Introduction
The decision by WTO members to negotiate to clarify and improve fisheries subsidies disciplines signals a new role for the WTO regime in ensuring the sustainability of fish and the fish trade. The WTO joins several existing legal regimes in recognizing the need for multilateral cooperation on fisheries issues to prevent the collapse of global fish stocks, such as the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS), voluntary instruments adopted by the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), and regional approaches. These regimes have responded in various ways to increasingly urgent calls for measures to address the serious decline in wild capture fisheries, where at least 50% of stocks are fully exploited and 25% are either overexploited, depleted, or recovering from depletion.Footnote 1 One of the major contributing factors to this crisis is overfishing.Footnote 2
The call for attention to the fishing sector by the WTO regime has come from economists as well as environmentalists. There is increasing recognition that marine fisheries operate globally at a net economic loss.Footnote 3 Perverse incentives to build up an already redundant global fishing fleet capacity, often exacerbated by political pressure for subsidies,Footnote 4 has created economic waste as well as ecological devastation. Much of the fishing sector is heavily supported by states. Although the level of support is difficult to access and quantify, a range of studies indicate that subsidies could amount to a quarter of the value of revenues in the fisheries sector or even higher.Footnote 5 Based on a collection of notifications and data supplied by the countries, Japan provides between US$2 and $3 billion annually to its fishing industry.Footnote 6 Significant amounts are also paid out by the European Union,Footnote 7 the United States, Canada, Korea, and China.Footnote 8 While much of this support promotes useful management and conservation techniques, it also risks overfishing through capacity enhancement. Indeed, the size and technological capability of fishing fleets has reached immense dimensions and has helped to ensure that fish is one of the most highly traded food and feed commodities. The value of this trade has reached US$71.5 billion, representing at least a 20% increase over the latest recorded four-year period and a 51% increase since 1994.Footnote 9 Apart from value increases, the volume of exported fisheries product increased by nearly 8% from 2002 to 2004.Footnote 10 Thirty-eight per cent of the estimated 142 million tonnes of fisheries and aquaculture production went into exports in 2004.Footnote 11
The attempt by the WTO to discipline fisheries subsidies seems to make environmental and economic sense. Indeed, the express link between the subsidies negotiations and concurrent Doha Round negotiations on trade and the environment acknowledges that the objectives of the new disciplines will be mutually supportive of a range of existing international regimes. Yet the interconnectedness of conservation and trade issues has given rise to significant legal hurdles for WTO members. There is an acute legal problem for the WTO to classify and discipline ecologically harmful subsidies when it has scant institutional or epistemic capacity in this regard. There are problems in the WTO deferring to principles of international fisheries management contained in existing regimes, especially when the WTO membership as a whole has not uniformly approved of such regimes. These problems have beset the framing of the disciplines, and learning and information sharing between regimes has been hindered by restrictive attitudes to observership and participation. In addition, the future implementation and adjudication of subsidies rules faces significant challenges, and there is significant uncertainty about whether organizations like the FAO should have a role in reviewing the fishing practices of subsidizing WTO members.
This article suggests these legal problems can be addressed by moving away from conceptions of strict legal mandates and legal hierarchies, and embracing deliberation and ongoing inter-regime scrutiny by a range of participants. It points to examples from the fisheries subsidies negotiations, as well as existing arrangements in other parts of the WTO covered agreements, to suggest renewed attention to procedures for learning, information-sharing, and multistakeholder deliberation. These procedures have implications for the ongoing effectiveness of the resulting fisheries subsidies disciplines, as well as fragmentation of laws and institutions within the international legal system.
Section 1 introduces regimes that relate to fisheries sustainability, including UNCLOS, the FAO, and the existing framework of the WTO's Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM Agreement). It describes ongoing efforts to clarify and improve fisheries subsidies disciplines, with special reference to reactions to the draft proposals circulated in November 2007. Section 2 examines the ongoing challenges for the WTO regime in framing rules and incorporating standards from fisheries regimes. It assesses the legal constraints on WTO members, intergovernmental organizations, and other actors in promoting learning about fisheries regimes, subsidy effects, and ecological concerns in the negotiations. It then analyses the proposed regime interaction in the rules themselves and compares existing procedures in the SCM Agreement and SPS and TBT Agreements relating to export credit undertakings and product standards. Section 3 engages with broader themes of governance and considers implications of ongoing deliberation and inter-regime scrutiny for the WTO and international law.
