Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-lrblm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T07:00:30.885Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The international propagation of the financial crisis of 2008 and a comparison with 19311

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2012

William A. Allen
Affiliation:
Cass Business School, bill@allen-economics.com
Richhild Moessner
Affiliation:
Bank for International Settlements and Cass Business School, richhild.moessner@bis.org
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We examine the international propagation of the financial crisis of 2008, and compare it with that of the crisis of 1931. Both crises featured a flight to liquidity and safety. We argue that the collateral squeeze in the United States, which became intense after the failure of Lehman Brothers, was an important propagator in 2008; in 1931 the acceptances granted by London banks to central European borrowers propagated the crisis to the UK. In both crises, central banks' reserve management actions contributed to the liquidity crisis. And in both crises, the behaviour of creditors towards debtors, and the valuation of assets by creditors, were very important. However, there was a key difference between the two crises in the range and nature of assets that were regarded as liquid and safe: central banks in 2008, with no gold standard constraint, could liquefy illiquid assets on a much greater scale.

Type
The past mirror: notes, surveys, debates
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2012

In this article, we examine the financial crisis of 2008, consider how it was propagated from country to country and compare it with the crisis of 1931. We choose these two particular crises because they were both global in scope, they both affected the world's principal financial centres and the crisis of 1931 had catastrophic consequences. In section I we describe the international flows of funds in the two crises. In Sections II to V we analyse several channels through which the recent crisis was propagated internationally – namely, the flight to safety and liquidity, the collateral squeeze, central bank reserve management and the unwinding of carry trades – and examine, in each case, the parallel with 1931. Section VI compares the international transmission channels in the two crises.

I

The recent financial crisis began in 2007 but became acute when Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy on 15 September 2008. This event falsified the prevailing assumption that no systemically important financial institution would be allowed to fail, and shocked US financial markets severely; it was followed by very heavy international flows of funds, which this section describes. In Section II, we analyse the very large domestic-currency-denominated flows to the United States and Japan (see Table 1, which shows flows through commercial banks in the second half of 2008). The inflow of funds to the United States was concentrated in the period after Lehman Brothers failed (Figure 1).

Figure 1. US commercial banks' net debt to related foreign offices and Fed swaps outstanding (in US$ billion)

aAll commercial banks; not seasonally adjusted. bWednesday level.

Sources: Federal Reserve tables H8 and H4.1.

Table 1. Exchange-rate adjusted changes in commercial banks' net external liabilities in the second half of 2008 (US$ billion)

Source: BIS international banking statistics, table 2.

Note: countries are included in this table if the total net external liabilities of banks located in that country changed by more than $30 billion in 2008Q4.

The large flows of dollars to the United States created shortages elsewhere, and caused severe stresses in foreign financial markets. It became impossible for commercial banks located outside the United States that had been financing longer-term US dollar-denominated assets with shorter-term wholesale funding to renew their funding from commercial sources. The shortages were largely relieved by swap lines provided by the Fed, but some of the financial market stresses persisted (see Allen and Moessner Reference Allen and Moessner2010). The withdrawal of external funding from commercial banks outside the United States caused their domestic lending to contract (Aiyar Reference Aiyar2011). The provision of dollar funds through Fed swap lines to foreign central banks was closely correlated with the inflow of funds to the United States through banks located in the United States (Figure 1).

During the spring and summer of 1931, following the collapse in May of Creditanstalt, the largest bank in Austria, there was an epidemic of severe banking or exchange rate crises in Europe, and some European countries suffered heavy outflows of gold from their reserves while trying vainly to support their banking systems.Footnote 2 It is now conventional wisdom that the disastrous events of 1931 were crucial in turning the recession following the stock market crash of 1929 into the Great Depression of the 1930s.Footnote 3

The turmoil in financial markets led to large international flows of funds. Total gold reserves actually rose somewhat in 1931, but they were redistributed among countries and some countries lost large amounts of gold (Table 2). The redistribution was the natural consequence under the gold standard of international flows of funds, which in the turbulent conditions were dominated by financial flows rather than current account flows.

Table 2. Changes in gold and foreign exchange reserves in 1931

Note: Countries which experienced a change of $30 million or more in their gold reserves are included in the table, along with certain countries which experienced banking crises.

aIncludes holdings of US Treasury as well as Federal Reserve.

Source: League of Nations Statistical Yearbook 1936–7, available at www.library.northwestern.edu/govinfo/collections/league/

The central banks of the Netherlands, Switzerland and above all France experienced heavy inflows of funds during 1931, amounting in all to $771 million (increase in gold reserves net of reduction in foreign exchange reserves).Footnote 4 There were heavy outflows from Germany, Austria and Hungary, where there were banking crises, and from the UK, where a banking crisis was avoided, but probably only because the country left the gold standard (in September 1931) rather than face the prospect of continued outflows and their deflationary consequences for the economy.Footnote 5 The scale of these countries' financial problems was larger than Table 2 suggests, because they all received official loans which partly offset their gold and foreign exchange losses. The United States also lost gold, but this was entirely the result of official loans to countries in distress, which increased by $306 million during 1931 (authors' calculation).

II

The recent crisis was propagated internationally by means of a flight to liquidity and safety, a collateral squeeze and the unwinding of carry trades. This and the following sections describe how these channels operated and examine, in each case, the parallel with 1931. We start here with the flight to liquidity and safety.

A flight to liquidity and safety began in 2007 when growing doubts about the value of mortgage-backed securities caused the ‘shadow banking system’ to begin to contract. The ‘shadow banking system’ consists of financial companies which were not banks but which performed maturity transformation by holding inventories of longer-term assets financed and collateralised by shorter-term liabilities such as asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP). This definition of shadow banks therefore includes many broker-dealers and hedge funds, but it excludes most money market mutual funds, which are strictly speaking not leveraged, because investors buy shares which have no guarantee of capital value.Footnote 6 Many shadow banks had acquired back-up liquidity guarantees from commercial banks in order to make their ABCP programmes attractive to investors, so that the growing doubts about the assets of the shadow banks, as well as about the mortgage assets of commercial banks themselves, led inevitably in turn to doubts about the soundness of commercial banks.Footnote 7 The flight intensified and turned into a crisis after Lehman Brothers failed.

The flight to liquidity and safety was manifested in many ways. For example, yield differentials between eurodollar deposits and US government liabilities widened sharply after August 2007. Not all government liabilities were considered safe, however, and yield differences between the securities issued by different governments widened. At the extreme, the government of Iceland had to impose exchange controls in 2008, while the governments of Greece and Ireland sought emergency official support in 2010. Commercial banks based in Iceland and Ireland were suspected of having negative net worth of such a size as to threaten the sustainability of their governments' finances, on the assumption that the governments would guarantee the deposits and perhaps some other liabilities of the banks. This undermined the credit standing of those countries' governments (and the banks). Other governments, such as in Spain, Portugal and the United Kingdom, tightened fiscal policy out of anxiety that their credit standing would otherwise deteriorate.

