1. Introduction
The multilateral trading system is in crisis. The causes are many: the collapse of the Doha Round; the paralysis of the Appellate Body; the abuse of the national security exception by the United States (US); the proliferation of unilateral measures; and last, but certainly not least, the trade war between the two big powers, the US and China, which has lasted for almost two years. The conclusion and signing of a bilateral Phase One trade dealFootnote 1 on 15 January 2020 has temporarily prevented further escalation of the trade war. The deal, however, has left most existing retaliatory tariffs intactFootnote 2 and has institutionalized the unilateral and confrontational approach to resolving disputes, which could reignite the bilateral trade tensions.Footnote 3 Moreover, the deal does not address the more significant and systemic issues, such as China's state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and industrial policies and subsidies. Instead, these issues are expected to be addressed by the two parties in their Phase Two negotiations.Footnote 4 Against this backdrop, it is reasonable to expect that the resolution of the US–China trade tensions will remain a hot topic in international trade.
As attempts to broker peace between the two, many proposals have been proffered. The latest is a thought-provoking joint statement entitled ‘US–China Trade Relations: A Way Forward’ (hereinafter ‘Statement’) and issued by a group of eminent Chinese/US economists and legal scholars on 27 October 2019.Footnote 5 As the product of the ‘US–China Trade Policy Working Group’ led by Jeffrey Lehman, Dani Rodrik and Yang Yao, the Statement counts among its illustrative list of signatories five Nobel laureates, three former Chief Economists of the World Bank, and some of the leading figures in the field of international trade such as Alan Deardoff, Gene Grossman, Robert Howse, Gregory Shaffer, Anne-Marie Slaughter, Robert Staiger, Michael Trebilcock, and David Trubek.
The Statement has received good coverage in major international media.Footnote 6 According to the Statement, the current discussion on US–China economic relations is futile as it has been cast as a binary choice between either ‘deep integration’ or ‘decoupling’. The Statement rejects the false dichotomy between the two and instead advocates a middle ground that grants more policy space to both countries than normally allowed under WTO rules. More specifically, for example, the Statement would allow ‘China to conduct its industrial and growth policies’ and ‘the US to safeguard its labor markets and technological systems’. This is achieved by classifying trade policies according to a ‘Four Buckets’ framework (Framework), which is designed to ‘promote productive negotiations about how to share the benefits and minimize the harms that attend bilateral trade, and to facilitate fair competition in the multilateral sphere of international trade’.
The ‘Four Buckets’ are reproduced below for accuracy and ease of analysis:
-
Bucket 1 (The ‘Prohibited’ Bucket): In this Bucket, Country A's actions or policies are likely to create significant distortions in global markets and can be presumed to entail global economic losses. It is appropriate that international norms prohibit actions or policies in this Bucket. ‘Beggar thy neighbor’ policies [footnote omitted] are canonical examples that fall under this Bucket. For example, country A may impose export or import restrictions with the express purpose of reaping monopoly pricing gains on world markets undermining other countries’ competitiveness. Or country A may engagement in discriminatory data policies that promote predatory pricing or rent extraction by national digital companies on foreign markets.
-
Bucket 2 (The ‘Bilateral Discussions and Adjustments’ Bucket): In this Bucket, Country A's policies cause harm to country B without necessarily taking on a beggar-thy-neighbor character or entailing global economic losses. We put in this Bucket those policies for which a mutually beneficial bargain can be worked out between the two nations that entails the removal of the policies in question. This will typically occur when Country B's perceived losses from the policy exceed the perceived gains to Country A from sticking with the policies. For example, Country A may engage in industrial policies that Country B's producers consider unfair and harmful; Country B may prevail on Country A to remove or scale back these policies by offering an alternative economic benefit (e.g., a reduction of Country B's countervailing tariffs).