1. Fragmented fisheries governance and overlapping regimes
States have historically cooperated on a range of functional and regional issues relating to fisheries, leading to a variety of self-standing laws and principles. These laws and principles can be grouped in ‘regimes’, a term used to emphasize the contrasting issue areas to which they respond.Footnote 12 In fisheries issues, state expectations have converged under the auspices of several treaties and international organizations, including UNCLOS,Footnote 13 the FAO, species-specific and regional fisheries management organizations, and environmental treaties such as the Convention on the International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Flora and Fauna (CITES). The resulting web of norms and institutions, which were all developed at different times and agreed by differing states, gives rise to problems of co-existence and conflict which are made more complex by the absence of a world legislature. It is part of a general phenomenon known as the ‘fragmentation of international law’.Footnote 14
Fragmentation has given rise to a number of challenges in fisheries policy and more generally. For example, there is the potential for states to file parallel proceedings at the International Tribunal of the Law of the Sea and another body, such as the WTO. This occurred in a dispute between the EC and Chile over swordfish landings.Footnote 15 In addition, courts and tribunals may find it necessary to interpret laws within one regime by reference to laws that have been developed within another regime. This occurred most famously in a WTO dispute over a US import ban on shrimp.Footnote 16
Recent literature on the fragmentation phenomenon has concentrated on situations where international norms come into relationships of conflict or interpretation.Footnote 17 This problem is usually manifest at the stage of dispute settlement in international law, when states have already negotiated and implemented relevant laws. In providing recommendations for states, a Study Group of the International Law Commission (ILC) recently published a ‘toolbox’ of relevant principles to provide guidelines for legal practice.Footnote 18 The ILC pointed to principles such as the rule of lex specialis, according to which a more specific treaty will usually trump the general treaty,Footnote 19 in order to find the true intent of the state parties in these situations.
Less attention, however, has been given to the impact of fragmentation on the making of international rules, and the ILC Study Group concluded that there was a need for greater analysis of ‘the notion and operation of “regimes”’.Footnote 20 Indeed, in the context of WTO rules on fisheries subsidies, there is considerable uncertainty about how regimes should interact in their formulation as well as their future application. There is as much scope for international lawyers to contribute understanding and ideas about collaboration and cohesion in rule making within regimes as there is in a focus on ex post rules determining priority in later disputes. An analysis of regime interplay during rule making may even contribute to a different understanding of conflicting norms and of the way regimes interact after rules are made. To introduce this discussion, the remainder of this section provides an overview of the main regimes of relevance to the fisheries subsidies negotiations.
Law of the sea and ‘optimum utilization’
UNCLOS promotes an objective of ‘optimum utilization’ of fisheries. Its greatest impact on fisheries governance has been the recognition that the exclusive economic zone (EEZ) of states extends to 200 nautical miles.Footnote 21 As a result, 90% of fish resources are now located within the national jurisdiction of coastal states.Footnote 22 Broadly speaking, there are two main ways a state ‘utilizes’ the fish within its EEZ: (1) by allowing their own registered vessels to fish within these areas; or (2) by granting access to other states, having had regard to the rights of land-locked and geographically disadvantaged states.Footnote 23 Many of the states that procure such access have large vessel capacity that has historically been used in their own coastal areas or in distant waters. The European Union, for example, has entered into 20 bilateral fishing agreements, primarily with developing countries in Africa, which allow EU vessels to fish within the EEZs of these countries.Footnote 24
The remainder of the oceans outside the EEZs continues to be classified as ‘high seas’.Footnote 25 These areas contain a number of highly migratory species of significant commercial value, in addition to ‘straddling stocks’ which move back and forth across EEZ boundaries. There is significant competition between states to fish for these species and disincentives for such states to adopt conservation measures that could benefit ‘free-riding’ states. As such, these species are especially vulnerable to ‘the tragedy of the commons’.Footnote 26
