Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-5r2nc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T04:35:58.909Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introduction to the special issue on the Centenary of Frank H. Knight's Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2021

Per L. Bylund*
Affiliation:
School of Entrepreneurship, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, Oklahoma, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: per.bylund@okstate.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Frank H. Knight's magnum opus Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, published in 1921, is widely recognized for introducing and establishing the distinction between risk and uncertainty. It is also known for developing a novel theory of the firm and business profit based on entrepreneurial judgment. However, the work's relevance for institutionalism has only rarely been addressed or even acknowledged. This introduction to the special issue organized to celebrate the centenary of Knight's tome briefly summarizes the work's institutionalist implications and the articles that comprise the special issue.

Type
Introduction
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd.

The year 2021 marks the 100th anniversary of the publication of Frank H. Knight's highly influential first book, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (1921). The book, if not Knight himself, has become known primarily for the important distinction it introduced between the concepts risk, understood as probabilistic, and uncertainty, which is non-probabilistic and open-ended.

Although Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit introduces this distinction and produces a theory based on it, Knight's purpose was not merely to define uncertainty as distinct from risk. His aim was another.

Published by Houghton Mifflin, the book is a revised version of the essay ‘Cost, Value and Profit’, itself based on Knight's doctoral dissertation. The essay won second place in a contest, which guaranteed its publication in book form (Emmett, Reference Emmettforthcoming). The dissertation, defended at Cornell University already 1916, was titled ‘A Theory of Business Profit’, which is perhaps a better indication of the book's aim and topic.

Even though Knight in the book produces a theory of the firm, it is different from the theories of the firm influential in contemporary economics (e.g. Coase, Reference Coase1937; Grossman and Hart, Reference Grossman and Hart1986; Williamson, Reference Williamson1975). Rather than distinguished as an ‘authority relation’ (c.f. Bylund, Reference Bylund2014; Simon, Reference Simon1951), Knight sees the firm as an institutional solution to problems that arise in the market economy due to uncertainty. The theory is dynamic and is both based on and explains the role of entrepreneurship in the unfolding of the market process.

Knight's theory states that entrepreneurs, who pursue new business ideas, act under uncertainty and can therefore not rely on measures to mitigate probabilistic risk. Instead, they must act guided primarily or only by their own judgment (McMullen, Reference McMullen2015) of future market conditions and the expected value of what they bring.

In Knight's own words, entrepreneurs must rely on their judgment to form ‘an estimate of an estimate’ (Knight, Reference Knight1921: 227) on which they then choose to act. These estimates are of course highly uncertain, since they refer to a future that is both unknown and unknowable. This is for the entrepreneur an opportunity, since economic profits are earned by those exercising superior judgment. But it is also a limitation, because the quality and value of someone's judgment cannot be known ex ante and, therefore, it cannot be accurately priced and traded as an economic good. Consequently, judgment cannot earn a market wage like other skills and qualities, and entrepreneurs therefore cannot take employment in existing businesses selling only their judgment. To act on their judgment, then, they must themselves organize production using the estimates they have formed.

Thus, the business firm is to Knight an institution of the market economy created by entrepreneurs to deal with the uncertainty of the future. There are two important aspects of this uncertainty. First, the business firm is the organizational structure through which the entrepreneur's judgment can be implemented for production. It is thereby, to Knight, the one means by which the entrepreneur's judgment can be exercised in the market and, consequently, earn a return in the form of profits. Where the entrepreneur's judgment is lacking, however, he or she suffers losses. Knight's theory of business profit is thereby a theory of entrepreneurship, where the uncertainty of the enterprise is borne by the entrepreneur for which profits (losses) are earned (suffered).

Second, the business firm's organized production offers a means to overcome, or at least manage, the uncertainty through a ‘divide and conquer’ strategy. The entrepreneur employs experts within the firm, who have specific expertise. Employees are, as specialized experts, trusted to exercise their own (derived) judgment limited to their specific expertise to solve problems that arise. The firm is a formalized, hierarchical ‘division of intellectual labor’ of sorts (c.f. von Mises, Reference von Mises1998).