The liabilities of central banks in countries with stable public finances were also regarded as liquid and safe, and the demand for them surged. Central banks, having learned the lessons of the Great Depression, generally supplied deposits and other liabilities in large quantities, using the proceeds to acquire additional assets. In doing so they fulfilled the role of ‘lender of last resort’ in defence of financial stability. The balance sheets of some central banks, including those of the United States, the euro area and the United Kingdom, ballooned in size (Figure 2).

Figure 2. Central bank balance sheet size, 2007–2009 (in national currencies, mid 2007 = 100)

Sources: Datastream, national data.

We doubt whether anxiety on the part of US banks about foreign banks' solvency was the main cause of the post-Lehman inflow to the United States. It is true that the yield differentials between commercial bank and government liabilities widened still further at that time. However, as Table 6 shows, most of the increase in late 2008 in amounts due from commercial banks in the United States to their foreign offices was on account of foreign banks, not US-chartered banks; moreover, there was no reason why the failure of Lehman Brothers (and the rescue of AIG, which occurred at much the same time) should have increased US banks' unease about foreign banks.

In 1931, doubts developed about some countries' ability to sustain the gold standard, and the dominant concerns of international investors were liquidity and safety. This meant avoiding currencies which might leave the gold standard and be either devalued or subjected to standstill agreements or other administrative obstructions to scheduled payments, and avoiding exposures to commercial banks whose soundness was in doubt.Footnote 8 It is interesting to consider the counterparts to the flows of gold in the countries that were most affected by the crisis.

Table 3 provides such information in respect of the three main gold-losing countries, namely Germany, Austria and the United Kingdom. In Germany and Austria, the central bank's loss of gold and foreign exchange reserves was more than compensated by an increase in its domestic assets, largely if not entirely accounted for by emergency assistance provided to distressed domestic commercial banks. In the United Kingdom, the central bank's balance sheet (with the Issue and Banking Departments consolidated) contracted slightly during 1931 and the increase in domestic assets was slightly smaller than the fall in gold and foreign exchange.

Table 3. Changes in central and commercial bank balance sheets in gold-losing countries in 1931 (US$ million, except where shown)

Sources: Central bank data: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1976); Commercial bank data: Deutsche Bundesbank (Reference Bundesbank1976), Sheppard (Reference Sheppard1971).

Central bank liabilities (notes and deposits) increased moderately in Austria and the UK, but they fell sharply in Germany, where the banknote circulation fell by 7.8 per cent. It can safely be assumed that central banks supplied banknotes on demand, and that the fall in the note circulation was driven by demand, not supply. Real GDP in Germany fell by 7.6 per cent in 1931,Footnote 9 and retail prices fell by 8.5 per cent,Footnote 10 and it is plausible that the fall in incomes caused the fall in demand for banknotes. However, it was less than a decade since Germany had experienced hyperinflation, and the fall in demand for banknotes might also have reflected a loss of confidence in the Reichsmark and in Germany's ability to remain on the gold standard.

France, the Netherlands and Switzerland all ran down their foreign exchange reserves in 1931, but in each case total reserves of gold and foreign exchange rose by a large amount (Table 4). In each case there were large increases in both the banknote issue and in deposits with the central bank; and the percentage increases in the banknote issues were far larger than could be explained by changes in domestic economic conditions.Footnote 11 It seems highly likely that banknotes were among the destinations of the flight to liquidity and safety. It is also quite possible that deposits in the three central banks were also flight destinations. In particular, the Banque de France dominated the French banking scene in that era; its note circulation alone was much larger than the total of commercial bank deposits; and it did a great deal of what would now be regarded as commercial banking.Footnote 12

Table 4. Changes in central and commercial bank balance sheets in gold-receiving countries in 1931 (US$ million)

Sources: France: Federal Reserve Board, Banking and Monetary Statistics 1914–1941; Netherlands: Nederlandse financiële instellingen in de twintigste eeuw: Balansreeksen en naamlijst van handelsbanken. De Nederlandsche Bank Statistische Cahiers no. 3, 2000; Switzerland: Swiss National Bank www.snb.ch/en/iabout/stat/statpub/histz/id/statpub_histz_actual.

III

The heavy inflow of funds to the United States after Lehman Brothers failed was partly a side-effect of a collateral squeeze which took place in the United States at that time. A collateral squeeze affects companies such as shadow banks which use their assets as collateral for their borrowings. The mechanics of a collateral squeeze are described in detail by Adrian and Shin (Reference Adrian and Shin2009 and Reference Adrian and Shin2010) and Allen and Moessner (Reference Allen and Moessner2011). In this section, we illustrate the effects of the collateral squeeze by reference to the experiences of a large broker-dealer, Morgan Stanley, and explain how the squeeze affected commercial bank balance sheets and sucked dollar funds into the United States from other countries.

The realisation that Lehman Brothers had been allowed to fail suddenly undermined the credibility of other broker-dealers, of which Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch and Morgan Stanley were by far the largest.Footnote 13 Not only did lenders of money require them to pledge much larger margins of surplus collateral, but their market trading counterparties, mainly hedge funds to which the broker-dealers provided prime brokerage services, became much less tolerant of unsecured exposures to them. These developments put immense pressure on broker-dealers to find new sources of capital and unsecured liabilities.

Gorton and Metrick (Reference Gorton and Metrick2009) provide data obtained from dealers showing how ‘haircuts’, i.e. margins of surplus collateral demanded from borrowers of cash under bilateral repurchase agreements, increased very sharply, especially after Lehman Brothers failed.Footnote 14 Copeland, Martin and Walker (Reference Copeland, Martin and Walker2010) report that in the tri-party repo market, haircuts did not increase much, and suggest reasons for the difference in behaviour between the bilateral and tri-party markets. They also suggest that some of the lenders in the bilateral repo market were prime brokers lending cash to their hedge fund clients, who may have had no other source of funds. Some of the prime brokers will have been broker-dealers who were themselves under liquidity pressure, and they may have demanded more collateral from their clients in order to ease their own liquidity situations. And the FCIC (2011, p. 361) say that, after Lehman Brothers failed, the two clearing banks in the tri-party market became concerned about their intra-day exposures to broker-dealers and demanded more collateral.

