Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-grxwn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T06:39:58.323Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Do Better Committee Assignments Meaningfully Benefit Legislators? Evidence from a Randomized Experiment in the Arkansas State Legislature

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 March 2015

David E. Broockman
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of California, Berkeley, 210 Barrows Hall, Berkeley, CA 94720, USA; e-mail: broockman@berkeley.edu
Daniel M. Butler
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis, Campus Box 1063, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130-4899, USA; e-mail: daniel.butler@wustl.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

A large literature argues that the committee assignment process plays an important role in shaping legislative politics because some committees provide legislators with substantial benefits. However, evaluating the degree to which legislators benefit from winning their preferred assignments has been challenging with existing data. This paper sheds light on the benefits legislators accrue from winning their preferred committee assignments by exploiting rules in Arkansas’ state legislature, where legislators select their own committee assignments in a randomized order. The natural experiment indicates that legislators reap at most limited rewards from winning their preferred assignments. These results potentially raise questions about the robustness of widely held assumptions in literatures on party discipline and legislative organization.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Experimental Research Section of the American Political Science Association 2015 

Scholars have long argued that legislators gain appreciable advantages from serving on their preferred committees. Fenno (Reference Fenno1973) first identified legislators’ three main goals—achieving re-election, crafting good public policy, and securing influence in their chamber—and argued that committee memberships can help legislators achieve all of them. Scholars since Fenno have consistently found empirical evidence that legislators who receive their preferred committee assignments are more likely to win re-election (Bullock Reference Bullock1976; Crain and Sullivan Reference Crain and Sullivan1997; Fowler et al. Reference Fowler, Douglass and Clark1980; Heberlig Reference Heberlig2003; Katz and Sala Reference Katz and Sala1996; Maltzman Reference Maltzman1997; Milyo Reference Milyo1997; Shepsle Reference Shepsle1978; Smith and Deering Reference Smith and Deering1983).Footnote 1 Scholars have also argued that valuable committee assignments help legislators gain prestige and power among their colleagues as they vie for leadership positions (Fenno Reference Fenno1973; Manley Reference Manley1970; Shepsle Reference Shepsle1978), and raise more money (Dow et al. Reference Dow, Endersby and Menifield1998; Grier and Munger Reference Grier and Munger1991; Grier and Munger Reference Grier and Munger1993; Milyo Reference Milyo1997; Romer and Snyder Reference Romer and Snyder1994). While the benefits of committee assignments have been primarily studied in Congress, similar patterns have been found in state legislatures (e.g., Hedlund and Patterson 1992; Kanthak Reference Kanthak2009). Numerous scholars thus argue that membership on certain committees is instrumental in legislators’ attempts to attain re-election, achieve their policy goals, and gain influence among their colleagues.

The existence and magnitude of these advantages is important to understand for several reasons. Most importantly, leading theories of legislative politics argue that control over committee assignments is a key tool party leaders use to discipline legislators (e.g., Coker and Crain Reference Coker and Crain1994; Cox and McCubbins Reference Cox and McCubbins1993; Crook and Hibbing Reference Crook and Hibbing1985; Kanthak Reference Kanthak2004; Roberts and Smith Reference Roberts and Smith2003; Rohde and Shepsle Reference Rohde and Shepsle1973; Sinclair Reference Sinclair1995; Stratmann Reference Stratmann2000). However, endogeneity may confound existing work investigating the impacts of committee assignments on legislators’ careers: if party leaders tend to systematically place some legislators on more desirable committees, observational differences between legislators across committees may be biased estimates of the causal effect of committee membership (although see Grimmer and Powell Reference Grimmer and Powell2013).

We add to the growing literature using randomized experiments to study legislative politicsFootnote 2 with novel evidence on the causal effects of winning preferred committee assignments on legislators’ careers from the Arkansas state legislature. In Arkansas, parties play no role in making standing committee assignments; instead, legislators choose their own assignments in the order of their seniority. Crucially, for legislators who have served the same length of time, this seniority order is determined by a random lottery. Some legislators are thus randomly assigned to have a better opportunity to select their preferred assignments, a situation equivalent to randomly assigning party leaders’ intention to reward some members with access to their most preferred committee assignments and consign others to their least preferred assignments.