The entrepreneur's judgment spans the entire enterprise and defines the opportunity, but the entrepreneur is unlikely to have sufficient expertise to exercise superior judgment in response to specific problems that may arise. Thus, under the umbrella of the entrepreneur's overall judgment, people are employed in the firm based on their specific expertise. The entrepreneur's decision to employ them is based on their objective expertise but also, and more importantly, their expected decision-making ability in their area of expertise. They are thus employed to handle future, unforeseen events as ‘proxy entrepreneurs’ (Foss et al., Reference Foss, Foss and Klein2007).

While Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit is an exercise in ‘pure economic theory’ (Bylund, Reference Bylundforthcoming), it is also a critique of perfect competition model and a work of institutional importance. The theory of the firm that it develops is open-ended and focused on the indeterminate outcomes of entrepreneurs' bearing of uncertainty (Boudreaux and Holcombe, Reference Boudreaux and Holcombe1989) and is in this sense a different animal than most economic theories of the firm (for exceptions see e.g. Bylund, Reference Bylund2016; Lewin, Reference Lewin2011)

Importantly, Knight was something of an institutionalist (Hodgson, Reference Hodgson, Biddle, Davis and Medema2001), perhaps even ‘in a strong and meaningful sense’ (Hodgson, Reference Hodgson and Hodgson2004). However, Knight is difficult to pin down. He was not a simple but rather unique thinker, and typically found his own way and his own answers to questions. So also with respect to institutions, which he found ‘far more limited and inefficient’ (Packard et al., Reference Packard, Bylund and Clarkforthcoming) than many of his contemporaries. To Knight, institutions ‘belong to an intermediate category, between instinct and intelligence’ (Knight, Reference Knight1947: 224).

Knight also relied extensively on economic theory. As already noted, his magnum opus is, by his own account, a ‘study in “pure theory”’ (1921: xi). But it is also, in many ways, positioned as a critique of the pure-theory model of perfect competition. While he found theory important and ‘the first step’ (1921: 6 emphasis in original) in generating knowledge about the world, he found it important to not rely only on theory. Instead, pure theory is approximate and must be augmented by adding specific factors so that it can explain observed phenomena. The task of the scientist (economist) is to take pure theory closer to observed reality using ‘the method of successive approximations’ (1921: 6) to find a ‘correct “middle way”’ (1921: 6) between pure theory and inductive analysis. In the words of Buchanan (Reference Buchanan and Knight1968: 426 quoted in Hodgson, Reference Hodgson and Hodgson2004), Knight was ‘that rare theorist who is also an institutionalist, an institutionalist who is not a data collector’.

There are many reasons to consider the institutionalist aspects of Knight's thought (Hodgson, Reference Hodgson and Hodgson2004), including in his Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, to elaborate on Knightian thought's implications for institutional economics, bring to a fore its forgotten or perhaps misunderstood contributions, reconsider its history as well as reinterpret and reintegrate it into modern thinking, and apply Knight's contributions and concepts in empirical research. The many great contributions to this special issue do just that.

Starting off, Emmett (Reference Emmett2021) brings attention to the often-overlooked last chapters of Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Emmett argues that these chapters are of particular importance to institutional economics as they address how uncertainty affects not only the entrepreneur but the social organization of economic activity.

In the second article, Burns et al. (Reference Burns, Manish and Nair2021) extend the analysis of Knightian uncertainty beyond the market setting. While the open market offers means to coordinate production through economic calculation, this is not obviously the case in non-market institutional settings. Specifically, they ask who undertakes judgment under uncertainty, what goals and whose preferences matter, and how is error detected and corrected in democratic government and the non-profit or philanthropic sector.

The third article, by Frølund (Reference Frølund2021), contributes to the burgeoning literature on institutions and entrepreneurship (e.g. Bylund and McCaffrey, Reference Bylund and McCaffrey2017; Henrekson and Sanandaju, Reference Henrekson and Sanandaju2011) by developing a model that details the relationship between entrepreneurship and institutions under uncertainty.

The fourth article, authored by Dold and Rizzo (Reference Dold and Rizzo2021), recognizes that Knight's theory of the firm suggests distributed entrepreneurship and responsibility, thereby challenging the hierarchical view of the firm. The authors develop Knight's seemingly modern ‘philosophical vision’ and discuss institutional implications in terms of monocultures, cognitive team diversity, and venture capitalism.

