(4), pp. 819–32.10.1016/j.respol.2015.01.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caves, R. (1998), ‘Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36(4), pp. 1947–82.Google Scholar
Corrado, C., Haskel, J. and Jona-Lasinio, C. (2012), ‘Productivity growth, intangible assets and ICT: some international evidence, http://www.worldklems.net/conferences/worldklems2012/worldklems2012_Jona_Lasinio.pdf.Google Scholar
Corrado, C., Hulten, C. and Sichel, D. (2006), ‘Intangible capital and economic growth’, NBER Working Paper 11948, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Criscuolo, C. and Leaver, M. (2005), Offshore Outsourcing and Productivity, Paris, OECD available at http://www.oecd.org/sti/sci-tech/35637436.pdf.Google Scholar
Dal Borgo, M., Goodridge, P., Haskel, J. and Pesole, A. (2013)., ‘Productivity and growth in UK industries: an intangible investment approach’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 75(6), pp. 806–34.Google Scholar
Diewert, W.E. (1978), ‘Hicks’ aggregation theorem and the existence of a real value-added function’, in Fuss, M. and McFadden, D. (eds), Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications, pp. 1752, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Disney, R., Haskel, J. and Heden, Y. (2003), ‘Restructuring and productivity growth in UK manufacturing’, Economic Journal, 113(489), pp. 666–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doucouliagos, C. and Laroche, P. (2003), ‘What do unions do to productivity? A meta-analysis’, Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society, 42(4), pp. 650–91.Google Scholar
Färe, R. and Primont, D. (1995), Multi-Output Production and Duality: Theory and Applications, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fariñas, J., López, A. and Martín-Marcos, A. (2011), ‘Offshoring, domestic outsourcing and productivity: a production function approach ISGEP Workshop’, available at http://www.leuphana.de/fileadmin/user_upload/PERSONALPAGES/Fakultaet_2/Wagner_Joachim/files/Farinas_Lopez_Martin-Marcos.pdf.Google Scholar
Feenstra, R., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. (2013), PWT 8.0 – A User Guide, available at http://www.rug.nl/research/ggdc/data/pwt/v80/pwt_80_user_guide.pdf.Google Scholar
Felstead, A., Gallie, D., Green, F. and Zhou, Y. (2007), Skills at Work, 1986–2006, Oxford: ESRC Research Centre on Skills, Knowledge and Organizational Performance.Google Scholar
Field, S. and Franklin, M. (2013), Micro-data Perspectives on the UK Productivity Conundrum – An Update, Newport, Office for National Statistics, available at http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171766_329419.pdf.Google Scholar
Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J. and Krizan, C.J. (2001), ‘Aggregate productivity growth: lessons from microeconomic evidence’, in Hulten, C., Dean, E.R. and Harper, M.J. (eds), New Developments in Productivity Analysis, pp. 303–72, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gandhi, A., Navarro, S. and Rivers, D. (2012), ‘On the identification of production functions: how heterogenous is productivity’, Collegio Carlos Alberto Working Paper 288, Collegio Carlos Alberto.Google Scholar
Gennaioli, N., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2013), ‘Human capital and regional development’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), pp. 105–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Girma, S., Greenaway, D. and Wakelin, K. (2001), ‘Who benefits from foreign direct investment in the UK?’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 48(2), pp. 119–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorg, H., Henry, M. and Strobl, E. (2008), ‘Grant support and exporting activity’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(1), pp. 168–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Government Office for Science (2013), The Future of Manufacturing: A New Era of Opportunity and Challenge for the UK, London, available at http://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/255922/13-809-future-manufacturing-project-report.pdf.Google Scholar
Gregory, M., Zissimos, B. and Greenhalgh, C. (2001), ‘Jobs for the skilled: how technology, trade, and domestic demand changed the structure of UK employment, 1979–90’, Oxford Economic Papers, 53(1), pp. 2046.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffith, R. (1999), ‘Using the ARD establishment level data to look at foreign ownership and productivity in the United Kingdom’, Economic Journal, 109(456), pp. F416–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffith, R., Redding, S. and Simpson, H. (2005), ‘The dynamics of establishment productivity: technology transfer and productivity dispersion’, IFS Working Paper, London, Institute for Fiscal Studies, available at http://www.princeton.edu/~reddings/papers/grs_v2_final.pdf.Google Scholar