UNCLOS provides that all states will continue to enjoy the traditional freedoms of fishing in the high seas, but this right is qualified by the need to conserve living resources.Footnote 27 States whose nationals fish in the high seas are expected to cooperate to conserve and manage living resources and to establish regional institutions for this purpose.Footnote 28 Similarly, coastal states and fishing states whose vessels move between EEZs and the high seas in order to catch highly migratory species, such as tuna, are to cooperate through relevant organizations.Footnote 29 These ‘regional fisheries management organizations’ (RFMOs), some of which had existed before UNCLOS was agreed,Footnote 30 now number over 20.Footnote 31 Some are specific to species; others are based on regions.Footnote 32
A major problem of UNCLOS has been that even if conservation measures are developed within RFMOs, some nationals reflag their vessels to register them with non-member states that offer ‘flags of convenience’.Footnote 33 In addition, many vessels (including those flying flags of convenience and those that are authorized) are increasingly involved in fishing that is illegal, unreported, and unregulated.Footnote 34
In 1995, attempts to improve the management of the high seas culminated in a new ‘Fish Stocks Agreement’Footnote 35 which has been ratified by over 70 countries. The Fish Stocks Agreement applies to highly migratory fish stocks and fish stocks that straddle the high seas and EEZs.Footnote 36 It provides that parties who fail to become members of an existing regional regime and refuse to apply conservation and management measures can be denied access to the relevant fishery.Footnote 37
As is clear from the brief description given above, the law of the sea regime's achievement of ‘optimal utilization’ depends heavily on the institutions within which states cooperate on conservation and management measures. Both UNCLOS and the Fish Stocks Agreement rely on existing or to-be-established RFMOs for implementation and management.Footnote 38 Unfortunately, however, many RFMOs suffer from problems in restraining overfishing.Footnote 39 In addition to this lack of regional support, there is little direct support at the international level. The UN Division for Ocean Affairs and the Law of the Sea provides advice and research on the implementation of UNCLOS, but does not have specific functions relating to fisheries.Footnote 40 The General Assembly of the UN has a broad oversight and makes annual resolutions but is not involved in any specific monitoring of treaty implementation or compliance.Footnote 41 The only other international institution is a UN specialized agency that seeks to improve ‘the efficiency of the production and distribution of all food and agricultural products’: the FAO.Footnote 42
The FAO instruments and ‘responsible fisheries’
The reliance on coastal states and RFMOs to control the exploitation and development of fisheries within the law of the sea regime has largely failed to secure responsible fisheries management. Advocacy for a different approach to fisheries management and conservation has taken place within the FAO, where members have sought to establish principles and standards within a voluntary ‘soft-law’ framework. States do not need to be a party to UNCLOS to be a member of the FAO, and indeed some have joined the FAO without agreeing to UNCLOS.Footnote 43
The FAO collects and publishes fisheries dataFootnote 44 and provides institutional support for the negotiation and ongoing revision of a range of instruments, including binding agreements, voluntary codes, plans of actions, and technical guidelines. It is made up of several governing bodies, including sectoral committees such as the Committee on Fisheries in which members may apply to participate.Footnote 45
In seeking to address the reflagging of fishing vessels into flags of convenience, FAO members adopted in 1993 a ‘Compliance Agreement’.Footnote 46 Two years later, the FAO conference adopted the Code of Conduct for Responsible Fisheries (‘Code of Conduct’), which sought to engage with technical, socio-economic and environmental factors relating to sustainable fishing.Footnote 47 Reiterating the duty of states to cooperate through regional institutions,Footnote 48 the Code of Conduct is also directed at fishing entities, NGOs, and persons including ‘fishers, those engaged in processing and marketing of fish and fishery products and other users’.Footnote 49 Voluntary ‘International Plans of Actions’ (‘IPOAs’) provide further elaboration of the Code of Conduct for specific species and issues.
