Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-g4j75 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T07:09:44.616Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Ownership and M&A Performance in a Transitional Economy: The Case of the Chinese Real Estate Industry

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 October 2015

Hongyan Yang
Affiliation:
The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, China
Jing Ru
Affiliation:
Peking University, China
Ting Ren
Affiliation:
Peking University, China
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In a transitional economy such as China's, when resources are unevenly distributed across different sectors, the disadvantaged sector may seek a growth path that bypasses resource constraints. We investigated this phenomenon in the context of the Chinese real estate industry. By comparing the post–merger and acquisition (M&A) performance of acquiring firms between state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and privately-owned enterprises (POEs), we attempted to show that POEs are better performers in the market should they be granted equitable resources, and the superior performance is strengthened by market-oriented institutional environment. We used M&A events data of publicly listed real estate firms in China from 2004 to 2012, in conjunction with firm characteristics and province-level market environment data. We found the results to be consistent with our hypotheses. In particular, compared to SOEs, privately-owned acquiring firms tend to have better post-M&A performance when both the regions of the acquirer and the target have high level of marketization. The results suggest that the private sector in China's transitional economy is potentially more efficient than the state-owned sector, as long as the market environment is favorable.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The International Association for Chinese Management Research 2015 

INTRODUCTION

Through mergers and acquisitions (M&As), acquiring firms seek to advance financial capability and increase firm value. Previous studies suggest that firms’ M&A performance might be influenced by acquiring firms’ previous M&A experience, the prior relationship between the acquiring and target firms, the organization structure of the acquiring firm, and the payment method of M&A (Agrawal, Jaffe, & Mandelker, Reference Agrawal, Jaffe and Mandelker1992; Hayward, Reference Hayward2002; Hayward & Hambrick, Reference Hayward and Hambrick1997; Walker, Reference Walker2000). Despite the above, the conventional wisdom about why M&As fail to improve the performance of the acquiring firm is entrenched in the divergent interests between the owners and the managers of the acquiring firm (Bebchuk & Grinstein, Reference Bebchuk and Grinstein2005; Hayward & Hambrick, Reference Hayward and Hambrick1997; Roll, Reference Roll1986).

In an emerging economy such as that of China, the divergent interest between the managers of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and the state owners generates severe problems affecting firm efficiency in decision-making and operation (Kornai, Reference Kornai1986; Kornai, Maskin, & Roland, Reference Kornai, Maskin and Roland2003). However, SOEs in an emerging economy may obtain various support and resources from the government, such as better material supplies and distribution networks (Luo & Tan, Reference Luo and Tan1998), or easier access to financing from state-controlled banks and government bailouts (Buckley, Clegg, Cross, Liu, Voss, & Zheng, Reference Buckley, Clegg, Cross, Liu, Voss and Zheng2007; Faccio, Masulis, & McConnell, Reference Faccio, Masulis and McConnell2006; Nguyen, Le, & Bryant, Reference Nguyen, Le and Bryant2013). Regardless of a series of reforms to privatize the state-owned sector and establish privately-owned enterprises (POEs) in the economy (McMillan & Woodruff, Reference McMillan and Woodruff2002), SOEs have regained momentum in recent years (Meyer, Reference Meyer2011). The debate over the appropriate role of the state in economic organizations and the implications for state ownership continues to be waged (Micklethwait, Reference Micklethwait2011). To extend this line of thinking, our study investigates the difference in post-M&A performance between SOEs and POEs and further examines how different regional institutions may influence the post-M&A performance gap between SOEs and POEs in China's transitional economy.

During the institutional transition, the variance of institutional settings affects firms’ performance (Kogut & Zander, Reference Kogut and Zander2000). In transitional economies, market-facilitating institutions, such as property rights protection, capital markets, labor markets, and regulatory authorities, are not as well developed as they are in developed economies (Allen, Qian, & Qian, Reference Allen, Qian and Qian2005). Furthermore, different from developed economies, large-scale transitional economies such as China have imbalanced development of institutional environments across subregions (Chan, Makino, & Isobe, Reference Chan, Makino and Isobe2010). It is of particular interest in the present study to investigate how the heterogeneous institutional environments of the acquiring and target firms will affect the post-M&A performance of different types of acquiring firms.

The real estate industry in China, one of the most heavily intervened industries by the Chinese government (Tian & Ma, Reference Tian and Ma2009), becomes an appropriate setting to observe the impact of ownership difference and institutional variance on firm M&A performance. In China, urban land is officially owned by the state, whereas rural land is collectively owned (Ding, Reference Ding2003; Ho & Lin, Reference Ho and Lin2003). The state controls the land market through its monopolization of the sale of land-use rights. Compared to POEs, the state-owned developers have better opportunities to secure land due to their closer relationship with the government, which owns the ultimate rights over the land (Zhang, Reference Zhang2012).

In recent years, there have been a large number of M&A events in the Chinese real estate industry, allowing detailed investigation of the research question. M&As provide acquiring firms with unique access to valuable resources held by target firms (Das & Teng, Reference Das and Teng2000; Wernerfelt, Reference Wernerfelt1984). Real estate developers may secure land from target firms through M&As, because land is a major asset of firms, and the transaction of pure land ownership between firms is not permitted in China. Therefore, the key motive for firms in the real estate industry to acquire other firms is to obtain the major asset of the industry and grow. For historical reasons, a substantial amount of urban lands were allocated to SOEs. These SOEs became acquiring targets in the process of reform and restructuring, especially attracting cross-region M&As.

Cross-region M&As within Mainland China inevitably face the difficulty of dealing with heterogeneous institutional environments. The decentralization of control from the central to local governments has allocated the rights of revenue collection to local governments, leading to the autonomy of the regional government and the variation in institutional environments across regions (Tsui, Reference Tsui2005; Wong, Reference Wong2000; Xu, Reference Xu2011). China has formed a mixture of legal, administrative, and market mechanisms where the market plays an ‘invisible hand’ role, with the local government's intervention (Tan, Li, & Xia, Reference Tan, Li and Xia2007). Since China has a vast disparity in terms of the depth of market economy across regions and provinces (Fan, Wang, & Zhu, Reference Fan, Wang and Zhu2010), companies do not face a uniform institutional environment when they operate business in different locations of the country. When real estate companies pursue M&As across regions, they need to adapt to different environments, and the institutional differences influence M&A activities and performance.

We compared the post-M&A performance between SOEs and POEs and further examined the institutional influence on the difference. In so doing, we were able to demonstrate that a particular kind of institutional environment may benefit the development of the private sector. Our empirical results indicate that, in general, privately-owned acquiring firms outperform SOEs, and such advantage is stronger when both the regions of the acquiring firm and the target firm have a high level of marketization but weaker to none when either of the regions has a low level of marketization.