-
Bucket 3 (The ‘Domestic Adjustments’ Bucket): In this Bucket, a mutually beneficial bargain cannot be negotiated – perhaps because Country A's policies bring perceived gains to Country A that exceed the perceived losses by Country B, so that Country B is unable to offer Country A adequate exchange for removing or scaling back the policies in question. In this case, Country A keeps its policies and Country B is allowed to undertake well-calibrated domestic policy adjustments that demonstrably aim to reduce or minimize harm to its domestic economy. For example, Country B may implement regulations on domestic firms to curtail the leakage of sensitive technological material to foreign firms. Or Country B may raise trade barriers to protect communities adversely affected by exports from Country A. What is essential here is that the ‘remedy’ employed by Country B must be proportionate and well-targeted at the domestic objective (i.e., it is not a threat targeting Country A or a raising of the stakes in a trade war).
-
Bucket 4 (The ‘Multilateral Governance’ Bucket): In this Bucket, Country A's actions or policies (with or without any response from Country B) are likely to affect commerce with Country B in a way that is likely to cause spillover damage to the economy of Country C. It is appropriate that international norms and governance procedures be applied to manage such situations. For example, Country A may provide discriminatory trade benefits to Country B, such as by agreeing to reduce tariffs on one product from Country B without reducing tariffs on the same product from Country C.
According to the Statement, central to the Framework are Buckets 2 and 3 which are ‘designed to tackle cases where Country A's policies have adverse implications for Country B, but the harm is the incidental consequence of, and not the primary motivation for, those policies’.
This article seeks to contribute to the ongoing debates about how the US–China trade tensions may be resolved by examining the weaknesses of the Statement and developing an alternative framework to advance the US–China trade talks. We believe that the Statement has two major flaws. The first flaw, discussed in Section 2, is that the Statement provides excessive policy space to both countries and leaves a wide range of protectionist measures unregulated. To facilitate negotiations, we will need some policy space, but not the excessive policy space as suggested in the Statement. Section 3 tackles the second flaw which concerns the failure of the Statement in recognizing that WTO rules and its dispute settlement rulings have already provided sufficient policy space for Member states. More importantly, the Framework is likely to set the bilateral negotiations in a direction which sidelines WTO rules and further undermines the multilateral trading system. Overall, the Statement provides little substantive guidance for the parties to resolve the true problems behind their trade tensions. It would not allow the parties to maximize gains from trade and enhance national welfare precisely because of the allowance of excessive policy space which creates the flexibility for the application of protectionist and trade distortive policy instruments. In Section 4, we propose an alternative framework which seeks to strike a proper balance between the preservation of policy space and the regulation of protectionist measures, a balance that is better aligned with the approach taken under the WTO. Our framework is intended not only to avoid breaches of WTO rules but also to encourage the parties to conduct their negotiations in a way that would lay the groundwork for more inclusive negotiations, ultimately re-invigorating the multilateral trade negotiations under the WTO. Section 5 then offers some illustrations of how our framework may be applied in practice by drawing on the Phase One trade deal. Section 6 sets forth the conclusion.
2. Excessive Policy Space and the Lack of Discipline on Protectionism
The Framework allows excessive policy space and lacks sufficient discipline over protectionist measures. It distinguishes between beggar-thy-neighbor policies and other policies. As defined in the Statement, a beggar-thy-neighbor policy ‘seek[s] to increase domestic economic welfare at the expense of other countries’ welfare’. The Statement further clarifies that such policies include only those ‘adopted with express beggar-thy-neighbor purpose in mind’ (emphasis added). Purposeful beggar-thy-neighbor policies are prohibited under Bucket 1, whereas other policies are allowed under Buckets 2 and 3, which are at the core of the Framework according to the Statement. These ‘non-prohibited’ policies clearly include protectionist measures defined broadly as those adopted to protect domestic industries through measures conferring a competitive advantage to local industries or undermining the competitive condition of foreign competitors. Accordingly, in this paper, protectionist measures or protectionism are not merely concerned about border measures but include all trade and domestic policies and measures which have the effect of altering the condition of competition in favor of domestic actors vis-à-vis foreign competitors regardless of the presence of a protectionist intent. The examples envisaged under Buckets 2 and 3 – i.e. unfair and harmful industrial policies, domestic regulations in pursuit of certain policy objectives, and ‘trade barriers to protect communities adversely affected by exports’ – are broad enough to encompass all such protectionist measures. Instead of prohibiting such measures, the Framework essentially recommends that the parties negotiate whether they may be reduced or removed, and, if they cannot, how their economic impact on the counterparty may be rebalanced. Accordingly, the Framework provides wide latitude for the US and China to exclude protectionist measures from a trade deal.