The FAO Code of Conduct recognizes the problem that there are too many boats fishing for too few fish. It provides that states should take measures ‘to ensure that fishing effort is commensurate with the productive capacity of the fishery resources and their sustainable utilization’.Footnote 50 This is not simply preventative: the Code recognizes that excess fishing capacity needs to be ‘eliminated’.Footnote 51 States' management measures are to provide that ‘the economic conditions under which fishing industries operate promote responsible fisheries’.Footnote 52
Although the Code of Conduct does not mention subsidies expressly, two IPOAs call on states to reduce subsidies which contribute to the build-up of excessive fishing capacity: the IPOA for the Management of Fishing Capacity (‘IPOA-Capacity’), which was adopted in 1999,Footnote 53 and the IPOA to eliminate illegal, unregulated and unreported fishing (‘IPOA-IUU’).Footnote 54
The FAO's IPOA-Capacity calls upon states to ‘reduce and progressively eliminate all factors, including subsidies and economic incentives … which contribute, directly or indirectly, to the build-up of excessive fishing capacity’.Footnote 55 Supported by information on subsidies to be gathered by the FAO,Footnote 56 states are to achieve capacity reduction in four ways: (1) by conducting national, regional, and global assessments of capacity; (2) by preparing and implementing national plans; (3) by strengthening RFMOs; and (4) by undertaking immediate action for major straddling, highly migratory and high seas fisheries.Footnote 57 To date, only two states have submitted ‘national plans of action’ on capacity to the FAO: the United States and Namibia.
The FAO's IPOA-IUU also refers to subsidies. It calls on states to ‘avoid conferring economic support, including subsidies, to companies, vessels or persons that are involved in IUU fishing’, but only ‘to the extent possible in their national law’.Footnote 58 The plan provides that the FAO will have a role in collecting relevant information and analysis on subsidies practices.Footnote 59 To date, national plans on combating IUU fishing have been notified by Australia, Canada, Chile, Korea, New Zealand, and the United States.Footnote 60
The voluntary approach to subsidies reduction has largely failed to change national policies and has failed to alleviate the overfishing and economic drain in the fishing sector. At the World Summit on Sustainable Development in 2002, states were reminded that to achieve sustainable fisheries they must ratify or accede to UNCLOS and the Fish Stocks Agreement, effectively implement the FAO Code of Conduct, and urgently develop and implement national and regional plans of action, in particular the IPOA-Capacity (by 2005) and the IPOA-IUU (by 2004).Footnote 61 For the elimination of subsidies contributing to IUU fishing and overcapacity, however, attention had moved from the law of the sea regime and FAO instruments. Instead, states were called upon to improve relevant parts of a legal regime that directly confronts the national policies of subsidizing states: the World Trade Organization.Footnote 62
WTO subsidies disciplines
The weakness of the law of the sea and FAO regimes in addressing the economics of the fishing sector has led to increased attention on the WTO regime and, in particular, on its disciplines on subsidies. Members have agreed to clarify and improve the SCM Agreement's disciplines as part of the Doha Round.
The SCM Agreement
The WTO SCM Agreement disciplines the use by WTO members of certain subsidies that are specific to enterprises or industries and regulates the actions other WTO members can take to counter the effects of such subsidies. It categorizes subsidies as prohibited, actionable, or non-actionable. These categories are often described by mixing a traffic light metaphor: the prohibited subsidies are ‘red-box’, actionable subsidies are ‘amber-box’ and non-actionable subsidies are ‘green-box’. The green-box, which includes subsidies for the adaptation of existing facilities to environmental sustainability, has lapsed under the existing SCM framework.Footnote 63
WTO members have so far been unwilling to challenge the fisheries subsidies of another WTO member under the SCM Agreement. On the one hand, it is fairly certain that most government support to the fishing sector will be ‘deemed’ to be a subsidy.Footnote 64 On the other hand, the breadth of practice of granting fisheries subsidies may mean that WTO members are reluctant to expose themselves to scrutiny when pursuing claims.Footnote 65 Indeed, even if WTO members do not provide subsidies themselves, they may indirectly benefit from subsidies of other members which are used to procure access rights for fleets to fish in distant water EEZs. Such rights, for example, are sometimes obtained by WTO members through non-financial arrangements, such as the provision of preferential trade incentives.Footnote 66