This study contributes to both theory building and practical policymaking. First, it extends the theory of corporate governance by suggesting that the ownership structure not only influences firms’ performance, but also has an impact on firms’ post-M&A performance. Second, the study examined the subnational institutions’ impact on firms’ post-M&A performance. It adds to our understanding of the heterogeneity of institutions in institutional theory. The heterogeneity of institutional environment complicates the M&A process from both the acquiring and target firm sides. It guides our thinking about cross-region M&As in different institutional environments in a transitional economy context. Third, our study advocates possible solutions to private firm owners and managers alike in the transitional economy that M&As might be an effective way to overcome the resource constraints and grow in such an institutional environment.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESES

On the basis of a survey of 334 published articles on M&As in the top 16 leading business journals from 1980 to 2010, Santos, Ferreira, Reis, and Almeida (Reference Santos, Ferreira, Reis and Almeida2012) concluded that no single theory is dominant in M&A research; most M&A research is based on four theoretical perspectives: agency theory, institutional theory, transaction cost theory, and resource-based view. Research has shown that institutional environments generate various constraints under which a rational economic actor makes a decision, consequently affecting behaviors and outcomes (La Porta, Lopea-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, Reference La Porta, Lopea-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny1997; Lee, Peng, & Barney, Reference Lee, Peng and Barney2007; Peng, Sun, Pinkham, & Chen, Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009). For studying firm strategies in emerging economies, institutional theory has also been recognized as one of the most relevant perspectives (Hoskisson, Eden, Lau, & Wright, Reference Hoskisson, Eden, Lau and Wright2000; Nguyen et al., Reference Nguyen, Le and Bryant2013; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009; Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson, & Peng, Reference Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson and Peng2005). However, treating institutions as only a background will hinder deeper understanding of a firm's strategic behavior (e.g., Clougherty, Reference Clougherty2005; Oliver & Holzinger, Reference Oliver and Holzinger2008), and the deficiency can be more salient in emerging economies such as China where the institutional arrangements are quite distinct from the developed economies (Lau & Bruton, Reference Lau and Bruton2008). Consistent with the call for research on the effects of a firm's external environment on managing resources (Bettis & Hitt, Reference Bettis and Hitt1995; Sirmon, Hitt, & Ireland, Reference Sirmon, Hitt and Ireland2007), M&A research has also been increasingly focusing on the effects of institutional environments, including governmental, societal, and political, on firm performance (Santos et al., Reference Santos, Ferreira, Reis and Almeida2012).

Rising to the preeminent position in strategy research over the past two decades or so (Lockett, Thompson, & Morgenstern, Reference Lockett, Thompson and Morgenstern2009), the resource-based view stresses that a firm's competitive advantage lies in the firm's unique resources that are valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-substitutable (Barney, Reference Barney1986, Reference Barney1991; Wernerfelt, Reference Wernerfelt1984). Through M&As, firms may gain a shortcut access to or control over these kinds of unique resources (Barkema & Vermeulen, Reference Barkema and Vermeulen1998; Karim & Mitchell, Reference Karim and Mitchell2000). It is not the resource per se that matters, but how the resource is employed to explain performance differences (Peteraf & Bergen, Reference Peteraf and Bergen2003; Wernerfelt, Reference Wernerfelt1984). Therefore, acquiring firms may benefit from their investments when they create a uniquely valuable combination of their assets with those of the acquired firm.

Institutional context is considered crucial to influence resource decisions to achieve firm competitive advantage (Oliver, Reference Oliver1997). Recent research has called for the integration of the resource-based view and the institutional perspective on examining firm strategy, behavior, and performance in emerging economies (Peng, Reference Peng2003; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009). In emerging economies, scholars particularly emphasize the impact of institutions on firm strategic decisions, resource acquisition, and firm performance (Peng, Wang, & Jiang, Reference Peng, Wang and Jiang2008; Yamakawa, Peng, & Deeds, Reference Yamakawa, Peng and Deeds2008). For instance, some researchers have examined the impact of market-supporting institutions on entry strategies when foreign investors enter emerging economies (Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik, & Peng, Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009). Aligned with this stream of research, the present study shows how the institutional environment at a subnational level affects POEs’ performance against SOEs when M&A is employed as a strategic choice in China's transitional economy.

Ownership Difference in Acquiring Firms’ M&A Performance

In a transitional economy, connections with government provide firms a favorable environment in which to operate businesses (Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000). SOEs tend to have convenient access to critical resources, such as better material supplies and distribution networks (Luo & Tan, Reference Luo and Tan1998), and financial capital from state-controlled banks and government bailouts (Faccio et al., Reference Faccio, Masulis and McConnell2006; Nguyen et al., Reference Nguyen, Le and Bryant2013), due to the incentive alignment with government brought about by state ownership. SOEs gain through resource leverage with help from the government relationship in enhanced financial performance (Sun, Tong, & Tong, Reference Sun, Tong and Tong2002), improved operation efficiency (Tian & Estrin, Reference Tian and Estrin2008), and increased innovative capacity (Steensma & Yang, Reference Steensma and Yang2013).

However, support from government is a double-edged sword. Most prominently, the ‘soft budget’ constraint of state ownership hampers the incentives of SOE managers to compete in the market (Kornai, Reference Kornai1986; Kornai et al., Reference Kornai, Maskin and Roland2003; Ramamurti, Reference Ramamurti2000). This incentive issue is evidenced by the finding that state-owned firms’ easy access to long-term debt is positively associated with long-term investment and negatively associated with firm performance (Li, Yue, & Zhao, Reference Li, Yue and Zhao2009). Private owners, in contrast, have the incentive to maximize the performance of their firms and are disciplined by threats of bankruptcy and takeover (Hanke, Reference Hanke and Hanke1987), which is supported by research findings that, together with collectively-owned enterprises, POEs outperform SOEs in profitability and productivity when controlling for tax rate (Park, Li, & Tse, Reference Park, Li and Tse2006).

Furthermore, the government is concerned with its own interests and extorts profits from businesses (Frye & Shleifer, Reference Frye and Shleifer1997; Shleifer & Vishny, Reference Shleifer and Vishny1998). Political objectives such as maintaining employment instead of maximizing profits hurt SOEs’ efficiency (Boycko, Shleifer, & Vishny, Reference Boycko, Shleifer and Vishny1996; Estrin & Perotin, Reference Estrin and Perotin1991). To make things worse, these political objectives often change from one administration to the next, generating uncertainty of government policies that hampers the efficiency of SOEs’ operation and governance and hinders enterprise restructuring (Frydman, Hessel, & Rapaczynski, Reference Frydman, Hessel and Rapaczynski1998; Netter & Megginson, Reference Netter and Megginson2001). As a trade-off of government support, SOEs may suffer from political control in the selection and replacement of top managers, who are appointed directly by the government (Xu, Zhu, & Lin, Reference Xu, Zhu and Lin2005). This creates uncertainties at the organizational level, impeding the management and control of the firm. Due to their close relationship with the government, SOEs suffer more than POEs from government intervention (Netter & Megginson, Reference Netter and Megginson2001).