An impression of the nature and scale of the resulting collateral squeeze on broker-dealers is provided in Table 5, which shows a condensed version of Morgan Stanley's balance sheet, as at its 10-K and 10-Q reporting dates. Between September and November 2008 Morgan Stanley experienced a massive withdrawal of unsecured funding. The main element was an outflow of $203 billion on account of ‘payables', which we surmise included reductions in collateral provided by trading counterparties to Morgan Stanley, and notably by the hedge funds to which Morgan Stanley provided prime brokerage services.Footnote 15 Prime brokerage clients also exercised their contractual rights to borrow from Morgan Stanley. The FCIC reports that cash and securities withdrawn from non-bank prime brokers were transferred to prime brokers which were in bank holding companies, and to custodian banks (see FCIC, p. 360).

Table 5. Condensed balance sheet of Morgan Stanley, 2008 (US$ billion)

Sources: 10-K and 10-Q reports, information released by Federal Reserve about use of credit and liquidity facilities (see www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_transaction.htm).

Notes: aDate of peak usage of Fed facilities; see text for more details. bEnd of September.

Source: FCIC (2011, p. 363).

Morgan Stanley's total unsecured funding fell by $239 billion in September–November 2008. The company drew down $49 billion of liquid assets, so that its liquid assets met about a fifth of the loss of unsecured funding. The company reduced its other assets by $279 billion, or 35 per cent, in the three months, so that its total assets decreased by $328 billion.Footnote 16 It also raised new capital from investors. The company used its liquid assets to buy time, while making large reductions in total assets. The reduction in total assets in September–November was about one and a half times the reduction in capital and unsecured borrowing. Morgan Stanley had surplus collateral at the beginning of the crisis, in addition to its liquidity reserve, which it was able to deploy with the help of the emergency liquidity facilities provided by the Fed, in order to soften the immediate impact of the outflows of funds on its balance sheet.Footnote 17

Between 3 September and 31 December 2008, the net debt of commercial banks located in the United States to their foreign offices increased by $575 billion, of which $410 billion was accounted for by foreign-related banks. This suggests that the flow of dollars to the United States reported in Table 1 was largely or entirely concentrated in flows to banks located in the United States from their foreign affiliates (Cetorelli and Goldberg Reference Cetorelli and Goldberg2009). Table 6 shows how the commercial banks' balance sheets changed over the same period.

Table 6. US commercial banks: changes in selected balance sheet items from 3 September 2008 to end December 2008 (US$ billion)

Source: Federal Reserve tables H8, H4.1.

The increase in bank assets, other than cash, is not hard to explain. Commercial banks had provided liquidity guarantees to issuers of commercial paper, including shadow banks issuing asset-backed commercial paper, and as the ABCP market dried up, the guarantees were called. The increase arising from this source appears to have outweighed the decrease that will have arisen from debt repayments by shadow banks which had sold assets as a necessary reaction to the collateral squeeze. On the liabilities side, it may seem remarkable that the deposits of US-chartered commercial banks increased at all during this turbulent period. We attribute the phenomenon to two factors. The first is federal deposit insurance (100 per cent of deposits up to $250,000 were insured, the limit having been temporarily increased from $100,000 in the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, signed by President Bush on 3 October). The second is that there was a flight, which had begun in 2007, from other asset types which had come to be regarded as risky. These included certain kinds of commercial paper, notably ABCP, and money market mutual funds after 16 September 2008, when the Reserve Fund announced that two of its funds were worth less than 100 cents in the dollar (see Baba, McCauley and Ramaswamy Reference Baba, McCauley and Ramaswamy2009; Pozsar et al. Reference Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft and Boesky2010).Footnote 18 The funds coming out of the commercial paper market, money market mutual funds and other stressed markets had to be placed somewhere, and Treasury securities were in fixed supply. Investors who did not roll over their ABCP holdings on maturity left the money in the bank. There was nowhere else for them to go, except perhaps to banknotes or real assets, and the outlook for bank deposits was not bad enough for that (though the price of gold rose very sharply). The increase in bank deposits caused by the flight from money market mutual funds and the shadow banking system evidently outweighed the reduction that will have arisen from the purchases by real-money investors of assets sold by shadow banks.

Thus the contraction of the shadow banking system led to changes in bank balance sheets but had no effect on aggregate commercial bank liquidity. The acquisition of additional assets by commercial banks as the shadow banking system contracted did not affect their aggregate cash flow, because the contraction of the shadow banking system also provided them with additional deposits; in other words, it involved no pressure at all on the liquidity of the banking system in aggregate. The enforced deleveraging of some shadow banks will have led to a fall in the bank deposits of real-money investors, who must have bought the assets that shadow banks sold, but the funds withdrawn by real money investors will have been used by the shadow banks to repay commercial bank loans, so that the effect on the commercial banks' aggregate cash flow will again have been zero. Individual banks, however, cannot have been sure that the amounts of money that they had to find to finance additional assets on their balance sheets would all come back to them in additional deposits, or that lost deposits would all come back to them in the form of loan repayments. In the turmoil, they must have become much more uncertain about their future cash flows. The increase in cash assets recorded in Table 6 can therefore be interpreted as additional precautionary demand for liquid assets.

During a collateral squeeze, unsecured borrowing (or drawing down of unsecured deposits) was especially valuable, since it generated cash without any immediate loss of collateral. Unsecured borrowing was difficult during the 2008 crisis, but some financial companies had foreign affiliates which they could induce to place funds with them in the form of new deposits or loans, or to repay existing debts owed to them, as part of intra-group funds transfers. Against this background, the increase of $575 billion in commercial banks' ‘net debt to foreign offices’ shown in Table 6 is understandable. Foreign bank affiliates (branches and agencies of foreign banks) in the United States were under greater pressure than US-domiciled banks. They had lost much of the funding they had previously received from money market mutual funds.Footnote 19 Foreign bank branches (the most common type of affiliate) were not allowed to take deposits of less than $100,000 from US citizens and residents, and could therefore not receive smaller deposits that were fleeing from money market mutual funds. Moreover, deposits in foreign bank branches established after 19 December 1991 were not covered by US deposit insurance. Foreign bank affiliates' deposits fell by $258 billion (Table 6). Their ‘borrowings from others’ – presumably mainly from the Fed – increased by $73 billion,Footnote 20 and they raised $410 billion from their foreign offices, compared with the $165 billion that US- chartered banks raised from their foreign offices during the same period.

In fact, most of the external inflow to the United States took place in October and November. Commercial banks' net debt to foreign offices increased by just $74 billion between 3 September and 1 October, but it had increased by a further $457 billion by 3 December. The inflow was facilitated by swap lines provided by the Fed to foreign central banks, which enabled the foreign offices of commercial banks located in the United States to remit dollar funds to the United States (Allen and Moessner Reference Allen and Moessner2010).Footnote 21 The inflow of funds from abroad thus played a large role in easing the collateral squeeze in US financial markets during October and November, and in financing the large repayments of borrowings from the domestic emergency liquidity facilities provided by the Fed.