The Framework is unlikely to facilitate the US–China trade talks, despite the wide regulatory freedom it provides. In failing to impose any hard rules on protectionism, the Framework fails to tackle the core problems that trade negotiations are concerned about in reality. For eight decades, international trade cooperation has been predominantly devoted to constraining protectionism.Footnote 7 WTO rules, the final product of multilateral trade negotiations, cover more than policies with express beggar-thy-neighbor purposes. For example, the Preamble of the Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the WTOFootnote 8 targets barriers to trade and discriminatory treatment that may or may not be motivated by beggar-thy-neighbor purposes. Examples that are more specific include some of the most fundamental rules of the WTO such as: (1) Article III of the GATT, the national treatment principle, which inhibits the use of discriminatory measures ‘so as to afford protection to domestic production’;Footnote 9 (2) Article XI of the GATT, which prohibits import or export quantitative restrictions irrespective of whether such restrictions are motivated by a beggar-thy-neighbor purpose; (3) Article II of the GATT, which allows Member governments to impose tariffs (as long as they do not exceed the committed/bound levels), even though such tariffs may have an express beggar-thy-neighbor purpose. Under the WTO's dispute settlement mechanism, the trade rules have been interpreted and applied in a way that seeks to discipline protectionist measures that adversely affect trade or the competitive condition of foreign companies vis-à-vis domestic industries of regulating members.Footnote 10 The above is not to suggest that the US–China negotiations must follow exactly the WTO model. Rather, the point is that the Framework does not address the core problems that exist in reality and the governments’ behavior behind these problems.Footnote 11
Most of the issues that have provoked the US–China trade tensions arise from various trade barriers, which may or may not be motivated by a beggar-thy-neighbor purpose. Indeed, the ongoing bilateral trade war has been dominated by tit-for-tat tariffs which are widely regarded as beggar-thy-neighbor policies.Footnote 12 However, the tariffs are just one of the means that the Trump Administration employed to push China to yield to US interest on certain systemic issues. These issues, identified in the joint statement of the US, the EU, and Japan (amongst other public announcements and official documents), mainly include China's non-market economic system, SOEs, industrial policies and subsidies, and so-called ‘forced’ technology transfer.Footnote 13 These issues are also central to US complaints about China's compliance with WTO obligations.Footnote 14 Although the exact demand of the US on these issues remains ambiguous, US concerns are loud and clear. To put it plainly, the US is unhappy with the various barriers and market-distorting policies and practices that China maintains to afford protection or competitive advantage to its domestic industries in pursuit of broader goals for economic development.Footnote 15 Accordingly, the US's central requests, in broad terms, are that China removes state intervention in commercial activities, as well as trade-restrictive and distortive policies and practices, to enhance its level of liberalization and maintain a level playing field for US companies. It is evident that these concerns and requests are not confined to policies with an express beggar-thy-neighbor intent but are so extensive as to capture all policies and practices having a protective, trade-restrictive, and distortive effect that jeopardizes the competitive position of US companies vis-à-vis their Chinese counterparts. While the US's demand that China ‘fundamentally change[s] its approach to the economy and trade’Footnote 16 would be too ambitious and intrusive to be fulfilled,Footnote 17 a framework which essentially leaves all protectionist and trade distortive policies without an express beggar-thy-neighbor purpose untouched will not be acceptable to either party.