The absence of any litigation on fisheries subsidies may, instead, be attributed to a lack of certainty about the applicability of the red-box and amber-box disciplines of the SCM Agreement, as currently framed. Current red-box subsidies are those subsidies that are contingent on export performance or the use of local content.Footnote 67 Because the majority of fisheries subsidies are granted by countries such as Japan that are net importers of fish, and are usually designed to encourage domestic fish supply rather than exports, the red-box test is said to be difficult to meet in many cases. Also ill-suited is the red-box's emphasis on ex-ante legal design rather than effects.Footnote 68
The actionable subsidies of the amber-box, on the other hand, are assessed according to their adverse effects on the trade interests of other WTO members. These subsidies, which must also be specific to a particular enterprise or industry,Footnote 69 are assessed according to injury to the domestic industry of another member, the nullification or impairment of benefits of another member, or serious prejudice to the interests of another member.Footnote 70 The establishment of these adverse effects is difficult in the fisheries context, however, given that the likely distortions caused by fisheries subsidies will be in resource availability, rather than price for exporters, and that such effects are spread over heterogeneous fisheries products.Footnote 71
A further deficiency for the disciplining of fisheries subsidies under the current framework relates to inadequate compliance with the SCM Agreement's notification and surveillance regime. WTO members are obliged to notify the WTO annually of any subsidy granted or maintained,Footnote 72 yet fisheries programmes are apparently underreported and the WTO lacks meaningful data for the fisheries sector.Footnote 73
Discussion between WTO members about the need to address fisheries subsidies, and the possible inadequacies of the SCM Agreement, took place in the Committee on Trade and Environment (CTE) in the 1990s. Although the linkage between trade and environmental policies is often considered sceptically given perceived problems of effectiveness,Footnote 74 the disciplining of fisheries subsidies falls squarely within the available measures and objectives of the WTO. In 2001, WTO members launched the Doha Round of negotiations, and included fisheries subsidies on the agenda for reform.
The Doha negotiations
WTO members have agreed to negotiate to ‘aim to clarify and improve WTO disciplines on fisheries subsidies, taking into account the importance of this sector to developing countries’, as part of a wider scale reform of the SCM and Anti-Dumping Agreements.Footnote 75 The negotiations have been assigned to the Negotiating Group on Rules (‘Rules Group’), which reports to the WTO's Trade Negotiations Committee.
WTO members have acknowledged the environmental dimension to the fisheries subsidies negotiations by referring to the mutual supportiveness of trade and environment.Footnote 76 The link between the trade-distorting and environmental harmful aspects of fisheries subsidies has been restated in the course of the negotiations. The Ministerial Declaration at the Hong Kong meeting of trade ministers in 2005 states that Ministers
recall our commitment at Doha to enhancing the mutual supportiveness of trade and environment, note that there is broad agreement that the Group should strengthen disciplines on subsidies in the fisheries sector, including through the prohibition of certain forms of fisheries subsidies that contribute to overcapacity and over-fishing, and call on Participants promptly to undertake further detailed work to, inter alia, establish the nature and extent of those disciplines, including transparency and enforceability. Appropriate and effective special and differential treatment for developing and least-developed Members should be an integral part of the fisheries subsidies negotiations, taking into account the importance of this sector to development priorities, poverty reduction, and livelihood and food security concerns.Footnote 77
In November 2007, the Chair of the Rules Group, Ambassador Guillermo Valles Games, circulated a draft consolidated text of the proposed disciplines (‘Chair's text’).Footnote 78 The Chair's text is in the form of an annex (‘Annex VIII’) of the SCM Agreement. Since then, there have been several meetings in which some WTO members have criticized various aspects of the Chair's text. These criticisms have been summarized in a draft document issued on 28 May 2008,Footnote 79 which describes the difficulties in making effective rules that still address development priorities, poverty reduction, and food security concerns. The Chair tabled a ‘roadmap’ of key issues rather than a new draft text on 19 December 2008.Footnote 80
Two main positions have been taken by the Rules Group participants leading up to the Chair's text. The first position, associated with an informal grouping of WTO members self-named ‘Friends of Fish’,Footnote 81 is based on a conviction of the link between enhanced subsidy disciplines and trade, environmental and development needs.Footnote 82 These countries have proposed a general prohibition of all fishery subsidies that support fishing enterprises with limited exceptions. Exceptions to this prohibition, which would be identified and defined during the negotiations, would relate to subsidies that are expressly concerned not to encourage overfishing, such as subsidies to decommission vessels and support social programmes to retrain workers for other industries.