Following the reasons above, we offer several explanations for the potential superior post-M&A performance of POEs over SOEs. First, POEs and SOEs differ in motives when selecting M&A targets. The selection of the acquiring target affects the performance of the acquiring firm. As an independent and rational market player, a POE is more likely to follow the rules of profit maximization to select acquiring targets. In contrast, regardless of business feasibility, SOEs are likely to follow government's political goals, such as a plan of industrial restructuring or individual promotion (Brouthers & Bamossy, Reference Brouthers and Bamossy1997; Uhlenbruck & De Castro, Reference Uhlenbruck and De Castro2000). On the contrary, POEs tend to select M&A targets based upon market-oriented motivation to integrate and recombine the resources in order to achieve synergy and better firm performance. Different motives lead to different outcomes. Non-market-oriented M&A motives of SOEs lead to lower M&A market performance, while market-oriented POEs’ M&A motives lead to higher M&A market performance.

Second, the multiple goals of SOE acquiring firms will distract their effort from consolidating the target firm's resources and assets in an effective way. For example, in order to maintain employment, SOEs are less likely to downsize the acquired target. Lack of management knowledge and skills also hampers how acquiring firms integrate and make use of the target firm to achieve synergy. Given the external intervention from government and internal lack of management knowledge, SOEs may not be able to effectively integrate the acquired firm. As evident in Zhang, Zhou, and Ebbers (Reference Zhang, Zhou and Ebbers2011), Chinese SOEs are less likely to succeed in an overseas acquisition than are other types of acquiring enterprises.

Third, post-M&A communication between the acquiring firm and the target firm is vital for M&A success (Stahl & Sitkin, Reference Stahl, Sitkin, Stahl and Mendenhall2005). The bureaucracy regime of SOEs generates conflicts and difficulties during the post-M&A process, especially when sufficient value exchanges and communications are missing (Ellis, Reus, & Lamont, Reference Ellis, Reus and Lamont2009). Even though both the acquiring firm and the target firm are SOEs, they cannot establish an effective communication mechanism and integrate (Zhang et al., Reference Zhang, Zhou and Ebbers2011). In contrast, POE acquiring firms may be able to take advantage of their flexibility and effectiveness to select an M&A target and successfully integrate the target company to achieve synergy and competitive advantage.

In the Chinese real estate industry, due to the institutional background described above, privately-owned developers cannot compete with state-owned developers, especially the largest central-government-owned ones, in acquiring land from the government. Therefore, M&As are the alternative for the POEs in the industry to acquire this important resource and grow. As M&As are relatively competitive business activities, we expect POEs to perform better than SOEs as acquiring firms.

Hypothesis 1: The post-M&A performance of POEs as acquiring firms will be better than that of SOEs as acquiring firms in China's real estate industry.

Institutional Influence, Ownership, and Acquiring Firms’ M&A Performance

Institutional environments are able to influence the firm's decision-making, behavior, and performance (La Porta et al., Reference La Porta, Lopea-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny1997; Lee, Peng, & Barney, Reference Lee, Peng and Barney2007; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Sun, Pinkham and Chen2009). For example, Vaaler and Schrage (Reference Vaaler and Schrage2009) found that policy stability affects firms’ choice of residual state ownership. Although some policies are set at the national level, the implementation is often carried out at the regional level (Meyer & Nguyen, Reference Meyer and Nguyen2005). Different regions in China have formed quite diverse cultural and institutional settings due to historical and political factors (Xu, Reference Xu2011). Fan et al. (Reference Fan, Wang and Zhu2010) generated a provincial level marketization index that incorporates factors such as government-market relationships, development of the nonstate sector, market intermediaries, and contract enforcement, indicating that the development of the institutional environment varies greatly across provincial regions in China. Consequently, firms develop different capabilities, such as market and nonmarket capabilities, to adapt to the distinct institutional environments (Griffiths & Zammuto, Reference Griffiths and Zammuto2005; Wan, Reference Wan2005).

Market-facilitating institutions typically encompass several key features: effective legal framework and its enforcement, sufficient protection of property rights, transparent information systems, and rigorous regulatory regimes (Meyer et al., Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009). The quality of such institutions, where either the acquiring firm or the target firm operates, affects the integration process and post-M&A performance of SOE or POE acquiring firms. SOE and POE firms have their distinct competitive advantages in the transitional market. SOEs have access to rare resources under the control of the government (Li & Xia, Reference Li and Xia2008; Peng, Tan, & Tong, Reference Peng, Tan and Tong2004), whereas POEs are more efficient and effective to adapt to market changes (Peng et al., Reference Peng, Tan and Tong2004; Tan, Reference Tan2002). In particular, when both the acquiring and target firms are in the environment with high level of marketization, POEs are able to use their advantageous position over SOEs to select and access target firms and to obtain sufficient resources and support from the institutional environment to integrate target firms. Therefore, POEs are more likely to achieve synergy and enhance the competitive advantages through M&A activities in such a favorable institutional environment. In the following, we further illustrate the institutional effects of the target firm's region, acquiring firm's region, and their combinational effects on the ownership difference in firm post-M&A performance.

When the target firm is in a region with a high level of marketization, the local government tends to help to overcome resource constraints by liberalizing markets within its authority to attract investment (Meyer & Nguyen, Reference Meyer and Nguyen2005), suggesting fewer interventions in target firms’ business operations. On the other hand, well-developed regions, compared to underdeveloped regions, have easier access to the statistics and information about market size, economic growth, infrastructure, investment policies, business partners, and their likely behaviors (He, Reference He2002). Available information contributes to reducing information asymmetry and transaction costs of undertaking the due diligence and contract negotiations necessary for acquisitions and post-M&A restructuring (Peng, Reference Peng2006). The efficiency and effectiveness of POEs can be more prominent than SOEs, since market-facilitating institutions usually come with sufficient competition. Based upon their advantageous market knowledge and management skills, POEs have better capabilities than SOEs to identify the potential value of acquisition and to select the target firm accordingly. In addition, a good market institution of the target firm ensures investor protection in order to accomplish M&A integration and share continuous interests, generating gains for the acquiring firm (Moeller & Schlingemann, Reference Moeller and Schlingemann2005).

When the acquiring firm is in a region with a high level of marketization, the market institutions affect the acquiring firm's overall competitive capabilities (Capron & Guillén, Reference Capron and Guillén2009). Without resource constraints vis-à-vis SOEs, POE acquiring firms tend to hold favorable positions against SOE counterparts in competitive markets with well-established institutions. For instance, banks in the regions equipped with better institutions may reduce discrimination against the private sector, whereas more available alternative financing channels may alleviate financial constraints over private firms (Li et al., Reference Li, Yue and Zhao2009), and the specialized market intermediaries such as law firms and accounting firms in the well-established market may have enough knowledge to deal with various problems in the M&A transaction process. However, SOEs may lose their competitive advantage, since they have less opportunity to obtain additional support from government. Under such circumstances, market-based capabilities rather than interpersonal relationships (for example, political ties) are gradually implemented to achieve good performance (Luo, Huang, & Wang, Reference Luo, Huang and Wang2012; Peng et al., Reference Peng, Wang and Jiang2008).

