Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-d8cs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T04:17:47.937Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Quantifying the Non-Use Value of Biodiversity in Cost–Benefit Analysis: The Dutch Biodiversity Points

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 January 2021

Frits Bos*
Affiliation:
CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, The Hague, Netherlands
Arjan Ruijs
Affiliation:
ACTIAM Sustainable Asset Management, Utrecht, Netherlands
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Biodiversity points are a quantitative measure for biodiversity. For over a decade, biodiversity points are being applied in the Netherlands for measuring the impact of roads, enclosure dams, and other water management projects on the non-use value of biodiversity. Biodiversity points are quite similar to the quality-adjusted life years used for cost-effectiveness analysis of healthcare treatments. Biodiversity points can be calculated by multiplying the size of the ecotope (e.g., number of hectare), the ecological quality of the ecotope (0–100 %), and the ecological scarcity of each type of ecotope. For many infrastructure projects, the impact on the non-use value of biodiversity can be a principal purpose or a major co-benefit or trade-off, for example, for a park, a fish sluice, a road, an ecoduct, an enclosure dam, or a marine protected area. Biodiversity points are a simple, transparent, and standardized way to aggregate and quantify the qualitative or ordinal assessments by ecological experts. For measuring the non-use value of biodiversity, they are also more informative than valuation by revealed or stated preferences methods. This paper provides the first overview of the application of this method in the Dutch practice of cost–benefit analysis. It also discusses its merits and limitations. The calculation and use of biodiversity points are illustrated by four case studies.

Type
Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis

1. IntroductionFootnote 1

Ecosystem services are the services of ecosystems, like forests, soil, water, and air. Three types of ecosystem services are commonly distinguished (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018, Chapter 13):

  1. (i) Provisioning services, like food, timber, and drinking water.

  2. (ii) Regulation and maintenance services, like fertility of the soil and water safety provided by dikes.

  3. (iii) Cultural services, like recreation services and the symbolic value of very old trees and whales.

Ecosystem services contribute only to human welfare when they are final and are not intermediate. Provisioning services and cultural services like food and recreation services are final ecosystem services as they contribute directly to human welfare. Regulatory services, like fertility of the soil, are usually intermediate services as they often contribute only indirectly to human welfare. However, water safety provided by dikes is a final service contributing directly to human welfare.

Biodiversity refers to the stock of natural capital in terms of the variation, size, and quality of species, populations, and ecosystems. Biodiversity can have a direct impact on human welfare by providing, for example, a nice environment for walking in a forest. However, it can also have an indirect impact on human welfare by providing a good-quality ecosystem essential for providing future ecosystem services. Biodiversity may also be relevant for human welfare without a clear link to ecosystem services, for example, from an options perspective, an inheritance perspective, or an existence and symbolic perspective. When the link between the quantity and quality of biodiversity and ecosystem services is absent or not very clear, the value of biodiversity could be labeled as the non-use value of biodiversity (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018, chapter 13).

For many cost–benefit analyses (CBAs), properly assessing the welfare effects of a policy measure on ecosystem services and biodiversity is important. This does not only apply to CBAs on nature policy but also to those on other policy areas such as mobility, agriculture, and water safety, as the policy measures in these policy areas often have impacts on ecosystem services and biodiversity. For example, a new road connecting two cities through a forest is good for mobility but has also impact on the value of ecosystem services and biodiversity. The use value of the forest may increase due to the reduction in travel time for visitors. But the non-use value, for example, the inheritance value of the forest and the biodiversity of its species may be affected severely by fragmenting the forest and by increasing traffic, pollution, and visitors.

Various strands of literature have addressed the question of how to incorporate the effects of a policy measure on ecosystem services and biodiversity in CBAs. However, in the scientific literature on CBA, CBA guidelines and textbooks and CBA practice, there is no general agreement on how to define and assess the welfare impacts due to changes in ecosystem services and biodiversity (Boyd et al., Reference Boyd, Ringold, Krupnick, Johnston, Weber and Hall2014; Schaefer et al., Reference Schaefer, Goldman, Bartuska, Sutton-Grier and Lubchenco2015).

In the scientific literature, a large number of studies provide monetary values of the welfare effects of changes in ecosystem services and biodiversity (see e.g., TEEB, 2010; Markandya, Reference Markandya2016) or discuss methodologies that can be used in CBA (see, e.g., Atkinson & Mourato, Reference Atkinson and Mourato2008; Freeman et al., Reference Freeman, Herriges and Kling2014; Johnston et al., Reference Johnston, Boyle, Adamowicz, Bennett, Brouwer, Cameron, Hanemann, Hanley, Ryan, Scarpa, Tourangeau and Vossler2017). In this literature, there is a clear bias toward studies focusing on novel estimation methods without considering their practical applicability (Laurans et al., Reference Laurans, Rankovic, Billé, Pirard and Mermet2013). Effects on ecosystem services and biodiversity in these studies are described in general terms, without specifying the impact of the policy measure, for example, on the number of visitors to a park, the appreciation of an area, the health effects of replacing a forest by a road, or effects on land productivity. As a consequence, they often yield unreliable estimates in monetary terms or estimates that cannot be used in a CBA for analyzing specific policy measures (Bartkowski et al., Reference Bartkowski, Lienhoop and Hansjürgens2015). Furthermore, by focusing on the valuation of the use of various specific ecosystem services, like recreational services, they generally ignore the non-use value of biodiversity.

General CBA guidelines,Footnote 2 general CBA textbooks (e.g., Boardman et al., Reference Boardman, Greenberg, Vining and Weimer2006; Mishan & Quah, Reference Mishan and Quah2007), and guidelines on CBA and the environment (e.g., OECD, 2006, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018; USEPA, 2014) only pay limited attention to ecosystem services and biodiversity and do not specify how changes in natural capital affect welfare and how they can be measured. Due to this lack of clear guidelines, CBA practitioners employ varying definitions of what “natural capital” is and how changes in natural capital affect welfare. This also causes problems in defining what to value.

The studies on the Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB, 2010, Reference Brouwer, Brander, Kuik, Papyrakis and Bateman2013) take stock of existing national and international initiatives and country practice on measuring ecosystems and biodiversity. They have advanced substantially the literature in this field. In contrast to the scientific literature, they are more frank about the costs and limitations of various valuation methods. For example, contingent valuation and choice modeling are described as “Expensive and technically difficult to implement. Prone to biases in design and analysis” (TEEB, Reference Brouwer, Brander, Kuik, Papyrakis and Bateman2013, p. 66). However, the TEEB studies do not provide clear guidelines on which ecosystems to include, how to include biodiversity, how to deal with substitutability, and how to prevent double counting. Furthermore, it is explicitly stated that the purpose is to provide guidance for environmental accounting at the national or regional level and that the purpose is not to provide guidance for CBA, i.e., analysis of a project or specific (set of) policy measures (TEEB, Reference Brouwer, Brander, Kuik, Papyrakis and Bateman2013, p. 48).

The new OECD Handbook on CBA and the environment (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018) devotes one chapter to the measurement of ecosystem services and biodiversity. It is clear about the limitations of measuring the non-use value of biodiversity by looking at ecosystem services and stated preference methods, for example:

  1. (i) “the emphasis on ecosystem services says little about the value of biodiversity defined by the Convention on Biodiversity … typical ecosystem services at best only implicitly reflect the contribution of this biodiversity (the contribution of the richness, complexity and resilience of species and the ecosystems that they inhabit) if at all.” (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018, p. 318)

  2. (ii) “Therefore, while stated preferences may provide sound valuation for high-experience, use value goods, the further one moves to consider indirect use and pure non-use values, the more likely one is to encounter problems.” (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018, p. 317)

  3. (iii) “preferences need not always conform to what is ecologically feasible or sustainable. Thus, in the Morse-Jones et al. study, respondents had a massively stronger preference for iconic, ‘charismatic’ animals which outweigh concerns regarding ecologically crucial issues such as extinction threat. So, for example, willingness to pay to conserve lions, even where these animals are not threatened by extinction, hugely outweighs stated values for say a species of frog, even when it is on the brink of extinction.” (OECD, Reference Atkinson, Braathen, Groom and Mourata2018, p. 325)

The Netherlands have a long tradition in CBA.Footnote 3 The way ecosystem services and biodiversity have been incorporated in Dutch CBAs has changed drastically over time: from CBAs in which major impacts on ecosystem services and biodiversity were not even mentioned to CBAs in which the impact on ecosystem services are valued as much as possible and effects on the non-use value of biodiversity are measured by biodiversity points. These biodiversity points measure the impact of a policy measure on the amount and the quality of biodiversity in a standardized way. It takes into account the area of ecosystems affected, the ecological quality of each area, and a weight factor per type of ecosystem reflecting the contribution of the ecosystem to species richness and the threat level to that ecosystem. Unlike the qualitative, nominal or ordinal, assessments by ecological experts in environmental impact assessments (EIAs), biodiversity points are a quantitative measure. As a consequence, biodiversity points can be used for cost-effectiveness and also for assessing the net benefits of a project with biodiversity as a co-benefit or trade-off.