Harris, R. (1987), ‘The role of manufacturing in regional growth’, Regional Studies, 21(4), pp. 301–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Drinkwater, S. (2000), ‘UK plant and machinery capital stocks and plant closures’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 62(2), pp. 243–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2012), ‘Is productivity higher in British cities?’, Journal of Regional Science, 52(5), pp. 762–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2013a), ‘The direct contribution of FDI to productivity growth in Britain, 1997–2008’, The World Economy, 36(6), pp. 713–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2013b), ‘Intangible assets, absorbing knowledge and its impact on firm performance: theory, measurement and policy implications’, Contemporary Social Science: Journal of the Academy of Social Sciences, 8(3), pp. 346–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2015a), ‘The impact of exporting and importing goods and services on productivity in the UK’, The World Economy, 38(11), pp. 1781–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2015b), ‘Plant-level determinants of total factor productivity in Great Britain, 1997–2008’, Journal of Productivity Analysis, 44(1), pp. 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, R. and Moffat, J. (2016), ‘The UK productivity puzzle, 2008–2012: evidence using plant level estimates of total factor productivity’, Oxford Economic Papers, 69 (3). pp. 529–49.Google Scholar
Harris, R. and Robinson, C. (2003), ‘Foreign ownership and productivity in the United Kingdom estimates for U.K. manufacturing using the ARD’, Review of Industrial Organization, 22(3), pp. 207–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1966), Causes of the Slow Rate of Economic Growth in the United Kingdom, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1996), ‘What firms do? Coordination, identity, and learning’, Organization Science, 7(5), pp. 502–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, P. (1997), The Age of Diminished Expectations: US Economic Policy in the 1990s, 3rd edn., Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Levinsohn, J. and Petrin, A. (2003), ‘Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables’, The Review of Economic Studies, 70, pp. 317–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madsen, J. (2013), ‘Human capital and the world technology frontier’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), pp. 676–92.Google Scholar
Martin, R. (2008), ‘Productivity dispersion, competition and productivity measurement’, CEP Discussion Paper 692, Centre for Economic Performance.Google Scholar
Mason, G., O'Mahony, M. and Riley, R. (2018), ‘What is holding back UK productivity? Lessons from decades of measurement’, National Institute Economic Review, 246(1), pp. R2435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, M. and Polanec, S. (2015), ‘Dynamic Olley-Pakes productivity decomposition with entry and exit’, The RAND Journal of Economics, 46(2), pp. 362–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Metcalf, D. (2003), ‘Unions and productivity, financial performance and investment: international evidence’, in Addison, J. and Schnabel, C. (eds), International Handbook of Trade Unions, pp. 118–71, Cheltenham, UK, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Moffat, J. (2013), ‘Recent micro-economic trends in the manufacturing sector’, Future of Manufacturing EP23, Government Office for Science.Google Scholar
Oesch, D. and Rodríguez Menés, J. (2011), ‘Upgrading or polarization? Occupational change in Britain, Germany, Spain and Switzerland, 1990–2008’, Socio-Economic Review, 9(3), pp. 503–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olley, G.S. and Pakes, A. (1996), ‘The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry’, Econometrica, 64(6), pp. 1263–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Donnell, C. (2016), ‘Using information about technologies, markets and firm behaviour to decompose a proper productivity index’, Journal of Econometrics, 190(2), pp. 328–40.Google Scholar
O'Mahony, M. (1998), Britain's Productivity Performance 1950–1996: An International Perspective, London: National Institute of Economics and Social Research.Google Scholar