In the fifth article, Hudik and Bylund (Reference Hudik and Bylund2021) address Knight's method and derive general principles from his focus on a ‘middle way’ between pure theory and induction. These are then used to identify the proper balance between theory and historicism in modern studies such as entrepreneurship and management.

The sixth article, by Eabrasu (Reference Eabrasu2021), elaborates on Knight's distinction between risk and uncertainty to analyze the contrast between actuarial institutions and entrepreneurship. He finds that insurance, especially parametric such, does not automatically reduce entrepreneurial profits.

In the seventh article, Clarke (Reference Clarke2021) reconceptualizes financial governance. Noting that Knightian uncertainty limits social scientific knowledge and therefore the capacity of governance, he argues there is a need for a politics of uncertainty able to cope with ignorance of the future.

The eighth article, by Nabisaalu and Bylund (Reference Nabisaalu and Bylund2021), draws on Knight (Reference Knight1921) and Williamson (Reference Williamson2000) to produce an integrated institutional model for analyzing entrepreneurial finance. Applying the model to the entrepreneurial nation of Uganda, they find that entrepreneurs wrestle with problems regarding access to finance.

The ninth article, by Audretsch and Belitski (Reference Audretsch and Belitski2021), applies Knightian uncertainty to knowledge generated in incumbent organizations to explain the role of entrepreneurs as innovators. The authors find, studying over 9,000 firms, that entrepreneurial startups have greater returns from knowledge spillovers than intrapreneurs.

In the 10th article, Boettke and Candela (Reference Boettke and Candela2021) analyze the place of Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit in the development of 20th century economics. They find that the work is a progenitor of both mainstream microeconomics, studying utility maximization under fixed parameters, and price theory, the ‘mainline’ continuation of economic thought from its classical and early neoclassical roots (c.f. Boettke, Reference Boettke2012).

Rounding off this special issue, the 11th article, by McCaffrey et al. (Reference Salerno, Dorobat and McCaffrey2021), argues that Knight's theory of monopoly as contingent on institutional barriers to entry builds on and refines the price theory of Menger ([1871] Reference Menger2007). Specifically, monopoly as institutionally contingent shapes the choices of consumers and producers, which allows for identifying real monopoly gains.

These 11 articles address a number of institutional aspects and implications of the theorizing in Knight's Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. While each is important in its own right, combined they establish the lasting importance of Knight's work as well as its continuing relevance to economic thought – and institutionalism. As several of the articles suggest, not only has Knight's magnum opus made lasting impressions on economics proper, but the theory is, even after a century, surprisingly modern. It still has much more to offer.

This is perhaps particularly true for institutional economics, in which Knight's work, while recognized (Hodgson, Reference Hodgson, Biddle, Davis and Medema2001), has yet to rise to prominence. As the articles in this special issue make clear, whether or not Knight can be placed squarely under the institutionalism banner, there is much in Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit of institutional nature and with institutional implications; and this already influential work still has much to contribute to theorizing and research.

This special issue serves as a steppingstone into the second century of research inspired by Knight. The 11 articles herein suggest that institutional economists have much to gain by taking a deeper look at Knightian thought, both Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit and beyond, and inspire new research contributions.