We exploit this randomized lottery to test whether legislators who have a more complete and higher quality slate of committee assignments to choose from gain appreciable benefits over those who are forced to accept the assignments no other legislators want. We find no evidence that legislators are more likely to attain their principal goals as a result of attaining their preferred assignments.

THE RANDOMIZED COMMITTEE LOTTERY IN ARKANSAS

The random assignment of Arkansas legislators in the committee assignment process occurs as follows. Each legislator in Arkansas’ two state legislative chambers has a seniority number, and legislators choose their own standing committee assignments in the order of this seniority number.Footnote 3 This seniority number is first determined by how long a member has served in the chamber, with the lowest numbers (and thus the first choice of committee assignments) going to those who have served longest. Crucially, however, the seniority number of legislators who have served the same length of time is randomly determined: before their first term, legislators draw numbers written on slips of paper out of a hat to determine their seniority within their freshman class. Their relative seniority within their cohort stays with them for the remainder of their time in the legislature.

Although legislators’ seniority is randomized across their entire cohort, committee assignments in the House are allotted within four separate ‘‘caucus districts’’ corresponding to the four congressional districts in Arkansas. Because only a certain pre-set number of legislators from each caucus district can sit on each committee, House members only compete with legislators in their caucus district for committee seats.

Legislators thus choose their committees in a fully randomly assigned order only within chamber-cohort-caucus groupings. We therefore compute a metric Relative Rank to capture legislators’ relative seniority of legislators within these fully randomized groupings. This Relative Rank metric gives the percentile ranking of each legislator's lottery number relative to the legislators in their year-chamber-cohort-caucus district on a 0 to 1 scale. Legislators assigned to 1 are the most senior in their year-chamber-cohort-caucus district group (and thus can select the best committee assignment available to those in their caucus district elected at the same time) and legislators with a 0 are the least senior. Likewise, a Relative Rank value of 0.5 would mean that the legislator is at the 50th percentile and chooses in the middle of her group.

To illustrate how Relative Rank is determined, Table 1 presents a fictional 25-member Arkansas House populated with legislators in their first or second term. Note that all legislators in their first term have lower seniority numbers than the legislators in their second term, shown in part (a). The resulting Relative Rank metric is shown for our fictional legislature in part (b). Legislators are arranged in groups by their cohort and caucus district and then sorted by their randomized seniority number within these groups because legislators pick their own assignments in direct succession within these groups. Thus, for example, within caucus district A, legislator 4 would pick first, followed by legislator 6 and 11. Once the senior members finish picking, legislators 14, 15, 18, and 23 would then pick the remainder of the assignments allocated to district A.

Table 1 Hypothetical Example of how Relative Rank is Computed

Notes: This table illustrates how Relative Rank is calculated using a hypothetical 25-member Arkansas House populated with legislators who were either just elected or are serving their second term.

In summary, we use legislators’ Relative Rank as our independent variable and analyze its effects within the fully exchangeable legislators who share the same chamber-cohort-caucus district. Note that, as a result, we do not analyze only one experiment; instead, we pool the results from a series of many smaller experiments, one in each year-chamber-cohort-caucus district group (see Table 1). For this reason, we also drop legislators who have no peers in their cohort and caucus district (such as legislator 13 in Table 1) from the analysis; these legislators have no counterfactual peers for comparison. We account for this pooling across the year-chamber-cohort-caucus district groups by including fixed effects for these groups in the analysis.

CONTRASTING RELATIVE RANK AND TYPICAL MEASURES OF LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ASSIGNMENT QUALITY

One may wonder why a committee assignment lottery in the Arkansas legislature would provide useful data for broader theories of legislative organization. Box 1 compares the determinants of the committee assignment process in Arkansas to the process elsewhere in order to illustrate the benefits of studying this question in the Arkansas context.

Box 1 The Benefits of Using Arkansas to Study the Effects of Committees

In most other legislatures, party leaders are thought to hold some legislators in higher regard than others as a result of their service and loyalty to the party. This regard cannot be measured directly and is sometimes proxied with party unity scores (e.g., Cox and McCubbins Reference Cox and McCubbins2005). Moreover, party leader regard and strategy is also endogenous to other aspects of the legislators’ career that might influence their assignment choices and legislators’ behavior, such as the safeness of legislators’ seats.