Collateral seems to have been less widely used in 1931 than in 2008, and the liquidity squeeze was propagated directly from the countries immediately affected by the crisis to London, which was the world's main international financial centre. People and companies needing liquidity on account of the crises would naturally have drawn it from London. In particular, London merchant banks had provided extensive acceptance credits to central European borrowers, especially in Germany.Footnote 22 After the crises, the borrowers could not pay the bills on time, and the acceptors were therefore liable to the holders of the bills. Standstill agreements were reached under which the creditors agreed not to call in the debts, and the existing credits were frozen on their original terms but interest payments were guaranteed (Forbes Reference Forbes1987, p. 575). The German agreement provided that there was to be no discrimination among the creditors, but that the German authorities would discriminate in favour of remittances due under the agreement (Sayers Reference Sayers1976, pp. 506–7). German debtors were required to provide eligible bills for acceptance. As Roberts (Reference Roberts, Roberts and Kynaston1995, p. 164) aptly says, ‘Under this agreement German bills remained in the [London] market and were repeatedly renewed on expiry, the sort of practice which had hitherto caused apoplexy in the Discount Office [of the Bank of England].’

The central European crisis and the standstill agreements put great strain on the liquidity (and capital) of the London accepting houses and seriously aggravated the existing lack of liquidity of the London money market as a whole. The Bank of England's initial position, before the standstill agreements had been reached, had been that bills drawn against frozen credits, once renewed, would not be eligible for rediscount, and that no loans would be made to accepting houses with large frozen positions (Sayers Reference Sayers1976, p. 505), though the Bank encouraged the clearing banks to provide support to the accepting houses.Footnote 23 The Bank's attitude is not surprising, since the total debts in London covered by the standstill agreement were £66 million, compared to the Bank of England's gold reserves of £132 million at the end of July 1931. However, the standstill agreement with Germany required the debtors to provide eligible bills for acceptance. Eligibility was a matter for the Bank of England, and Sayers reports that ‘the Bank [of England] leaned over backwards to ensure marketability’ of standstill bills, and that ‘in the first half of 1932 nearly half the bills discounted at the Bank [of England] were of German origin’ (Sayers Reference Sayers1976, pp. 507 and 509 footnote 1). It is impossible to trace through time the amounts of such bills that the Bank purchased. But whatever the amounts may have been, the residual liquidity problems of the merchant banks represented a kind of contingent liability of the Bank of England, and the inadequacy of the Bank's own liquidity was in any case already threatening the sustainability of sterling's gold parity.Footnote 24

Using such bank-by-bank data as are publicly available, Accominotti (Reference Accominotti2009) shows that the banks which were most exposed to standstill bills also experienced large deposit outflows during 1931, and thus faced a double threat to their liquidity. Nearly all of the accepting houses' deposits were of foreign origin, according to Truptil (Reference Truptil1936, p. 314), and it is plausible that those banks whose acceptances were largely central European also had a high proportion of central European deposits, which would naturally have been withdrawn during the crisis to meet the depositors' liquidity needs.

The alternative to the standstill agreements would have been a default by the debtors, which ‘threatened to bankrupt several of the merchant banks, probably some of the discount houses, and possibly to provoke a crisis in the banking system’ (Roberts Reference Roberts1992, p. 253). The artificial maintenance of the fiction that standstill bills were high-quality liquid assets in London was the price of avoiding that outcome. The experience of J. Henry Schröder and Co., one of the accepting houses hardest hit by the crisis, illustrates this. In July 1931, Schröders' frozen debts were £4.9 million, compared with partners' capital of £3.2 million at the end of 1930 (Table 7) (Roberts Reference Roberts1992, p. 264). Schröders were required to withdraw standstill bills from the money market during the 1930s, but the withdrawal was very gradual and was not completed until September 1939.

Table 7. J. Henry Schröder and Co., balance sheet 1929–39 (£ million)

Source: Roberts Reference Roberts1992, appendix IV(i).

The British clearing banks, of course, had much larger liquid liabilities than the accepting houses,Footnote 25 but the vast majority of their liabilities were presumably of domestic origin and not very vulnerable to flight. Their demand and time deposits fell by £58 million between June and October 1931, but as Billings and Capie (Reference Billings and Capie2010) recount, they were able to withstand the shocks of 1931 without any special support, and to provide support themselves to accepting houses and other banks in distress.Footnote 26 We agree with Billings and Capie that there was no financial crisis in Britain in 1931.Footnote 27 That was because the ability and willingness of the monetary authorities to defend the gold parity fell far short of the liquid assets of the clearing banks. According to the British Government statement issued on 20 September 1931, when the gold standard was suspended, ‘since the end of July funds amounting to more than £200 millions have been withdrawn from the London market’.Footnote 28 The cash and liquid assets of the London clearing banks had amounted to £586 million in June 1931, however.Footnote 29

IV

Central banks themselves contributed to the liquidity problems of commercial banks in both crises, as their reserve managers joined in the flight to liquidity and safety. In the middle of 2008, global foreign exchange reserves were $7.4 trillion. They were, and are, generally managed by central banks separately from domestic market operations. Typically, the pursuit of returns by central banks is subject to a low tolerance for the risk of losses and lack of liquidity. In this respect, the operations of central banks are very similar to those of many commercial asset managers with conservative investment mandates. However, quite extensive information is available about the reserve management behaviour of central banks, thanks to the data released under the IMF Special Data Dissemination Standard, to the BIS international banking statistics and to US sources.

Pihlmann and van der Hoorn (Reference Pihlmann and Van der Hoorn2010) show that, after a period in which they appeared willing to take increasing amounts of risk in pursuit of additional returns, reserve managers withdrew $150 billion of unsecured deposits from banks between August 2007 and August 2008 (before Lehman Brothers failed), and a further $150 billion between September and December 2008 (of course, not all of the deposit withdrawals will have been from banks in the United States). McCauley and Rigaudy (Reference McCauley and Rigaudy2011) show that central banks also retreated from US federal agency debentures and securities lending, and describe how they redeployed the funds withdrawn from commercial banks, e.g. in government debt.

On plausible assumptions, the unsecured deposits that central bank reserve managers withdrew from commercial banks will have been replaced by collateralised loans extended to the commercial banks concerned by their home central banks. Thus the net effect of the withdrawal of unsecured deposits will have been a drain of collateral assets from commercial banks to central banks.