The biodiversity points method was developed in 2009 at PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, the official expert institute of the Dutch government on the environment (Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009; precursors are Strijker et al., Reference Strijker, Sijtsma and Wiersma2000; Sijtsma, Reference Sijtsma2006); it is sometimes also referred to as ecological points method or the Threat-weighted Ecological Quality Area Method (T-EQA). It could be regarded as a specific way of habitat equivalence analysis, which is commonly used for natural resource damage assessment or biodiversity loss compensation (Roach & Wade, Reference Roach and Wade2006; Ray, Reference Ray2008; Wende et al., Reference Wende, Tucker, Quétier, Rayment and Darbi2018). In the Netherlands, the biodiversity point method has been applied to many different case studies by many different researchers and consultancy firms (see Sections 4 and 5). According to the Dutch guidelines on CBA (Romijn & Renes, Reference Romijn and Renes2013; Klooster et al., Reference Klooster, Warringa and Ohm2018), biodiversity points are an innovative and practical method to measure the impact on the non-use value of biodiversity. The biodiversity points method and its application to various Dutch case studies has been published in international journals and books on ecology and land use (Strijker et al., Reference Strijker, Sijtsma and Wiersma2000; Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van der Heide, van Hinsberg, Hull, Alexander, Khakee and Woltjer2011, Reference Sijtsma, van der Heide and van Hinsberg2013, Reference Sijtsma, van der Veen, van Hinsberg, Pouwels, Bekker, van Dijk, Grutters, Klaassen, Krijn, Mouissie and Wymenga2020; van Puijenbroek et al., Reference van Puijenbroek, Sijtsma, Wortelboer, Ligtvoet and Maarse2015). European legislation on protection of birds and their habitats and of marine waters requires impact analysis and CBA of the policy measures. Estimating the benefits is commonly regarded as the major problem in conducting such analysis. Recently, in European networks of policy-makers and researchers on the socioeconomic analysis of such policy measures, the biodiversity points method has been put forward as one of the solutions to this (Liefveld et al., Reference Liefveld, Didderen, Lengkeek, Japink, Bouma and Visser2011; van Oostenbrugge et al., Reference van Oostenbrugge, Slijkerman, Hamon, Bos, Machiels, van de Valk, Hintzen, Bos, van der Wal and Coolen2015; Spaans, Reference Spaans2020).

This paper contributes in two ways to the existing literature on CBA, ecosystem services and biodiversity. Firstly, international guidelines on CBA and environmental services (e.g., OECD, 2006; EPA Guidelines, 2014) focus on discussing valuation issues, usually in rather general terms and with a strong focus on the analytical methodologies and with very limited attention to CBA practice and the link to actual policy decision-making. This paper stresses that to support public decision-making, it may be more informative to put an equally strong focus on defining which effects on the quality and quantity of ecosystem services and biodiversity to include in CBA and how to ensure that only the effects relevant for welfare are included.

Secondly, this paper provides an overview of methods applied in Dutch CBAs to measure the volume and quality of ecosystem services and biodiversity, with a focus on the biodiversity point method. This paper provides the first overview of the history and application of this method in the Dutch CBA practice during the past decade. It also discusses its merits and limitations.

The outline of this paper is as follows. Section 2 starts with a general overview on CBA, ecosystem services, and biodiversity (“nature”) in the Netherlands. In the subsequent sections, six case studies of CBA on water management and transport infrastructure are discussed. Two case studies in 2000 and 2005 on “Room for water” and “Room for the river” compare various alternatives on their cost-effectiveness for nature. They are the topic of Section 3. These case studies illustrate how the impact on ecosystem services and biodiversity was measured in cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) before the introduction of the biodiversity point method. The method of biodiversity points and its application in four different case studies are discussed in Section 4. Conclusions about the merits and limitations of biodiversity points in CEA and in a full-fledged CBA are drawn in Section 5.

2. General overview on CBA and nature in the Netherlands

2.1. Early CBAs on flood risk ignoring major negative effects on nature

Up to the 1970s, CBAs in the Netherlands mainly pertained to major investments in flood risk management. Examples include the 30 km long Southern Sea enclosure dam (Afsluitdijk) and the Delta Works, each of which costed about 6–7 % of GDP. The impact on nature was usually not included in these CBA’s.

The 1901 CBA on the Southern Sea enclosure dam (Lely, Reference Lely1901) looked at many different types of costs and benefits but ignored the negative impact on water quality and fish. Similarly, following the massive flooding of the southwestern part of the Netherlands in 1953, the CBA on the Delta Works (Tinbergen, Reference Tinbergen1953) compared two alternatives to ensure sufficient flood risk safety: raising and strengthening dikes all along the waterways versus shortening the coastline by blocking the estuary mouths with barrier dams (Delta Works). Many different types of costs and benefits were monetized, quantified, or at least mentioned. But closing off the estuary mouths by barrier dams would turn tidal salt water areas into fresh water lakes like the IJsselmeer (the former Southern Sea); these substantial negative effects on nature were ignored in the CBA. Decades later, following increasing international concerns about the environment, in Dutch public debate, these negative effects on nature were stressed. As a consequence, in 1976, the Dutch government decided to construct semi-closed barrier dams. This was an entirely new option for flood risk management (only in case of serious danger of flood risk, the barrier dams are closed). It was much more expensive than closed barrier dams but the advantage was that negative effects on nature were limited.

2.2. Environmental impact analysis (EIA) as an input for CBA

Reporting environmental effects of public investments, including those on nature, started in 1978. NEI and RIN (1978) presented an EIA and a CBA comparing the extension of the port of Den Helder with alternative solutions in the ports of IJmuiden and Rotterdam. Basically, most effects on nature were given in physical terms that were presented next to monetary costs and benefits. Some effects on nature were monetized, in particular, the foregone revenues of fishing, the loss of shell lime production, and the loss of water cleaning capacity. The impact of a new port on five basic functions of nature (production function, intermediary and supporting function, informative function, regulatory function, and conservation function) was specified and at least scored qualitatively (with minus and plus signs) for 13 different sub-functions. Nearly a decade later, a European ActFootnote 4 made EIAs obligatory.

Unlike a CBA, EIA does not translate positive and negative effects in nature into monetary terms and usually do not consider double counting, that is, whether several environmental impacts lead to the same impact on welfare. But their information can be used as an input for CBA. For example, in the CBA on deepening the Westerschelde waterway from the Netherlands to Antwerp (Saitua, Reference Saitua2004), the EIA was used to claim that from a European perspective, the environmental effects were negligible. This is still the role of EIA in most Dutch CBAs on transport infrastructure and spatial projects (see Annema & Koopmans, Reference Annema and Koopmans2015).

2.3. National guidelines on CBA and nature

To improve the quality and consistency of CBA, national CBA guidelines for transport infrastructure were developed (Eijgenraam et al., Reference Eijgenraam, Koopmans, Tang and Verster2000). It does not explicitly discuss the effects on nature of infrastructure projects. The valuation of effects on nature in CBA was separately addressed in a supplementary guidance (Ruijgrok et al., Reference Ruijgrok, Brouwer and Verbruggen2004) and an overview with key figures for such valuation of nature (Witteveen & Bos, Reference Witteveen and Bos2006).