Unlike the regard party leaders have for legislators, this first stage of the assignment process (Relative Rank) is both exogenous and directly measurable in Arkansas. Although there are undoubtedly other factors that influence whether legislators achieve their goals, these factors will be uncorrelated with the assignment mechanism in our data—the randomized lottery—whereas in traditional data they may be highly correlated with the assignment mechanism—the strategic decisions party leaders make. Moreover, although party leader regard cannot be measured in other legislatures, we can observe legislators’ Relative Rank directly.

In neither Arkansas nor in other legislatures can we directly measure the desirability of each committee to each legislator. However, as with other studies, we are not ultimately interested in the average effects of legislators being assigned to particular committees; we are interested in the effect of legislators’ ability to win the assignments they want.Footnote 4 Because a chance to choose one's own assignment is randomly determined in Arkansas, we can measure the impact of legislators having a better chance of getting their preferred assignments (the first stage of the process) directly on their outcomes. This makes increases in Relative Rank similar to hypothetical exogenous increases in party leader regard we would ideally deliver in other legislatures.

ADDITIONAL CHECKS: THE DESIRABILITY OF COMMITTEES AND PRE-TREATMENT BALANCE

Although our statistical model does not rely upon measures of each committee's desirability to each legislator, the Appendix verifies that committees in Arkansas are at least meaningfully heterogeneous in their desirability to legislators (see especially Figures A1 and A2 in the supplementary Appendix).

Table 2 also presents a balance check on whether the legislator's partisanship or characteristics of their districtsFootnote 5 predict either the relative rank metric or legislators’ original seniority numbers. In both cases, the pre-treatment covariates do not predict legislators’ treatment status. This gives us additional confidence that the randomization was successful and no other confounding factors lead some legislators to gain their preferred committee assignments within chamber-cohort-caucus district groupings.

Table 2 Balance of Covariates across Relative Rank and Seniority Score

Notes: In the first column, the dependent variable is the scaled random seniority rank of each legislator within their caucus district. The variable ranges from 0 to 1, with legislators assigned to 1 as the most senior. In the second column, dependent variable is the seniority rank of each legislator within their caucus district. The variable ranges from 1 to 100 in the House and 1 to 35 in the Senate, with legislators assigned to 1 as the most senior. No results are significant at the 0.10 level.

DATA AND DEPENDENT VARIABLES

Our analysis uses 2,173 legislator-term observations from the period 1977–2011.Footnote 6 We analyze thirteen dependent variables related to three aspects of legislators’ careers and goals: legislators’ electoral success, chamber leadership, and policy productivity.

For electoral goals, we used data from Carsey et al. (Reference Carsey, Berry, Niemi, Powell and Snyder2007) and the Arkansas Secretary of State's website on whether each legislator won re-election, lost their primary re-election, lost their general re-election, ran for or won higher office, retired, was opposed in the general election, and was opposed in the primary election, as well as their general and primary election vote shares. We collected the amount of campaign money that each incumbent raised from www.followthemoney.org.

For chamber leadership, we collected data from the Arkansas Legislative Digest on whether legislators served in party or chamber leadership.

Policy productivity variables were only available for the years 2005–2008. For those years we collected data from the Arkansas Legislative Digest on the number of bills legislators filed and the number of bills they passed, a metric many other scholars have used to measure policy productivity and effectiveness.

Last, we used members’ roll call votes from 1997–2010 to measure the percentage of the time they vote with their party on roll calls where the majority of Democrats opposed the majority of Republicans (Party Unity); and the percentage of the time they vote with their party on roll calls where the majority of Democrats opposed the majority of Republicans and their party lost the vote, i.e., when the majority of their party is rolled (Party Unity (Losing Votes)).

RESULTS: ARE COMMITTEE ASSIGNMENTS VALUABLE TO LEGISLATORS?