The second position, which has been taken by Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and others, contests the link between subsidies and environmental damage, and instead asserts that inadequate fisheries management is the main cause of unsustainable fishing.Footnote 83 These countries contend that subsidies are not dangerous to fishery resources if the fisheries regime is properly managed, and that reliance on the work of the fisheries management regimes is sufficient. In line with this approach, developing coastal states that oppose subsidies disciplines have argued that fisheries management issues are not an appropriate subject for the WTO and that other forums, such as the FAO, should address subsidies issues.Footnote 84 The EC has also stated that other forums have priority over the WTO Rules Group.Footnote 85
Although Japan, Korea, and Taiwan have accepted the jurisdiction of the WTO to deal with the issue,Footnote 86 they have maintained their emphasis on the non-WTO management of fisheries.Footnote 87 As an alternative to the recommendation of a comprehensive ban put forward by the Friends of Fish, these WTO members advocate the general permissibility of fisheries subsidies with certain limited prohibitions.Footnote 88 They propose that WTO members identify the subsidies that they deem illegal, such as capacity-enhancing and IUU-supporting subsidies, and allow all others.Footnote 89 Japan has also proposed that certain subsidies for vessel construction be allowed if the fisheries are properly managed.Footnote 90 This reliance on management has attracted strong criticism from other WTO members.Footnote 91
Within both sets of positions, there is an underlying problem of how the WTO should differentiate between harmful subsidies and those subsidies that enhance sustainability of the fishing sector. There are no universal definitions; instead, much depends on the context in which the subsidies are provided and the underlying social and economic conditions. For example, a subsidy used to decommission an existing vessel, which may be ‘good’ to reduce overcapacity of one state, may be ‘bad’ if the vessel is made available to another overexploited fishery. There is significant disagreement in particular about how the Rules Group, in framing and implementing the new rules, should rely on information and incorporate existing norms from other regimes. For example, is it relevant that there is not, and never can be, parallel membership between the WTO and other relevant regimes (in the sense that some WTO members, such as the Customs Territory of Taiwan, are ineligible to be members of the FAO)? Should this lack of uniformity of state membership lead WTO members to rely solely on their own fisheries and environmental ministries to coordinate information? What other models for learning and information-exchange, such as institutional observership or informal deliberation, can be used? What effect will such inter-regime collaboration have on the implementation of the disciplines and proposed use of standards, benchmarks, and peer review from the law of the sea and FAO? Section 2 examines the challenges and opportunities of regime interaction in the WTO negotiations.
2. The challenges and opportunities of regime interaction
The challenges and opportunities of interaction by the WTO with other regimes in the fisheries subsidies negotiations can be divided into the need to learn about existing regimes, which arises largely, but not solely, at the negotiation stage, and the need to entrench inter-regime linkages in the proposed disciplines. Accordingly, the first sub-section examines learning and information exchange in the context of the Rules Group activities. It suggests that inter-regime learning is variously facilitated and constrained by legal assumptions that can be separated into three different models. The second sub-section then considers how the Chair's text incorporates standards, benchmarks, and peer review from the law of the sea and FAO regimes. This ongoing regime interaction is compared to existing rules in the SCM Agreement and the SPS and TBT Agreements, which allow for ongoing interaction between the WTO, the OECD, and a number of organizations involved in product standards. This comparative analysis informs the emphasis in Section 3 on inter-regime deliberation and scrutiny as safeguards against international law's fragmentation.
Negotiations and inter-regime learning: three models
Rules Group participants have learned about the law of the sea and FAO regimes in various ways. First, they have drawn upon their own national resources, for example by consulting with fisheries agencies and environmental ministries. Secondly, they have heard directly from intergovernmental organizations, such as the FAO. Thirdly, they have deliberated with stakeholders, ranging from industry organizations, other NGOs, other intergovernmental organizations, and other countries, within informal forums. These three modes of learning can be conceptualized as models that focus on learning and information exchange by: (1) state actors; (2) actors working within the international institutional framework, including secretariat staff; and (3) stakeholders affected by the rules. These three models, while at first glance apparently simplistic, follow common theoretical assumptions about the role of states within international law. The purpose of the models is therefore not to analyse the strategy of the negotiators,Footnote 92 but to assess differing conceptions of regime interaction. These conceptions have major implications for international law's fragmentation and for the practical and effective operation of the resulting disciplines on fisheries subsidies.