The market-oriented institutional environment on both acquiring and target sides provides a most favorable environment for POE acquiring firms to leverage their competitive advantage potential and results in superior post-M&A performance. In the post-M&A stage, the integration between the acquiring and target firms is affected by the organizational culture and administrative structure embedded in their regions, respectively. The compatibility of the organizational culture and administrative structure between the acquiring and target firms assists the communication between the two organizations and facilitates learning (Brock, Reference Brock2005; Vermeulen & Barkema, Reference Vermeulen and Barkema2001). On the contrary, unsuccessful integration directly impedes the synergy or competitive advantage the acquiring firm wants to achieve (Appelbaum, Gandell, Yortis, Proper, & Jobin, Reference Appelbaum, Gandell, Yortis, Proper and Jobin2000). In summary, although the high quality of both the acquiring firm and the target firm can benefit both POEs and SOEs, POEs will gain more while SOEs’ relative advantage from government support and intervention will decline; therefore, POEs’ competitive advantage over SOEs can be strengthened in achieving superior post-M&A performance.

In contrast, underdeveloped market institutions spawn obstacles in the M&A process, preventing POEs from demonstrating competitive advantages over SOEs. When target firms are in regions with low level of marketization, government intervention and volatility in the policy regime hinders M&A target assessment and selection (Aybar & Ficici, Reference Aybar and Ficici2009). When acquiring firms are in regions with low level of marketization, it is difficult for POEs to accumulate adequate market knowledge under serious resource constraint. SOE acquiring firms may obtain additional support of favorable resources such as financial capital from the government. However, that support is likely attached to nonmarket goals of the government.

Even though the acquiring firm is from a region with relatively high level of marketization, it still faces the uncertainty and complexity of choosing a valuable target firm in a region with a relatively low level of marketization. Overall, if the institutional difference between the acquiring firm in a region with a high level of marketization and the target firm in a region with a low level of marketization is substantial, it will hamper the M&A performance by preventing synergy and learning (Vermeulen & Barkema, Reference Vermeulen and Barkema2001).

In summary, only when both the acquiring and target firms are in developed market institutions is the post-M&A performance difference between POE and SOE acquiring firms more pronounced. When either the target or acquiring firm is in an underdeveloped market environment, the intervention of government and imbalanced distribution of key resources will impede the M&A motive, process, and post-M&A integration, leading to the diminishing of the competitive advantage of POEs over SOEs.

Hypothesis 2: The superior post-M&A performance of POEs over SOEs as acquiring firms will be stronger when both the acquiring and target firm regions are of high level of marketization than the other three situations when either the acquiring or the target firm region is of low level of marketization.

METHOD

Sample

We used a sample of Chinese publicly listed real estate firms from the Wind M&A database, which is provided by the Wind Information Company, a leading financial data provider in Mainland China. The initial sample included completed Chinese M&A events in which acquiring firms are listed real estate developers in the main board (A-share) market. We recorded the date of disclosure of a deal as the event date. After linking to the provincial statistical data, the sample spans from 2004 to 2012. We adopted several criteria to organize unusual events. First, we removed the events that were conducted by the related parties of the acquiring firms. These events were not directly conducted by the listed acquiring firms themselves, but were required to be reported by the acquiring firms and, therefore, included in the database. Second, if one event occurs through several phases within a year, we combined the different transactions into one event. Third, if one acquiring firm acquires different targets within one year, we treated them as different events. Last, we used trade volume to control for the effect on the acquiring firm's performance.

The sample includes a total of 599 events. For each event, we recorded information on the event date; ownership status of the acquiring firm; ownership status of the target firm; acquisition type (share or asset acquisition); proportion of shareholding on the target firm; trade volume; business relatedness of the acquiring firm and the target firm; age and size of the acquiring firm; acquisition experience of the acquiring firm; locations of the acquiring firm and the target firm; GDP per capita of their provinces; and year-end financial data. Regarding the information that is not released in the database, we checked the details from individual M&A public reports. According to China Stock Exchange regulation, the publicly listed firms are required to release an announcement when there is an event potentially causing substantial stock price fluctuation. All of the public reports are released by listed firms according to the information disclosure regulation under the supervision of the China Securities Regulatory Commission.

We also collected information about market environment for the 31 province-level administrative regions, including provinces and municipalities in Mainland China (Fan et al., Reference Fan, Wang and Zhu2010), and matched the data with the regions of the acquiring firm and the targets in each M&A event. We used the registration place as the acquiring firm's region and checked the M&A public reports for the target's region.

Among the sample M&A events, 81% are business-related M&As, indicating the clear attempt to acquire the core resource, the land, through M&As. As a matter of fact, more M&A events occurred in the eastern area than the rest of the country. Guangdong, Shanghai, Zhejiang, Beijing, and Tianjin are the top five province-level regions hosting M&A events, accounting for about 71.45% of total M&A events as the origin of the acquiring firms and about 58.26% as the home of the target firms. Also, the M&As boomed in 2008 when the number of M&A events reached 144, more than 8 times higher than that in the previous year, indicating that real estate firms may be more willing to pursue M&As during financial crises because of the lower asset value than that during typical times.

Measures

Dependent variable

We used Tobin's Q as the dependent variable to measure post-M&A performance of the acquiring firms. Tobin's Q is a common indicator of expected long-run firm performance, which is calculated as the ratio of the market value to the replacement cost of a firm (Lindenberg & Ross, Reference Lindenberg and Ross1981). In the regression analyses, we used the difference of the current and the previous year-end data to capture the potential performance balance achieved from the M&A events in the past year. Therefore, the dependent variable is ∆Tobin's Q. This indicator, along with some others, is often used by researchers to examine the performance change that is generally seen as the result of M&A events (Bruner, Reference Bruner2002).

Independent variables

Acquiring firm ownership is a dichotomous variable indicating the ownership type of the acquiring firm. It is characterized by two groups: 1 if the acquiring firm is a POE, 0 if the acquiring firm is a SOE. We used ownership type of the actual controller of the acquiring firm to measure this variable. In most cases, the actual controller is the largest shareholder. Only in rare cases is the actual controller not the largest shareholder but instead controls the company through particular agreements or arrangements. In the Chinese context, although the firm's actual controller may not be the largest shareholder at times, the firm tends to follow the behavioral and performance patterns of a sole ownership type (Li, Xia, Long, & Tan, Reference Li, Xia, Long and Tan2012).