Table 3 presents the estimated benefits that legislators gain from obtaining their preferred committee assignments. In all the regressions the independent variable is Relative Rank, the scaled randomized seniority of legislators within their year-chamber-cohort-caucus district that allows them to pick from a much larger and more desirable set of committees. Because Relative Rank varies from 0 to 1, the coefficient on this variable indicates the estimated difference between the most and least senior member within each cohort—that is, between the cohort members who have the most and least choice in their assignments. These limiting cases are roughly analogous to the situations in which a hypothetical party leader wished to reward a loyal legislator with the best available committee assignment that more senior members had not already taken or, alternatively, consign a disloyal one to the last remaining assignment after all others legislators’ wishes were granted.Footnote 7

Table 3 Effect of Seniority within Cohort (Relative Rank) on Outcomes of Interest (OLS)

Notes: Fixed effects refer to the groups in which the randomization takes place (i.e., for each year-chamber-cohort-caucus district group). The independent variable for all regressions, relative rank, is the scaled random seniority rank of each legislator within their randomization group. The variable ranges from 0 to 1, with legislators assigned to 1 as the most senior. Coefficients represent the estimated effects of being the most senior member instead of the least senior member. No outcomes are significant at the 0.10 level. Ns differ in regressions with dependent variables for which data is not available for all years.

The dependent variables, each described in the previous section, are listed under each of the headings in Table 3. For each outcome, we present the results from a regression without any fixed effects and the results from a regression with fixed effects for year-chamber-cohort-caucus district (i.e., the groups within which the randomizations occur). Table 3 shows that legislators’ relative rank does not have a statistically significant effect on any measures of their election outcomes. Legislators who have their pick of committee assignments are not meaningfully more likely to win their primary or general election bids, raise campaign money, run for or win for higher office, deter opponents, or increase their vote share. We also find that legislators are no more likely to write nor pass bills as a result of their seniority. Further seniority does not affect legislators’ probability of becoming a party leader, nor how they vote.Footnote 8

In their totality, the results are consistent across outcomes and highly surprising in light of decades of relatively unchallenged conventional wisdom about the benefits legislators accrue from winning their preferred committee assignments. We find no statistically significant effects for a legislators’ seniority on the outcomes of interest we identified (with a generous threshold of p < 0.10). Further, our estimates are based on a large number of observations and have substantively small standard errors. For example, the 95% confidence interval for the estimate of the decreased probability that a legislator loses a general election because of their seniority extends only to 1.2 percentage points.Footnote 9

EXTERNAL VALIDITY

As with any data in the social sciences, results from this one setting are ultimately not dispositive about other contexts. For example, Arkansas implemented legislative term limits in the 1990s, which may have decreased the value of committees.Footnote 10 Similarly, one party dominated Arkansas for most of the time period under study, possibly decreasing the need for members of the majority party to secure benefits from their committee assignments.

Despite these differences, there are many ways in which the Arkansas legislature is similar to other legislatures. For example, the majority party in Arkansas exercises power that is comparable to the level of power enjoyed in other states (Anzia and Jackman Reference Anzia and Jackman2013). Similarly, committees have sole jurisdiction over large policy areas, supervise regulatory agencies, are responsible for doling out substantial sums of state money, and are de facto veto points for legislation in their jurisdiction. The committees and parties in the Arkansas legislature are similar enough to those in other legislatures that scholars should take interest in these results and consider revisiting the importance of committee assignments to legislators’ career goals. That committee assignments have large effects on legislators’ careers is a central assumption in many theories of party discipline and legislative organization, but most existing studies are unable to identify the causal effect of assignments on legislators’ success. At least in Arkansas, where persuasive causal identification is possible, legislators appear to reap at most relatively minor benefits from winning their preferred committee assignments.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIALS

For supplementary material for this article, please visit Cambridge Journals Online http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/XPS.2014.30.

Footnotes

1 We know of only a few studies in the large literature on committee assignments that have suggested the benefits to legislators are limited (Bullock Reference Bullock1972; Hogan Reference Hogan2004).

2 E.g., Kellerman and Shepsle 2009, Rogowski and Sinclair Reference Rogowski and Sinclair2012, Grimmer and Powell Reference Grimmer and Powell2013, Grose Reference Grose2014.

3 Legislators serve on two standing committees. Legislators choose their first committee in the order of seniority and then choose their second committee in the same order. As Supplementary Figure 1 in the online appendix shows and we discuss, this arrangement leads to significant heterogeneity in the quality of legislators’ committee assignments, with legislators choosing first systematically serving on different committees from those who choose later in the process.