As a result, attempts were made to include, for example, effects of changes in nature on housing prices, health, and recreation. Due to shortage of data and a lack of primary valuation studies, this resulted in many cases in arbitrary assumptions or token entries – indicating that the effect was relevant but that no reliable monetary value could be estimated. In other CBAs, some impacts were double counted, or other errors were made in quantifying and valuing the welfare effects in terms of cost and benefits.

In 2013, an updated CBA guideline was published by CPB and PBL (Romijn & Renes, Reference Romijn and Renes2013), which included a brief discussion of accounting for the impact on nature.Footnote 5 This topic is covered more in-depth in the supplementary guideline on CBA and nature (Klooster et al., Reference Klooster, Warringa and Ohm2018). The guideline on CBA and nature recommends the use of biodiversity points for measuring the impact on biodiversity. It also stresses the importance of providing clarity about the welfare effects of changes in nature. For example, most regulating services, like natural pest control and water purification are intermediate services. They indirectly affect welfare as they are an input in the production function for final ecosystem services. Effects on these intermediate services are to be indirectly included in a CBA through their effects on the final services and the valuation thereof (see Boyd & Banzhaf, Reference Boyd and Banzhaf2007). Biodiversity – the variety of genes, species, and ecosystems – holds a special position in these guidelines. Biodiversity is important to guarantee a continued delivery of ecosystem services over the long term and for maintaining ecosystem resilience (Cardinale et al., Reference Cardinale, Duffy, Gonzalez, Hooper, Perrings, Venail, Narwani, Mace, Tilman, Wardle, Kinzig, Daily, Loreau, Grace, Larigauderie, Srivastava and Naeem2012; Isbell et al., Reference Isbell, Gonzalez, Loreau, Cowles, Díaz, Hector, Mace, Wardle, O’Connor, Duffy, Turnbull, Thompson and Larigauderie2017).

3. Two CBAs without biodiversity points

In 1993 and 1995, the water levels in the major Dutch rivers Rhine, Meuse, Waal, and IJssel rose to such levels that serious breaching of river dikes was only just avoided. The projects “Room for Water” and “Room for the River” meant a new flavor on the Dutch menu of preventive water management policies: spatial adjustments to increase safety. Two evaluation studies of these projects characterize how nature was included in CEA in the years before biodiversity points were introduced.

3.1. CEA comparing four strategies for improving safety along the rivers and coast

The first study refers to a quick-scan CEAFootnote 6 of a set of projects for improving safety along the rivers and coast (Stolwijk & Verrips, Reference Stolwijk and Verrips2000). Table 1 provides an overview of the monetary costs and benefits of water safety for four project alternatives.

Table 1 A CEA of four projects in the lower river region for increasing safety (Stolwijk & Verrips, Reference Stolwijk and Verrips2000, table 8, p. 55).

Next to monetized cost and safety benefits, four different types of non-monetary effects were taken into account: quality of landscape spatial beauty, quality of environment (including biodiversity), social consequences for farmers, and flexible water management. The scores in terms of a simple ordinal scale (5-point Likert scale) were assessed by experts. Insufficient information was available to estimate the monetary value of these non-monetary effects.

The approach provided some evidence that the spatial adjustments proposed in the alternatives (rerouting of the river Meuse, rerouting of the river Waal, and changing the discharge distribution over various rivers) had more positive environmental effects than the conventional approach of raising dikes; in particular, changing the discharge distribution would have positive effects on the environment according to the experts. However, the scores by the experts were not transparent, for example, it was not clear which criteria they had used to assess the change in the quality of environment. As a consequence, these expert scores were not very informative for redesigning the plans to better mitigate negative impacts or exploit potentials for co-benefits.

3.2. Four-dimensional CEA

The second study refers to an assessment of 600 specific policy measures and 4 packages of policy measures as part of the project Room for the River by Ebregt et al. (Reference Ebregt, Eijgenraam and Stolwijk2005). These policy measures were very heterogeneous, ranging from deepening trenches, moving dikes further away from the river, introducing extra channels, rerouting rivers, and raising dikes. They had a broad range of effects, many of which could not be well translated into monetary terms. For that reason, a so-called four-dimensional CEA was developed. For all investigated measures, four types of benefits were distinguished:

  1. (i) Extra landscape with high environmental quality (biodiversity) in hectares.

  2. (ii) Extra landscape with spatial beauty per kilometer along the river.

  3. (iii) Extra landscape attractive for leisure activities per kilometer along the river.

  4. (iv) Extra safety in terms of a reduction of high water level to the target high water level in m2.

For the three different types of landscape effects, the impact of the policy measures was estimated as the change in acreage of a wide range of ecotopes. This was used to create an expert opinion on biodiversity, spatial beauty, and leisure effects. The measure for biodiversity can be seen as a precursor of the biodiversity points method discussed in Section 4. Similar types of ecotopes are distinguished as in the biodiversity points approach but here weighting was done through expert review instead of through a predefined set of quality and weighting indices. The predefined weighting indices make the biodiversity points more transparent and objective.

For all 600 measures, information on their costs per unit of benefit was compared to the standard cost per benefit. The typical cost rate for an extra hectare of landscape with high environmental quality was 230,000 euros. This was much higher than the average costs per ha for increasing environmental quality in the Netherlands. Hence, combining extra safety with environmental development did not seem to be very cost-effective.

4. Four CBAs with biodiversity points

The unsatisfactory and arbitrary way of incorporating biodiversity in CBAs encouraged Sijtsma et al. (Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009) to develop an alternative approach; this was a joint effort by ecologists and economists. They proposed a CEA in which the net benefits that can be valued are compared with the change in so-called biodiversity points. The biodiversity point method, sometimes also referred to as the T-EQA method (van Puijenbroek et al., Reference van Puijenbroek, Sijtsma, Wortelboer, Ligtvoet and Maarse2015) or the ecological points method (Liefveld et al., Reference Liefveld, Didderen, Lengkeek, Japink, Bouma and Visser2011), measures the impact on the amount and quality of biodiversity in a standardized way (Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009; Jaspers et al., Reference Jaspers, Mouissie, Wessels, Barke, Kolen and Bucholc2016).

This biodiversity points approach is increasingly being applied in Dutch CBAs, resulting in more and more insight in what would be reasonable costs for obtaining an additional biodiversity point. This is in particular useful to compare the cost-effectiveness of project alternatives with respect to their impact on biodiversity. However, biodiversity points are also useful for assessing the net benefits of projects in which the impact on biodiversity is a major co-benefit or trade-off. In Dutch CBA practice, the impact on biodiversity is still often included as a token entry with some qualitative assessment. As a consequence, major impacts on biodiversity may be ignored in public decision-making. It also happens that the impacts on biodiversity are very limited but are exaggerated in public debate about the project for strategic reasons. Biodiversity points can be an important method to avoid such misunderstanding and misleading communication about the size of the impact on biodiversity.

4.1. How to measure biodiversity points?

The biodiversity points are calculated by multiplying three components:

  1. (i) The area of natural or semi-natural ecosystems affected (in hectares or square kilometers);

  2. (ii) The ecological quality of each area (0–100 %);

  3. (iii) A weight factor per type of ecosystem, reflecting the contribution of the ecosystem to species richness at national, European, or global level, which depends on the species present in the ecosystem and their threat level.

The ecological quality is measured by an intactness or robustness score, in a range from 0 to 1. This measure is determined for each of the relevant ecotopes based on the number of characteristic species present in the area relative to their presence in an intact ecosystem. These ecotopes and characteristic species are derived from the universal set of biodiversity indicators (Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD), 2004), the more detailed European set of biodiversity indicators (European Environment Agency, 2012) and the mean species abundance used in UNEP’s Global Environment Outlook. For this, national reference lists containing the species in an intact ecosystem are available, for example, for the Netherlands.Footnote 7 In Europe, for the Habitat Regulation (European Commission, 1992) and the Water Directive (European Commission, 2000), each EU-member country had to assess the ecological quality of ecotopes in comparison to a healthy ecological condition. So, this is already roughly similar to providing intactness or robustness scores for ecological quality.