Furthermore, the Framework lacks a clear and workable criterion. While ‘beggar-thy-neighbor policies’ are generally defined as those raising the welfare of the home country at the cost of worsening economic conditions abroad,Footnote 18 there seems to be no agreement on what may constitute such policies. Arguably, a protectionist measure is not necessarily a beggar-thy-neighbor policy. A tariff, for example, causes deadweight losses to the home country and hence does not produce the welfare gains that a beggar-thy-neighbor policy would produce. An ‘optimal tariff’ imposed by a big country having the capacity to influence terms-of-trade would be welfare enhancing at the cost of other nations.Footnote 19 Such a beggar-thy-neighbor effect, however, would need to be established by robust empirical evidence.Footnote 20 Even though a policy is shown to have a beggar-thy-neighbor effect, it will not automatically fall within the prohibited category of the Framework unless it is clearly motivated to have that effect. Such motivation is extremely difficult, if not impossible, to establish. A protectionist measure, in whatever form, may be motivated by a mix of protectionist and non-protectionist policy objectives without an intent to enhance national welfare at others’ costs. In the context of the US–China negotiations, it is unlikely that either party would voluntarily admit or accept a claim (by the other party) that its existing policies were aimed at harming the other's economy. Towards this end, the only measure that both parties would be willing to surrender is likely to be the beggar-thy-neighbor tariffs if the negotiations were to follow the Framework. However, to bring long-term peace to this trade war, the systemic issues (which are mostly non-tariff measures) must be resolved in a balanced way by disciplining the relevant protectionist policy instruments without restricting the parties’ freedom in their choice of non-protectionist regulatory goals.
In this regard, the Framework fails to distinguish between protectionist and non-protectionist policy objectives as well as between policy objectives and policy instruments used to achieve these objectives. It provides too much policy space for governments to adopt measures that do not genuinely serve any non-protective regulatory purpose. As will be discussed in Section 4, this would lead to a failure to achieve the overarching goal envisaged in the Statement, that is, to maximize the gains from trade.Footnote 21 For international trade to be welfare enhancing, countries must have the freedom to pursue any non-protectionist policy goals. At the same time, their choice of policy instruments to achieve such goals needs to be regulated through a balanced approach. Practically speaking, the Framework fails to recognize that excessive policy space may not be conducive to a trade deal. What governments usually need in trade negotiations is merely sufficient policy space so that they could secure the political support needed to reach a deal that reins in protectionist measures.
We do not have a crystal ball to foresee the ultimate outcome of the US–China negotiations, or more specifically whether and to what extent the negotiations will address protectionist and trade distortive policies. Our core criticism is that the Statement fails to provide a clear and viable framework for the ongoing negotiations. It grants too much policy space to the two governments to adopt protectionist and trade distortive policies which are precisely the major issues that this bilateral negotiation, and indeed trade negotiations in general, must address.
3. Failure to Respect WTO Rules
In addition to the problem discussed in the last Section, the Statement also ignores the fact that WTO law has already provided sufficient policy space for Member governments. In essence, WTO rules impose different degrees of restraints on a range of policy instruments arguably according to the level of adverse effects of these instruments on trade.Footnote 22 Such restraints include, for instance, the prohibition of import and export restrictions (the most trade-restrictive and distortive measures), and to a lesser degree the imposition of upper limits on (rather than prohibition of) tariffs, and the mere non-discrimination requirement on domestic measures leaving the flexibility for governments to use such measures to address regulatory concerns. In particular, for example, governments may maintain domestic subsidies although they need to remove the adverse effects on the interests of other Members or face countervailing measures. Non-specific subsidies are generally permitted regardless of their impact on trade. Furthermore, through instruments such as the Agreements on Technical Barriers to Trade and Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary Measures, WTO Members are allowed considerable leeway to choose their own policy objectives and the level of protection and may adopt measures, which otherwise would be WTO-inconsistent, to meet these objectives. To achieve a proper balance between trade liberalization and regulatory autonomy, the Appellate Body has taken efforts to address the protectionist elements of a contested measure without impairing Members’ capacity in pursuing chosen non-protectionist objectives.Footnote 23 The Statement does not explain why existing WTO rules are insufficient to provide the policy space needed by governments and hence why excessive policy space is required to facilitate the US–China negotiations.