In 1931, there were widespread reductions in foreign exchange reserves (Table 2), which continued in 1932 (Eichengreen and Flandreau Reference Eichengreen and Flandreau2008). The Genoa Conference of 1922 had recommended economising on gold in order to enable the world monetary system to adapt to the higher price levels that followed the inflation of the Great War while retaining the essential features of the gold standard (Brown Reference Brown1940, ch. 20; Eichengreen Reference Eichengreen1995, pp. 157–62). One technique was for foreign exchange reserves to supplement gold as backing for national currencies; they had the attraction for the holder that, unlike gold reserves, they were interest-bearing. In addition, in many countries gold coins, which had circulated freely before being withdrawn at the outbreak of war in 1914, were not returned to general circulation, so that the available gold could be concentrated on central bank reserves. However, when it became clear that national currencies might depart from the gold standard, foreign exchange reserves were hastily liquidated. By the end of 1932, foreign exchange holdings of central banks had fallen to 25 per cent of their pre-crisis total. The Bank for International Settlements (1933, p. 10) estimated that the reduction had involved the disposal of CHF 2.5 billion of foreign exchange reserves in settlements by debtor central banks which might otherwise have been made in gold, and outright sales of CHF 5 billion of foreign exchange reserves for gold. The total was therefore CHF 7.5 billion ($1,450 million).

Just as the addition of foreign exchange to gold as a medium for the holding of national reserves had enabled a larger amount of credit and bank deposits to be extended on the foundation of a limited global supply of gold during the 1920s, so the conversion of foreign exchange reserves back into gold caused a contraction in credit and bank deposits in the 1930s.Footnote 30

If the reserve managers' withdrawals from bank liabilities during the two crises are measured relative to the annual GDP of the United States (of course, in neither crisis was the withdrawal from claims on banks by reserve managers confined to US banks), then the withdrawal of $300 billion in 2007-8 (roughly 2 per cent) appears slightly larger than the CHF 7.5 billion of 1931-2 (1 ½ per cent). However, if the comparison is made relative to total short-term international indebtedness, then the 1931-2 withdrawal appears much larger (more than 10 per cent compared to roughly 1 per cent).Footnote 31

V

Carry trades involve borrowing in a currency in which interest rates are relatively low in order to finance the purchase of assets denominated in a currency in which interest rates are higher. The carry trader earns the difference between the interest (or other) returns on the purchased asset and the interest due on the borrowing, but is of course exposed to foreign exchange risk.

The long period after 1997 when interest rates were kept very low in Japan in order to help stimulate the economy provided ample opportunity for carry traders to borrow yen very cheaply and invest in high-yielding currencies, in many cases in fixed-income securities. The total amount of yen carry trades has been estimated at around $1 trillion (Cecchetti, Fender and McGuire Reference Cecchetti, Fender and McGuire2010). The attractiveness of yen carry trades diminished with the onset of the financial crisis, as the differentials between interest rates in yen and in other currencies narrowed and exchange rate volatility increased (Bank of Japan 2009, p. 65). Japanese banks' net external yen-denominated assets had continued to increase in the second half of 2007 and the first half of 2008, but there was a large flow of yen-denominated funds into Japanese banks in the second half of 2008 (Table 8), which is most naturally interpreted as the unwinding of yen carry trades. The unwinding was reflected mainly in a fall in the assets and liabilities of foreign banks located in Japan; domestically owned banks were barely affected. The dollar equivalent of the fall in the banks' net external assets between September 2008 and the end of 2009 was about $185 billion.

Table 8. Selected assets and liabilities of banks located in Japan: changes from end July 2008 to end December 2009 (JPY billion)

Source: Bank of Japan.

The unwinding of yen carry trades affected the countries in which the proceeds had been invested. The pre-crisis inflows to New Zealand were into bonds rather than bank deposits, so that the crisis did not cause a liquidity shortage there. However, the New Zealand dollar depreciated heavily, and 10-year bond yields remained little changed, after a brief dip, despite short-term interest rates falling from around 9 to around 3 per cent. New Zealand's current account balance of payments deficit narrowed from 8.7 per cent of GDP in 2008 to 2.9 per cent in 2009.

Carry trades were also undertaken in Swiss francs, notably in Hungary and Poland where Swiss franc-denominated mortgages became very popular. In 2008, more than half of total outstanding mortgages in both countries were denominated in foreign currencies, mainly Swiss francs. The lending banks had financed themselves largely with short-term wholesale market borrowing and when they were unable to roll over the borrowings they were forced to swap their domestic currencies, or sell them outright, for Swiss francs. The pressures thus created led to the drying up of FX swap markets and the Hungarian and Polish currencies depreciated sharply in the spot foreign exchange market. The pressures were partly relieved when the Swiss National Bank provided facilities for the central banks of Hungary and Poland to swap euros from their reserves for Swiss francs (Allen and Moessner Reference Allen and Moessner2010, section 11).

The nearest interwar analogue to carry trades was perhaps the international flows of funds which took place in the 1920s and 1930. In discussing the risks of present-day carry trades, Eichengreen (Reference Eichengreen2010) comments that ‘I could cite various historical illustrations of the danger. The locus classicus again is the Great Depression. The carry trade contributed to the unstable equilibrium of the 1920s, as investors funded themselves at 3% in New York to lend to Germany at 8%. Then as now, the migration of capital from low- to high-interest-rate countries was predicated on the mirage of stable exchange rates.’ Investors in the United States, for example, were attracted by the higher yields available on foreign bonds than on domestic ones. The principal borrower was Germany, whose current account deficit was much larger than its postwar reparation payments. Germany's issuance of long-term foreign loans between 1924 and 30 June 1931 amounted to RM 9.6 billion ($400 million, 9.6 per cent of Germany's GDP in 1931) and its short-term external debts in July 1931 were RM 12.0 billion ($500 million, 20.5 per cent of GDP). However, the flows were not unwound after the banking crises of 1931; rather, there was a wave of bond defaults, standstill agreements and exchange controls, following the banking crises in the debtor countries.Footnote 32

VI

The propagation of the two crises had some common features. The flight to liquidity and safety was a leading characteristic of both. There was a sudden wave of suspicion about the safety of assets which had hitherto been regarded as secure, and institutions which were thought to be over-exposed to such newly doubtful assets were subject to the risk of liquidity crises if they had short-maturity liabilities fixed in money value. In both crises, deposit outflows were not the only important sources of liquidity pressure on banks: in 1931, the central European acceptances of the London merchant banks were a serious problem, as, in 2008, were the liquidity commitments that commercial banks had provided to shadow banks. And in both crises, the managers of central banks' international reserves participated in the flight to liquidity and safety in the same way as other market participants. In 1931, the international transmission of the liquidity pressure was direct, since the London accepting houses were creditors of the debtors who could not repay; by contrast, in 2008 it was indirect, as the collateral squeeze which originated in the mortgage market put great pressure on foreign banks in the United States, which in turn transmitted it to other countries.