4 This distinction is important because different committees may have different values to different legislators. For example, legislators from rural districts may accrue greater benefits from being placed on the Agriculture committee than legislators from urban districts.

5 Unfortunately, the US Census only began providing this legislative district level data beginning with the 2000 Census. However, the seniority selection process has remained the same throughout the past several decades, so we do not expect that our results would have differed if we had access to such data for previous decades.

6 There are 2,431 legislator-term observations during this period. However, only 2,173 of these observations are used because some legislators were the only ones elected in their caucus district in their cohort, and thus were not subject to any randomization, and because some committee assignment data was missing from 1977.

7 Legislators can be expected to choose their most preferred available choice since they choose for themselves (i.e., in a “serial dictatorship” arrangement; see Satterthwaite and Sonnenschein Reference Satterthwaite and Sonnenschein1981).

8 This rules out an alternative explanation for the null findings, namely that legislators receive electoral benefits from more attractive committee assignments but use this additional ‘‘political capital’’ to vote more with their party. In this way, committee membership might grant members leeway to vote against their constituents’ preferences (Cain, Ferejohn, Fiorina Reference Cain, Ferejohn and Fiorina1987, 87). However, the results show that legislators with more attractive committee assignments are not more likely to vote with their party. The reliable pattern in other legislatures that party leaders place more loyal legislators on more prestigious committees may be a result of party leader attempts to stack committees with reliable loyalists.

9 We also tested whether the results varied by legislators’ tenure in office by rerunning the models and including dummy variable for legislators in the second term and another for legislators serving in their third-plus term (i.e., their third, fourth, fifth, etc. term) and interaction terms between these dummy variables and relative rank. The results of the analysis are presented in Table A2 of the supplementary materials. The results confirm the findings here. In a few cases the effect of relative rank is significant, but in those few cases it goes in the wrong direction.

10 Although we cannot definitely speak to what would have occurred, had Arkansas not implemented term limits when it did, we reran the main analysis (i.e., Table 3) with interaction terms for each decade to see if in one of the early decades relative rank had a significant effect. The results, which are provided in the supplementary materials (see Table A3), show that the effects do not change much at all. In fact, the only coefficient that achieves statistical significance actually points in the wrong direction.