EIAs generally provide a lot of information on ecological quality, before and after the policy intervention. This information should first be extended and translated into ecotypes and per ecotype, the number of characteristic species in the area. This can then be translated into ecological quality scores, before and after the policy intervention. Multiplying the ecological quality scores for the different ecotopes by the acreage of their area gives the Ecological Quality Area score (EQA) per ecotope.

Finally, the EQAs of the ecotopes are multiplied with standardized weight factors that indicate the threat level to the ecotope. This threat level is related to the relative number of red list species in the ecotope. Extremely threatened ecotopes have the highest weight, while commonly occurring ecotopes with common and not threatened species have the lowest weight. As a result, an intervention in a highly threatened ecotope results in a higher score than a similar intervention in a non-threatened ecotope. For example, salt marshes have a weighting factor of 2.4, nutrient-poor peatlands and moist heather lands have a weighting factor of 1.2, and agricultural grasslands have a weighting factor of 0.4.

Determining the weighting factors is not fully straightforward, and different methods and data sources are possible (see Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009). However, most important is that these weights are standardized for each country and based on systematic ecologic data collection which is objective and transparent. This approach is similar to how CO2-equivalents are used to aggregate different types of emissions or how different health effects are summarized by the indicator Disability Adjusted Life Years.

Biodiversity points or T-EQA is defined as:

$$ \mathrm{Biodiversity}\hskip0.5em \mathrm{points}={\sum}_{i=1}^n{\mathrm{Area}}_i\times {\mathrm{Quality}}_i\times {\mathrm{Weight}\ \mathrm{factor}}_i $$

with i ∈ {1, …, n}, the different types of ecosystem types or nature types.

This implies that in order to calculate the impact of a policy measure in terms of biodiversity points, 10 steps are necessary:

  1. (i) Select the relevant ecosystem types in the impacted area.

  2. (ii) Assess the size of the area of each ecosystem type in the current situation (baseline).

  3. (iii) Assess the characteristic species for each ecosystem type.

  4. (iv) Assess the threat level or relative weight of each ecosystem type; the relative number of red list species within this ecosystem might be used as a first proxy.

  5. (v) Calculate the local intactness of these ecosystems based on the presence of characteristic species relative to the number that would be present in an intact ecosystem. This gives a % score ranging generally from 0 to 100 %. Rescale this ecological quality from 0 to 1.

  6. (vi) Calculate the number of biodiversity points for the current situation using the information from steps 1 to 5.

  7. (vii) Specify the acreage of the changes in ecosystem types in the project alternatives.

  8. (viii) Assess the ecological quality per ecosystem type in the project alternatives.

  9. (ix) Calculate the number of biodiversity points in the project alternatives using information from steps 4, 7, and 8.

  10. (x) Compare the number of biodiversity points in the project alternatives with those in the current situation.

An advantage of the biodiversity point method is that decision-makers have a single objective measure to compare biodiversity effects of alternative interventions. For some questions, this is more useful than the range of impacts shown by an EIA. Where an EIA is useful to assess whether legal norms are exceeded, it is not very useful to compare, for example, an intervention impacting fish stocks with an alternative intervention impacting water quality in an adjacent area. The scarcity-based weighting of the biodiversity points allows decision-makers to compare these incomparable impacts.

Four examples can illustrate the use of the biodiversity point method in Dutch CBA practice.

4.2. CBA of increasing biodiversity by raising groundwater levels

For three areas in the peatlands in the Netherlands, two alternatives for raising the groundwater levels are compared in a CBA (Witteveen et al., Reference Witteveen, Bos and Arcadis2006). Both alternatives improve biodiversity. The second alternative leads to the highest levels of aquatic biodiversity. In this CBA, the effects on biodiversity were monetized on the basis of willingness to pay. The scientific basis for the willingness-to-pay values, however, was rather weak.Footnote 8 The study did not properly present the biodiversity change to the respondents and was not clear about the population impacted by the change proposed. This is a well-known risk of poorly designed stated preference research.

Sijtsma et al. (Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009) recalculated the results but now with biodiversity points. Table 2 presents the results of this study, with the biodiversity effects given both in monetized values as well as in biodiversity points. Monetized values hardly differ between the two alternatives, whereas the biodiversity points clearly show that the alternatives have different biodiversity impacts. Next to that, the area having the largest monetized value does not result in the highest gain in biodiversity points.

Table 2 Results from a full CBA and a CBA presenting biodiversity points separately.

The revised information provides more relevant information to policy-makers than the original information in the badly designed stated preference research. It enables them to distinguish between the effects on nature of both alternatives. Moreover, it allows them to evaluate for which alternative and in which area they obtain the highest extra biodiversity per euro invested. This information in biodiversity points may be supplemented with a more qualitative description of the impacts on nature of the various alternatives.

4.3. CBA extra lanes for the highways near Amsterdam

Extra lanes for the highways near Amsterdam is currently the largest infrastructure project in the Netherlands. The investment is about 4 bln euros. These lanes are extended near a nature reserve (Naardermeer). As a consequence, there are negative effects on this nature reserve. In the official CBA on this project, the impact on biodiversity was only mentioned briefly and qualitatively.

Sijtsma et al. (Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009)Footnote 9 calculated the impact in terms of biodiversity points for this project and four nature-friendly project alternatives (see Table 3). This reveals that:

  1. (i) The impact of the baseline project of extra lanes compared to the current situation is a reduction of 149 biodiversity points (last line of Table 3).

  2. (ii) In comparison to the baseline project, the four supplementary project alternatives lead to less disturbance of animals but also to a destruction of habitat. As a consequence, in terms of biodiversity points, only two of these alternatives have a net positive impact (streamline 4 × 23 lanes and most environmental friendly alternative). And these net impacts (15 and 40 biodiversity points) are not sufficient to overcome the negative impact in the baseline project (−149 biodiversity points). The other two project alternatives have small net negative impact (−7 and −12 biodiversity points).

  3. (iii) The net impact on biodiversity of this project and its project alternatives is quite small (e.g., effect of the baseline project is −149 biodiversity points). It is also small compared to the impact of the peatland projects in the example above, ranging from 800 to about 1800 biodiversity points. This reflects that the peatland project is very effective in limiting the rapid deterioration of peatland due to drought, while the extra lanes have a much less and more indirect effect on the unique flora and fauna nearby.

Table 3 Extra lanes for the highway Schiphol–Amsterdam–Almere on the nature reserve Naardermeer, impact in terms of biodiversity points for four project alternatives.

4.4. CEA for the reconstruction of the Afsluitdijk

The first major official study using the biodiversity-points methodology for public decision-making was the CEA of the Afsluitdijk by Grevers and Zwaneveld (Reference Grevers and Zwaneveld2011). In order to meet legal safety standards of flooding once every 1/10,000 years, this enclosure dam needed fundamental reconstruction. The dam should also continue to meet two other functions: managing the water level in the IJsselmeer and providing good connections for transport by car and by ship. This renovation could be combined with new functions with respect to nature, for example, dikes combined with trees (green dikes) and special sluices for fish.

The CEA showed the effects on nature in two different ways: the extent to which legal environmental protection standards were met and the score in biodiversity points. In contrast to the perspective of minimal legal standards for the environment, the score in biodiversity points does not only look at negative effects on the environment but also takes into account how much extra biodiversity can be created.

In order to calculate the biodiversity points for the plans to renovate the Afsluitdijk, the impact area and the different habitats had to be distinguished and the quality and relative weight of each habitat had to be assessed. The impact area considered was 3 km on both sides of the 33 km long Afsluitdijk. Table 4 provides an overview of the different habitats in the area, their weight scores and their current, pre-intervention quality scores. The quality scores were based on earlier estimates for the European Water Framework Directive.

Table 4 Habitats surrounding the Afsluitdijk (Wessels et al., Reference Wessels, Jaspers, Wortelboer, van Puijenbroek, Zwaneveld, Grevers and Sijtsma2011).

The table shows that the ecological quality varies from zero for paved surface to 3.4 for areas with a sweet–salt water gradient. The current situation is 11,770 biodiversity points, for an area of 19,000 ha. The average ecological quality is 37.5 % and the average weighting factor is 1.6.