Control variables

We controlled for a number of other factors that might impact firm performance from M&As, which can be classified by three dimensions: deal characteristics, firm characteristics, and characteristics of the firm's region. There are five control variables of deal characteristics. Acquisition type (share or asset acquisition) is 1 if the target is stock equity, and 0 if the target is asset. Proportion of shareholding is the percentage of the target's total shares that the acquiring firm obtained through an M&A event, indicating the degree of transfer of control right from the target firm to the acquiring firm; for asset targets, the value of the variable is 0. Volume-to-size ratio is the amount paid by the acquiring firm for the M&A event divided by the acquiring firm's previous year's total assets. Relatedness is captured as a dummy variable coded as 1 if the business of the target firm is related to real estate, such as property development, property management, and construction, and 0 if otherwise. Target firm ownership is 1 if the target is owned by a POE, and 0 if the target is owned by an SOE.

Several firm characteristic variables are controlled for. Size is the natural log of the acquiring firm's book value of total assets at the end of last year. Studies have shown that firm size can systematically affect a range of strategic and performance variables (for example, Keats & Hitt, Reference Keats and Hitt1988) and acquiring firms’ M&A performance (Bruner, Reference Bruner2002). Age is the duration of the firm from the founding year to the year that the M&A event occurred. Experience is the level of general acquisition experience, a simple count of the accumulated number of M&As previously completed by the same acquiring firm.

In addition, there are control variables related to characteristics of the firm's provincial location. Same region is 1 if both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in the same province, and 0 otherwise. Acquiring firm GDP per capita and target firm GDP per capita are the logarithm of GDP per capita of the acquiring firm province and the target firm province of the previous year, respectively, measuring the economic development of the regions. We included year dichotomous variables for the period 2004–2012. Table 1 provides descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations for the variables.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations

Notes: a N = 599, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 (two-sided test).

Following Fan et al. (Reference Fan, Wang and Zhu2010), we constructed two variables to describe the market environment in which the M&A events occurred. First, the degree of proportion of market allocation of resources (PMAR) was 1 minus the ratio of provincial government expenditure to provincial GDP, reversely indicating the degree of government interference in a province. In the analysis, we constructed the indicator for acquiring firms and target firms separately. Second, the social fixed asset invested by non-state-owned sector (SFAINS) was 1 minus the ratio of social fixed asset invested by state-owned sector to the total social fixed asset investment at the provincial level, suggesting the depth of private investment in the region. We also constructed separately the variable for acquiring firms and target firms.

Analysis

We adopted multivariate linear regressions to investigate the main relationship between ownership type of the acquiring firms and M&A performance, as measured by ∆Tobin's Q. We further divided the full sample into four groups by the median of the two dimensional variables that measure the degree of favorable market environment for POEs in the acquiring firm's and the target's regions, PMAR and SFAINS, respectively. If both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in regions with high (above median) PMAR (SFAINS) level, we labeled the group as a High-High (H-H) group. By the same token, we constructed groups of L-L, H-L, and L-H. Each group includes a different number of M&A events.

Evidently, M&A events were more likely to occur between regions with similar levels of market characteristics. By the PMAR dimension, 230 of the 599 total events (or 38%) occurred in the H-H group, and 228 (or 38%) occurred in the L-L group; only 80 and 61 events each (13% and 10%, respectively) occurred in the H-L and L-H groups. By the SFAINS dimension, 239 of the 599 total events (or 40%) occurred in the H-H group, and 238 (or 40%) took place in the L-L group; only 61 events (or around 10%) occurred in both the H-L and L-H groups.

RESULTS

We summarize the regression results of ownership difference in M&A performance of acquiring firms in Tables 2 and 3, according to the two dimensions of marketization levels measured by PMAR and SFAINS in the acquiring firm's and the target's regions, respectively, with control over other confounding factors. We found supportive results with Hypothesis 1 in the estimates using ∆Tobin's Q as the dependent variable (first columns in Tables 2 and 3, p < 0.01), which indicates more performance improvement from M&As initiated by POEs than SOEs. To dispel potential concern with the self-selection issue, for instance, the lower performance of SOEs is not driven by their lower competence, but rather it is declining performance that drives them to acquire, we checked the previous performance, as measured by Tobin's Q, of SOE acquiring firms three years prior to M&As and did not find an obvious pattern of performance decline.

Table 2. Ownership difference in M&A performance of acquiring firms – PMAR

Notes: *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01 (two-sided test). H-H: both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in the regions with high (above median) level of marketization (measured by PMAR); L-L: both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in the regions with low level of marketization. H-L: the acquiring firm is in the region with high level of marketization, while the target firm is in the region with low level of marketization. L-H: the acquiring firm is in the region with low level of marketization, while the target firm is in the region with high level of marketization.

Table 3. Ownership difference in M&A performance of acquiring firms – SFAINS

Notes: *p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01 (two-sided test). H-H: both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in the regions with high (above median) level of marketization (measured by SFAINS); L-L: both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in the regions with low level of marketization. H-L: the acquiring firm is in the region with high level of marketization, while the target firm is in the region with low level of marketization. L-H: the acquiring firm is in the region with low level of marketization, while the target firm is in the region with high level of marketization.

We further examined the M&A effects on the acquiring firms’ performance under four different scenarios of market environment. The H-H scenario suggests that the M&A event occurs between regions both with high level of marketization, measured by the (reversed) degree of government intervention (PMAR) or the degree of nonstate investment (SFAINS). By the same token, we have three other scenarios that are labeled L-L, H-L, and L-H. From these sets of analyses, we attempted to show the exact market institutional environment that may be more suitable for POEs in terms of more evidently demonstrating their competitive advantages vis-à-vis SOEs.

Table 2 presents results when the sample is divided into groups by the PMAR dimension. First, looking at the H-H column, when both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in regions with high level of PMAR, privately-owned acquiring firms achieve better-than-SOEs M&A performance, as measured by ∆Tobin's Q (p < 0.01). This result supports Hypothesis 2. Second, the results also suggest that privately-owned acquiring firms may perform better than SOEs in scenario L-L to a much lesser degree (p < 0.10), and the comparison of M&A performance between POEs and SOEs in scenarios H-L and L-H is not evident. This set of results is consistent with Hypothesis 2.

Table 3 shows similar patterns of results when the sample is divided into groups by the SFAINS dimension, which is another way to consider the marketization level in the region. From the H-H column, we find privately-owned acquiring firms achieve better-than-SOEs M&A performance, as measured by ∆Tobin's Q (p < 0.01), supporting Hypothesis 2. No evident difference between POEs and SOEs is found in the other three scenarios. These results are also consistent with Hypothesis 2.