In both crises, the behaviour of creditors towards debtors, and vice versa, and the valuation of assets by creditors, were very important. The decision of the creditors of the central European countries during the 1931 crisis to reach standstill agreements, rather than declaring loans in default, meant that higher valuations could be placed on the debts. This made a difference to the immediate outlook for financial and economic stability in both central Europe and in the creditor countries, since defaults would probably have precipitated bank failures in the latter. The standstill agreements, together with the Bank of England's forbearance with regard to standstill bills, gave the accepting houses time to adjust while remaining in business (eight years, as it turned out), and thus performed a similar function to the Fed's provision of emergency liquidity to banks and broker-dealers in 2008. Market participants knew that the standstill bills might not be repaid, and in that sense they had full information. Nevertheless, it is arguable that the Bank of England's forbearance involved a deliberate distortion of the valuation of the bills and in that sense was not transparent, and that this instance of non-transparency helped to protect financial stability in the UK in 1931.

In 2008, the environment was very different. Gorton (Reference Gorton2010, chapter 3) argues that wholesale financial markets dried up because it was very difficult for holders of mortgage-backed securities to know how far they were exposed to subprime mortgage risk, and impossible for wholesale financial market participants to know how far their trading counterparties were exposed to it. In the absence of active markets, it was impossible to mark holdings of mortgage-backed securities to market for valuation purposes, and holders were driven to value them by reference to proprietary models, which, even though approved by regulators, did not carry conviction in the market. Audited accounts showing positive net worth did not provide reassurance as to solvency. In 2008, non-transparency was seriously damaging to financial stability.

However, there was a very important difference between the two crises, in the range and nature of assets that were regarded as ‘safe havens’ – i.e. which were regarded as liquid and safe. Central banks provided much more liquidity after the 2008 crisis than they had done in 1931, when they had been inhibited by the constraints of the gold standard. And inter-central bank co-operation worked far better: official international liquidity provision in 1931 was inadequate, whereas in 2008 Federal Reserve swap lines relieved many of the financial stresses in countries outside the United States that had followed Lehman Brothers' failure (Moessner and Allen Reference Moessner and Allen2011).

The gold standard set a benchmark for liquidity and safety that could be met only by assets of a certain kind, namely gold and assets which could be confidently expected to be convertible into gold at the parity rate. Commercial banks had experienced financial stress in many countries, there was no deposit insurance, and commercial bank liabilities were in many cases not regarded as safe. Budget deficits were regarded as incompatible with continued adherence to the gold standard. When doubts arose about particular classes of assets, such as claims on commercial banks, there was a scramble for assets in the elite group. The group included the liabilities (notes and deposits) of central banks which were regarded as being securely attached to the gold standard, but those central banks felt unable to expand their balance sheets much, partly for fear of undermining their ability to remain on the gold standard. They were unable to implement Bagehot's remedy for a banking crisis, of lending freely against good collateral at a high interest rate (Bagehot Reference Bagehot1892, pp. 198–201). As a result, monetary policy was very tight in gold standard countries, despite the depression, and countries abandoned the gold standard when its effects became intolerable, notably the United Kingdom in 1931 and the United States in 1933. As countries left the gold standard and their currencies depreciated, the pressures on those that remained increased. In fact, no country was still on the gold standard after 1936. The supply of liquid and safe assets was not only inelastic, but it also contracted over time, and the gold standard, being therefore incompatible with satisfactory management of the crisis, collapsed.

In 2008, a wider range of assets was regarded as liquid and safe, even though the relative prices of assets within the group could change. The group included deposits in a wide range of central banks, including those of the countries with the largest banking systems, and a wide range of government securities. Market participants were much more tolerant of budget deficits than they had been in the 1930s. Most governments accepted contingent liability for the safety of at least some bank deposits, and in some cases expanded deposit insurance even though the recession induced by the financial crisis had weakened their own finances. Crucially, it was possible to implement Bagehot's remedy and to expand the supply of liquid and safe assets massively without undermining their credibility among market participants. Thus central banks were able in effect to take on the function of money market intermediaries, as wholesale deposits migrated onto their balance sheets, and as they on-lent the funds to relieve shortages elsewhere in the market. Large budget deficits (which would have been anathema in 1931) emerged as automatic fiscal stabilisers came into operation and as some countries additionally undertook discretionary fiscal easing, and the contingent liabilities that most governments accepted for the security of at least some bank liabilities became more threatening. Nevertheless there was no serious loss of confidence in the safety of most governments' debts.Footnote 33

Thus the international monetary system, comprising both official institutions and the set of prevailing market beliefs, was much less fragile and much more resilient in 2008 than it had been in 1931. As a result, the near-term consequences of the recent crisis have been much less severe. It is too early to tell what the longer-term consequences might be.

Footnotes

2 Williams (Reference Williams1963) denotes the period that began in May 1931 as the ‘final phase’ of the crisis and describes how the crisis developed until then. For an account of the Austrian crisis, see Cottrell (Reference Cottrell, Roberts and Kynaston1995).

3 See e.g. Friedman and Schwartz (Reference Friedman and Schwartz1963), Bernanke and James (Reference Bernanke and James1991/2000), Ahamed (Reference Ahamed2009), Ritschl (Reference Ritschl2009). Accominotti (Reference Accominotti2011, p. 2) finds that ‘the 1931 crash accounts for most of the observed co-movement in international markets during the 1930s. Not only was the 1931 crisis the most global financial shock of the Great Depression, but it also acted divisively.’

4 The data in Table 2 are not fully consistent with the data in Section II, which are mainly from national sources. The differences are not large enough to affect our interpretation of the data.

5 James (Reference James2001, pp. 70–4) argues plausibly that bank liquidity was an important influence on official decision-making in the UK.

6 Nevertheless, the Fed went to great lengths in 2008 to prevent money market mutual funds from ‘breaking the buck’, by establishing the Asset-backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility and the Money Market Investor Funding Facility. The Fed commented that: ‘Without additional liquidity in the money markets, forced sales of ABCP could have depressed the price of ABCP and other short-term instruments, resulting in a cycle of losses to MMMFs and even higher levels of redemptions and a weakening of investor confidence in MMMFs and the financial markets’ (see www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_amlf.htm).

7 See for example Pozsar et al. (Reference Pozsar, Adrian, Ashcraft and Boesky2010).

8 At that time commercial banks disclosed much less about their financial condition than they do these days, so that there was plenty of scope for such doubt.