This table shows that the current quality of the shoreline and marshes in the Makkumer Noorwaard is 54 per cent. Its weighting factor is 1.6. With an area of 300 ha, these marshes have 300 × 1.6 × 0.54 = 259 biodiversity points. Suppose that you build an additional 100 hectares of marshes at the expense of shallow sweet open water, then you gain 100 × 1.6 × 0.54 = 86.4 biodiversity points but lose 100 × 1.3 × 0.35 = 45.5 biodiversity points.

According to Table 5, only some alternative interventions and options have substantial impact on nature, for example, the natural enclosure dam, the 500 ha extra marshes, and the fish sluice. They either result in larger areas of rare habitat types (with high weighting scores) or result in substantial quality improvements. The table also shows that the option Green Afsluitdijk has a clear positive effect on biodiversity: an increase of 1600 biodiversity points. An interesting result was that nearly the same amount of biodiversity points (1500) could be obtained by constructing a fish sluice in the Afsluitdijk but at only a fraction of the costs: not 550 mln euro but 10 mln euro. Hence, fish sluices were much more cost-effective for improving biodiversity.

Table 5 Renovating the enclosure dam: cost-effectiveness of various options for extra biodiversity (see Wessels et al., Reference Wessels, Jaspers, Wortelboer, van Puijenbroek, Zwaneveld, Grevers and Sijtsma2011).

This CEA was well received by policy-makers. The results were almost completely adopted in the final decision of the Dutch Cabinet (Zwaneveld et al., Reference Zwaneveld, Grevers, Eijgenraam, van der Meulen, Pluut, Hoefsloot and de Pater2012). The option Green enclosure dam was rejected, and it was decided to construct a fish sluice. Subsequent political decision-making led to a much more advanced and fish-friendly but also much more expensive fish sluice (35 mln euro).

4.5. CEA meta-study on infrastructure defragmentation

On request of the Dutch government, recently a meta-study was conducted about the cost-effectiveness of 175 defragmentation policy measures in the period 2004–2018 (see Table 6). Four types of defragmentation alternatives were distinguished: ecoduct, viaduct, big faunatunnel, and small faunatunnel. The major conclusions are:

  1. (i) Large faunatunnels and viaducts with share use of traffic and animals are more cost-effective for stimulating biodiversity than ecoducts (0.08 mln euro per biodiversity point versus 0.18 mln euro per biodiversity point); small faunatunnels are by far the least cost-effective, i.e., on average more than double as costly than ecoducts (0.38 mln euro per biodiversity point).

  2. (ii) The cost-effectiveness differs between ecoducts: the more nature areas are in the direct vicinity, the more cost-effective.

  3. (iii) Buying agricultural land and using this for nature purposes is about as cost-effective for biodiversity than a viaduct or big faunatunnel. However, the ecological improvement of existing nature zones is even much more cost-effective (0.02 mln euro per biodiversity point).

The results of this meta-study can also be compared with those of the other biodiversity studies. In terms of impact on biodiversity, one ecological connection results in somewhat more than 10 biodiversity points (146 connections, in total 1791 biodiversity points). This implies that, for example, the fish sluice in the enclosure dam with 1500 biodiversity points is broadly comparable to 150 ecological connections. In terms of cost-effectiveness, a fish sluice in the enclosure dam (0.02 mln euro per biodiversity point) is comparable to ecological improvement of existing areas and much more cost-effective than ecological connections.

5. Conclusions and looking forward

The way nature has been incorporated in Dutch CBAs has changed over time: from CBAs in which major impacts on nature were not even mentioned to CBAs in which the impact on ecosystem services are valued as much as possible and effects on biodiversity are measured in biodiversity points. In some earlier CBAs, like Stolwijk and Verrips (Reference Stolwijk and Verrips2000) and Ebregt et al. (Reference Ebregt, Eijgenraam and Stolwijk2005), in particular, for measuring the non-use value of biodiversity, ordinal scaling or quantitative measures were used, like the change in the number of hectares of high-environmental quality. But no detail was shown, and the rarity of the species in the habitat was not taken into account.

In a whole range of recent Dutch studies on CBA and measuring the impact of projects on nature, biodiversity effects are quantified in terms of “biodiversity points,” and the method has been further standardized for terrestrial and aquatic nature (salt, sweet):

  1. (i) the revisited CBA on raising groundwater levels in order to protect peatlands (Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009);

  2. (ii) the revisited CBA on extra lanes for the highway Schiphol–Amsterdam–Almere (Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van Hinsberg, Kruitwagen and Dietz2009);

  3. (iii) the CEA on renovating the enclosure dam of the Lake IJssel (Grevers & Zwaneveld, Reference Grevers and Zwaneveld2011);

  4. (iv) the report on evaluating biodiversity of the North Sea using eco-points, in order to test its applicability for European Marine Strategy Framework Directive assessments (Liefveld et al., Reference Liefveld, Didderen, Lengkeek, Japink, Bouma and Visser2011);

  5. (v) the CEA on the management of the water level in the Lake IJssel in view of the rising sea level (Bos et al., Reference Bos, Zwaneveld and Puijenbroek2012);

  6. (vi) the report on evaluating projects in the Delta program for water management with six new case studies on biodiversity points (van Gaalen et al., Reference van Gaalen, van Hinsberg, Franken, Vonk, van Puijenbroek and Wortelboer2014);

  7. (vii) the CBA on seabed protection on the Frisian front and central oyster grounds (van Oostenbrugge et al., Reference van Oostenbrugge, Slijkerman, Hamon, Bos, Machiels, van de Valk, Hintzen, Bos, van der Wal and Coolen2015);

  8. (viii) the report on nature-friendly area development, water safety, and transport infrastructure projects with five new case studies on biodiversity points (Jaspers et al., Reference Jaspers, Mouissie, Wessels, Barke, Kolen and Bucholc2016);

  9. (ix) the CEA meta-study on defragmentation policy measures to enable wildlife crossing of roads, channels, and railway tracks (Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van der Veen, van Hinsberg, Pouwels, Wymenga, Krijn, Klaassen, Mouissie, Grutters, van Dijk, Wackwitz and Kisjes2018, Reference Sijtsma, van der Veen, van Hinsberg, Pouwels, Bekker, van Dijk, Grutters, Klaassen, Krijn, Mouissie and Wymenga2020).

  10. (x) the CEA on (re)introducing limited tidal waves in the Grevelingen Lake in order to improve water quality (Fiselier & Botman, Reference Fiselier and Botman2020).

The biodiversity point method is recommended by the new national guidelines on CBA (Romijn & Renes, Reference Romijn and Renes2013; Klooster et al., Reference Klooster, Warringa and Ohm2018). Also specific guidelines have been developed on how to measure and use biodiversity points in CBA and ecological studies to support public decision-making on natural capital, ecosystem services, and biodiversity (Jaspers et al., Reference Jaspers, Mouissie, Wessels, Barke, Kolen and Bucholc2016; Rijkswaterstaat, 2020).

Biodiversity points are a practical and transparent method to quantify the impact of policy measures on biodiversity. They are especially useful for policy measures that have a major impact on ecosystems, such as nature policies or infrastructural works near nature or protected areas. They can be very helpful to formulate more nature friendly or cheaper policy alternatives or to find more cost-effective compensation measures.

For assessing the net benefits of projects, biodiversity points provide a standardized quantitative summary measure for the impact on biodiversity. This biodiversity measure can be decomposed into its constituent parts, is based on acreage of the impact area, internationally standardized ecological quality indicators and nationally standardized threat weights, and can be checked on its consistency of application for various CBAs. For assessing the overall effects of a project, this is more informative than qualitative (nominal or ordinal) expert opinions on a policy measure’s impact on biodiversity; these are generally not standardized and comparable for different CBAs and cannot provide an indicator of change in biodiversity per euro invested. Sensitivity analysis with a range of reasonable different cost-prices per biodiversity point can show net benefits fully in monetary terms.

The use of biodiversity points can be advanced by providing overviews of their costs per point for various types of nature at various locations and various types of policy measures. This overview can give concrete examples of relatively cheap interventions for improving or protecting nature (e.g., a fish sluice in the enclosure dam of the Lake IJssel) and much more expensive ones. The overview can also discuss the factors determining these differences in cost-effectiveness. If such an overview is available, this would be a great help for assessing biodiversity points in another CBA or CEA.

Biodiversity points are quite similar to the quality-adjusted life years used for CEA of healthcare treatments. The major merits of biodiversity points are:

  1. (i) simple, as a simple linear function is used with only four variables;

  2. (ii) transparent, as it consists of a standardized formula with scores per ecotype for three variables;

  3. (iii) relatively cheap, as it only involves assessment by ecological experts, and no expensive well-designed survey of willingness to pay is needed. But, of course, in comparison to a purely qualitative assessment by ecological experts, it is more expensive. This is the price to be paid for quantification;

  4. (iv) uses a lot of information already available in EIA;

  5. (v) linked to international classifications and lists of scarcity and therefore objective and independent and useful for international comparisons.

There are also various clear limitations:

  1. (i) the biodiversity points measured generally pertain to one specific year and not to the whole period of the CBA;Footnote 10 this is a limitation if the impact is not the same for the whole period.

  2. (ii) shows linear relationships, for example, biodiversity points of 2 hectare of an ecotope is two times 1 hectare and no threshold or minimum size required; this is a limitation as in ecology many relationships are nonlinear.

  3. (iii) In calculating biodiversity points, perfect substitution is assumed between the size of the area, ecological quality, and ecological scarcity; this is a limitation as substitution will often be quite imperfect according to ecological experts.

  4. (iv) no other criteria are used for assessing biodiversity; according to ecological experts, information like the number of birds or fish per speciesFootnote 11 may also be important to assess biodiversity.

  5. (v) different methods of operationalization are possible, by choosing somewhat different ecotypes or species.Footnote 12

  6. (vi) the applicability of biodiversity points differs per type of biotope. It is more difficult for water quality-related biodiversity than for land biodiversity, as the impact area is larger and the impacts are more difficult to define (Bos et al., Reference Bos, Zwaneveld and Puijenbroek2012; Bos & Ruijs, Reference Bos and Ruijs2019).

  7. (vii) expert opinions on scarcity are used, not a valuation reflecting preferences of individual citizens. As a consequence, biodiversity points are in particular suited for measuring the non-use value of biodiversity.

If the focus of the study is on the biodiversity impacts of a change, biodiversity points may not provide sufficient information for decision-making. Yet, as it summarizes all biodiversity information in one number, it makes it a very useful method in CEA.

The biodiversity points method is a practical method for measuring the non-use value of all kinds of biodiversity. It is ready for international application in CBA. During the past decade, the biodiversity points method has been applied to dozens of case studies in a wide range of contexts in the Netherlands. Various articles on the biodiversity points method and these case studies have been published in international journals and books on ecology and land use (Strijker et al., Reference Strijker, Sijtsma and Wiersma2000; Sijtsma et al., Reference Sijtsma, van der Heide, van Hinsberg, Hull, Alexander, Khakee and Woltjer2011, Reference Sijtsma, van der Heide and van Hinsberg2013, Reference Sijtsma, van der Veen, van Hinsberg, Pouwels, Bekker, van Dijk, Grutters, Klaassen, Krijn, Mouissie and Wymenga2020; van Puijenbroek et al., Reference van Puijenbroek, Sijtsma, Wortelboer, Ligtvoet and Maarse2015), and various other papers are available in English (Liefveld et al., Reference Liefveld, Didderen, Lengkeek, Japink, Bouma and Visser2011; van Oostenbrugge et al., Reference van Oostenbrugge, Slijkerman, Hamon, Bos, Machiels, van de Valk, Hintzen, Bos, van der Wal and Coolen2015; Spaans, Reference Spaans2020) and have been presented internationally. Some translations of Dutch guidelines and case studies are also forthcoming.

Footnotes

1 Earlier drafts of this paper (Bos & Ruijs, Reference Bos and Ruijs2018, Reference Bos and Ruijs2019) were presented at the 10th BCA-Conference (Washington, March 15–16, 2018) and the 21st BIOECON-Conference (Wageningen, September 11–13, 2019). The authors would like to thank Bahman Kashi, Jeroen Klooster, Carl Koopmans, Steve Newbold, Rolf Groeneveld, Shiri Zemah Shamir, Frans Sijtsma, David Weimer, Gerbert Romijn, Gusta Renes, Sonja Kruitwagen, Ton Manders, Rob Aalbers, Bernadette Botman, Manon Spaans, Rob van der Veeren, and Arjen van Hinsberg for their comments.

2 See for example, World Bank (2010), the Asian Development Bank (2013), the USA Benefit–Cost Centre (Zerbe et al., Reference Zerbe, Davis, Garland and Scott2010), the UK Greenbook (HM Treasury, Reference Treasury2011), and the EU CBA guidelines for investment in infrastructure financed by the cohesion funds (European Commission, 2014).

3 For more than a century, CBA is used to support decision-making on public investments in the Netherlands, see Bos and Zwaneveld (Reference Bos and Zwaneveld2017) and Bos (Reference Bos2008).

4 Act on environmental impact assessment, Directive 85/337 EEC.

5 Recently, also the discount rates to be used in Dutch CBAs have been changed. In 2016, it was decided to reduce the official discount rate from 5.5 to 3 %. For nature, an annual relative price increase of 1 % is prescribed (Werkgroep Discontovoet, 2015; Koetse et al., Reference Koetse, Renes, Ruijs and de Leeuw2018). As a consequence, the net effect for nature is a discount rate of 2 %.

6 A CEA is a CBA in which a specific purpose, like a target for extra transport capacity on a road, a water safety norm, an emission goal or a nature policy standard. It is defined in advance and only the net benefits of policy proposals that meet this purpose are compared. The distinctive feature of CEA is that the costs and benefits of meeting the specific purpose are ignored.However, if one of the policy alternatives scores better than the target for the specific purpose, these extra benefits of this policy alternative should also be included in the CEA. Furthermore, in case the net benefits of meeting a specific targeted purpose may be clearly negative, it is often wise not to take this purpose for granted and to conducting a full CBA, i.e. including the costs and benefits of meeting that specific purpose.

7 Reference lists of “species pursued” have been prepared for monitoring the Dutch nature policies and contain the pursued biotic and abiotic characteristics of each nature type. Using the reference lists, for each nature area measurable objectives can be set and monitored. They provide the basis for conservation planning and management and national and European nature policies.

8 The willingness to pay was calculated as 5 euro per household per year times the local impact population. The 5 euro was an arbitrary value with no clear link to the three major previous studies on peatland in the Netherlands; information from the latter studies was also not applicable, as the project and situation were quite different.

10 So, preferably the average of the whole period should be taken; even some discounting may be considered (Koetse et al., Reference Koetse, Renes, Ruijs and de Leeuw2018).

11 Such other criteria can be added to the basic formulae of the biodiversity points (Fiselier & Botman, Reference Fiselier and Botman2020; Rijkswaterstaat, 2020). However, this makes the method less simple.

12 This can be partly resolved by guidelines on this (see Jaspers et al., Reference Jaspers, Mouissie, Wessels, Barke, Kolen and Bucholc2016; Rijkswaterstaat, 2020).

References

Annema, J. A., and Koopmans, C.. 2015. “The Practice of Valuing the Environment in Cost-Benefit Analyses in Transport and Spatial Projects.” Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 58: 16351648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asian Development Bank. 2013. “Cost-Benefit Analysis for Development: A Practical Guide.” Mandaluyong City, Philippines.Google Scholar
Atkinson, G., and Mourato, S.. 2008. “Environmental Cost-Benefit Analysis.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 33(1): 317344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartkowski, B., Lienhoop, N., and Hansjürgens, B.. 2015. “Capturing the Complexity of Biodiversity: A Critical Review of Economic Valuation Studies of Biological Diversity.” Ecological Economics, 113: 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boardman, A. E., Greenberg, D. H., Vining, A. R., and Weimer, D. L.. 2006. Cost-Benefit Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 3rd edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson.Google Scholar
Bos, F. 2008. “The Dutch Fiscal Framework; History, Current Practice and the Role of the Central Planning Bureau.” OECD Journal on Budgeting, 8(1): 748.Google Scholar
Bos, F., and Ruijs, A.. 2018. How to Account for the Impact on Nature in CBA Practice? Five Case Studies from the Netherlands, Paper Presented at the 10th BCA-Conference, Washington, March 15–16, 2018.Google Scholar
Bos, F., and Ruijs, A.. 2019. Biodiversity in the Dutch Practice of Cost-Benefit Analysis, CPB Background Document.Google Scholar
Bos, F., and Zwaneveld, P.. 2017. Cost-Benefit Analysis for Flood Risk Management and Water Governance in the Netherlands: An Overview of One Century. The Hague, The Netherlands: CPB Background Document August 2017, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis.Google Scholar
Bos, F., Zwaneveld, P., and Puijenbroek, P.. 2012. Een snelle kosten-effectiviteitanalyse voor het Deltaprogramma IJsselmeergebied, CPB Background Document.Google Scholar
Boyd, J., and Banzhaf, S.. 2007. “What Are Ecosystem Services? The Need for Standardized Environmental Accounting Units.” Ecological Economics, 63: 616626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, J., Ringold, P., Krupnick, A., Johnston, R. J., Weber, M. A., and Hall, K.. 2014. “Ecosystem Services Indicators: Improving the Linkages Between Biophysical and Economic Analyses.” International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 8: 359443.Google Scholar
Cardinale, B. J., Duffy, J. E., Gonzalez, A., Hooper, D. U., Perrings, C., Venail, P., Narwani, A., Mace, G. M., Tilman, D., Wardle, D. A., Kinzig, A. P., Daily, G. C., Loreau, M., Grace, J. B., Larigauderie, A., Srivastava, D. S., and Naeem, S.. 2012. “Biodiversity Loss and Its Impact on Humanity.” Nature, 486: 5967.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD). 2004. Decision VII/30.Google Scholar
Ebregt, J., Eijgenraam, C. J. J., and Stolwijk, H. J. J.. 2005. Kosteneffectiviteit van maatregelen en pakketten – kosten-baten analyse voor Ruimte voor de Rivier, deel 2 (Cost-effectiveness of measures and packages – cost-benefit analysis for More Room for Rivers, Part 2), CPB document 83, The Hague, The Netherlands.Google Scholar
Eijgenraam, C. J. J., Koopmans, C. C., Tang, P. J. G., and Verster, A. C. P.. 2000. Evaluatie van infrastructuurprojecten; leidraad voor Kosten-batenanalyse, Deel I. The Hague, The Netherlands: Hoofdrapport Onderzoeksprogramma Economische Effecten Infrastructuur.Google Scholar
European Commission. 1992. Council Directive 92/43/EEC of 21 May 1992 on the Conservation of Natural Habitats and of Wild Fauna and Flora.Google Scholar
European Commission. 2014. Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis of Investment Project; Economic Appraisal Tool for Cohesion Policy 2014-2020.Google Scholar
European Environment Agency. 2012. Streamlining European biodiversity indicators 2020: Building a future on lessons learnt from the SEBI 2010 process. Available at: https://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/streamlining-european-biodiversity-indicators-2020. (accessed November 4, 2020).Google Scholar
Fiselier, J., and Botman, B.. 2020. Pilot Grevelingen Natuurlijk Kapitaal, Ecosysteemdiensten en Biodiversiteit. Report by Royal Haskoning DHV and B2 Consultancy.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. M. III, Herriges, J. A., and Kling, C. L.. 2014. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values, 3rd edition. New York: RFF Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grevers, W., and Zwaneveld, P.. 2011. Een kosten-effectiviteitsanalyse naar de toekomstige inrichting van de Afsluitdijk. The Hague, The Netherlands: CPB.Google Scholar
Isbell, F., Gonzalez, A., Loreau, M., Cowles, J., Díaz, S., Hector, A., Mace, G., Wardle, D. A., and O’Connor, M. I., Duffy, J. E., Turnbull, L. A., Thompson, P. L., and Larigauderie, A.. 2017. “Linking the Influence and Dependence of People on Biodiversity Across Scales.” Nature, 546: 6572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaspers, C. J., Mouissie, M., Wessels, S., Barke, J., Kolen, M., and Bucholc, A.. 2016. Natuurpuntensysteem voor uniforme waardering van natuur-kwaliteit. Houten, The Netherlands: SWECO Nederland.Google Scholar
Johnston, R. J., Boyle, K. J., Adamowicz, W., Bennett, J., Brouwer, R., Cameron, T. A., Hanemann, W. M., Hanley, N., Ryan, M., Scarpa, R., Tourangeau, R., and Vossler, C. A. 2017. “Contemporary Guidance for Stated Preference Studies .Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 4(2): 319405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klooster, J., Warringa, G., and Ohm, J.. 2018. Werkwijzer Natuur: Maatschappelijke Kosten-Baten Analyses. CE Delft, The Netherlands: Arcadis.Google Scholar
Koetse, M. J., Renes, G., Ruijs, A., and de Leeuw, A. J.. 2018. Relative Price Increase for Nature and Ecosystem Services in Cost-Benefit Analysis. The Hague, The Netherlands: PBL Background Study.Google Scholar
Laurans, Y., Rankovic, A., Billé, R., Pirard, R., and Mermet, L.. 2013. “Use of Ecosystem Services Economic Valuation for Decision Making: Questioning a Literature Blindspot.” Journal of Environmental Management, 119: 208219.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lely, C. 1901. Ontwerp van wet tot afsluiting en droogmaking van de Zuiderzee met toelichtende memorie, Text downloadable via www.gutenberg.org, eBook 36317.Google Scholar
Liefveld, W. M., Didderen, K., Lengkeek, W., Japink, M., Bouma, S., and Visser, M. M.. 2011. Evaluating Biodiversity of the North Sea Using Eco-points; Testing the Applicability for European Marine Strategy Framework Directive (MSFD) Assessments, Bureau Waardenburg Consultants for Environment & Ecology. Report on Request of the Dutch Ministry of Infrastructure and Water Management. Google Scholar
Markandya, A. 2016. Cost-benefit Analysis and the Environment: How to Best Cover Impacts on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services, OECD Working Papers 101, Paris, France: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J., and Quah, E.. 2007. Cost-Benefit Analysis. 5th edition. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
NEI and RIN. 1978. Een haven op het Balgzand? Een economische en ecologische afweging van de voor- en nadelen van een beperkte zeehavenontwikkeling ten behoeve van Den Helder. Rotterdam, The Netherlands: Rijksinstituut voor Natuurbeheer, Nederlands Economisch Instituut.Google Scholar
OECD. 2006. Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Environment: Recent Developments. Paris, France: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
OECD. 2018. Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Environment: Further Developments and Policy Use. Paris, France: OECD Publishing. Report by Atkinson, G., Braathen, N. A., Groom, B., and Mourata, S. Google Scholar
Ray, G. L. 2008. Habitat Equivalency Analysis: A Potential Tool for Estimating Environmental Benefits. Vicksburg, MS: U.S. Army Engineer Research and Development Center. http://www.dtic.mil/cgibin/GetTRDoc?AD=ADA475708&Location=U2&doc=GetTRDoc.pdf Google Scholar
Rijkswaterstaat. 2020. Handreiking natuurlijk kapitaal en ecosysteemdiensten grote wateren. Royal HaskoningDHV and B2consultancy.Google Scholar
Roach, B., and Wade, W. W.. 2006. “Policy Evaluation of Natural Resource Injuries Using Habitat Equivalency Analysis.” Ecological Economics, 58(2): 421433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romijn, G., and Renes, G.. 2013. General Guidance for Cost-Benefit Analysis. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis / PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency . The Hague, The Netherlands. Available at https://www.pbl.nl/sites/default/files/downloads/pbl-cpb-2015-general-guidance-for-cost-benefit-analysis_01512.pdf. (accessed November 4, 2020).Google Scholar
Ruijgrok, E. C. M., Brouwer, R., and Verbruggen, H.. 2004. Waardering van Natuur, Water en Bodem in Maatschappelijke Kosten-batenanalyses, Aanvulling op de Leidraad OEI, In opdracht van het ministerie van Landbouw, Natuur en Voedselkwaliteit, in samenwerking met de ministeries van Verkeer en Waterstaat, Economische Zaken, Financiën en VROM.Google Scholar
Saitua, R. 2004. Verruiming van de vaarweg van de Schelde; een maatschappelijke kosten-batenanalyse. The Hague, The Netherlands: CPB, VITO.Google Scholar
Schaefer, M., Goldman, E., Bartuska, A. M., Sutton-Grier, A., and Lubchenco, J.. 2015. “Nature as Capital: Advancing and Incorporating Ecosystem Services in United States Federal Policies and Programs.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112(24): 73837389.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sijtsma, F. J. 2006. “Project Evaluation, Sustainability and Accountability – Combining Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA) and Multi-Criteria Analysis (MCA).” PhD Thesis, University of Groningen. Stichting REG, nr 27. Groningen. http://dissertations.ub.rug.nl/faculties/eco/2006/f.j.sytsma/.Google Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., Farjon, H., van Tol, S., van Hinsberg, A., van Kampen, P., and Buijs, A.. 2013. “Evaluation of Landscape Changes – Enriching the Economist’s Toolbox with the Hotspot Index.” In The Economic Value of Landscapes, edited by Heijman, W., and van der Heide, C. M. J., 136164. London, UK: Routledge.Google Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., van der Heide, C. M., and van Hinsberg, A.. 2011. “Biodiversity and Decision-support: Integrating CBA and MCA.” In Evaluation for Participation and Sustainability in Planning. Chapter 9, edited by Hull, A., Alexander, E., Khakee, A., and Woltjer, J., 197218. London, UK: Routledge.Google Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., van der Heide, C. M., and van Hinsberg, A.. 2013. “Beyond Monetary Measurement: How to Evaluate Projects and Policies Using the Ecosystem Services Framework.” Environmental Science & Policy, 32: 1425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., van der Veen, E., van Hinsberg, A., Pouwels, R., Bekker, R., van Dijk, R. E., Grutters, M., Klaassen, R., Krijn, M., Mouissie, M., and Wymenga, E.. 2020. Ecological Impact and Cost-effectiveness of Wildlife Crossings in a Highly Fragmented Landscape: A Multi-method Approach, Landscape Ecology (Forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., van der Veen, E., van Hinsberg, A., Pouwels, R., Wymenga, E., Krijn, M., Klaassen, R., Mouissie, M., Grutters, M., van Dijk, R., Wackwitz, E., and Kisjes, K.. 2018. Analyse van kosten en baten van het Meerjarenprogramma Ontsnippering (MJPO), Report by the University Groningen, Faculty of Spatial Sciences.Google Scholar
Sijtsma, F. J., van Hinsberg, A. V., Kruitwagen, S., and Dietz, F.. 2009. Natuureffecten in de MKBA’s van projecten voor integrale gebiedsontwikkeling. Den Haag, The Netherlands: PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency.Google Scholar
Spaans, M. 2020. “Marine Protected Areas in the Europe; An Assessment of the Current Status and the Representation of Benefits in Socio-economic Analyses in Order to Support Decision-making, Dutch Ministry of Infrastructure and Water Management.” Paper Presented at the OSPAR Meeting June 2020.Google Scholar
Stolwijk, H., and Verrips, A.. 2000. Ruimte voor water; kosten en baten van zes projecten en enige alternatieven, CPB Werkdocument 130.Google Scholar
Strijker, D., Sijtsma, F. J., and Wiersma, D.. 2000. “Evaluation of Nature Conservation – An Application to the Dutch Ecological Network.” Environmental and Resource Economics, 16(4): 363373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
TEEB. 2010. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Mainstreaming the Economics of Nature: A Synthesis of the Approach, Conclusions and Recommendations of TEEB. Bonn, Germany: TEEB.Google Scholar
TEEB. 2013. A Synthesis of Approaches to Assess and Value Ecosystem Services in the EU in the Context of TEEB, TEEB Follow-up Study for Europe, edited by Brouwer, R., Brander, L., Kuik, O., Papyrakis, E. and Bateman, I.. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: VU, University of Amsterdam, Institute for Environmental Studies.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, J. 1953. De economische balans van het Deltaplan (Annex to the report of the Deltacommission).Google Scholar
Treasury, H. M. 2011. The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government Treasury Guidance. London, UK: TSO.Google Scholar
USEPA. 2014. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. Available at: https://www.epa.gov/environmental-economics/guidelines-preparing-economic-analyses. (accessed November 4, 2020).Google Scholar
van Gaalen, F., van Hinsberg, A., Franken, R., Vonk, M., van Puijenbroek, P., and Wortelboer, R.. 2014. Natuurpunten: kwantificering van effecten op natuurlijke ecosystemen en biodiversiteit in het Deltaprogramma, PBL Background Paper.Google Scholar
van Oostenbrugge, H., Slijkerman, D., Hamon, K., Bos, O., Machiels, M., van de Valk, O., Hintzen, N., Bos, E., van der Wal, J., and Coolen, J.. 2015. Effects of Seabed Protection on the Frisian Front and Central Oyster Grounds; A Cost Benefit Analysis, LEI Wageningen and IMARES, Report on Request of the Dutch Ministry of Infrastructure and Water Management. Google Scholar
van Puijenbroek, P. J. T. M., Sijtsma, F. J., Wortelboer, F. G., Ligtvoet, W., and Maarse, M.. 2015. “Towards Standardised Evaluative Measurement of Nature Impacts: Two Spatial Planning Case Studies for Major Dutch Lakes.” Environmental Science and Pollution Research, 22(4): 24672478.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wende, W., Tucker, G. M., Quétier, F., Rayment, M., and Darbi, M. (eds.). 2018. Biodiversity Offsets:European Perspectives on No Less Loss of Biodiversity Loss and Ecosystem Services. Cham, Switzerland: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werkgroep Discontovoet. 2015. Rapport van de Werkgroep Discontovoet 2015.Google Scholar
Wessels, S., Jaspers, H., Wortelboer, R., van Puijenbroek, P., Zwaneveld, P., Grevers, W., and Sijtsma, F.. 2011. Natuurpunten voor de Afsluitdijk, Toets, Kennisplatform over Milieueffectrapportage, 3: 28.Google Scholar
Witteveen, & Bos, . 2006. Kentallen Waardering Natuur, Water, Bodem en Landschap; hulpmiddel bij MKBA’s, Ministerie van LNV.Google Scholar
Witteveen, & Bos, , and Arcadis, . 2006. CBA daling grondwater veengebieden.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2010. Cost-benefit Analysis in World Bank Projects.Google Scholar
Zerbe, R., Davis, T. B., Garland, N., and Scott, T.. 2010. Towards Principles and Standards in the Use of Benefit-Cost Analysis; A Summary of Work, Report by the Benefit-Cost Analysis Center.Google Scholar
Zwaneveld, P., Grevers, W., Eijgenraam, C., van der Meulen, Y., Pluut, Z., Hoefsloot, N., and de Pater, M.. 2012. “De kosten en baten van de Toekomst van de Afsluitdijk; Economisch onderzoek, gebruik daarvan en invloed op het uiteindelijke kabinetsbesluit.” Water Governance, 2(2): 2334.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 A CEA of four projects in the lower river region for increasing safety (Stolwijk & Verrips, 2000, table 8, p. 55).

Figure 1

Table 2 Results from a full CBA and a CBA presenting biodiversity points separately.

Figure 2

Table 3 Extra lanes for the highway Schiphol–Amsterdam–Almere on the nature reserve Naardermeer, impact in terms of biodiversity points for four project alternatives.

Figure 3

Table 4 Habitats surrounding the Afsluitdijk (Wessels et al., 2011).

Figure 4

Table 5 Renovating the enclosure dam: cost-effectiveness of various options for extra biodiversity (see Wessels et al., 2011).

Figure 5

Table 6 CEA meta-study on infrastructure defragmentation (Sijtsma et al., 2018, 2020).