To check the robustness of the previous results, we analyzed three sets of alternative explanation. First, in order to distinguish institutional influence from the level of growth of specific provincial real estate markets, we examined M&As that occurred in the same province with the same institutional environment. In our study, 351 of the 599 total events (or 59%) occurred in the same province. The results are consistent with the previous analyses: POEs are likely to have better M&A performance than SOEs when they are in supporting market-oriented institutional settings. Second, we checked how the institutional distance between the two regions affects the difference in M&A performance. The results show that similar institutional settings facilitate private firms to maintain advantage over SOEs in M&A activities. If the institutional distance between the acquiring firm and the target firm is too large, private ownership may not help or may even hurt M&A performance. Third, we made a two-year lag of the dependent variable to show the firm performance change after the M&A event. The results are consistent. For the interest of space, the results of robustness check are not shown here but are available from the authors upon request.

DISCUSSION

In this study, we investigated the post-M&A firm performance in the transitional economy context. Particularly, we compared and contrasted the post-M&A firm performance between SOEs and POEs. We further examined the moderating role of the institutional context at the subnational level. We found that POEs’ performance is generally better than that of SOEs in M&A activities, and the performance gap is more pronounced when the market institution is more developed in both the acquiring firm region and the target firm region. These results confirm our observation that, in the context of the Chinese real estate industry, private firms often suffer from resource constraints in a transitional economy. Further, in the Chinese real estate industry, when SOEs are more accessible to lands facilitated by abundant financial support from the government and the state-owned banks, POEs may seek M&As as an alternative to overcome the resource constraints and to expand the business.

Our study is based upon previous findings that private ownership generally outperforms state ownership (e.g., Megginson, Reference Megginson2005; Park et al., Reference Park, Li and Tse2006). We applied the rationale to firm post-M&A performance. Firm ownership type not only influences overall firm performance, but also post-M&A performance. In addition, we emphasized the important impact of regional institutional environment in the transitional economy.

Our study suggests that the post-M&A performance difference between POEs and SOEs is the greatest when both the acquiring firm and the target firm are in regions of more market-oriented regional institutional environment. We viewed China as a natural lab of heterogeneous institutional environment across regions and investigated how the diversifying institutional environment affects the M&A performance of firms. We examined both the acquiring and target firms’ institutional environment, not only considering the impact from the external environment but also the cultural and administrative proximity between the acquiring and target firms. The present study enriches institutional theory by providing evidence on how the heterogeneity of the institutions affects firm behavior in M&A activities and their pathways to growth. Consistent with the previous subnational institution research of foreign investment strategies (Chan, Makino, & Isobe, Reference Chan, Makino and Isobe2010; Meyer & Nguyen, Reference Meyer and Nguyen2005), we found that the diverse institutions cross regions do matter even when M&A transactions occurred only between local firms. Furthermore, our study recognizes that both home and host market institutions affect the acquiring firm's M&A performance, where previous studies mostly focused on the host market institutions. We contributed to the growing related literature by presenting the interactive effect of firm ownership and subnational institutions.

Limitations and Future Research Directions

There are several limitations of the present study. First, we followed the convention to use the type of actual controller as the criterion to define ownership status. However, ownership structure of firms in China has become more complicated, and even minor state ownership existing in private firms may have significant impact on firm behavior (Tian & Estrin, Reference Tian and Estrin2008; Vaaler & Schrage, Reference Vaaler and Schrage2009). Second, although controlling for the ownership of target firms, we still lack detailed information about nonlisted target firms, and target firms’ participation in post-M&A decision-making and process is not evident. Third, post-M&A integrations such as retention of top management team, financial evaluation, due diligence, conversion of information system, human resources integration, and sales and product integration are all important aspects to analyze post-M&A performance (Appelbaum et al., Reference Appelbaum, Gandell, Yortis, Proper and Jobin2000), but they are not covered in the present study due to the scope of the research question and availability of data.

In lieu of the limitations, future research may extend the investigation to the circumstances of mix ownership and residual state shareholding of firms and incorporate post-M&A decision-making, process, and integration into the analytic framework. In addition, the interactive impact of ownership and subnational institutions can be generalized to other cross-region strategic actions, and other institutional indicators, such as bank loans for private business and law enforcement efficiency (Allen et al., Reference Allen, Qian and Qian2005), can be specifically analyzed to enrich the understanding of institutional environment.

Practical Implications

The findings from the study have some practical implications. They suggest that the market-oriented environment may help POEs to secure important resources in China's transitional economy. Therefore, based on the findings of the study, in order to develop the private sector, the government in transitional economies should take measures to improve the market environment, such as reducing interference in firm operations, encouraging nonstate investment, and raising the degree of marketization. As shown by the study, private ownership will eventually demonstrate its advantage over state ownership, should it be granted an equitable market environment.

This study answers the question of how POEs in a transitional economy have grown rapidly in a resource-constrained environment. We suggested that M&As could become an important alternative way for POEs in the Chinese transitional economy to overcome the resource constraints and grow. In an underdeveloped market institution, resource allocation to firms is not efficient or effective. Corporate managers in such an environment might concentrate on M&A activities in order to obtain rare resources and grow. Government policy makers in the transitional economy might generate policies that facilitate the transactions of M&As to consolidate resources and encourage the growth of POEs.

Our research sheds light on different types of transactions in a transitional market according to the diverse institutional environments. In order to adapt to the institutional environment, firms might want to choose relevant strategies, such as M&A, strategic alliances, or others. Furthermore, the choices of firm strategies may aggregately shape the institutional development in the transitional economy, particularly in such a diversified institutional environment at the regional level in China.

CONCLUSION

The present study is motivated by the phenomenon in China's transitional economy that private enterprises suffer constraints in key resources while having governance advantages against SOEs. Focusing on the M&A context and the real estate industry, the study reveals that POEs do excel SOEs in post-M&A performance, should the institutional environment be market oriented and favorable to POEs. The findings suggest that the disadvantaged private sector may seek M&A as an alternative growth path to bypass resource constraints and realize its competitive advantages; however, the attempt can only be achieved in a healthy market environment. Hence, the study calls for further attention from both academia and policy makers to the interplay of ownership and subnational institutional context in China's transitional economy. While the private sector has become a substantial economic growth engine in China, its status still falls short of optimal establishment and demands substantial institutional improvement to secure its further development and contribution to the advancement of the national economy.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/mor.2015.30

Footnotes

The first author gratefully acknowledges the financial support from the Management and Marketing Department of Hong Kong Polytechnic University.