9 Source: Maddison (Reference Maddison2010).

10 Source: League of Nations Statistical Yearbook 1932–3, table 125.

11 For example, the retail price index of 34 products sold in Paris fell by 12.8 per cent during 1931 (source: Bulletin de Statistique Generale, accessible on NBER historical statistics website). Williams (Reference Williams1963, p. 101) says that a series of bank failures in France in 1930 stimulated the demand for banknotes, but data published by the League of Nations show that the note circulation rose by FRF 9.3 billion in 1931, whereas bank deposits fell by just FRF 1.5 billion.

12 For a description of the Banque de France and its activities, see Mouré (Reference Mouré1991, chapter 4).

13 Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley became bank holding companies on 23 September 2008, which enabled them to improve their access to Federal Reserve financing and thereby improve their market credibility. Merrill Lynch agreed to a takeover by Bank of America during the weekend before Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy. Their fortunes in the immediate post-Lehman period are vividly related in the report of the United States Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (FCIC 2011, chapter 20)

14 See also International Monetary Fund (2010, chapter 2).

15 Singh and Aitken (Reference Singh and Aitken2009) suggest that the withdrawals by hedge funds were motivated by fears of rehypothecation, that is, the fear that their assets would be pledged by the prime broker as collateral for the prime broker's own borrowing, and that they would be hard or impossible to disentangle if the prime broker became insolvent.

16 The reported decreases in asset holdings in September–November will include the effects of falls in the prices of assets held at the end of August, as well as of transactions during the three months.

17 Note that whereas Morgan Stanley's borrowings from the Fed peaked at $100 billion on 29 September 2008, the collateral it had pledged to the Fed at that date was valued at $225 billion.

18 Of course, some of the sales of ABCP were made by money market mutual funds that had experienced heavy redemptions.

19 The run on money market mutual funds and its effect on foreign banks in the US are documented by Baba, McCauley and Ramaswamy (Reference Baba, McCauley and Ramaswamy2009). Fender and Gyntelberg (Reference Fender and Gyntelberg2008, p. 9) estimate that investors withdrew $184 billion from money market mutual funds between 10 and 24 September 2008. Another indication of the scale of the run is that drawings on the facility set up by the Fed to finance purchases of commercial paper from MMMFs, which began operations on 22 September 2008, reached $150.7 billion on 2 October.

20 Why did foreign banks not borrow more from the Fed? Perhaps they were concerned about being stigmatised as weak banks if the fact of their large borrowing became public; perhaps in some cases they did not have the right kind of collateral; perhaps raising funds from foreign affiliates was perceived as less costly than borrowing from the Fed, though the last seems unlikely in the light of the disruption that the withdrawal of dollar funds caused in foreign money markets.

21 See also Committee on the Global Financial System (2010a) on cross-border funding pressures and proposed measures to address them, and Committee on the Global Financial System (2010b). The more complex determinants of liquidity risk in many currencies are discussed in Domanski and Turner (Reference Domanski and Turner2011, pp. 4-10).

22 Readers unfamiliar with acceptance credits are recommended to consult the account in Accominotti (Reference Accominotti2009, section 2).

23 See Diaper (Reference Diaper1986, p. 69) and Roberts (Reference Roberts1992, pp. 252–3). It appears that the Bank of England did in the event provide financial support to certain accepting houses: see Sayers (Reference Sayers1976, p. 531). The position that the Bank took in 1931 was very different from the one it took in comparable circumstances in 1914: see Sayers (Reference Sayers1976, pp. 77-8).

24 The Macmillan report, published on 13 July 1931, had disclosed that the UK's short-term external liabilities were much larger than its short-term external assets. Its estimate of short-term external liabilities as at 31March 1931 was £407 million in deposits, bills and advances, plus £153 million in acceptances (Committee on Finance and Industry Report 1931, appendix I, table 11). This estimate has now been superseded (it was too low). The Bank of England's gold reserves averaged £142 million in March 1931 (appendix II).

25 Demand and time deposits in the ten London clearing banks were £950 million and £792 million, respectively, in June 1931. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1976, section 15, table 168).

26 See Billings and Capie (Reference Billings and Capie2010, table 1) for details.

27 For the definition of financial instability on which the judgement is based, see Allen and Wood (Reference Allen and Wood2006).

28 See Sayers (Reference Sayers1976, appendix 23).

29 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1976, table 168). The figure of £586 million includes cash reserves, money at call and short notice, and bills discounted.

30 For further discussion, see Moessner and Allen (Reference Moessner and Allen2011).

31 Data on short-term international indebtedness are as quoted by Moessner and Allen (Reference Moessner and Allen2011).

32 Copious information is provided in Royal Institute of International Affairs (1937). Yields on domestic and foreign bonds issued in the United States are shown on p. 170 and Germany's external debts are quantified and discussed on pp. 234–9.