More importantly, the rebalancing approach embedded in Buckets 2 and 3 of the Framework is likely to lead to inconsistencies with WTO rules. Generally speaking, the wide coverage of Buckets 2 and 3 may well leave protectionist instruments unregulated or under-regulated, falling short of WTO requirements. For example, under Bucket 2, the parties may agree that China shall reduce and confine industrial subsidies to high-tech firms to certain levels but may maintain a limited list of discriminatory policies within an agreed timeframe to provide space for the production and sale of domestically made high-tech products (e.g. electric cars). In return, the US may agree to remove or reduce a selected range of antidumping and countervailing duties on Chinese imports. It is evident that these discriminatory measures would breach the national treatment rule. To use this example the other way around, the parties may agree that China maintains its current level of industrial subsidies to high-tech firms for a period of time during which the US may increase tariffs on a selected range of Chinese imports. Such a tariff increase would not be allowed under GATT Article II if it goes beyond the corresponding bound level. If the tariff increase is based on an existing antidumping and/or countervailing duty, then it may not be compatible with the substantive and procedural requirements for the imposition of such duties under the relevant WTO agreements. This would be an example of a Bucket 3 policy. Notably, such deals are not necessarily ‘mutually beneficial’, as characterized in the Statement, for the discriminatory measures and increased tariffs would be detrimental to the welfare of both countries.
Finally, the Statement does not consider what new rules are needed to address the so-called China-specific issues. Many scholars believe that existing WTO rules are insufficient in handling the challenge of China, which as a non-market economy does not fit with the multilateral trading system built on market economy principles.Footnote 24 As we have argued in detail elsewhere, however, existing WTO rules, including China-specific ones, may have provided sufficient tools to deal with the trade-distorting conduct of Chinese SOEsFootnote 25 or the alleged ‘forced’ technology transfer.Footnote 26 The issue, therefore, may not be the lack of rules but the lack of utilization of the existing rules. As demonstrated by China's experience during and after its accession to the WTO, China has been willing to accept restraints on its national policies according to multilateral rules and to comply with unfavorable rulings of WTO tribunals.Footnote 27 Thus, it is much preferable to use WTO law and litigation to discipline China's trade policies. But this approach has been abandoned by the current US Administration, which chose to resort to unilateralism rather than multilateralism to resolve trade tensions. One argument for the need of new rules would be that the existing rules may be further elaborated to enhance their efficacy. Examples of this include Section 9.1 of the Protocol on the Accession of ChinaFootnote 28 and Paragraph 46 of the Report of the Working Party on the Accession of China.Footnote 29 The former requires China to ensure all prices for goods and services in all sectors are determined by market forces; and the latter prevents the Chinese government from influencing commercial decisions of SOEs and state-invested enterprises. While these obligations provide abundant flexibility for WTO Members to challenge a wide range of protectionist and trade distortive policies and practices of the Chinese government including via state entities, they could still be improved through the elaboration of more detailed legal criteria for Members and WTO tribunals to apply, such as specific factors for determining whether Chinese prices are market prices or whether an SOE made a particular decision purely on a commercial basis.Footnote 30 Furthermore, new rules may be needed to address new situations or practices such as variations and developments in China's industrial policies and subsidization and the lack of information on these measures. We will provide some illustrations on these issues in Section 5.
In short, the Statement fails to recognize that the existing WTO rules, as interpreted and applied by WTO tribunals, may have already provided the policy space needed by governments, both to pursue chosen non-protectionist objectives as well as to counter the effects of foreign measures. It fails to account for the efficacy of the existing rules in dealing with the China challenge. Instead, by encouraging the parties to negotiate bilateral deals in total disregard of existing WTO rules, the Statement only works to further undermine the multilateral trading system.
4. An Alternative Framework
An alternative framework is needed to guide the parties to negotiate specific disciplines on all sorts of protectionist measures and the policy space needed especially in the areas where the systemic issues arise. Our framework is not intended to impose undue restrictions on the regulatory autonomy of the parties. Instead, we seek to strike a proper balance between disciplining protectionism and preserving policy space in line with the approach taken by WTO rules and jurisprudence. This balance could be achieved by drawing on the theoretical guidance emanating from the Theory of Distortions and Welfare (Theory).Footnote 31 Ultimately, we believe the bilateral negotiation should lay the groundwork for broader negotiations under the WTO (rather than create a significant deviation from it).
The Theory addresses one of the longest-standing criticisms of free trade, that is, trade liberalization may not enhance national welfare when a domestic externality or non-economic objective exists.Footnote 32 It establishes two important propositions: (1) trade liberalization would remain welfare enhancing if the externality or objective is tackled separately with an optimal or first-best policy instrument; and (2) the most economically efficient policy instrument is one which strikes most directly at the source of the externality or objective. Therefore, in the pursuit of a domestic non-protectionist policy objective, the first-best policy would generally be a domestic instrument (e.g. internal tax or subsidy) which strikes directly at the locus of the problem, as opposed to a trade measure (e.g. an import tariff or quota). In other words, the more directly an instrument addresses the root of the problem, the more economically efficient it tends to be. When there is more than one externality/objective, the first-best policy would be the use of two or more domestic policy instruments tackling specifically the source of each externality/objective. A major qualification of the Theory concerns the side effects associated with the application of a first-best policy instrument. However, whether the existence of such side effects would render the optimal instrument economically inferior to other instruments requires careful assessment.Footnote 33
The Theory provides a framework for trade negotiations with two general steps:
• first, trade negotiations must identify the externalities/objectives that governments need to address and allow the flexibility for governments to choose their own non-protectionist regulatory goals; and
• second, trade negotiations should focus on governments’ choice of policy instruments in pursuit of their chosen goals taking into account the economic efficiency of the chosen instruments and their possible alternatives (as per the Theory), their effectiveness in fulfilling the goals, and the side effects of using a more optimal policy instrument.
Based on this framework, trade negotiations will continue to further trade liberalization in a way that allows nations to gain from trade and enhance economic welfare. The reason why trade negotiation/cooperation is needed to achieve an economically preferable outcome is that governments may well succumb to the pressure of powerful interest groups (i.e. import-competing producers) to maximize short-term political gains (at the expense of the long-term national economic interest). As a result, the political choice of trade policies and policy instruments would not necessarily follow the economic rationale; and the more economically efficient measures might just be less attractive politically.Footnote 34 This suggests that in choosing policy instruments to pursue a given regulatory goal, the political preference would likely be compromised by protectionist interests. Trade negotiations provide an effective way for governments to resist protectionist pressure by incorporating the interests of anti-protectionist groups (e.g. exporters) into domestic political calculus.Footnote 35
Compared with the Statement, our framework offers a better mechanism to facilitate the US–China trade negotiation. First and foremost, we draw a distinction between protectionist and non-protectionist objectives and between policy objectives and policy instruments. We specifically target protectionism, the key problem that trade negotiators seek to address in reality. As discussed in Section 2, we define ‘protectionism’ in this paper to have a broad meaning encompassing all policies and policy instruments that tilt the conditions of competition in favor of domestic actors vis-à-vis their foreign competitors. Our focus is on the protective and trade distortive effect rather than the intent of such measures. Meanwhile, our framework recognizes the regulatory freedom of both countries in their choice of policy objectives and provides a platform for them to negotiate all sorts of policy instruments they may adopt to pursue the desired regulatory goals. It encourages the two governments to use the most economically efficient instruments while allowing the flexibility for them to justify the use of second-best means. In doing so, our framework would be more balanced by allowing sufficient but not excessive policy space and would lead the negotiation in a direction whereby both countries would gain from further trade liberalization and less disguised protectionism.
Furthermore, our framework provides more substantive guidance for the bilateral negotiation. Instead of leaving the parties with unfettered latitude whereby they may agree to the use of a wide spectrum of protectionist instruments (subject to rebalancing), our framework offers economic guidance for them to determine how to restrain protectionism. Such guidance may be applied, for example, to all industrial policies that China employs to foster its high-tech industries. As demonstrated above, the steps of negotiation would involve (1) the identification of self-selected non-protectionist policy goals, and then (2) an assessment of whether the policy instrument(s) currently employed to pursue a given goal is the first-best means. More specifically, this latter step would involve sophisticated negotiations on why a sub-optimal measure has been applied, whether it could be replaced by an alternative means, etc. taking into account the impacts on trade and the capacity of the government concerned in accomplishing its chosen objectives.