References

REFERENCES

Anzia, S. F. and Jackman, M. C. 2013. “Legislative Organization and the Second Face of Power: Evidence from U.S. State Legislatures.” Journal of Politics 75 (1): 210224.Google Scholar
Bullock, C. S. III. 1972. “Freshman Committee Assignments and Re-election in the United States House of Representatives.” American Political Science Review 66 (3): 9961007.Google Scholar
Bullock, C. S. III. 1976. “Motivations for Congressional Committee Preferences: Freshmen of the 92nd Congress.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 1 (2): 201212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cain, B. E., Ferejohn, J. and Fiorina, M. P. 1987. The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Carsey, T. M., Berry, W. D., Niemi, R. G., Powell, L. W. and Snyder, J. M. 2007. State Legislative Election Returns, 1967–2003 (ICPSR 21480).Google Scholar
Coker, D. C. and Crain, M. W. 1994. “Legislative Committees as Loyalty-Generating Institutions.” Public Choice 81: 195221.Google Scholar
Cox, G. W. and McCubbins, M. D. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cox, G. W. and McCubbins, M. D. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the US House of Representatives. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Crain, M. W. and Sullivan, J. T. 1997. “Committee Characteristics and Re-Election Margins: An Empirical Investigation of the US House.” Public Choice 93 (3): 271285.Google Scholar
Crook, S. B. and Hibbing, J. R. 1985. “Congressional Reform and Party Discipline: The Effects of Changes in the Seniority System on Party Loyalty in the US House of Representatives.” British Journal of Political Science 15 (2): 207226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dow, J. K., Endersby, J. W. and Menifield, C. E. 1998. “The Industrial Structure of the California Assembly: Committee Assignments, Economic Interests, and Campaign Contributions.” Public Choice 94 (2): 6783.Google Scholar
Fenno, R. F. 1973. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Fowler, L. L., Douglass, S. R. and Clark, W. D. Jr 1980. “The Electoral Effects of House Committee Assignments.” Journal of Politics 42 (1): 307319.Google Scholar
Grier, K. B. and Munger, M. C. 1991. “Committee Assignments, Constituent Preferences, Campaign Contributions.” Economic Inquiry 29 (1): 2443.Google Scholar
Grier, K. B. and Munger, M. C. 1993. “Comparing Interest Group PAC Contributions to House and Senate Incumbents, 1980–1986.” Journal of Politics 55 (3): 615643.Google Scholar
Grimmer, J. and Powell, E. 2013. “Congressmen in Exile: The Politics and Consequences of Involuntary Committee Removal.” Journal of Politics 75 (4): 907920.Google Scholar
Grose, C. 2014. “Field Experimental Work on Political Institutions.” Annual Review of Political Science 17: 355370.Google Scholar
Heberlig, E. S 2003. “Congressional Parties, Fundraising, and Committee Ambition.” Political Research Quarterly 56: 151162.Google Scholar
Hedlund, R. D. and Patterson, S. C. 1992. “The electoral antecedents of state legislative committee assignments.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 17 (4): 539559.Google Scholar
Hogan, R. E. 2004. “Challenger Emergence, Incumbent Success and Electoral Accountability in State Legislative Elections.” Journal of Politcs 66 (4): 13091329.Google Scholar
Kanthak, K. 2004. “Exclusive Committee Assignments and Party Pressure in the US House of Representatives.” Public Choice 121: 391412.Google Scholar
Kanthak, K. 2009. “US State Legislative Committee Assignments and Encouragement of Party Loyalty: An Exploratory Analysis.” State Politics and Policy Quarterly 9 (3): 284303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, J. N. and Sala, B. R. 1996. “Careerism, Committee Assignments, and the Electoral Connection.” American Political Science Review 90: 2133.Google Scholar
Kellerman, M. and Shepsle, K. A. 2009. “Congressional Careers, Committee Assignments, and Seniority Randomization in the US House of Representatives.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 4: 87101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maltzman, F. 1997. Competing Principals: Committees, Parties, and the Organization of Congress. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manley, J. F. 1970. The Politics of Finance: The House Committee on Ways and Means. Boston: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Milyo, J. 1997. “Electoral and Financial Effects of Changes in Committee Power: The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Budget Reform, the Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the Money Committees in the House.” Journal of Law and Economics 40 (1): 93111.Google Scholar
Roberts, J. M. and Smith, S. S. 2003. “Procedural Contexts, Party Strategy, and Conditional Party Voting in the US House of Representatives, 1971–2000.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (2): 305317.Google Scholar
Rogowski, J. C. and Sinclair, B. 2012. “Estimating the Causal Effects of Social Interaction with Endogenous Networks.” Political Analysis 20: 316328.Google Scholar
Rohde, D. W. and Shepsle, K. A. 1973. “Democratic Committee Assignments in the House of Representatives: Strategic Aspects of a Social Choice Process.” American Political Science Review 67: 889905.Google Scholar
Romer, T., and Snyder, J. M. 1994. “An Empirical Investigation of the Dynamics of PAC Contributions.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (3): 745769.Google Scholar
Satterthwaite, M. and Sonnenschein, H. 1981. “Strategy-proof Allocation Mechanisms at Differentiable Points.” Review of Economic Studies 48 (4): 587597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. 1978. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle: Democratic Committee Assignments in the Modern House. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sinclair, B. 1995. Legislators, Leaders, and Lawmaking. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, S. S. and Deering, C. J. 1983. “Changing Motives for the Committee Preferences of New Members of the United-States House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 8: 271281.Google Scholar
Stratmann, T. 2000. “Congressional Voting Over Legislative Careers: Shifting Perceptions and Changing Constraints.” American Political Science Review 94 (3): 665676.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Hypothetical Example of how Relative Rank is Computed

Figure 1

Box 1 The Benefits of Using Arkansas to Study the Effects of Committees

Figure 2

Table 2 Balance of Covariates across Relative Rank and Seniority Score

Figure 3

Table 3 Effect of Seniority within Cohort (Relative Rank) on Outcomes of Interest (OLS)

Supplementary material: File

Broockman and Butler supplementary material

Appendix

Download Broockman and Butler supplementary material(File)
File 575 KB