33 There were exceptions, as noted in Section II.

References

REFERENCES

Accominotti, O. (2009). London merchant banks, the central European panic, and the sterling crisis of 1931. Available at http://web-docs.stern.nyu.edu/old_web/economics/docs/FinHist/Accominotti_SterlingCrisis.pdf.Google Scholar
Accominotti, O. (2011). Asymmetric propagation of financial crises during the Great Depression. Available at www2.lse.ac.uk/economicHistory/whosWho/profiles/oaccomminotti@lseacuk.aspx.Google Scholar
Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2009). The shadow banking system: implications for regulation. Banque de France Financial Stability Review no. 13, September, pp. 1–10.Google Scholar
Adrian, T. and Shin, H. S. (2010). Liquidity and leverage. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 328. Available at www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr328.pdf.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance. London: Windmill Books.Google Scholar
Aiyar, S. (2011). How did the crisis in international funding markets affect bank lending? Balance sheet evidence from the United Kingdom. Bank of England Working Paper no. 424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, W. and Moessner, R. (2010). Central bank co-operation and international liquidity in the financial crisis of 2008-9. Bank for International Settlements Working Paper no. 310.Google Scholar
Allen, W. and Moessner, R. (2011). The collateral squeeze of 2008. Central Banking, 21(3), pp. 84–9.Google Scholar
Allen, W. and Wood, G. (2006). Defining and achieving financial stability. Journal of Financial Stability, 2, pp. 152–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baba, N., McCauley, R. and Ramaswamy, S. (2009). US dollar money market funds and non-US banks. BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp. 6581.Google Scholar
Bagehot, W. (1892). Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market, 10th edition. London: Kegan Paul, French, Trübner & Co.Google Scholar
BANK FOR INTERNATIONAL SETTLEMENTS (1933). Third Annual Report.Google Scholar
BANK OF JAPAN (2009). Financial markets report. Reports and Research Papers, March. Available at www.boj.or.jp/en/type/ronbun/mkr/data/mkr0903.pdf.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. and James, H. (1991/2000). The gold standard, deflation and financial crisis in the Great Depression: an international comparison. Reprinted in B. Bernanke, Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Billings, M. and Capie, F. (2010). Financial crisis, contagion and the British financial system between the wars. Unpublished MS.Google Scholar
BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM (1976). Banking and Monetary Statistics.Google Scholar
Brown, W. A. JR (1940). The International Gold Standard Reinterpreted 1914–1934. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Cecchetti, S., Fender, I. and McGuire, P. (2010). Toward a global risk map. BIS Working Paper no. 309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
COMMITTEE ON FINANCE AND INDUSTRY (1931). Report. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office (Macmillan report).Google Scholar
Cetorelli, N. and Goldberg, L. (2009). Banking globalization and monetary transmission. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 333. Available at http://newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr333.pdf.Google Scholar
COMMITTEE ON THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM (2010a). The functioning and resilience of cross-border funding markets. CGFS Papers no. 37.Google Scholar
COMMITTEE ON THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM (2010b). Funding patterns and liquidity management of internationally active banks. CGFS Papers no. 39.Google Scholar
Copeland, A., Martin, A. and Walker, M. (2010). The tri-party repo market before the 2010 reforms. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 477. Available at http://data.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr477.pdf.Google Scholar
Cottrell, P. L. (1995). The Bank in its international setting. In Roberts, R. and Kynaston, D. (eds.), The Bank of England: Money, Power and Influence, 1694–1994. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bundesbank, Deutsche (1976). Deutsches Geld- und Bankwesen in Zahlen 1876–1975. Frankfurt am Main: Fritz Knapp.Google Scholar
Diaper, S. (1986). Merchant banking in the inter-war period: the case of Kleinwort, Sons & Co. Business History, 28(4), pp. 5576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domanski, D. and Turner, P. (2011). The great liquidity freeze: what does it mean for international banking? Asian Development Bank Institute Working Paper Series no. 291.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1995). Golden Fetters – the Gold Standard and the Great Depression 1919–1939. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (2010). The Great Recession and the Great Depression: reflections and lessons. Central Bank of Chile Working Papers no. 593.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. and Flandreau, M. (2008). The rise and fall of the dollar, or when did the dollar replace sterling as the leading international currency. NBER Working Paper no. 14154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fender, I. and Gyntelberg, J. (2008). Overview: global financial crisis spurs unprecedented policy action. BIS Quarterly Review, December, pp. 124.Google Scholar
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (FCIC, 2011). Report. US Government Printing Office. Available at http://fcic.law.stanford.edu/report.Google Scholar
Forbes, N. (1987). London banks, the German standstill agreements, and ‘economic appeasement’ in the 1930s. Economic History Review, 2nd series, 40(4), pp. 571–87.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. (1963). A Monetary History of the United States 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Gorton, G. (2010). Slapped by the Invisible Hand: The Panic of 2007. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gorton, G. and Metrick, A. (2009). Securitized banking and the run on repo. NBER Working Paper no. 15223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND (2010). Global Financial Stability Report. October.Google Scholar
James, H. (2001). The End of Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2010). Statistics on world population, GDP and per capita GDP, 1–2008 AD. Available at www.ggdc.net/maddison/content.shtml.Google Scholar
McCauley, R. N. and Rigaudy, J.-F. (2011). Managing foreign exchange reserves in the crisis and after. In Bank for International Settlements, Portfolio and Risk Management for Central Banks and Sovereign Wealth Funds, BIS Papers no. 48, pp. 19–47.Google Scholar
Moessner, R. and Allen, W. (2011). Banking crises and the international monetary system in the Great Depression and now. Financial History Review, 18(1), pp. 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mouré, K. (1991). Managing the Franc Poincaré: Economic Understanding and Political Constraint in French Monetary Policy 1928–1936. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pihlmann, J. and Van der Hoorn, H. (2010). Procyclicality in central bank reserve management: evidence from the crisis. IMF Working Paper WP 10/150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pozsar, Z., Adrian, T.Ashcraft, A. and Boesky, H. (2010). Shadow banking. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 458. Available at www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr458.html.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritschl, A. (2009). War 2008 das neue 1931? Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, 20/2009. Available at www.bpb.de/files/PQYS6J.pdf.Google Scholar
Roberts, R. (1992). Schroders: Bankers and Merchants. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, R. (1995). The Bank and the City. In Roberts, R. and Kynaston, D. (eds.), The Bank of England: Money, Power and Influence, 1694–1994. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ROYAL INSTITUTE OF INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS (1937). The Problem of International Investment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sayers, R. S. (1976). The Bank of England 1891–1944, 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sheppard, D. K. (1971). The Growth and Role of UK Financial Institutions 1880–1962. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Singh, M. and Aitken, J. (2009). Deleveraging after Lehman – evidence from reduced rehypothecation. IMF Working Paper WP/09/42.Google Scholar
Truptil, R. J. (1936). British Banks and the London Money Market. London: Jonathan Cape.Google Scholar
Williams, D. (1963). The 1931 crisis. Yorkshire Bulletin of Economic and Social Research, 15(2), pp. 513–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. US commercial banks' net debt to related foreign offices and Fed swaps outstanding (in US$ billion)aAll commercial banks; not seasonally adjusted.bWednesday level.Sources: Federal Reserve tables H8 and H4.1.

Figure 1

Table 1. Exchange-rate adjusted changes in commercial banks' net external liabilities in the second half of 2008 (US$ billion)

Figure 2

Table 2. Changes in gold and foreign exchange reserves in 1931

Figure 3

Figure 2. Central bank balance sheet size, 2007–2009 (in national currencies, mid 2007 = 100)Sources: Datastream, national data.

Figure 4

Table 3. Changes in central and commercial bank balance sheets in gold-losing countries in 1931 (US$ million, except where shown)

Figure 5

Table 4. Changes in central and commercial bank balance sheets in gold-receiving countries in 1931 (US$ million)

Figure 6

Table 5. Condensed balance sheet of Morgan Stanley, 2008 (US$ billion)

Figure 7

Table 6. US commercial banks: changes in selected balance sheet items from 3 September 2008 to end December 2008 (US$ billion)

Figure 8

Table 7. J. Henry Schröder and Co., balance sheet 1929–39 (£ million)

Figure 9

Table 8. Selected assets and liabilities of banks located in Japan: changes from end July 2008 to end December 2009 (JPY billion)