References

Audretsch, D. B. and Belitski, M. (2021), ‘Frank Knight, Uncertainty and Knowledge Spillover Entrepreneurship society’, Journal of Institutional Economics (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boettke, P. J. (2012), Living Economics: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow, Oakland, CA: Independent Institute.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J. and Candela, R. A. (2021), ‘The Common Sense of Economics and Divergent Approaches in Economic Thought: A View From Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 115 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000229.Google Scholar
Boudreaux, D. J. and Holcombe, R. G. (1989), ‘The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm’, Managerial and Decision Economics, 10(2): 147154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1968), in Knight, F. H. (ed.), International Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences. Hodgson, pp. 424428.Google Scholar
Burns, S., Manish, G. P. and Nair, M. (2021), ‘Knightian Uncertainty in non-Market Institutional Settings: The Case of Democracy and Nonprofit Civil Society’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 115 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000382.Google Scholar
Bylund, P. L. (2014), ‘The Firm and the Authority Relation: Hierarchy vs. Organization’, in Guinevere Nell (ed.), Austrian Theory and Economic Organization. US, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 97120. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137368805_5.Google Scholar
Bylund, P. L. (2016). The Problem of Production: A New Theory of the Firm. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bylund, P. L. (forthcoming), ‘Understanding the Limits of Pure Theory in Economics: Knight and Mises’, Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology.Google Scholar
Bylund, P. L. and McCaffrey, M. (2017), ‘A Theory of Entrepreneurship and Institutional Uncertainty’, Journal of Business Venturing, 32(5): 461475, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2017.05.006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, C. (2021), ‘The Legacy of Frank H. Knight for the Politics of Financial Governance’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 115 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000436.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica, 4(16): 386405, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dold, M. F. and Rizzo, M. J. (2021), ‘Frank Knight and the Cognitive Diversity of Entrepreneurship’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 118 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000321.Google Scholar
Eabrasu, M. (2021), ‘Bet Against Yourself: Integrating Insurance and Entrepreneurship’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 114 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000394.Google Scholar
Emmett, R. B. (2021), ‘Uncertainty and the Social Organization of Economic Activity’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 113 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000254.Google Scholar
Emmett, R. B. (forthcoming), ‘The Writing and Reception of Risk, Uncertainty and Profit’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beab005.Google Scholar
Foss, K., Foss, N. J. and Klein, P. G. (2007), ‘Original and Derived Judgment: An Entrepreneurial Theory of Economic Organization’, Organization Studies, 28(12): 18931912, https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840606076179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frølund, K. (2021), ‘Institutions, Uncertainty, and Entrepreneurial Judgment’, Journal of Institutional Economics (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, S. J. and Hart, O. D. (1986), ‘The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration’, Journal of Political Economy, 94(4): 691719, https://doi.org/10.1086/261404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrekson, M. and Sanandaju, T. (2011), ‘The Interaction of Entrepreneurship and Institutions’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(1): 4775, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137410000342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2001), ‘Frank Knight as an Institutional Economist’, in Biddle, J., Davis, J. and Medema, S. (eds.), Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honour of Warren J. Samuels, London: Routledge, pp. 6189.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2004), ‘The Maverick Institutionalism of Frank Knight’, in Hodgson, G. M. (ed.), The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, London: Routledge, pp. 322343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hudik, M. and Bylund, P. L. (2021), ‘Let's do it Frank's Way: General Principles and Historical Specificity in the Study of Entrepreneurship’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 116 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000205.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Boston & New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1947), Freedom and Reform: Essays in Economics and Social Philosophy, New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Lewin, P. (2011), Capital in Disequilibrium: The Role of Capital in A Changing World, Auburn, AL, USA: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
McMullen, J. S. (2015), ‘Entrepreneurial Judgment as Empathic Accuracy: A Sequential Decision-Making Approach to Entrepreneurial Action’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 11(3): 651681, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137413000386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, C. (2007), Principles of Economics (J. Dingwa), Auburn, AL, USA: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Nabisaalu, J. K. and Bylund, P. L. (2021), ‘Knight, Financial Institutions, and Entrepreneurship in Developing Economies’, Journal of Institutional Economics: 115 (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000308.Google Scholar
Packard, M. D., Bylund, P. L. and Clark, B. B. (forthcoming), ‘Keynes and Knight on Uncertainty: Peas in a Pod or Chalk and Cheese?’, Cambridge Journal of Economics.Google Scholar
Salerno, J. T., Dorobat, C. E. and McCaffrey, M. (2021), ‘Monopoly as a “Culture-History Fact”: Knight, Menger, and the Role of Institutions’, Journal of Institutional Economics (This paper is in This Issue), https://doi.org/doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1951), ‘A Formal Theory of the Employment Relationship’, Econometrica, 19(3): 293305, https://doi.org/10.2307/1906815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Mises, L. (1998), Human Action: The Scholar's Edition, Auburn, AL, USA: Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3): 595613, https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.38.3.595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar