20.1 The Surprising Lack of Harmonisation
Intellectual property (IP) laws have experienced considerable harmonisationFootnote 1 within the European Union (EU) in the last decades. The success story of EU IP law began in the 1980s with Directive 89/104. Today, EU IP law covers trademarks,Footnote 2 designs,Footnote 3 geographical indications,Footnote 4 copyrights,Footnote 5 plant varietiesFootnote 6 and trade secrets.Footnote 7 The EU even managed to achieve a certain degree of harmonisation in the field of patent law with Directive 98/44, and most recently Regulation 1257/2012 that introduced enhanced cooperation for the creation of unitary patent protection. Looking at the IP family, in comparison to its siblings, the utility model (UM) has been EU’s “Cinderella” up until now. No directive or regulation deals specifically with UM protection.
The vacuum of EU law in the field of UMs is surprising for at least three reasons: Firstly, UM protection in the EU is nationally fragmented and porous.Footnote 8 Germany (since 1891),Footnote 9 Poland (since 1919)Footnote 10 and Spain (since 1929), for example, have provided UM protection for approximately a century. France introduced its first law on “certificats d’utilité” in January 1968.Footnote 11 Countries such as Hungary (since 1991), Denmark (since 1992),Footnote 12 Finland (since 1992),Footnote 13 Czechia (since 1992), Bulgaria (since 1993) and Austria (since 1994) all implemented UM protection in the final decade of the twentieth century. Belgium and the Netherlands had protected inventions for quite some time under a regime of so-called “short-term” patents but have no such system in place today. Other countries like Sweden and Luxembourg have never had a sub-patent protection regime.
Secondly, UM protection clearly varies within the EU Member States that afford protection to UMs.Footnote 14 There is no homogenous understanding as to many core features of UM protection, for example the eligible subject matter, the requirements for protection (e.g. novelty or inventive step) or the term of protection.Footnote 15 One of the reasons for these divergences is the lack of minimum standards for UM protection within the international framework. Copyright, trademark or patent law, for example, have received a certain degree of international harmonisation, at least via TRIPS, while UMs were only mentioned in the Paris Convention after the Revision Conference of Washington in 1911.Footnote 16 The policy space countries enjoy in designing their national UM systems is therefore quite broad.Footnote 17
Thirdly, the lack of EU harmonisation is surprising, as UM systems are traditionally intended to offer protection for technological advancements at low costs and thus to address the particular needs of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).Footnote 18 The European Commission (EC) has repeatedly emphasised the importance of SMEs for Europe’s economyFootnote 19 and the need to boost their use of IP.Footnote 20 Nevertheless, the EU never implemented a regulation or directive on UM protection.
This chapter will take a fresh look at the need for harmonisation of UM protection in the EU. It will first look back at EU harmonisation efforts in the past (Section 20.2), before demonstrating the need for EU harmonisation (Section 20.3). It will then describe and question the traditional arguments for UM protection (Section 20.4). Thereafter, the chapter will lay out the EU’s policy options and analyse them critically (Section 20.5). It will become clear that there are no perfect solutions to address the need for harmonisation. The chapter will offer thoughts on a new conceptional starting point for further reform efforts (Section 20.6) before concluding (Section 20.7).
20.2 Failed Attempts of the EC
The EC took serious steps towards unification and harmonisation of UM protection during the flourishing years of EU IP law in the 1990s. The EC authorised a study on the economic impact of UM protection with the German Ifo Institute for Economic ResearchFootnote 21 in the early 1990s. The Institute undertook a two-step survey in France, Italy, Spain and the UK questioning first patent attorneys and later industrial companies and independent inventors about their use and or desirability for UM protection in the European Community.Footnote 22 The EC interpreted the results as indicating that manufactures, inventors and patent lawyers advocated a unified system of UMs in the European Community.Footnote 23
A potential European reform of UMs in the 1990s also attracted interest from the academic community. Although the director of the influential Max-Planck Institute (MPI), Friederich-Karl Beier, was in Reference Beier1991 still sceptical about a unified European UM and more in favour of a mere approximation of the respective national laws through a Community Directive,Footnote 24 his opinion changed. In the first half of the 1990s, the MPI held various workshops and discussions with experts from academia and practice,Footnote 25 after which it proposed a Community UM and a full draft Regulation in 1994.Footnote 26
All of these developments led to the EC’s Green Paper on the Protection of Utility Models in the Single Market in July 1995.Footnote 27 The Commission introduced four different options.Footnote 28 Firstly, a directive approximating all national laws, secondly, a directive requiring the mutual recognition of national rights in other member states, thirdly, a Community UM, and fourthly, a combination of the options. The Commission’s Green Paper was in favour of the third option: the creation of a new UM right at the EC level.
However, the creation of a Community UM received very little support.Footnote 29 Firstly, some Member States did not see sufficient reason to introduce such a system, in particular the powerful UK,Footnote 30 which did not offer second-tier protection of inventions in its national laws.Footnote 31 Secondly, the language issue remained a barrier. To be a low-budget alternative to patents, the application process needs to be affordable. Therefore, translations in all official EU languages were not feasible for a pan-European UM application. Versions in just one or only a few privileged languages (e.g. English, French and German) would have been cheaper but particularly detrimental to the targeted user community of the system, namely SMEs outside of countries in which these languages were widely spoken.Footnote 32
Consequently, the Commission proposed a directive approximating the legal arrangements for the protection of inventions by UMs on 12 December 1997.Footnote 33 After the Opinion of the Economic and Social Committee of 27 May 1998 and the Resolution of the European Parliament of 12 March 1999, the Commission presented an amended proposal for a directive on 28 June 1999.Footnote 34
The work on the adoption of the proposal was suspended in March 2000.Footnote 35 The Commission prioritised the renewed efforts of a Community Patent Regulation (CPR), which resulted in a proposal in 2000.Footnote 36 Ultimately, not only did the CPR not materialise, but the Commission also withdrew the amended proposal for a UM directive in September 2005,Footnote 37 allegedly because it was unlikely to advance further in the legislative process as it could not overcome the opposition from a minority of Member States including the UK.Footnote 38
In 2013, the EC intended to update its information and analysis on the economic effects of UMs.Footnote 39 It commissioned a study on the economic impact of UM legislation in selected Member States, the final report from which was published in 2015. The study suggested refraining from making a decision on a unitary UM at the European level for the moment, so as to investigate further possibilities and to pursue a careful harmonisation process of national UM systems.Footnote 40 Since then, no further action has been taken.
Many things have changed since the main attempts were made to introduce an EU UM law in the 1990s. During these earlier discussions, the UK was one of the leading Member States opposing such measures. Since then, the UK has withdrawn from the EU, and with it one of the major opponents to the EU UM law.Footnote 41 Moreover, recent advances in the unification of the patent system have generated momentum for a re-evaluation of EU UM protection. Although the EU has not managed to set up an own patent system yet, the European patent with unitary effect and the Unified Patent Court (UPC) are built on initiatives within the EU and are based to a certain extentFootnote 42 on EU law.
20.3 Two Reasons for the Harmonisation of UM Law
20.3.1 The Existing EU IP Framework
The first reason for EU harmonisation is linked to parts of the EU’s secondary law.Footnote 43 Various legal acts refer to UMs in their scope of application. Given the heterogeneous nature of UM protection within the EU Member States, it is unclear under which conditions a legally protected subject matter is considered a UM and therewith falls in their scope.Footnote 44 For example, Regulation 608/2013 on customs enforcement of IP rights (Customs Regulation, IPCR) defines UMs as an IP right (Art. 2 (1) (k)). The Regulation sets out the conditions and procedures for action by the customs authorities regarding goods suspected of IP infringement. However, the Regulation does not define what a UM is or what conditions qualify a protected subject matter as such. As discussed earlier, the conditions for UM protection clearly varies within the EU Member States that afford protection to UMs.
The situation is similar for Directive 2004/48/EC (Enforcement Directive, IPED). The IPED does not mention UMs explicitly, but it does apply to any infringement of IP rights as provided for by EU law and/or by the national laws of the Member States (Art. 2 IPED) without defining what an IP right or UM is.Footnote 45 It is therefore unclear which kind of national sub-patent rights the Member States must protect with the full spectrum of measures, procedures and remedies enshrined in the IPED. Even an early draft of the EC’s proposal for a regulation on standard essential patents included UMs within its scope.Footnote 46 It would have raised a similar uncertainty, though subsequent versions of the proposal removed UMs from its scope.
The lack of a common concept of UM creates not only issues for the application of the EU’s secondary law but also for its interpretation. The aforementioned Customs Regulation and Enforcement Directive set certain standards for the enforcement of IP law. In the last decades, awareness has been growing that a one-size-fits-all approach is detrimental to an efficient IP framework. A more holistic approach is required taking into account the nature of the IP right, the context of the infringement and the proportionality of a remedy.Footnote 47 If the ECJ were to decide on the requirements to issue a preliminary injunction based on a UM under Art. 9(1)(a) of the IPED, it would be impossible to strike the right balance without having a common understanding of the protected subject matter the law intends to enforce. A holistic approach would need to differentiate based on the conditions for UM protection in the Member States. This distinction is crucial because the right balance significantly varies whether the subject matter is a trivial advancement, possibly even obvious to a person skilled in the art,Footnote 48 or if the national UM is essentially a full-fledged patent with just a shorter duration and no prior substantive examination before the grant.Footnote 49 One might argue that patentability requirements are neither harmonised by the EU, so these uncertainties are not specific to the UM rights but to the protection of inventions on a more general level within the EU. A significant distinction to patents is, however, that the conditions for patent protection are harmonised either through or as a consequence of the Strasbourg and the Munich conventions.Footnote 50 Moreover, a general framework can be found in Article 27 ff. of the TRIPS Agreement that brings the national patent systems within the EU closer together than the UM systems.
One might think that an ECJ interpretation of the term “UM” or “IP” after a referral by a national court could have at least a similar effect. With its preliminary ruling in “Cofemel”, for example, the Court set the requirements for copyright-protectable work due to the absence of a definition in the various legal acts of the EU.Footnote 51 However, the situation in copyright law is hardly comparable to UM law as various legal acts by the EU design a copyright framework with exploitation rights, limitations and exceptions, etc.Footnote 52 These legal acts as well as the respective decisionsFootnote 53 give at least a certain guidance on a general understanding of copyright law as well as some key features of the copyright framework which hints towards an EU concept of “work”. There is no secondary law of the EU addressing UM protection. Moreover, UMs are registration rights where legal clarity provided by a Directive or Regulation is more important than in the field of unregistered rights such as copyrights.Footnote 54
20.3.2 The Single Market
The second reason for the introduction of an EU UM law refers to the concept of the EU single market and is based on the EU’s primary law. The discussions which took place in the 1990s and the proposals of the EC have already featured these aspects.Footnote 55 The recitals of the two proposed directives outline the porous nature of the protection of UMs across the EU and the differences in the existing UM protection systems, which have the potential to obstruct the free movement of goods and distort competition within the internal market. The explanatory memorandum mentioned explicitly Art. 2,Footnote 56 Art. 3(c),Footnote 57 Art. 3(g)Footnote 58 and Art. 7aFootnote 59 of the old EC Treaty in this regard. According to the Commission, the fragmentation of protection forces right holders to avoid markets in which they cannot obtain an equivalent protection for their invention.Footnote 60 Moreover, the significant variations between national systems make it even more difficult to obtain cross-border protection as an invention which qualifies for protection in one Member State may not qualify, at least not on the same terms, in another, according to the EC.Footnote 61 These aspects trigger a need for legal expert advice creating administrative difficulties and a major cost factor. The Commission pointed out that such a situation restricts innovative activity and distorts competition.Footnote 62 In 2008, Gómez Segade advanced that these risks are even stronger today than they were in the 1990s due to the subsequent EU enlargement increasing the degree of fragmentation and heterogeneity.Footnote 63
In its reasoning more than 25 years ago, the Commission focused largely on the interests of potential right holders – an approach that stems from the IP zeitgeist of that period. However, not all the points the EC advanced are entirely convincing. There are doubts as to whether businesses would avoid the EU or specific Member States for the sole reason that their inventions would not be eligible for UM protection in these jurisdictions. Third parties can copy and sell their products in these countries regardless of whether the originator is present. Offering goods also in these national markets can be attractive for the originator if he can recoup his R&D costs through his business in a Member State that protects his technology as a UM anyways. A recent study even suggests that marginal disharmony in the field of UMs works reasonably well for those right holders who can effectively navigate such environments.Footnote 64 They are able to optimise the differential appropriability of these rights to achieve protection efficiencies and accommodate national differences, according to Cahoy and Oswald.Footnote 65
A modern analysis of the effects of the status quo needs to integrate the perspective of the right holders’ competitors. Today, this appears to be the major reason for UM harmonisation from a “single market perspective”. The lack of harmonisation and therewith the lack of transparency creates disincentives to commercialise products also on the side of enterprises who do not hold any rights, or which hold rights in another Member State. A firm willing to offer goods within the internal market is at risk of running into UM infringement in one part of the single market while selling products legally in another part. This risk, along with the lack of transparency, currently poses the most significant potential threat to hinder the free movement of goods and to distort competition as companies might refrain from offering their goods and services in Member States where they are not entirely aware of the peculiarities of the national law on UMs.
20.4 General Reasons for UM Protection
We have seen now that the existing EU’s secondary law on IP as well as the concept of the single market call for a harmonisation of UM protection on an EU level. Before looking into the EU’s policy options, we want to get a clearer picture of the general reasons for UM protection as these aspects will have an impact on the analysis of the policy options for harmonisation.
Traditionally, governments, institutional actors, practice and scholarship indicate three main reasons to establish or maintain a UM system. Notably, all three refer somehow to the patent system (“cheaper”, “faster” and “lower”), which makes them “relative grounds” for UM protection. Therefore, the justification for UM systems is also a “relative justification” as it bears a strong tie to its “big brother” – the patent system. It will become clear that the main task of a UM system is to perform a gap-filling function, which intends to overcome certain shortcomings of this brother system.Footnote 66 It will also become apparent that the traditional arguments for UM protection are to a certain extent ambiguous and the justification of UM protection is therefore rather weak.
20.4.1 Cheaper
UM systems are intended to lower the cost barriers for the IP protection of technical inventions,Footnote 67 and come in the form of “registration rights”.Footnote 68 UMs do not have to pass a full-blown substantive examination before protection is granted.Footnote 69 This is different than the majority of patent systems in the EU and the European Patent Convention (EPC) where an office investigates substantive patentability requirements before registering the right. Hence, IP offices can offer UM protection for less than patent protection. As mentioned in the beginning, UM protection is therefore supposed to be particularly attractive for SMEs which have a relatively small budget for IP protection in comparison to larger enterprises.Footnote 70
The potential savings for an SME to obtain UM protection instead of patent protection might be less than expected. The office fees for UM protection are indeed lower than the fees for patent protection in many countries. However, some SMEs, in particular micro entities, can achieve patent protection with discounts in various jurisdictions.Footnote 71 Furthermore, the overall costs for UM protection are primarily driven by patent attorney fees for drafting claims and specifications, which are comparable to those within the patent system.Footnote 72 Finally, it is more likely that the UM will be challenged than a patent for the same invention during its lifetime as the office does not perform a full-blown substantive examination of UM applications. Therefore, the enforcement costs of UMs can be even higher than the enforcement costs within a patent system.Footnote 73 Taking this into account, UMs may not provide SMEs access to effective IP protection that is substantially cheaper.
20.4.2 Faster
As there is no requirement for a substantive examination, a UM system offers protection faster than a patent system.Footnote 74 Patents are generally granted years after the application, whereas UMs will be registered within months or even weeks. In Germany, one of the countries prominent for its UM system,Footnote 75 the registration procedure to obtain UM protection is completed after 4.2 months on average while the patent granting procedure takes usually 2.5–3 years.Footnote 76
Given the speed of registration, UMs are sometimes used as measures to protect an invention that is subject to a patent application while the application is still pending. A patent application does not provide a right to an injunction in many jurisdictionsFootnote 77 while a UM does.Footnote 78 Therefore, companies may “branch-off” UMs from prior patent applications as permitted in some Member States. An applicant is allowed to claim the filing and, if applicable, priority date of a previously submitted patent application for a subsequent UM application provided the latter application concerns the same invention.Footnote 79
However, fast IP protection is in numerous cases not very attractive. UMs are published upon registration as a quid pro quo for protection. Therewith, the invention leaves the sphere of secrecy more rapidly than it would under the 18-month publication delay for patent applications. Thereafter, competitors can use the information as a springboard for subsequent developments, which might not make UM protection very attractive for applicants. We can observe similar reluctance to opt for fast protection with patents. Patent applicants requiring faster search or examination can ask the European Patent Office (EPO) to have their applications processed under the programme for accelerated prosecution of European patent applications (PACE).Footnote 80 However, data indicate that very few applicants are interested in such fast-track proceedings,Footnote 81 allegedly due to the secrecy inherent in a slower examination.Footnote 82
Even if access to speedy IP protection is necessary while a patent application is prosecuted, patent internal measures might be just as feasible as a separate UM registration and allow for a more coherent policy approach.Footnote 83 Art. 67 (2) of the EPC, for example, requires the Contracting States to ensure at least that the applicant can claim compensation reasonable in the circumstances from any person who has used the invention after the date of publication of the application. However, the Contracting States are free in granting earlier or stronger protection,Footnote 84 for example enshrining a UM-style right to an injunction in their national laws.Footnote 85
20.4.3 Lower
Traditionally, UM systems offer protection for incremental innovation while the patent system is supposed to protect more substantial improvements over the state of the art. In many jurisdictions, the requirements for UM protection are lower than the prerequisites for patent protection, in particular the level of required inventiveness.Footnote 86 At the same time, UM protection is weaker and shorterFootnote 87 than patent protection as the idea is to provide a moderate IP right for the corresponding level of innovation.
However, it is often unclear precisely how to distinguish between low and high standards of inventiveness. In its groundbreaking decision “Demonstrationsschrank”, the German Federal Court of Justice pointed out that this is hardly possible in practice.Footnote 88 Moreover, granting UM protection below the non-obviousness standard of patent law offers IP protection for subject matter that is theoretically obvious to the person skilled in the art. This result amounts to a break in the general understanding of IP law and cannot be justified against the background of the constitutionally protected freedom of action of third parties, according to the German Federal Court of Justice.Footnote 89 The Court therefore held that the required threshold for inventiveness in UM law can only be the same as in patent law. Other countries followed suit.Footnote 90 These judicial concerns cast doubt on the viability of the lower standard of inventiveness in UM law from a legal perspective.
From public policy perspective, it is debatable whether monopoly rights should be granted for trivial achievements, particularly in times of IP thickets. The German Federal Court of Justice addressed this point from a purely legal perspective when referring to the third-party freedoms protected by fundamental rights. But one can also raise this argument from an economic perspective, as it has been done in the scholarship on UM protection.Footnote 91 Enterprises already have problems to identify the relevant patent rights during a freedom-to-operate (FTO) analysis when they seek to avoid IP infringement and hold-up. The efforts of firms must be substantially stronger when grain-sized innovation receives protection since trivial achievements are harder to trace. Moreover, in the case of UMs, the rights were not examined by the patent offices. Hence, the competitors are forced to investigate the validity of the claims.Footnote 92 This is particularly problematic for SMEs, the alleged core user of the UM system. Many authors have therefore unmasked the notion of UMs as small patents for small inventors as a myth.Footnote 93 There is a particular concern that large firms flood a promising area of technology with an array of UMs,Footnote 94 particularly since major international enterprises appear to be the core users of many national UM systems.Footnote 95
The overall economic impact of sub-patent protection within the EU appears therefore unclear and potentially negligible. Economic scholarship has found that UMs favour growth in developing countries when the capacity to conduct innovation research does not exist.Footnote 96 A minor innovation can be a learning device and thus a stepping stone for developing patentable inventions later.Footnote 97 UMs are considered particularly useful in times of “catching up”Footnote 98 but there is no conclusive evidence regarding their positive impact in developed and highly developed countries or economic unions. As discussed at length in Chapter 10, the impact of UMs in a highly developed country has been studied deeply and at different points in time in Australia where a UM-like system was established in 2001. However, after a short span of protection lasting about 20 years, the Australian government began the process of phasing the system out as it did not achieve its intended objectives. It is therefore very unclear whether there is a need to incentivise incremental innovation with the prospect of an inclusive right such as a UM.
20.5 The Policy Options
If the EU wants to become more proactive in the field of UM, there are multiple policy options to consider. The following gives an overview of the legally binding options based on regulations and directives. The overview leaves out the possibilities of enhanced cooperation (Art. 20 TEU)Footnote 99 and common European approaches beyond EU law.Footnote 100 A sound policy option needs to accomplish a difficult task: On the one hand, it must address the two major reasons that require an EU harmonisation of UM protection (see Section 20.3). On the other hand, it has to take into account that the justification for UM protection in general is rather weak (see Section 20.4).
20.5.1 The Instruments
In general, the EU has several different options for becoming more proactive in the field of EU IP law. The binding legal acts available to unify UM protection or to approximate the respective national laws are regulations and directives.Footnote 101 A regulation is binding in its entirety and directly applicable in all Member States (Art. 288(2) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU)). A directive is binding as well but only as to the result to be achieved. Hence, national authorities have the discretion to choose the form and methods (Art. 288(3) TFEU) and, as a general rule,Footnote 102 direct effect does not apply. In sum, it is for the Member States to adjust their laws and to give effect to the directive.
We must distinguish between maximum or full harmonisation on one hand and minimum harmonisation on the other when referring to the level of approximation the EU intends to achieve with a directive.Footnote 103 A directive can regulate a particular area exhaustively and preclude Member States from deviating from defined standards (maximum or full harmonisation). In the case of minimum harmonisation, the EU sets minimum standards and allows Member States to maintain or provide for more stringent national laws.
20.5.2 The Competences
The EU has no competences by right as they are all voluntarily conferred on it by its Member States (principle of conferral, Art. 5(1) of the Treaty on European Union (TEU)). It can only act within these competences defined by the Member States in the Treaties (Art. 5(2) TEU). Competences not conferred upon the EU in the Treaties remain with the Member States (Art. 4 (1), 5 (2) TEU).
We need to distinguish between the competencies to establish an EU IP right and the competencies to harmonise national laws on IP. Art. 118 TFEU empowers the EU to introduce an EU UM system,Footnote 104 and allows measures to be established for the creation of European IP rights to provide uniform protection throughout the EU and for the setting up of centralised EU-wide authorisation, coordination and supervision arrangements.Footnote 105 Art. 118 TFEU does not constitute “competition rules” for the purpose of Art. 3(1)(b) TFEU but it does fall within the “internal market” area in which the EU has shared competences under Art. 4(2)(a) TFEU.Footnote 106 Accordingly, pursuant to Art. 5(3) TEU, the principle of subsidiarity applies where EU legislature makes use of Art. 118 TFEU.Footnote 107 In practice, however, the importance of this principle is limited since it will be difficult for Member States to achieve the creation of IP rights, including an EU UM right, which benefits from EU-wide protection without EU intervention.Footnote 108 Hence, Art. 118 TFEU would serve as a basis to create an EU UM system by a Regulation.
An EU directive which does not establish uniform IP protection by the EU but merely intends to approximate national IP laws cannot be based on Art. 118 TFEU.Footnote 109 However, Art. 114 TFEU does provide a general competence for harmonisation measures “which have as their object the establishment and functioning of the internal market”. To limit the danger of an unduly wide interpretation that would lead to an open-ended form of EU power, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) requires for the substantive conditions to be fulfilled that the measures have the genuine objective of improving the conditions for the establishment and functioning of an internal market. They should address disparities between the legal systems of the Member States that significantly obstruct fundamental freedoms and thus have a direct effect on the functioning of the internal market.Footnote 110 The current situation has the potential to obstruct the free movement of goods and distort competition within the internal market, as discussed above. This gives the EU the competence to harmonise national UM regimes based on Art. 114 TFEU. The principle of subsidiarity also appliesFootnote 111 in the framework of Art. 114 TFEU but its importance is again limited in practice. If the substantive condition in the interpretation of ECJ is fulfilled, Member States will regularly struggle to prevent any negative impact on the international market without the action of the EU.Footnote 112
20.5.3 UM Regulation
20.5.3.1 Policy Option 1: EU UM Right
The first policy option is to adopt a regulation based on Art. 118 TFEU and to introduce an EU UM right providing for unified protection similar to the Community/EU trademark or the Community design. As mentioned in Section 20.2, this was the policy option the EC originally favoured in its green paper 1995. The registration would be administered by the European Union Intellectual Property Office (EUIPO). The EUIPO’s lack of expertise in assessing technical subject matter would be insignificant. UMs are registration rights, so the EUIPO’s task would be to perform a formality check prior to registration while EU UM courts could assess the substantive requirements for protection during infringement proceedings. The unification of UMs would ensure protection in all Member States of the EU but, at the same time, an objection against this EU right in any Member State could defeat or invalidate the right in its entirety. The regulation would provide a full-fledged and autonomous system including provisions on protected subject matter, infringement and enforcement. This new regime would not touch the national UM systems which could continue to exist in parallel if desired.
An EU right would solve the problem for inventors of the fragmented and porous nature of UM protection within the EU. Nonetheless, the fragmented protection provided by national UMs and the divergent national laws would persist, leading third-party businesses to encounter substantial expenses when conducting an FTO for the single market in order to mitigate the risk of infringing a parallel national right in one of the Member States. It is unclear whether such an EU system would lead at least de facto to a certain harmonisation of national systems in the long run.
Users seeking EU-wide protection will save costs with a pan-European right. Nevertheless, the costs for the EU and users to establish such a system, to maintain it and to make use of it cannot be underestimated. For example, the language issue mentioned above, which was a determining factor in the discussions of the 1990s, has still not entirely been solved. Today’s translation software dramatically reduces the administrative costs in comparison to the situation 30 years ago, but the EU has increased significantly in size (i.e. the number of Member States, and thus languages) since then. Also, overall administrative costs would increase to the extent that Member States retain their national UM systems and administration while the EU must invest in setting up and running a pan-European administrative structure.
In general, having an IP system that spans multiple countries and languages could not be anything but expensive. Thus, whether such a structure can provide an IP right for SMEs at low costs is doubtful. If such protection is indeed desired, it appears rather obvious that it should be offered “in the basement” via national UM rights with low administration costs while the more expensive European “bel étage” is reserved for substantial innovation examined by an office and protected by patents.Footnote 113
The other two substantial arguments against an EU UM are linked to the general justification of UM protection. First, as outlined above, the arguments and justifications for a UM protection system in a highly developed economic union lack strength. There is no conclusive evidence that a pan-European UM system would have a positive impact on the EU’s public welfare. It would be an experiment. One might argue that a regulation would be the right way to carry out such an experiment. In a more general context, Martin Husovec has advanced that if the EU legislator intends to experiment with new IP rights, it should use regulations instead of directives.Footnote 114 He made the point that if the EU has to repeal such an instrument once it has failed to deliver on its promises, it automatically ceases to exist also on the national level.Footnote 115 The EU legislator is not required to clean up and coordinate a removal in the national laws.Footnote 116 Although IP policy is less dynamic in reality than in theory,Footnote 117 Husovec’s point appears correct in the field of copyright law where rights come into existence without registration.Footnote 118 However, setting up a new EU registration system, hiring staff for an EU office, and teaching users on a pan-European level how to make use of new structures is far more costly and time consuming than a national experiment, making it also rather unlikely, not only for political reasons, that the EU would eventually repeal such a right. Hence, without a strong justification for UM protection, the EU should refrain from introducing an EU UM system – even if intended as a mere experiment.
The second substantial argument against an EU UM system arises from the framework of the system. Even if one sees the need for EU UM protection, it is unclear how one should design it. As noted above, UM systems are supposed to perform a gap-filling function. However, national patent laws are not harmonised, so the gaps to be filled are of different sizes and are based in different locations depending on the Member State. It is impossible to suggest a one-size-fits-all auxiliary tool in this constellation where the main system is multifaceted.Footnote 119
20.5.4 UM Directive
The other policy options would address national laws with a directive and would be based on Art. 114 TFEU. The directive could be combined with the first option (EU UM right) described above, similar to the situation in EU trademark or design law. Also, the following options could be combined.
20.5.4.1 Policy Option 2: Negative Full Harmonisation
There are two types of full harmonisation here. The first is negative full harmonisation, whereby EU law approximates national laws by pre-empting the field of UM protection.Footnote 120 Member States with a UM protection system would be required to abolish it as negative full harmonisation leaves no leeway for the national systems. This would create full transparency within the internal market, in particular for businesses that intend to operate across all geographical areas but are currently afraid of overlooking a national UM right in one Member State. Negative full harmonisation would also eliminate all costs related to the establishment, maintenance and usage of the UM system.
Pre-empting national IP rights means interfering with Art. 17(2) of the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights (CFR).Footnote 121 Nevertheless, this interference is easily in line with the Charter if it does not concern inventions that already exist as Art. 17 does not embrace any kind of institutional guarantee for IP rights which the legislator cannot touch.Footnote 122 Even if a “core property” were to exist that places certain forms of property outside of the legislator’s reach, it appears to be obvious that UM rights which have never been protected in some Member States would be considered to fall outside this scope.
Although Art. 17 CFR does not prohibit negative harmonisation, the legal and political threshold for such a measure is very high. According to the literature, negative harmonisation of IP rights is not necessary to overcome issues concerning the single market.Footnote 123 The European legislator is required to demonstrate that the national solution harms and should be avoided,Footnote 124 which might be possible given the considerable differences in national UM protection and the potential effects for the internal market. Most notably, however, negative harmonisation would imply that UM protection as such is expendable. Although the arguments for UM protection appear to be rather weak, it is also not possible to conclusively say that UM systems generate negative net effects. Therefore, the EU cannot pre-empt or impose to repeal such national systems.
20.5.4.2 Policy Option 3: Positive Full Harmonisation
The second type of full harmonisation is positive harmonisation. A directive would describe and impose a full-fledged UM protection system in Member States under their national laws. All Member States would be required to implement exactly the same system enshrined in this directive. The EC intended to go down this road during the harmonisation efforts in the second half of the 1990s, after the initial idea to create a Community UM right had received strong headwind.
The approximation of national laws could be combined with a mutual recognition of national UM rights by the Member States, as already mentioned in the EC’s Green Paper of 1995.Footnote 125 It would require the Member States to amend their own legislation to allow the applicant to request that his domestic UM is valid in another Member State and has similar effects there. However, this broader alignment would be hard to sell to the Member States as the registration of a national authority would go beyond the principle of territoriality with its effect in other Member States of the EU.
If the EU were to opt for a positive full harmonisation, national IP rights would still exist. The likelihood of continued porous protection would be reduced since inventors could apply cross-border for UM protection with similar national rights in all Member States. However, Option 3 would require the EU to take a positive stance on UM protection as per Option 1. As already discussed, the foundation for such a broad recommendation is rather weak.
20.5.4.3 Policy Option 4: Positive Minimum Harmonisation
Minimum harmonisation, in contrast, would not impose a specific system but rather set a minimum standard for the protection of UM that Member States could not fall below, for example requirements for protection or a minimum scope of protection provided by national UMs. The national law would need to implement these standards, but the individual Member States would have some leeway to exceed the terms of the directive in a defined direction.
The analysis of Option 4 is similar to that of Option 3. The major difference is that Option 4 gives Member States flexibility to react to national particulars with legislative choices. At the same time, however, this possibility might lead to the continuation of heterogeneous UM protection within the EU at least to a certain extent.
20.5.4.4 Policy Options 5 and 6: Opt-In Harmonisation (Minimum or Full)
A final policy option is opt-in harmonisation, whereby a Member State can freely decide whether it wants to maintain a UM system or not. However, should the Member State opt to protect UMs, the EU obliges the national system to conform to standards stipulated in the directive. The directive could have either a maximum/full or minimum harmonisation character meaning it could impose a specific framework that the Member State needs to implement (Policy Option 5) or merely define the key cornerstones of a UM system as minimum standards (Policy Option 6).Footnote 126 The main benefit of introducing opt-in harmonisation is to clarify the concept of a UM, especially with regard to existing secondary law of the EU, for example the IPCR and the IPED. As far as we are aware of, such an opt-in concept was not discussed by the EC during the 1990s.
Opt-in harmonisation does not force the EU to make a final decision on the establishment or maintenance of a UM protection system. It is for the Member States to make their own legislative choice. Given the inconclusive arguments for a UM protection system and its gap-filling function as an auxiliary tool to mainly non-harmonised patent systems, the national systems might be in the best situation to take such a decision.
If a Member State offers UM protection, users will be aware of the legal framework as it is the case in all Member States protecting UMs (Option 5) or at least they will be familiar with its key features which have to be the same (Option 6). An opt-in harmonisation would reduce, to some extent, the uncertainty deriving from the heterogeneous protection schemes currently existing in the EU. However, the general fragmentation and porous nature of protection with its detrimental effects on the single market would continue to exist. Furthermore, the EU would be required to set a proper, convincing and full-fledged blueprint for the design of national UM systems in the directive. As already mentioned above, this is hardly feasible given the gap-filling function of UM systems and the unharmonised area of patent law.
20.5.5 Recommendations
None of the policy options described above are entirely satisfying. All options except for the opt-in harmonisation would require a final stance by the EU on whether UM protection is positive or negative for the Member States. It is recommended that the Union refrains from such a decision as the general foundation of UM protection is ambiguous. There is no convincing argument for the introduction of a UM protection system in well-developed countries but there is also no conclusive argument that Member States should refrain from such protection. Moreover, designing a universal UM framework means filling gaps in the conspicuously heterogeneous national patent systems. Logically, before harmonising the UM framework, one would need to harmonise the patent system, but such an endeavour is not realistic at the moment.
If at all, harmonisation should address the different national laws by an opt-in harmonisation. This would leave the more general decision as to whether a national system requires a sub-patent protection system to the respective Member State. An opt-in solution would clarify the concept of UM for the application and interpretation of the other EU’s secondary law on IP, for example the Enforcement Directive. However, this option will not entirely resolve the existing problems of businesses working across boarders within the single market. These entities would still be required to inquire whether a certain invention is protected by a national UM in all Member States relevant for their business to avoid the risk of hold-ups. It will, however, implement one single standard for the UM framework of the national laws.
The overall analysis suggests that the EU is not well advised in implementing any of the outlined policy options. At the same time, the status quo is unsatisfactory and calls for an EU harmonisation, as pointed out in Section 20.3. Hence, further research is required to formulate compelling solutions.
20.6 A New Conceptional Starting Point
20.6.1 Two Assumptions for Further Research
Further research on the harmonisation of UMs within the EU should be based on two assumptions. Firstly, future efforts at harmonisation should embrace an outside-the-box thinking and consider a new understanding of the concept of UMs. As discussed above, one of the main reasons why UM protection within the EU is diverse is the lack of international harmonisation. At the same time, this vacuum offers a tremendous policy space to reflect on the understanding of UMs when defining a suitable UM policy for the EU.
Secondly, further research should not only aim at optimal policy options but also consider second-best solutions. The analysis above suggests that perfect results are not in sight as certain optimal conditions are incompatible. For example, not taking any stance on the design of UM laws and overcoming the heterogeneous forms of protection within the EU appears impossible.
20.6.2 UMs as Remuneration Rights and Opt-In Harmonisation
Given the unsatisfying policy options available, a valuable starting point for new research on the EU harmonisation of UM law might be a critical reflection on the basic concept of UMs. Legal entitlements can be protected with a liability rule instead of a property rule, as recognised by Guido Calabresi and Melamed in their seminal contribution on the methods of protection.Footnote 127 A liability rule does not prevent the use of an entitlement by a third party, but the right holder can ask for a remuneration as a compensation.Footnote 128 Such mechanisms are particularly recognised in EU copyright law.Footnote 129
In the following, we will touch upon the idea of a system that enshrines a liability rule and understands UMs as remuneration rights. “Take-and-pay” approaches for UM law have not been discussed to a noticeable extent in Europe.Footnote 130 This lack of research does not come as a surprise as the existing UM protection systems of the Member States work with property rules. The US scholarship, however, has examined the protection of UMs by a remuneration right.Footnote 131 The primary intention of these scholars is the reduction of barriers to marketsFootnote 132 – an idea that works particularly well also in the EU where a single market is subject to heterogenous forms of UM protection with the respective negative effects on competition.
We will include this new conceptional starting point in the framework of the most promising policy options outlined above: an opt-in harmonisation. The decision on the protection of UMs will still be left for the Member States. Nevertheless, if a Member State protects sub-patentable inventions, it would have to implement a liability rule. Hence, the EU is not required to decide on whether Member States can or must protect UMs but, as a second-best solution, the directive will decide on the “how”. Therefore, the act would leave no national leeway when defining the effects of UMs (full harmonisation) while other features of the UM system could be subject to a mere minimum harmonisation.
20.6.3 Addressing the Two Reasons for EU Harmonisation
Above, we pointed out two reasons for the need for EU harmonisation of UM law. One of them related to the existing IP framework in EU law and the lack of a common understanding of a UM right when interpreting and applying this law (see Section 20.3.1). An opt-in harmonisation of UM protection would solve this issue as it would give a clear definition of the concept of an UM.Footnote 133
The second reason for EU harmonisation concerned the adverse impact of the diverse UM frameworks on the single market (see Section 20.3.2). Businesses are at risk to infringe national UMs if they aim to operate in multiple countries of the EU without conducting a proper and expensive FTO in each and every relevant Member State. Their concern to be caught in a hold-up has a detrimental effect on the free movement of goods and bears the potential to obstruct competition in the internal market. The opt-in options discussed above (Policy Options 5 and 6) were able to address this issue only to a limited extend.
Obviously, the proposed concept of a remuneration right does not solve the existing problem for the single market entirely either. It does not overcome the fragmentation or porous UM protection within the EU. However, a liability approach will mitigate its effects as the extent of the negative effects are directly linked to the concept of UMs as exclusive rights. Remuneration in case an entity infringes an overlooked national UM in one part of the internal market creates fewer negative effects than a full-fledged exclusive right entitling preliminary and permanent injunctions and the risk of hold-up.Footnote 134 An understanding of UMs as remuneration rights has the potential to accommodate the interests of businesses better than a property rule regime. This is particularly true for SMEs which do not have the financial means to conduct EU-wide FTOs.
20.6.4 Accounting for the Conceptional Differences with Patents
Although the EU would be able to refrain from a general decision of UM protection, this proposal requires the Union to be convinced about the advantages of a liability rule over a property regime in UM law. A decision on the form of protection is less far-reaching than imposing a decision on the general existence of a UM protection system, particularly when choosing with liability rules an “intermediate form” of protection. Nevertheless, it is the potential trouble spot of this approach. Further research will need to examine the actual effects of such a concept for the European systems. At least to some extent, this research will be able to rely on the existing US literature.Footnote 135
Already now, it appears to be clear, that a liability rule will account better for the conceptional differences of patents and UMs. The prevailing consensus is that UMs are less robust than patents, with a lower threshold for protection, with a mere registration requirement, and with a pure gap-filling function to perform. It is therefore striking that UM holders are entitled to the same remedies as patent holders in the existing national laws and the EU framework.Footnote 136
UM protection systems appear to be one of the most appropriate systems of industrial property protection to work with a liability rule. In general, property rules have one main advantage over liability regimes: It is the form of entitlement which gives rise to the least amount of state intervention after the grant of a right.Footnote 137 It is for the parties to agree on a price for the usage of the protected subject matter while liability rules require some organ of the state to determine a value.Footnote 138 Hence, one could fear that shifting the existing property rule approach to a liability regime would increase the involvement of the judiciary in UM disputes. However, unlike most patent systems worldwide, the existing sub-patent protection systems work without pre-grant examination. These protection mechanisms are already court-intense in their design. The validity of the entitlement has not been examined by an IP office. The structure of the system leaves it for the post-registration phase and therewith for the courts to assess the protectability of the subject matter if a dispute arises.
20.6.5 Fulfilling the Auxiliary Function and Curing the Patent System
One concern of the Member States might be whether UMs as mere remuneration rights will still be able to fulfil their intended auxiliary function. UM protection systems are devised to cure gaps in the patent protection (“cheaper”, “faster”, “lower”). However, as briefly discussed above in Sections 20.4.1 and 20.4.2, the Member States have sufficient leeway to improve their national patent system if needed to provide for cheaper and faster protection. For example, if a Member State wants to offer cheaper access to IP protection to accommodate the needs of SMEs, it can offer fee discounts for such patent applicants. Moreover, if a Member State wants to offer faster protection for technical inventions by a property rule, e.g. already during patent prosecution, it could offer patent applicants access to interim injunctions if a preliminary assessment of the court deems the subject-matter patentable. Hence, Member States will need to internalise some of the auxiliary functions (“cheaper”, “faster” protection) performed by their existing national UM systems in their patent systems if they think that a property rule is required.
As a core result of such a directive, the Member States will not be able to offer a full exclusive right for inventions which do not fulfil the requirements of patent protection (“lower” protection). The national systems will need to accept the imposed remuneration approach if they opt for a UM protection system. It is unclear whether this could be a major concern for Member States. It is difficult to imagine cases in which compensation as protection is not sufficient to protect sub-patentable inventions that do not fulfil the requirements of patentability. This idea aligns with the broader consensus that stronger rights come with more stringent requirements. It is well-recognised in copyright law where neighbouring rights tend to protect less original subject matter with a more limited set of rights.
20.6.6 The Structure for Remuneration
There are two ways in which the proposed directive could implement a structure for remuneration. The directive might foresee the establishment of a collection society. Such bodies relieve the burden on individuals to enforce their own rights within the realm of copyright law.Footnote 139 UMs are registered rights which facilitate the collective management of royalties. However, setting up and running such organisations entail high administrative costs.
As an alternative, the directive could enshrine a compensation claim of the right holder against the user of a UM. The burden of enforcement of such an individual claim would lie on the right holder. Therefore, we recommend that the directive works with incentives that users inform the right holder about their exploitation of the UM (“notify-and-use”). This could be achieved by an obligation of the user to inform the right holder prior to the use or shortly thereafter. If not informed, the right holder will be entitled to claim double compensation.
20.7 Conclusion
In the last decades, the EU made tremendous efforts to approximate national IP laws and introduce unitary EU IP rights. Nevertheless, the realm of UM law has remained untouched, despite the various attempts of the EC during the 1990s. The UM protection in the EU is currently fragmented and porous since some Member States have UM protection systems in place while others do not. The existing systems also lack any homogenous understanding as to many core features of UM protection. The lack of harmonisation is surprising as UM systems are traditionally intended to offer protection for SMEs and the EC has repeatedly emphasised their importance for the European economy.
The concept of the single market and the existing EU IP framework call for a harmonisation on an EU level. The current situation builds obstacles to the free movement of goods and has the potential to distort competition due to the risk of hold-ups for businesses, particularly SMEs, which are supposed to be the core beneficiaries of UM systems. Moreover, the lack of a common understanding of UMs leads to problems in the interpretation and application of the EU’s secondary laws that refer to UMs without defining their concept.
The EU can harmonise UM protection either by a regulation or a directive based on Art. 114 or 118 TFEU. However, none of the policy options at hand are entirely convincing. Most of the options would require the EU to take a final decision on the existence of a national or EU UM protection system. Such a step cannot be recommended as the arguments for UM protection are to a certain extent ambiguous. UM systems perform a gap-filler function to overcome shortcomings of the patent system and most of the gaps could be dealt with by amending patent legislations instead of maintaining a sub-patent protection system. Moreover, there appears to be no conclusive evidence that the protection of inventions under lower standards than the patent system is contributing to public welfare in highly developed economies. At the same time, one can also not argue convincingly for the abolishment of UM protection systems. There is no proof that the social costs of UM systems offset their positive effects in the Member States. The best option appears to be an opt-in harmonisation of national UM systems which avoids a decision on the general existence of UM laws by the EU. However, it would not solve the negative effects of the fragmented and porous UM protection within the EU entirely. Moreover, it would require the EU to design a full-fledged gap-filling system in a constellation where the patent system as the main system is varying from Member State to Member State.
This dilemma leads to two assumptions: Further research should reconsider the basic concept of UMs when reflecting on EU harmonisation. Thereby, it should also consider second-best solutions. A new conceptional starting point might be an opt-in harmonisation of national UM systems requiring the Member States to shift from a property rule regime to a liability rule if they want to implement or maintain an UM protection system. This approach would address both reasons for an EU harmonisation. Particularly, a mere remuneration for UM usage by third parties would reduce the negative effects of the fragmented and porous UM protection in the single market. The Member States would be required to fill the existing gaps in their patent system with patent-inherent means. Although the EU would not be forced to take a final decision on the existence of UMs in the EU, it would impose a compulsory remuneration scheme. Further research will need to investigate whether the EU should feel comfortable in doing so.
Utility model patents and similar second-tier rights, collectively referred to as “utility models” for simplicity, are an important yet understudied class of intellectual property (IP) assets.Footnote 1 As discussed throughout this volume, these rights can offer quicker protection than conventional patents, thereby enabling better appropriability of shorter lifecycle innovations;Footnote 2 protect incremental inventions incapable of meeting the higher standards for conventional patents;Footnote 3 and more readily facilitate learning about how and why to use IP than the conventional patent system allows.Footnote 4 The main mechanism behind these benefits lies in the greater accessibility of utility models compared to conventional patents – namely the formal institutional regime that makes utility models easier, cheaper, and quicker to obtain from the government.Footnote 5
However, despite these purported benefits, there is scant comparative research examining the impacts of heterogeneities in the accessibility of utility models over time and around the world. These impacts may include, for example, differences in firms’ decisions to apply for utility models depending on the accessibility of the regime governing the rights, as well as lawmakers’ decisions to amend the regimes governing the rights due to concerns that they offer too much accessibility and therefore undermine utility model “quality.”Footnote 6 Examining these issues in further detail is important for several reasons. It can inform lawmakers about how to maximize utility model accessibility, which should enable wider adoption of the rights. Further research in this space can also maximize state revenues from utility model filing fees. It can also help lawmakers by identifying when too much accessibility can incentivize too many low-quality utility models and thus hamper innovation.Footnote 7
The purpose of this chapter is to evaluate the impacts of heterogeneities in the accessibility of utility models over time and in different economies (i.e., countries and regions) around the world. I do this by, first, briefly conceptualizing the core components of utility model accessibility: the height of the requirements governing the rights, the strictness of the requirements’ administration, and associated direct fees. Then, I summarize work in progress of mine that quantitatively analyzes how differences in the accessibility of utility models over time across a sample of 25 economies impacts the frequency of filing utility models.Footnote 8 Then, drawing directly on other prior research of mine, I provide a more granular, qualitative analysis for a subset of these economies that highlights differences in the accessibility of utility model regimes and their reforms in response to utility model quality concerns.Footnote 9
My research offers a few important lessons. First, there is evidence of an inverted U-curve between utility model regime accessibility and utility model usage: a moderate amount of accessibility may lead to more filings than a lot or a little accessibility – at least over time and multiple economies, ceteris paribus. Second, firms may substitute other means of appropriability for utility models when a utility model regime is less accessible and conventional patent regimes offer stronger rights. Third, utility model regimes may be made less accessible over time to limit quality problems with the rights, although the exact parameters of these reforms must be decided on an economy-by-economy basis.
21.1 Accessibility of Utility Model Regimes
The accessibility of an IP right is determined by how difficult it is to obtain from the government and to maintain as valid.Footnote 10 This accessibility dimension of an IP legal regime joins, of course, the distinct set of rules establishing the length and breadth of IP rights, as well as the mechanisms for their enforcement – referred to in shorthand by the economics and management literature as the “strength” of IP institutions.Footnote 11 The comparative accessibility of utility model regimes make utility models easier, cheaper, and quicker to obtain from the government than conventional patents.Footnote 12 Utility model regimes’ accessibility is determined by several components: the height of the legal requirements governing the rights, strictness with which the rights’ requirements are administered, and direct fees.
21.1.1 Height of Legal Requirements Governing the Rights
There are several subcomponents of the height of the legal requirements for utility models. The first is novelty. The strictest novelty threshold is absolute novelty, the next most restrictive threshold is relative novelty, and the least stringent threshold is local novelty. When novelty standards for utility models and conventional patents differ within economies, they are sometimes lower for utility models but still exist or, in some cases, are completely nonexistent in law.Footnote 13
The next subcomponent is the legal requirements for inventive step. Inventive step for conventional patents is usually thought of as the “nonobviousness” of an invention to a person skilled in the relevant prior art, but exact definitions for utility models differ among economies.Footnote 14 Moreover, some economies’ utility model systems have no inventive step requirements, while others have inventive step requirements but they are lower than for conventional patents, and some economies have the same inventive step requirements for both utility models and conventional patents.Footnote 15
Yet other requirements can fit underneath the height umbrella. These include, for example, standards for sufficiency of disclosure and establishing industrial applicability of the invention. These may vary somewhat among economies.Footnote 16
21.1.2 Strictness of Requirements’ Administration
There are several subcomponents of the strictness of how requirements for utility models are administered. The first is the examination process. Generally, there are two types of utility model patent examinations: a Preliminary Examination and Substantive Examination. Preliminary Examinations often only check formalities, for example, the clarity and completeness of claims and descriptions in the utility model application. However, in some cases, they may include a limited assessment of some substantive aspects of the application. In contrast, Substantive Examinations are more in-depth, assessing the extent to which the utility model application satisfies the legal requirements for novelty, inventive step, industrial applicability, patentable subject matter, among other standards (e.g., sufficiency of disclosure). In some economies, a Search Report – an assessment of the prior art most directly related to a patent application – is used in addition to a Preliminary Examination or as part of a Substantive Examination. This report can be mandatory and considered as a basis to not grant the utility model, mandatory but not considered as a basis for not granting the right, or simply available upon request to the applicant and/or other interested parties and kept only for their own purposes. Although some economies only require Preliminary Examinations for utility models while requiring Substantive Examinations for conventional patents, others require Substantive Examinations for both types of rights.Footnote 17
The second subcomponent is observations and related mechanisms. Economies have widely varying mechanisms to challenge the granting and validity of utility models. These can include an opposition mechanism, under which, during a certain period of time, third parties submit evidence to support the decision not to grant the utility model in the first place (pre-grant) or invalidate the right (post-grant). Although not always opposition mechanisms stricto sensu, various related mechanisms exist in different economies. Some economies have third party observation mechanisms under which third parties can submit information related to the patentability of a utility model, typically after publication but before grant; and this information may be “considered” to varying degrees, including not at all, by the patent office as a basis for not granting the utility model. Some economies have reexamination mechanisms, which can be ex parte or inter partes. Some economies have administrative revocation and invalidation mechanisms, which may or may not have time limits on when invalidation cases can be brought. Some economies have a combination of several of these mechanisms. Such mechanisms are similarly structured for utility models and conventional patents in some economies, although sometimes they are different for utility models, or do not exist at all.Footnote 18
21.1.3 Direct Fees
The official government fees associated with satisfying the aforementioned requirements and obtaining and maintaining a valid utility model are another important aspect of the accessibility of utility model regimes. Utility models around the world usually have substantially lower costs to obtain and maintain than conventional patents owing to their lower and less strict legal requirements.Footnote 19
21.2 Quantitative Analysis of Impact of Utility Model Regime Accessibility on Utility Model Usage
In this section, I draw directly on work in progress of mine that examines the impact of utility model regime accessibility on utility model usage.Footnote 20 On one hand, I conceptualize IP institutions that are too accessible (in other words, too lax) as disincentivizing firms from using those institutions. Here, insufficiently high institutional requirements will attract IP filings of low economic value, while insufficiently strict institutional requirements will create excessive uncertainty about the legal value of those IP filings. Eventually, this will create a vicious cycle whereby, on average, the IP right obtained is of such low economic and legal value that it is not worth the costs, including transaction costs, to obtain and maintain it in the first place. On the other hand, I conceptualize IP institutions that are insufficiently accessible as disincentivizing firms from using those institutions. Here, more restrictive institutional requirements will raise the costs, including transaction costs, of obtaining and maintaining the IP right beyond its economic and legal value.Footnote 21 In short – holding the breadth and length of IP offered by the state, and the associated direct fees, constant – while institutional requirements must be high and strict enough to make IP net beneficial to applicants, those that are excessive will make IP net costly. I therefore predict (H1): The accessibility of utility model regimes will have an inverted U-shaped relationship with utility model filings.
I formulate another prediction as well. Prior economic research indicates that firms may substitute conventional patents for utility models over time.Footnote 22 However, this research does not examine how the institutional requirements governing utility models vs. conventional patents may play into this decision-making. Building upon my aforementioned hypothesis, I propose that utility model regimes that are insufficiently accessible (i.e., too restrictive) may incentivize firms to consider filing conventional patents instead. This is because conventional patent regimes can offer much greater appropriability length and breadth, and more feasible enforcement, for the inventions they protect when compared to the protections afforded by utility model regimes. For example, the duration of protection for utility models is only a fraction of that afforded by conventional patents, and utility models may only protect a more restricted set of product subject matter and often exclude processes entirely.Footnote 23 As such, when conventional patent regimes offer especially strong protection and utility model regimes are relatively inaccessible, the former should be even more attractive substitutes for the latter. I therefore predict (H2): There will be fewer utility model filings in economies with both less accessible utility model regimes and conventional patent regimes that offer stronger rights.
I test these two hypotheses on a sample of 25 economies with utility model regimes or equivalents. These economies include Argentina, Austria, Brazil, Bulgaria, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, the Czech Republic, Ecuador, Germany, Guatemala, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Panama, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Russia, Spain, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey, Ukraine, and South Korea. These economies were selected because they are major sources of economic activity in their respective regions, collectively account for the vast majority (99 percent) of utility model filings around the world,Footnote 24 and the laws governing their utility models (in English or their native languages) over time could be relatively confidently located.
The dependent variable for both hypotheses is the annual filings of utility models in each country in the sample (UMs). Utility model grants were also separately analyzed, and similar findings were reached. This data was collected from WIPO’s IP Indicators database and from the official websites of the national IP offices. Since data prior to 1980 is highly spotty, as is newer data for some economies, I limited the sample to 1980–2014. This time period, nearly 40 years, is reasonable to evaluate the hypotheses. Also, most of the utility model institutions outside of Europe in my sample were first introduced in 1980 or later anyway.
Independent variable: For the first hypothesis, my independent variable is an index measuring the accessibility of utility model regimes in the sampled economies (UM Accessibility Index). The basis for the index is the laws, which I analyzed with support from a team of research assistants, governing utility models for each of the 25 economies in the sample from 1980 to 2014. Copies of the laws for each economy were obtained either from the official government websites of their IP offices or from the WIPO Lex Database. To construct my index from these laws, I build on the methodology developed and validated by Prud’homme (Reference Prud’homme2017a). However, I simplify my index somewhat to minimize error in the scoring process – as interpreting the laws of some of the 25 economies across these sub-indicators was sometimes overly difficult due to their lack of clarity. Table 21.1 outlines the indicators and sub-indicators used. The index is reverse coded, such that higher scores reflect a less accessible utility model regime.
a Source: Prud’homme Reference Prud’homme2024.
For hypothesis 2, the independent variable is the interaction between my UM Accessibility Index and Park’s (Reference Park2008) Patent Strength Index (Park Patent Index), data for which is available until 2015. The Park Patent Index proxies patent length and breadth from conventional patent regimes around the world.
I included several control variables. I constructed an index of the length (maximum duration of rights) and breadth (patentable subject matter) of the utility model regimes per country in the sample (UM Length & Breadth Index) from the same set of laws used for the UM Accessibility Index. A dummy variable was included to control for effects from utility model regimes being in place before the time period I analyzed, namely prior to 1980 (Old UM Regime). I further controlled for the Park Patent Index, GDP, population, total factor productivity, conventional patent filings, and economy fixed effects and year fixed effects.
In terms of estimation methods, for H1, following the methods in Haans et al. (Reference Haans, Pieters and He2016), the independent variable was squared to estimate the inverted-curvilinear relationship. For H2, curvilinear estimates with moderation effects (Haans et al. Reference Haans, Pieters and He2016) were used. In both estimations, the RHS variables were log-transformed and lagged by one year to avoid simultaneity with the dependent variable.
Figures 21.1 and 21.2 visually represent the results for H1 and H2, respectively. These figures and the full set of regression results, available upon request, provide robust, statistically significant support for both hypotheses.
21.3 Qualitative Analysis of Impact of Utility Model Regime Accessibility on Utility Model Quality
In this section, I draw directly on prior work of mine to provide a qualitative comparative analysis of accessibility dimensions of the utility model regimes in a subset of economies studied in the prior section.Footnote 25 I focus on Austria, China, the Czech Republic, Finland, France, Germany, and Italy, but also briefly consider Belgium and the Netherlands. I organize the analysis within the three-part categorization of utility model regime accessibility set forth earlier. When apparent, I emphasize situations where officials in the patent/utility model offices of these economies suspected that the accessibility of their utility model regimes was creating “quality” concerns and reformed their regimes in response. By “quality” of an IP right I broadly mean how well it is drafted, a definition often favored by IP attorneys; the extent to which it meets the legal standards for being granted, a definition often favored by legal scholars; and its technological and/or commercial worth, a definition often favored by economists.Footnote 26 As explained by Prud’homme and Zhang, the quality of all types of patents, utility models included, is important because:
First, an economy rife with low-quality patents is dangerously self-reinforcing because in such an environment rational firms seek more low-quality patents rather than higher-quality patents … In other words, poor patent quality creates path-dependency on inventions that do not significantly contribute to innovation. Second, poor patent quality generates uncertainty, which leads to lower incentives to innovate, which stifles technological development, entrepreneurship, employment, and ultimately growth and consumer welfare … Third, poor patent quality can increase barriers to entry, i.e., more patents blocking freedom-to-operate (FTO), and raise IP-related transaction costs. These barriers and costs are faced when merely identifying the rights in order to maintain FTO; otherwise navigating licensing of the rights; proactively invalidating the rights to maintain FTO; invalidating the rights as a defense in (frivolous or other) infringement disputes; otherwise defending against the rights, if they are difficult to invalidate, in infringement litigation; and defending against the rights if used as a basis for invalidity cases.Footnote 27
21.3.1 Height of Legal Requirements Governing the Rights
Among the economies studied, only Germany has relative novelty for utility models, whereas the other economies currently have an absolute novelty standard for utility models.Footnote 28 While Germany has maintained its novelty standard for some time now, the absolute novelty standard is inferably viewed by the other economies as useful to ensure utility model quality in an increasingly interconnected world.Footnote 29
Some economies have the same inventive step requirement for utility models as for conventional patents. Evidence is mixed, however, as to if this is optimal for balancing utility model quality with incentives to seek utility models in the first place. The experience of Germany offers a natural experiment highlighting this trade-off. A 2006 decision from the German Supreme Court changed the prior way of interpreting inventive step for utility models as lower than for conventional patents to require that the inventive step requirement be the same for both rights.Footnote 30 While perhaps encouraging higher-quality utility models according to some scholar’s conceptualization of the term, this decision was criticized by a range of experts based on legal grounds.Footnote 31 Also, the decision has been scrutinized on economic grounds given it appears to have discouraged filing of utility models by German entities at a time when filing for such rights could be helpful to improve their competitiveness.Footnote 32
The other economies studied have varying approaches to inventive step requirements for utility models relative to conventional patents. France has consistently maintained the same inventive step requirement for utility certificates and conventional patents.Footnote 33 In 2006, the Austrian Supreme Court ruled that the inventive step threshold for utility models, conversely to what the German court ruled the same year, should continue to be lower for utility models than conventional patents; however, in practice, the inventive step for the two rights is assessed similarly.Footnote 34 China,Footnote 35 Finland,Footnote 36 and ItalyFootnote 37 have lower inventive step thresholds in statute for utility models than conventional patents. The Czech Republic has lower inventive step thresholds in statute for utility models than conventional patents, although in practice the inventive step requirement is basically the same.Footnote 38
Different economies use varying methods to determine inventiveness of utility models. China is unique among the economies studied as it has written examination guidelines recommending narrowing prior art to one or two pieces, as well as narrowing the number of technical fields considered, when assessing the inventive step of utility models in “normal” cases.Footnote 39 However, in practice, the patent offices in the Czech RepublicFootnote 40 and FinlandFootnote 41 also usually use no more than one or two pieces of prior art to determine the validity of a utility model – although there are no written rules requiring this and, like in China, there is flexibility to use more pieces of prior art as necessary. Austria, Germany, and Italy have no such restrictions in practice or otherwise. Inventiveness of utility models in Italy and utility certificates in France is determined by the courts through a proceeding removed from the purview of the patent office in which external technical experts can be involved.Footnote 42
21.3.2 Strictness of Requirements’ Administration
Requiring a Search Report prior to granting a utility model, even if not considered as a basis for not granting the application but simply presented alongside it, can be a useful method for ensuring the quality of utility models. This approach is mandatory in Austria.Footnote 43 The costs of such a procedure to patent examiners or externally contracted agents can be included in the fees for filing the utility model. Some offices studied offer Search Reports or a type of report listing prior art relevant to utility model applications prior to publication of the application upon the applicants’ request and for a fee. They also offer such reports to any entity at any time after a utility model is granted for a fee, and such reports are available to the public. This appears to provide the requestor improved certainty regarding the quality of the utility model.
All economies studied consider several formalities in their Preliminary Examinations of utility models. These include the clarity and completeness of claims and descriptions. In some economies, Preliminary Examinations also examine more substantive elements. Finland requires an assessment of industrial applicability of utility models in the Preliminary Examination stage.Footnote 44 ChinaFootnote 45 and the Czech RepublicFootnote 46 require assessing if utility models “obviously” lack industrial applicability. Preliminary Examinations of utility model applications in Austria,Footnote 47 the Czech Republic,Footnote 48 China,Footnote 49 Finland,Footnote 50 France,Footnote 51 and ItalyFootnote 52 assess the patentability of subject matter therein in some form, in terms of obvious nonconformity or otherwise. Meanwhile, the only substantive element examined in the Preliminary Examination of a utility model in Germany is if the invention in the application has a technical background.Footnote 53
China is unique among the economies studied as the country’s National Intellectual Property Administration (CNIPA)’s Preliminary Examination for utility models assesses if the invention in the application “obviously” lacks noveltyFootnote 54 and, as of very recently, inventiveness.Footnote 55 These requirements appear useful to ensure the quality of utility models.Footnote 56
None of the economies studied require a full Substantive Examination for utility models. The lack of this requirement is said to enable utility models to be granted much quicker and cheaper than conventional patents which undergo such an examination. (This being said, multiple economies around the world do require substantive examinations for utility models.Footnote 57) Moreover, in the cases of the Netherlands and Belgium, lack of a substantive examination – or at least examination of novelty via a Search Report – appears to have created significant uncertainty in the equivalent of utility model regimes there by incentivizing the filing of low-quality rights. In fact, partially because of this, these economies ultimately abolished their utility models regimes in 2008 and 2009, respectively.Footnote 58
The economies studied adopt different approaches to third party observation mechanisms. A third-party observation mechanism is used for utility certificates in France.Footnote 59 Third parties in Italy can submit petitions on utility models during the examination procedure, although they are not considered part of a formal third party mechanism nor do they serve as a basis for the Italian patent office to not grant a utility model.Footnote 60 In Austria, while there is no formal mechanism to collect third party observations, if third parties provide the Austrian Patent Office with their observations they will be considered prior to the publication of the Search Report.Footnote 61 These mechanisms can help ensure quality utility models are granted.
The economies studied institute different utility model invalidation procedures. Some invalidation cases go directly to courts without involvement of patent offices, as in France and Italy. In the other economies studied, their patent offices serve as at least a first instance reviewer in a procedure that can then be appealed to the courts. As it is not straightforward to determine from available evidence, it is beyond the scope of this article to assess which of these two approaches are better for utility model quality.
21.3.3 Direct Fees
Relatively low official fees are another classic component of the utility model regime, at least costs lower than those associated with conventional patents. This differential reflects the often less-substantive nature of the examination process for utility models when compared to conventional patents. Also, the lower costs are meant to be one mechanism to enable small-scale inventors, who typically have limited money to protect their inventions, to obtain IP protection. Among the economies studied in this chapter, the nonsubsidized/otherwise preferentially reduced official costs associated with utility models are the lowest in the Czech Republic. This is one main reason cited by the Czech IP Office for the attractiveness of the utility model system to inventors in that economy.Footnote 62
Some economies offer special reductions and subsidization of official filing fees and other expenses associated with utility models. This does not necessarily create problems for utility model quality. For example, available evidence shows that subsidies for intellectual property rights in Italy – which, when distributed by provincial and local level entities, can go to utility models – do not appear to significantly hurt patent quality; however, they also do not appear to do much to improve patent quality.Footnote 63 However, in the case of China, some provincial/municipal and local subsidies and state-provided financial awards for utility models appear to have led to a surge in low-quality utility models.Footnote 64 In reaction to this, China’s CNIPA has continued to work with IP bureaus and other departments across the country to modify and restrict such incentive schemes.Footnote 65 The more significant size and widespread use of state-provided monetary patent incentives in China vs. in European economies, amongst other factors, likely explains the especially negative utility model quality in China.Footnote 66
In summary, utility model regimes need not be homogeneously accessible. However, sometimes, regimes that are too accessible need to be reformed to safeguard against significant utility model quality problems. This is illustrated by China’s experiences with significant state financial incentives for utility model fees alongside low and not strictly administered requirements for obtaining utility models, which stimulated low-quality utility models. The importance of carefully calibrating utility model regimes to safeguard the quality of corresponding rights is also illustrated by the low and not strictly administered requirements for obtaining the equivalent of utility models in Belgium and the Netherlands, which contributed to the abolishment of the regimes governing those rights altogether. In short, utility model regimes may be made less accessible over time to limit quality problems with the rights, although the exact parameters of these reforms need to be decided on an economy-by-economy basis.
21.4 Conclusions
This chapter examined the impacts of heterogeneities of utility model accessibility over time and around the world. I provided evidence of an inverted U-curve between utility model regime accessibility and utility model usage. I also showed that firms may substitute other means of appropriability for utility models when a utility model regime is less accessible and conventional patent regimes offer stronger rights. Lastly, I showed that utility model regimes may be made less accessible over time to limit quality problems with the rights, although the exact parameters of these reforms must be decided on an economy-by-economy basis.
Poor countries may find [IPRs] useful provided they are accommodated to suit local palates. The Commission suggests that the appropriate diet for each developing country needs to be decided on the basis of what is best for its development, and that the international community and governments in all countries should take decisions with that in mind.
This chapter explores the following theoretical extrapolations which are grounded from previous research findings in this area.Footnote 1 Based on the historical and existing literature review, it appears that utility model (UM) law has been defined and rationalized in various ways. And yet, UM laws can subsist as an independent (sui generis) regime within the IP pantheon of rights, untethered to international rules or global norms (save for procedural rules such as priority rules). As the law has pluralistic justificatory bases, and absent strict international rules, policy makers are free to choose existing rationales and/or expand the justifications for UM laws which best suit the local conditions. National UM laws can be sculpted to suit any local socio-economic interest or need.
Can UM law therefore be harnessed to plug existing gaps in protection for innovative practices outside the capitalist economy, including indigenous, traditional and/or community-based innovative practices? This endogenous growth approach would perhaps allow some countries to be guided by the diverse economy school of thought – whereby all types of innovations, initiatives and investments (including non-capitalist yet valued practices) can be nurtured through tailored property rights, or non-property-related remuneration schemes.
22.1 The Uneasy Discourse: Patents, Hybrids and Innovation
The quote at the start of this chapter derives from a 2002 report which analysed the capacity of intellectual property rules [IPRs] to develop in such a manner as to take greater account of the interests of developing countries and poor people.Footnote 2 One recommendation was that lawmakers in developing countries should introduce a system of utility models to foster “domestic innovation” as well as incremental innovation. The Report acknowledged the fact that parties in many low-income developing countries filed very few patent applications despite the presence of innovative activity; the problem was assigned to the defects within patent law, namely high transaction costs in terms of fees, examination and grant timelines, high thresholds and overall institutional complexity.Footnote 3
The “patent defects” argument is the traditional basis for three further inter-related rationales for UM systems: (i) a flexible hybrid right to ameliorate patent law defects, (ii) an IPR tool for small inventors/small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) to prevent free riding/imitative copying in important small and local industries, (iii) an IPR that acts as a spur to enhanced levels of innovation and technological catch-up and/or for improving the environment of developing countries.Footnote 4 Juma sets out a further justification for UMs in that they “may become a source of data on innovative activity and experience in technological management”.Footnote 5
The “patents promote innovation” refrain runs strongly in many other discourses on extending protection to new types of subject matter. Take, for instance, the 2021 Australian decision on the patentability of AI-generated inventions where the first tribunal determined that the meaning of “inventor” (and thus patent protection) should be extended to AI systems. Why? Because the policy objective of the Australian Patents Act 1990 was to promote
technological innovation and the publication and dissemination of such innovation by rewarding it, irrespective of whether the innovation is made by a human or not.Footnote 6
This line of reasoning (especially in relation to a no-examination and low-threshold UM system) leads to further assumptions as to how a comprehensive and extensive IPRs-framework benefits local economies: it encourages local innovations within indigenous cottage industries, it prevents the free-riding of minor or cumulative innovations, and it improves the legal and investment environment of developing countries, which in turn boosts local R&D needed to turn inventions into marketable innovations.Footnote 7
Two queries come immediately to mind. First, is there empirical evidence that existing UM systems encourage the innovation practice and environment? We deal with this in Section 22.2. However, a secondary query which is dealt with immediately below is: if lower patent thresholds can boost minor or cumulative innovation, why not just adopt lower patent thresholds?
22.1.1 Cumulative and Incremental Innovation: Lower Thresholds and Policy Limits
Innovation as a concept lies on a spectrum ranging from Arrow’s sweeping conception (innovation is the production of information) to Schumpeter’s broad definition.Footnote 8 Irrespective of the development and technological stage of the country or the company concerned – a lot of “innovation” is incremental and cumulative. This is equally true of both industrial and cultural innovation.Footnote 9 One of the key implications of that is the creation of new works requires access to and use of pre-existing data and works. So, lowering thresholds within patent (and even design) laws would be a useful policy if it extends to reward cumulative or minor innovation in ways that do not impose high transaction costs on follow-on innovations.
But such low thresholds, whilst benefitting the innovators of today, may hinder the innovation of tomorrow. Good policy dictates that all innovations cannot be categorized as legally patentable inventions. Moreover, if patent protection is structured in such a manner as to unduly require the sacrifice of scarce resources, any societal benefits and economic rent accruing from patent law would be dissipated. These arguments also explain (i) the high levels of novelty and inventiveness (theoretically) required, (ii) the range of limitations and exclusions in national IP laws to ensure that commonplace, obvious or mere workshop inventions and works are not protected,Footnote 10 and (iii) the lack of global consensus as to the eligibility of patentable subject matter such as computer programs, methods, genetic materials or inventions contrary to “morality and ordre public”?Footnote 11
Instead of lowering eligibility thresholds, the other historical solution is to either introduce a liability-rule-based system such as a statute-based tort or misappropriation law, or a hybrid property rights system. We will consider these next.
22.1.2 Revised Rationale for UMs
As I suggested above, the “IPRs promote innovation” mantra is not new and runs throughout the IP literature; and one can detect its influence when the discourse shifts to justifying new hybrid IPR systems in different contexts including fashion, design and plant variety rights.Footnote 12 And indeed, historically, local Procrustean solutions were the ideal means to overcome patent law defects. The solutions could accommodate “forbidden” subject matter, bypass inconvenient policy rules and remove procedural thresholds such as examination or even registration. Existing laws can be re-purposed and extended; or new sui generis rights can be created which emulate existing rights and rationales. Or liability-rule-based systems can be employed to introduce new tort actions.Footnote 13 These systems could operate in place of patents or copyright, or could alternatively operate in parallel, so that patents and copyright could then be used only for those inventions and creative works displaying a demonstrably high inventive step or level of creativity. In this manner, all sorts of new subject matter can be accommodated within any national IPR framework as ostensibly new sui generis regimes (or liability rule systems) can subsist.
The policy criticisms against such hybrid rights are varied. But they can be reduced to a single contention: by constructing a loose hybrid misappropriation or property regime, the traditional IPR system is in danger of being captured by the wrong parties and of being ignored by the “chosen” stakeholders. In the case of UMs, the targeted party usually includes local SMEs or the sole, indigenous innovator. On the other hand, hybrid rights may well be the best way to do so due to the inherent flexibilities in such systems; note such flexibilities within IP law in relation to non-creative databases, test data exclusivity, plant variety and plant patent rights, AI-derived and computer-generated works, and geographical indications.Footnote 14
So perhaps a better rationale for hybrid rights is that property rights may be a necessary allocation to underwrite/support risk-laden, investment-driven knowledge activities and results. This chapter employs this revised rationale to explain why UMs can play a role in a country’s local innovative system. As Cahoy and Oswald argue, UMs are “purely economic rights and are offered in countries at very different levels of development”.Footnote 15
22.1.3 UMs as Development Tools
A final consideration is in relation to the many studies which have emphasized the role of UMs as a catch-up and developmental tool in different contexts.Footnote 16 Thus, Maskus and McDaniel report that technology diffusion through UM applications had had a positive impact on Japan’s post-war productivity growth. Importantly, UM applications had an indirect impact on patent applications. They opine that this perhaps reflects a more fundamental industrial invention, through their stimulation of follow-on utility model applications, which were quickly diffused into commercial use.Footnote 17
A more recent empirical study by Kim et al. affirms this general conclusion in a more concise manner. According to them, UM protection allows developing economies to build up their “indigenous innovative capacities”.Footnote 18 Moreover, within such developing economies, the study found that UMs contributed specifically to technologically lagging firms.
Once firms become more technologically advanced, their performance is driven less by utility model innovations and more by patentable innovations. These results thus indicate that different types of intellectual property rights are more appropriate for countries at different stages of economic development. […] Incremental, adaptive R&D leads to innovations that qualify for such utility model protection and provides a foundation upon which to eventually produce patentable innovations.Footnote 19
This finding appears to lend credence to one of the rationales of UM in that it can enhance the capacity of SMEs/sole innovators to produce (future) patentable inventions – this is discussed further in Section 22.2.2.
Kim et al. conclude that developing countries need to construct the sort of IPR framework which is appropriate for their economic and development level; and that UM protection “can be an important factor affecting the production of patentable innovations only in middle-to-low income countries”. (emphasis added).Footnote 20 A more recent 2020 study for the Asian Development Bank confirms this – at least from the Korean perspective. Depending on the development stage of a firm (or country), the innovation policy should shift between the different forms of IPRs: early stages of development were associated with UMs while catch-up stages required trademark and design, and the globalization stage required patents.Footnote 21 Other studies have also alluded to the holistic IPR framework by noting that technologically strong and developed economies distrust an “easy” system and switch to the more rigorous patent regime, as their concerns shift to market-based competitiveness, the need to attract foreign direct investment, and the use of the utility model system by foreign companies (as in Australia and JapanFootnote 22).
The lesson for developing countries is to seriously consider introducing UMs into their IPR framework. But a lot of initial discourses must be had. And such countries should be realistic and view IPRs as mere tools for economic advancement that contribute to the enrichment of society. If it does not do this, then dump the policy.
What of developed nations? The reasoning appears to be linked again to the economic and innovative environment of the country in question. The 2013 Australian economic review confirmed that the economic effect of UMs decreases with the rise of technological capacity in industries (see Chapter 9 on the Australian system); however, the report also concluded that the continued use of UMs in Japan, Germany, France and Italy (see Chapters 11, 6, 5 and 7, respectively) suggests that these instruments may have a role in innovation and economic growth even in developed economies.Footnote 23
22.2 Mapping a Sui Generis UM System
The proliferation and diversity of UM laws globally is intriguing. There is no harmonized legal understanding nor pattern to UM protection under international law, with the different agreements being silent as to the nature and extent of the second-tier patent/UM right.Footnote 24 However, despite the recalcitrance of substantive international law to engage with UMs, these rights are recognized within the intellectual property chapters of free trade agreementsFootnote 25 or as investment assets under international investment agreements.Footnote 26 More than 100 countries have laws referencing second-tier patent protection resembling UM protection in some form or another.Footnote 27 Heikkilä’s analysis shows the following regional percentages of countries with a two-tiered patent system: 58% of EPO member states, 45% of ARIPO members and 60% of ASEAN members.Footnote 28
The studies show that developing economies can have mixed results due to changing national policies: on the one hand, UM and patent laws are transplanted from other more mature legal regimes, and then countries are faced with the task of transforming such laws to meet evolving local needs of the recipient country. Thus, patent regimes have been weakened in certain countries in order to shift low-income economies into the middle-income stages.Footnote 29 As one study concluded, national IPR policy should be holistically implemented in relation to how the IPR ecosystem works with the different development stages. Thus, in relation to Korean firms, the finding was that national policies should cater for different levels and different forms of IPRs for different development stages: from UMs at an earlier stage to designs in export-oriented sectors or trademarks in domestic market-oriented sectors, and finally to patents at the later development stages.Footnote 30
Using existing laws as a base template, developing countries are thus free to formulate or reject UM protection as they see fit. And should a country introduce such a regime, it can emulate existing regimes or build a bespoke system which is exclusively adapted to local socio-economic conditions and infrastructure subject to mutual reciprocity rules.Footnote 31
22.2.1 Narrow, Short and Non-registered?Footnote 32
The next step would be to consider the undesirable consequences of introducing a UM right which is too broad in terms of eligible subject matter, duration and scope of protection. Such concerns can include: excessive protection of innovations leading to an increase in wasteful claims and litigation; increased rent-seeking behaviour re-directing funding away from innovation or marketing to obtaining more rights via UM; over-utilization by foreign companies accompanied by under-utilization by local firms, leading to an increased outward flow of royalties and licensing fees; using UM system to cordon off research areas.
I would suggest, however, that the most fundamental questions to determine are:
Subject matter: Developing countries, in particular, should be cautious in broadening protection to cover all types of innovations – irrespective of whether they are minor and low-cost innovations, or whether they involve complex and cutting edge technologies such as biological and pharmaceutical products.Footnote 33 Previous experiences show that a generous UM regime will attract larger market players who use the UM regime as a means of circumventing the more stringent criteria under the patent system, and overuse the system in ways that make it hard for SMEs to compete.Footnote 34 Conversely, some of the UM laws are confined to protecting three-dimensional functional or technical designs and innovations, the term of protection is to a short 3–5 year duration, a local novelty threshold is adopted, and the scope of protection is limited to five or fewer claims.
Patent-type registration: Another consideration is whether developing countries should adopt a registration-based system? Especially one which emulates existing patent regimes, and its accompanying procedural formalities and costs? For example, the Australian Government’s report noted that one of the illusory benefits of the “innovation patent” regime was that the upfront and maintenance costs for innovation and standard patents were similar.Footnote 35 From the German perspective, it is apparent that imposing identical application structures on both standard patents and UMs (i.e. claims, description and drawings) results in incurring the same costs in the form of the trained patent agent. “The idea that a utility model application needs less care and competence than a patent application can have fatal consequences especially for sole inventors”.Footnote 36 And surely a quick, automatic right would solve the needs of SMEs to obtain quick injunctive relief again copying?
Hybrid design/UK right: An alternative way to protect cumulative or minor innovation would be to introduce a hybrid IPR fashioned on both industrial design and UM principle – such as the United Kingdom-type unregistered design right which extends to protecting functional shapes.Footnote 37 Historically, this is rather similar to first second-tier patent systems in the world. Both the British and German laws incorporated elements that would ordinarily constitute functional or utilitarian designs or objectives with spatial forms.Footnote 38
22.2.2 For Whom? Local Industries and SMEs
Who are the ultimate beneficiaries of UM laws? It may be that this will be dependent on the innovative capacity of each country, which in turn will depend on the industrial sector in focus. As this author and others have previously highlighted, a key argument for UMs is the ability of such second-tier laws to prevent free-riding and imitative copying. This is more so in relation to certain types of product sectors which are concerned, not so much with revolutionary technological breakthroughs, but more so with incremental or improvement innovation. And that it is quite likely that individuals or SMEs have a large presence in such industries where minor innovation is the norm, and unfair copying is rife.
Prud’homme, for example, notes several studies showing how UMs have had a significant effect on the labour productivity in China, with some benefit accruing directly to individual inventors and SMEs.Footnote 39 Similar reasons were also offered by the European Commission when it initially proposed the (unsuccessful) draft UM directive. In addition to highlighting certain local European industries in need of further protection, the Commission had highlighted the failure of patent law to protect minor innovations from SMEs.Footnote 40 The contrary narrative stems from Australia where a 2015 report noted that it was “unable to obtain adequate empirical evidence as to whether the system does or does not stimulate innovation” in Australian SMEs; a year later, the Australian Government’s Productivity report concluded that the UM system had failed to be a strategic tool to help SMEs.Footnote 41 More recent surveys note that it is the larger firms with more resources and IPR know-how who have utilized UMs as complementary instruments.Footnote 42
There are grumbles even under the much-lauded German UM system, with one commentator going as far as to suggest – as I do above – why not just change patent law and thus render UMs redundant?
Since the utility model is not examined by the Patent Office, the competitors are forced to examine the validity of the claims. These costs can be especially high for small and medium-sized companies (SMEs) which are not used to such examinations and need more advice. Thus, in many cases, SMEs are not the beneficiaries of the fact that the utility model is not examined, but the victims.Footnote 43
22.3 Valuing “Real Innovation” in Developing Countries: SDGs and the “Diverse Economies” Paradigm
IPRs ostensibly exist to benefit society. But this does not tell us much about the ends they are meant to serve nor how these ends ought to be achieved. Much of the literature and discourse revolve around the elusive and almost undefinable concept of “innovation” (or minor innovation).
“Innovative” countries which have national utility model regimes include Japan, China, Republic of Korea and Germany.Footnote 44 Conversely, other top “innovative” countries which have not embraced a national utility model regime, and which may or may not have similar economic histories or current innovative practices, include Switzerland, the United States, the United Kingdom, Singapore, Sweden and Canada.Footnote 45
22.3.1 Registrations Reflect Local Context
A recurring challenge is to resolve the conflicting picture that emerges from various empirical studies: some countries respond to the existence of a UM system, whilst others barely use it. The discourse in Section 22.2 reflects particularly pertinent considerations when we look at the global statistics issued by WIPO from 2019 to 2023.
With the major exceptions of China, Germany, Japan, Korea, Russia and Ukraine, UMs have not been well exploited in many of these countries. The standard patent protection system has been used more extensively and – apart from China – only a handful of UMs have been filed in those countries offering UM protection.Footnote 46 Heikkilä’s work shows that for each of the 40 years preceding 2020, UM filings at the patent offices of China, Japan, the Republic of Korea and Germany accounted for about 90 per cent or more of all global utility model filings.Footnote 47 If we focus solely at the global filings in 2023, we get an impressive figure of 3 million plus filings for UMs as opposed to 3.5 million for patents, and 1.5 million for industrial designs.Footnote 48 But 2.95 million filings originated in a single country – China. The second top country in terms of filing is Germany recording a very modest filing number at 9469.Footnote 49
If we turn to look at other regions, the registration figures remain low. For example, the 2022 ASEAN region statistics show the following approximations:Footnote 50
Indonesia – 3,200 |
Thailand – 3,700 |
Malaysia – 200 plus |
Cambodia – 13 (in 2018 registrations) |
Philippines – 1,800 plus |
Vietnam – 340 |
It is also difficult to reconcile the development ethos with the low registration rate in some African states which come under the Harare Protocol.Footnote 51 On the one hand, the UM system is treated as being a success in Kenya since (i) there has been a continuous increase in the UM application rate annually, and (ii) more than 90 per cent of UM applications were made by local entities. However, the actual numbers remain low: prior to 2015 when substantive examination was carried out on UMs, the success rate was as follows: out of 450 UM applications, 85 were registered (18.8 per cent success rate).Footnote 52
However, what do these statistics reveal other than registration is not a preferred mode by sole or small entitles? Do the registration figures for China indicate high innovative capacity or is it due to China’s distinctive national innovation policy which embraces, inter alia, innovation parks, IPRs pledge loans, compulsory licences and talent plans?Footnote 53 And to what extent do registration statistics indicate the local innovative environment or show that UM systems encourage domestic innovation?
22.3.2 Determining “Local Innovation”
Many economists, by focussing on Schumpeter’s narrow usage of innovation, see innovation as something which introduces new technology to the market.Footnote 54 This tends to view innovation as something inextricably linked to patent systems, and usually as extractive and capitalist commodities – discussed further in Section 22.3.3.
However, as Scherer points out, innovation does occur in cultural spheres such as music performance and composition, film making and book writing.Footnote 55 Innovation must be understood in the broader Schumpeterian sense: the usage of information in the creation of scientific and cultural goods. A correlated view is that most innovations, as opposed to groundbreaking and dramatic inventions, are routine and primarily devoted to product improvement or enhanced user-friendliness or searches for new uses for those products.Footnote 56
In sum, innovation is a complex process intertwined with factors such as the strength of the knowledge base, institutional arrangements, qualifications of the labour force, openness of the economy and an overall ability to take on board improvements achieved in other countries or sectors.Footnote 57
It may be more helpful to treat IP systems holistically and also as public policy regulatory institutions. Institutions that evolve over time and operate in diverse ways according to the local innovation and economic contexts. Therefore, the same UM system may be appropriate and functional in one context (e.g. under China’s national innovation policy) but inappropriate and dysfunctional in another (e.g. the Australian example). It can be difficult to predict how well such an institution transplanted to a completely different cultural, political or economic milieu will work in practice. And history offers some clear and important indicators. Take the case of Germany where UMs were introduced when the changing economic and industrial policies and landscape generated a perfect incubator for the newly coherent and unified industrial property policy, in the German free trade area in the late nineteenth century. And with Germany industrialising rapidly, the anti-monopoly and anti-patent movements were collapsing.
22.3.3 Observing and Valuing “Real Innovation”: Diverse Economies: An Inventory of Local Entrepreneurship
Part of the problem with any UM study is, I believe, the approach which accepts the categorization of UMs as “industrial property” under the Paris Convention. This leads to the logical extension of perceiving UMs as a subaltern second-tier regime, as an off-shoot of the “parent first-tier” patent regime, and as being a registered right. This is curious when one argument for UMs is the “flexibility” inherent in international IP and the flexibility that most nations presume when designing bespoke utility model laws.Footnote 58 It is arguable that the true test of the flexibility of UM systems would be to escape the strict IP typology and if UMs can be re-fashioned so as to protect “local innovation” in a broader and more meaningful fashion. The optimal way forward would be to (i) identify with precision the innovation culture within the country, thus optimizing the entire IPR framework needed, (ii) identify which cottage or fledgling industries are to be encouraged, thus tailoring the subject matter of protection to such industries, and (iii) map the different stages of development within that country for those specific industries.
I suggest that this sort of analysis, which will differ according to different economic and technological contexts, may be undertaken within the diverse economies framework. This theoretical framework has been labelled as a Marxist approach though a more gentle description may be that the diverse economies framework invites us to consider the heterogeneity of economic practices which produce knowledge and endeavours (including innovation).Footnote 59
Developing countries should cast a wide net to inventorize, capture and valorize all sorts of innovative activities, which are not necessarily produced as surplus, through locally grounded enterprises including cooperative, ecological, communal, non-profit and tribal enterprises. Such a diverse economies inventory may work to identify why, despite local innovative practices, there is so little interest in registration systems. Examples of diverse enterprises include:
tenant farmers in India who are in feudal-like relationships but manage up to one-fifth of India’s land holdings; or self-employed farmers in Kenya that make up almost 500 million small farm households worldwide;Footnote 60
the Mondragon Corporation representing 250 companies in the Basque region of Spain who engage in participatory cooperative activities to produce “innovative” products across finance, industrial, retail and knowledge sectors;Footnote 61 and
the Trent Market Garden/Flint Corn Community projects which are mixed student, Aboriginal cultural knowledge, and Indigenous seed saving supply and educational initiatives.Footnote 62
If we focus on IPRs and local innovation, a good example is the Sri Lankan cosmetics industry which incorporates traditional knowledge. According to findings, such industries are hesitant to use the patent system due to fear of (i) disclosure of valuable information to competitors, (ii) delays in the registration process which affects the short product life-cycle, (iii) lack of novelty and inventive step. And thus the authors suggest that UMs may be very appropriate for Sri Lanka at this stage.Footnote 63
More engagingly for our purposes, the diverse economies outlook asks policy makers to re-think and re-frame the “type” of sole innovators/SMEs that work and live in specific contexts. Are we expecting them to be the capitalist entrepreneur at the heart of the economic process: the heroic, charismatic, special people, with high levels of vigour, persistence and self-esteem, rational Western white males? Or can we expand our vision to include, say, SME owners who have limited cash flows and an unsympathetic bank manager?
Small and medium-sized enterprise (SME) owners often “just about manage” […]in the global South, this is especially so. […] Many fail, and enthusiasts for entrepreneurialism pay too little attention to the costs of this failure in financial terms (leading to debt poverty, perhaps homelessness) and in terms of mental health issues, internalization of feelings of being a “loser” who made “bad choices” in the enterprise culture, family breakups, and homelessness.Footnote 64
In this reality, SME owners may have very limited time, cash, energy and resources, it is odd, therefore, to believe that a registered system, with complex forms calling for legal services, would be the pathway to economic success in developing countries. Moreover, a truly local and small business is usually embedded within the local communities – staying through good times and bad, having a reputation to maintain, and using their surplus profits to support local services, groups, pubs and cafes, etc.Footnote 65
And yet, I have not found any UM law which emphasizes the “IPRs for local businesses” link or threshold.Footnote 66 Or else, one finds this link within national innovation policies such as the Chinese policy – which has led to more enthusiastic local participation. This re-assessment of “local innovation” can also vary widely despite the category of “developing countries”. The starting assumption is that the latter term refers to a country with comparatively low economic output, the World Bank uses “developing countries” as a convenient nomenclature for “low and middle income countries”, and bases its categorization on the gross national income (GNI). The UNDP Human Development Index looks at several factors in order to classify countries according to its “level of human development”, whilst the UN itself uses “developed regions, and developing regions, and Least Developed Countries” and the IMF employs “advanced economies, emerging and developing economies”. Therefore, Malawi and Mexico are developing countries but their respective GNIs are disparate: US$250 v US$9,860. This, in turn, does not explain other “developing” considerations, for example a developed country may still be an IP net importer nation.
22.3.4 Linking Innovation and UMs to SDGs
A final suggestion is that developing countries seriously consider tying UM legislation with SDGs, expressly in the statute or with a national innovation policy paper. “Innovation is not an end in and of itself: innovation is an instrumental good”.Footnote 67 Or as the WIPO policy paper on the SDGs states:
[w]e need innovation to help us rethink how to overcome poverty, hunger and premature mortality, how to combat climate change and preserve our natural world, how to optimize the use of artificial intelligence, and how to shape the future of work.Footnote 68
The value scheme under SDG9 can be linked, in a similar manner as advocated under the diverse economies theory, to the types of innovative and entrepreneurial activities which are of importance in the Global South (but not necessarily in the US or EU): build resilient infrastructure, promote inclusive and sustainable industrialization and foster innovation.
We leave the final note to Noto La Diega, Cifrodelli and Dermawan who advocate this perspective in the new technological field of AI-generated inventions. The question is whether developing countries should adopt the US/EU perspective of what constitutes patentable innovation, or do such countries adopt SDG9 values since they “constitute an incentive for the promotion of sustainable industrialisation and the upgrade of technological capabilities”.Footnote 69 Thus,
[t]o simply “export” the rationale for rejecting AI inventorship to the Global South should be regarded as a form of “patent colonialism”. Based on a deeper understanding of the wider industrial and socio-economic context, governments in the Global South should be able to use the patent system as both an industrial policy tool and a means for sustainability, and this may well include the acceptance of AI systems as inventors.Footnote 70