O'Mahony, M. and de Boer, W. (2002), ‘Britain's relative productivity performance: has anything changed?’, National Institute Economic Review, 179(1), pp. 3843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Mahony, M. and Timmer, M. (2009), ‘Output, input and productivity measures at the industry level: the EU KLEMS Database’, Economic Journal, 119, pp. F374403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, G. (2011), Budget Statement by the Chancellor of the Exchequer, available at http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/ http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/2011budget_speech.htm. Pencavel, J. (2003), ‘The surprising retreat of union Britain’, NBER Working Paper 9564, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Peng, F. and Kang, L. (2013), ‘Labor market institutions and skill premiums: an empirical analysis on the UK, 1972–2002’, Journal of Economic Issues, 47(4), pp. 959–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Penrose, E. (1959), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Price, R. and Bain, G. (1983), ‘Union growth in Britain: retrospect and prospect’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, 21(1), pp. 4668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Restuccia, D. and Rogerson, R. (2008), ‘Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with heterogeneous establishments’, Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(4), pp. 707–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riley, R., Rincon-Aznar, A. and Samek, L. (2018), ‘Below the aggregate: a sectoral account of the UK productivity puzzle’, ESCoE Discussion Paper 2018–06, Economic Statistics Centre of Excellence.Google Scholar
Rincon-Aznar, A., Forth, J., Mason, G., O'Mahony, M. and Bernini, M. (2015), UK Skills and Productivity in an International Context, BIS Research Paper, London, Department for Business, Innovation & Skills, available at https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/486500/BIS-15-704-UK-skills-and-productivity-in-an-international_context.pdf.Google Scholar
Schwörer, T. (2013), ‘Offshoring, domestic outsourcing and productivity: evidence for a number of European countries’, Review of World Economics, 149(1), pp. 131–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sianesi, B. and Van Reenen, J. (2003), ‘The returns to education: macroeconomics’, Journal of Economic Surveys, 17(2), pp. 157200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sudit, E. and Finger, N. (1981), ‘Methodological issues in aggregate productivity analysis’, in Dogramaci, A. and Adam, N. (eds), Aggregate and Industry-Level Productivity Analyses, pp. 730, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. and Pisano, G. (1998), ‘The dynamic capabilities of firms: an introduction’, in Dosi, G., Teece, D. and Chytry, J. (eds), Technology, Organization, and Competitiveness. Perspectives on Industrial and Corporate Change, pp. 193213, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Ark, B., Hao, J., Corrado, C. and Hulten, C. (2009), ‘Measuring intangible capital and its contribution to economic growth in Europe’, EIB Papers, 14(1), pp. 6293.Google Scholar
Van Biesebroeck, J., Yu, E. and Chen, S. (2016), ‘The impact of trade promotion services on Canadian exporter performance’, Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d'Economique, 48(4), pp. 1481–512.Google Scholar
Van Reenen, J. (2013), ‘Productivity under the 1997–2010 Labour government’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 29(1), pp. 113–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, J. (2012), ‘International trade and firm performance: a survey of empirical studies since 2006’, Review of World Economics, 148(2), pp. 235–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, C. and Brown, W. (2014), ‘From center stage to bit player: trade unions and the British Economy’, The Singapore Economic Review, 59(04), pp. 1450030–1450001–1450030–1450020.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Manufacturing percentage share of GDP, 1970–2014

Figure 1

Figure 2. Manufacturing TFP index (growth accounting approach), 1973–2009 (1997=100)

Figure 2

Figure 3. Manufacturing TFP, labour productivity, real gross output and employment indices, 1973–2012 (1973=1)

Figure 3

Figure 4. Factors affecting productivity 1973–2007 in UK manufacturing (1997=1)

Supplementary material: File

Harris and Moffat Supplementary Material

Harris and Moffat Supplementary Material

Download Harris and Moffat Supplementary Material(File)
File 135.9 KB