Finally, our framework would avoid WTO-illegal outcomes. As observed in Section 3, the design of the WTO rules is consistent with the economic rationale of the Theory by regulating policy instruments according to their respective welfare costs. In cases involving trade and non-trade values, the judicial approaches and decisions of WTO tribunals, particularly those of the Appellate Body, have also been largely consistent with the economic rationale.Footnote 36 Our framework is intended to achieve the same balance that the WTO rules are designed to achieve and therefore would be inherently WTO-consistent. To minimize any incidental WTO-inconsistencies in practice, the negotiations must also involve consideration of whether the policy instruments that the parties agree to use for chosen non-protectionist regulatory goals may breach WTO rules.
5. A Way Out for the Trade War
To illustrate the practical application of our framework, we use the recently concluded US–China Phase One trade deal as an example. The deal covers many areas, which can be largely grouped under two categories: market access and rules issues. The market access commitments are supposed to solve the trade imbalance problem, which is what prompted President Trump to launch the trade war in the first place. Technically speaking, however, all the additional tariffs imposed by the US over the past two years were triggered by the rules issues. This is because their justifications were provided by the Section 301 Report into China's Acts, Policies, and Practices Related to Technology Transfer, Intellectual Property, and Innovation, which resulted from the investigation launched in August 2017 to address Chinese measures requiring ‘the transfer of American technology and intellectual property to enterprises in China’.Footnote 37
According to the Phase One trade deal, China has agreed to end its practice of ‘forced’ technology transfer. In essence, this issue concerns Chinese laws and practice which mandate, explicitly or implicitly, the transfer of technology by foreign companies to their Chinese partners in the course of foreign direct investment.Footnote 38 However, China's commitment in the deal does not necessarily mean that it has to abandon its overarching goal for technological development. To the contrary, China still retains considerable freedom to adopt policy instruments to pursue that goal so long as it does not have protectionist effects. To do this properly, we need to first identify the externalities retarding technological development. If the externality lies in the failure of the capital market to provide sufficient finance for research and development (R&D), then China could correct such market failures through measures such as higher tax incentives for R&D expenses deduction, more government investment in fundamental research, etc. If the externality lies in the lack of access to information and knowledge, then the Chinese government may take steps to enhance flow of information and knowledge without undermining the legitimate rights of other stakeholders. Both measures would address the chosen objective(s) more directly than ‘forced’ technology transfer and tend to be more efficient and less-trade-restrictive policy instruments. Indeed, China's existing WTO commitments have included a general obligation to avoid ‘forced’ technology transferFootnote 39 and recently China has revised its Foreign Investment LawFootnote 40 (FIL) to better implement that obligation. However, as flagged in Section 3, future negotiations could add more details to the existing commitment by imposing specific obligations on, for example, transparency to address the longstanding concern about implementation and enforcement, and a restriction on the abuse of national security as a justification for ‘forcing’ technology transfer. The Phase One deal has included a provision to ensure due process and transparency for US companies involved in administrative proceedings related to matters of technology transfer in China. However, in view of China's past experience with its WTO transparency obligations,Footnote 41 a more comprehensive and detailed transparency provision would probably be needed to tackle other potential issues in China's implementation of the FIL.Footnote 42 The final outcome of the negotiation would be a compromise which strikes a balance between China's pursuit of technological development and the protection of the legitimate interests of US firms. Where the Chinese subsidies have affected the competitive position of US firms, rebalancing could be achieved through the application of countervailing measures in accordance with relevant WTO rules.