Accepted by: Heli Wang

References

REFERENCES

Agrawal, A., Jaffe, J. F., & Mandelker, A. N. 1992. The post-merger performance of acquiring firms: A re-examination of an anomaly. Journal of Finance, 47 (4): 16051621.Google Scholar
Allen, F., Qian, J., & Qian, M. 2005. Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics, 77 (1): 57116.Google Scholar
Appelbaum, S. H., Gandell, J., Yortis, H., Proper, S., & Jobin, F. 2000. Anatomy of a merger: Behavior of organizational factors and processes throughout the pre-during-post-stages (part 1). Management Decision, 38 (9): 649662.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aybar, B., & Ficici, A. 2009. Cross-border acquisitions and firm value: An analysis of emerging-market multinationals. Journal of International Business Studies, 40 (8): 13171338.Google Scholar
Barkema, H., & Vermeulen, G. 1998. International expansion through start-up or through acquisition: An organizational learning perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 41 (1): 726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32 (10): 12311241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17 (1): 99120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebchuk, L. A., & Grinstein, Y. 2005. Firm expansion and CEO pay. Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper No. 533; Johnson School Research Paper No. 27-06.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettis, R. A., & Hitt, M. A. 1995. The new competitive landscape. Strategic Management Journal, 16 (S1): 719.Google Scholar
Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1996. A theory of privatization. Economic Journal, 106: 309319.Google Scholar
Brock, D. M. 2005. Multinational acquisition integration: The role of national culture in creating synergies. International Business Review, 14 (3): 269288.Google Scholar
Brouthers, K. D., & Bamossy, G. J. 1997. The role of key stakeholders in international joint venture negotiations: Case studies from Eastern Europe. Journal of International Business Studies, 28: 285308.Google Scholar
Bruner, R. F. 2002. Does M&A pay? A survey of evidence for the decision-maker. Journal of Applied Finance, 12 (1): 4868.Google Scholar
Buckley, P. J., Clegg, L. J., Cross, A. R., Liu, X., Voss, H., & Zheng, P. 2007. The determinants of Chinese outward foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (4): 499518.Google Scholar
Capron, L., & Guillén, M. 2009. National corporate governance institutions and post-acquisition target reorganization. Strategic Management Journal, 30 (8): 803833.Google Scholar
Chan, C. M., Makino, S., & Isobe, T. 2010. Does subnational region matter? Foreign affiliate performance in the United States and China. Strategic Management Journal, 31 (11): 12261243.Google Scholar
Clougherty, J. 2005. Antitrust holdup, cross-national institutional variation, and corporate political strategy implications for domestic mergers in a global context. Strategic Management Journal, 26 (8): 769790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Das, T. K., & Teng, B. S. 2000. A resource-based theory of strategic alliances. Journal of Management, 26 (1): 3161.Google Scholar
Ding, C. 2003. Land policy reform in China: Assessment and prospects. Land Use Policy, 20 (2): 109120.Google Scholar
Ellis, K. M., Reus, T. H., & Lamont, B. T. 2009. The effects of procedural and informational justice in the integration of related acquisitions. Strategic Management Journal, 30: 137161.Google Scholar
Estrin, S., & Perotin, V. 1991. Does ownership always matter? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9 (1): 5572.Google Scholar
Faccio, M., Masulis, R. W., & McConnell, J. J. 2006. Political connections and corporate bailouts. Journal of Finance, 61 (6): 25972635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fan, G., Wang, X., & Zhu, H. 2010. NERI index of marketization of China provinces 2009 report (in Chinese). Beijing: Economic Science Press.Google Scholar
Frydman, R., Hessel, M. P., & Rapaczynski, A. 1998. Why ownership matters? Politicization and entrepreneurship in the restructuring of enterprises in Central Europe. Economic Research Reports No. 98–14, C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics, New York University.Google Scholar
Frye, T., & Shleifer, A. 1997. The invisible hand and the grabbing hand. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 87 (2): 354358.Google Scholar
Griffiths, A., & Zammuto, R. F. 2005. Institutional governance systems and variations in national competitive advantage: An integrative framework. Academy of Management Review, 30 (4): 823842.Google Scholar
Hanke, S. H. 1987. The necessity of property rights. In Hanke, S. H. (Ed.), Privatization and development: 4751. San Francisco: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Hayward, M. L. A. 2002. When do firms learn from their acquisition experience? Evidence from 1990–1995. Strategic Management Journal, 23: 2139.Google Scholar
Hayward, M. L. A., & Hambrick, D. C. 1997. Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42 (1): 103127.Google Scholar
He, C. 2002. Information costs, agglomeration economies and the location of foreign direct investment in China. Regional Studies, 36 (9): 10291036.Google Scholar
Ho, S. P. S., & Lin, G. C. S. 2003. Emerging land markets in rural and urban China: Policies and practices. China Quarterly, 175: 681707.Google Scholar
Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43 (3): 249267.Google Scholar
Karim, S., & Mitchell, W. 2000. Path-dependent and path-breaking change: Reconfiguring business resources following acquisitions in the U.S. medical sector, 1978–1995. Strategic Management Journal, 21 (10): 10611081.Google Scholar
Keats, B. W., & Hitt, M. A. 1988. A causal model of linkages among environmental dimensions, macro organizational characteristics and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 31: 570598.Google Scholar
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 2000. Did socialism fail to innovate? A natural experiment of the two Zeiss companies. American Sociological Review, 65 (2): 169190.Google Scholar
Kornai, J. 1986. The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39 (1): 330.Google Scholar
Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. 2003. Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41 (4): 10951136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Porta, R., Lopea-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. 1997. Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52: 11311150.Google Scholar
Lau, C. M., & Bruton, G. D. 2008. FDI in China: What we know and what we need to study next. Academy of Management Perspectives, 22 (4): 3044.Google Scholar
Lee, S. H., Peng, M. W., & Barney, J. B. 2007. Bankruptcy law and entrepreneurship development: A real options perspective. Academy of Management Review, 32 (1): 257272.Google Scholar
Li, K., Yue, H., & Zhao, L. 2009. Ownership, institutions, and capital structure: Evidence from China. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37 (3): 471490.Google Scholar
Li, S., & Xia, J. 2008. The roles and performance of state firms and nonstate firms in China's economic transition. World Development, 36: 3954.Google Scholar
Li, S., Xia, J., Long, C. X., & Tan, J. 2012. Control modes and outcomes of transformed state-owned enterprises in China: An empirical test. Management and Organization Review, 8 (2): 283309.Google Scholar
Lindenberg, E. B., & Ross, S. A. 1981. Tobin's Q ratio and industrial organization. Journal of Business, 54: 132.Google Scholar
Lockett, A., Thompson, S., & Morgenstern, U. 2009. The development of the resource-based view of the firm: A critical appraisal. International Journal of Management Reviews, 11 (1): 928.Google Scholar
Luo, Y., & Tan, J. J. 1998. A comparison of multinational and domestic firms in an emerging market: A strategic choice perspective. Journal of International Management, 4 (1): 2140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, Y., Huang, Y., & Wang, S. L. 2012. Guanxi and organizational performance: a meta-analysis. Management and Organization Review, 8 (1): 139172.Google Scholar
McMillan, J., & Woodruff, C. 2002. The central role of entrepreneurs in transition economies. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16 (3): 153170.Google Scholar
Megginson, W. L. 2005. Financial economics of privatization. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, K. E., Estrin, S., Bhaumik, S. K., & Peng, M. W. 2009. Institutions, resources, and entry strategies in emerging economies. Strategic Management Journal, 30 (1): 6180.Google Scholar
Meyer, K. E., & Nguyen, H. V. 2005. Foreign investment strategies and sub-national institutions in emerging markets: evidence from Vietnam. Journal of Management Studies, 42 (1): 6393.Google Scholar
Meyer, M. W. 2011. Is it capitalism? Management and Organization Review, 7 (1): 518.Google Scholar
Micklethwait, J. 2011. Taming Leviathan: A special report on the future of the state. Economist Newspaper.Google Scholar
Moeller, S. B., & Schlingemann, F. P. 2005. Global diversification and bidder gains: A comparison between cross-border and domestic acquisitions. Journal of Banking and Finance, 29 (3), 533564.Google Scholar
Netter, J., & Megginson, W. 2001. From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39 (2): 321389.Google Scholar
Nguyen, T. V., Le, N. T. B., & Bryant, S. E. 2013. Sub-national institutions, firm strategies, and firm performance: A multilevel study of private manufacturing firms in Vietnam. Journal of World Business, 48 (1): 6876.Google Scholar
Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advantage: Combining institutional and resource-based views. Strategic Management Journal, 18 (9): 697713.Google Scholar
Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. 2008. The effectiveness of strategic political management: A dynamic capabilities framework. Academy of Management Review, 33 (2): 496520.Google Scholar
Park, S. H., Li, S., & Tse, D. K. 2006. Market liberalization and firm performance during China's economic transition. Journal of International Business Studies, 37 (1), 127147.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28 (2): 275296.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2006. Making M&A fly in China. Harvard Business Review, 84 (3): 2627.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. 2000. Managerial ties and firm performance in a transition economy: The nature of a micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal, 43:486501.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., Tan, J., & Tong, T. W. 2004. Ownership types and strategic groups in an emerging economy. Journal of Management Studies, 41 (7): 11051129.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., Sun, S. L., Pinkham, B., & Chen, H. 2009. The institution-based view as a third leg for a strategy tripod. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23 (3): 6381.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., Wang, D., & Jiang, Y. 2008. An institution-based view of international business strategy: A focus on emerging economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39: 920936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peteraf, M., & Bergen, M. 2003. Scanning dynamic competitive landscapes: A market-based and resource-based framework. Strategic Management Journal, 24 (10): 10271041.Google Scholar
Ramamurti, R. 2000. A multilevel model of privatization in emerging economies. Academy of Management Review, 25 (3): 525550.Google Scholar
Roll, R. 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business, 59: 197216.Google Scholar
Santos, J. C., Ferreira, M. P., Reis, N. R., & Almeida, M. R. 2012. Mergers and acquisitions research: A bibliometric study of top strategy and international business journals. globADVANTAGE Center of Research in International Business and Strategy Working Paper No. 91.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1998. The grabbing hand: Government pathologies and their cures. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sirmon, D. G., Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. 2007. Managing firm resources in dynamic environments to create value: Looking inside the black box. Academy of Management Review, 32 (1): 273292.Google Scholar
Stahl, G. K., & Sitkin, S. B. 2005. Trust in mergers and acquisitions. In: Stahl, G. K. & Mendenhall, M. (Eds.), Mergers and acquisitions: Managing culture and human resources: 82102. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Steensma, H. K., & Yang, H. 2013. The influence of state ownership on innovation in market competition. Academy of Management Proceedings, 2013 (1): 15283.Google Scholar
Sun, Q., Tong, W. H., & Tong, J. 2002. How does government ownership affect firm performance? Evidence from China's privatization experience. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 29: 127.Google Scholar
Tan, J. 2002. Impact of ownership type on environment, strategy, and performance: Evidence from China. Journal of Management Studies, 39 (3): 333354.Google Scholar
Tan, J., Li, S., & Xia, J. 2007. When iron fist, visible hand, and invisible hand meet: Firm-level effects of varying institutional environments in China. Journal of Business Research, 60 (7): 786794.Google Scholar
Tian, L., & Estrin, S. 2008. Retained state shareholding in Chinese PLCs: Does government ownership always reduce corporate value? Journal of Comparative Economics, 36 (1): 7489.Google Scholar
Tian, L., & Ma, W. 2009. Government intervention in city development of China: A tool of land supply. Land Use Policy, 26 (3): 599609.Google Scholar
Tsui, K. Y. 2005. Local tax system, intergovernmental transfers and China's local fiscal disparities. Journal of Comparative Economics, 33 (1): 173196.Google Scholar
Uhlenbruck, K., & De Castro, J. O. 2000. Foreign acquisitions in Central and Eastern Europe: Outcomes of privatization in transitional economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43 (3): 381402.Google Scholar
Vaaler, P. M., & Schrage, B. N. 2009. Residual state ownership, policy stability and financial performance following strategic decisions by privatizing telecoms. Journal of International Business Studies, 40 (4): 621641.Google Scholar
Vermeulen, F., & Barkema, H. 2001. Learning through acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal, 44 (3): 457476.Google Scholar
Walker, M. M. 2000. Corporate takeovers, strategic objectives, and acquiring-firm shareholder wealth. Financial Management, 29 (1): 5366.Google Scholar
Wan, W. P. 2005. Country resource environments, firm capabilities, and corporate diversification strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 42 (1): 161182.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5 (2): 171180.Google Scholar
Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W. 2005. Strategy research in emerging economies: Challenging the conventional wisdom. Journal of Management Studies, 26 (1): 133.Google Scholar
Wong, C. 2000. Central-local relations revisited: The 1994 tax sharing reform and public expenditure management in China. China Perspectives, 31: 5263.Google Scholar
Xu, C. 2011. The fundamental institutions of China's reforms and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 49 (4): 10761151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, L. C., Zhu, T., & Lin, Y. M. 2005. Politician control, agency problems and ownership reform. Economics of Transition, 13 (1): 124.Google Scholar
Yamakawa, Y., Peng, M. W., & Deeds, D. 2008. What drives new ventures to internationalize from emerging to developed economies? Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, 32 (1): 5982.Google Scholar
Zhang, J., Zhou, C., & Ebbers, H. 2011. Completion of Chinese overseas acquisitions: Institutional perspectives and evidence. International Business Review, 20 (2): 226238.Google Scholar
Zhang, Y. 2012. Institutional sources of reform: The diffusion of land banking systems in China. Management and Organization Review, 8 (3): 507533.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations

Figure 1

Table 2. Ownership difference in M&A performance of acquiring firms – PMAR

Figure 2

Table 3. Ownership difference in M&A performance of acquiring firms – SFAINS

Supplementary material: File

Yang supplementary material

Translated abstracts

Download Yang supplementary material(File)
File 14.3 KB