Another example is the alleged lack of access to the Chinese market by American farmers. This is why the deal includes substantive commitments by China to greatly expand purchase of US manufactured goods, agricultural goods, energy products, and services for a total of at least $200 billion over the 2017 baseline amount in 2020 and 2021. It remains to be seen whether China would fulfill this commitment and if so, how.Footnote 43 It also remains unclear how China may implement this commitment without violating WTO rules such as the prohibition on quota under GATT Article XI, the MFN principle under Article I, and the non-discriminatory administration of quota under Article XIII.Footnote 44 What is clear is that this commitment is non-reciprocal and one-sided against China, and hence does not provide a balanced and long-term approach to the resolution of the bilateral trade tensions. Under our framework, instead of setting explicit import quotas, the two sides should first try to identify the problems under the current system that affect market access. For example, whether the lack of market access was due to high tariffs, restrictive non-tariff barriers such as arbitrary sanitary and phytosanitary measures without sufficient scientific justifications, or simply the result of pure market forces of supply and demand. Once the source of the problem is properly identified, the two sides can then try to negotiate a proper solution. For example, if high tariffs are the reason, then the US could request China to reduce its tariffs. Of course, this would need to be done on an MFN basis. At the same time, the US should also recognize legitimate Chinese interests. For example, China's high tariffs could be due to the concern of the government over the livelihood of the farmers. In this case, the US could help China to design an appropriate farmers-support program, such as direct cash payment by government to farmers that is not tied with agricultural outputs, which would be less trade restrictive and more efficient than collecting tariffs from American farmers and then transferring the proceeds to the Chinese farmers. If China prefers to use trade measures, it could negotiate for the use of tariff-rate quotas or even special safeguard measures reserved for sensitive products, which would be more flexible and have minimal impacts on trade.Footnote 45
A final example would be China's industrial policies which involve the use of a mix of policy instruments such as the provision of subsidies to and preferential treatment of strategic sectors.Footnote 46 These policies have not been covered in the Phase One deal and will be subject to further negotiations. As flagged in Section 3, new rules may be needed to address variations and developments in these policies. This may involve, inter alia, a more nuanced definition of SOEs, an expanded scope of subsidies, and enhanced transparency and access to information to reduce the difficulties for complaining countries to discharge the burden of proof on the above and other related issues.Footnote 47 Under our framework, the bilateral talk should start by identifying the exact policy objectives that China seeks to pursue under the overall industrial development plan and then focus on those existing instruments of concern to the US by exploring alternative means to attain these objectives. In this article, we do not intend to offer a detailed analysis of all these systemic issues behind the US–China trade tensions and all the policy instruments that may need to be negotiated. Such an analysis will need to be deferred to another article. Here, our objective is to set out the general framework and to demonstrate how it may work in reality.
In the longer term, we believe that the US–China negotiations should aim to lay the groundwork for more inclusive trade negotiations which would eventually contribute to re-invigorating the multilateral negotiations under the WTO. This is achievable if one considers the history of China's negotiations for entry into the WTO, which shows that a US–China bilateral deal is key to accomplishing a multilateral deal.Footnote 48 The fact that both the bilateral and the multilateral negotiations now face new challenges does not mean that they are insurmountable. Our framework provides a starting point for the bilateral negotiation which should, in our view, contribute to, and form an integral part of, further negotiations on a multilateral basis.
Conclusion
As it is often said, one should never let a good crisis go to waste. As all trade scholars would recall, it was, after all, the Second World War which prompted the establishment of the multilateral trading system. Likewise, the current US–China trade war also presents an excellent opportunity to reflect on the shortcomings of the current system and reform the rules of international trade. In the process, we must resist the temptation, as suggested by the Statement, to indulge the two big powers with too much ‘policy space’. Such a framework will not solve the problems, but will create a dangerous precedent for bypassing existing rules in favor of more ‘policy spaces’ for governments. This would, in turn, undermine the rules-based multilateral institution, and run contrary to the aim of ‘perpetual peace’, because the ‘state of peace must be formally instituted, for a suspension of hostilities is not in itself a guarantee of peace’.Footnote 49
While the US–China Phase One deal might or might not be the beginning of the end of the trade war, it definitely should mark the beginning of a long-running process of readjustment of the bilateral trade relationship. Such a process must be based upon the respect of multilateral rules and institutions, because the world cannot afford to have its two largest economies openly flouting such rules and institutions, which provide the only foundations for a ‘perpetual peace’.
Acknowledgement
The authors have benefited from valuable comments by Simon Lester and insightful discussions with Professor Steve Charnovitz. We are also grateful for very constructive comments from two anonymous reviewers. We are responsible for any errors or oversights. All websites cited are current as of 13 April 2020.