Self-contained regimes and national policy coordination
The first model conceives of learning as driven by state actors within the international system. Such actors, in the context of the Doha Round, include customs territories that have WTO membership. According to this model, the trade delegations in the Rules Group seek to ascertain and represent the consolidated views of their respective states in crafting fisheries subsidies disciplines. Such views will, to varying degrees, include the perspectives of domestic stakeholders who will be affected by the trade rules, although this is a matter for individual WTO members.Footnote 93
In the context of international law's fragmentation, the question arises as to how this model caters for global policy issues that involve several overlapping regimes. The immediate response is to emphasize the national policy coordination between domestic rule-making sectors. Trade ministries must coordinate with fisheries ministries, environmental ministries and other relevant departments in ways that are specific to the vagaries of each policy problem and the different structures and constitutions (federalist, unitary, etc) of each domestic legal system. Depending on whether the particular WTO member is a member of other intergovernmental organizations, such domestic national coordination may also draw on information and experience in other regimes. For example, some Rules Group participants have shown initiative in reporting on their relevant experience in other organizations. This information has influenced proposals, written and oral replies, and even negotiation strategy.Footnote 94
This conception is apparently consistent with the findings of the ILC Study Group, in that it focuses on the need for the consent of the primary actors of international law, namely states, in resolving issues of fragmentation. It also resonates with traditional accounts of ‘state sovereignty’ in international law that emphasize the state as the supreme authority, and claim that, although states are bound by the general system of international law, they are not subject to specific international laws except by their consent.Footnote 95 This perspective is often heard in the trade regime through the mantra that the WTO is a ‘member-driven organization’.
There are extreme versions of the attempt by states to monopolize the influences of particular regimes. For example, the Doha negotiations on the relationship between WTO rules and specific trade obligations in certain multilateral environment agreements (MEAs) are expressly limited to WTO members that are already parties to the relevant MEAs.Footnote 96 As such, WTO members have agreed to negotiate on the boundaries between trade and other regimes, but only for situations where WTO members have already consented to the other regimes (‘parallel membership’). In consequence, there is an express refusal to consider regime interaction that occurs in situations where there is not uniform membership between the WTO and other regimes. This perspective is echoed in some WTO cases, such as the Biotech panel's restrictive mode of treaty-interpretation.Footnote 97
These extreme attitudes lead to the view that the WTO operates as a ‘self-contained regime’.Footnote 98 This view is logically unsustainable, however, when one considers that international regimes ‘are always situated in a systemic environment’.Footnote 99 Moreover, the view is inconsistent with WTO jurisprudence that trade law should not be read ‘in clinical isolation from public international law’.Footnote 100 Practically, too, the extreme ideal of parallel membership is bound to fail. There is no parallel membership between the WTO and any of the relevant intergovernmental organizations dealing with fisheries.Footnote 101 For example, Singapore, Brunei Darussalam, and the member custom territories are not members of the FAO (and conversely there are several FAO members that are not WTO members). In addition, organizations such as the OECD have exclusive membership and are closed to many WTO members.
In addition to flaws in the notion of parallel membership for regime interaction, a sole reliance on national policy coordination for effective international fisheries governance is insufficient. There are major deficiencies in domestic policy coordination in the fisheries context.Footnote 102 Perhaps because of the relative unimportance of fisheries issues on some national policy agendas, there are failures in coordinating national information and positions, leading to diverging state positions within different international regimes. Moreover, there is a practical need in the fisheries context for information and expertise on global, as well as intra-state, behaviour. Given that failures in achieving fisheries sustainability often occur because of insufficient restraint by a multitude of states, an overarching perspective on fisheries is needed, rather than a reliance on individual accounts from WTO members themselves. Such a perspective exists in the context of rules and data developed in other international regimes, including within organizations like the FAO. The next sub-section thus considers how representative organizations interact for inter-regime learning.
Interaction by intergovernmental organizations
A second model of information sharing acknowledges the role of international organizations in inter-regime learning to assist in the crafting of rules on fisheries subsidies. Such coordination between international organizations has long been regarded as essential in combating problems of legal fragmentation.Footnote 103 Links between organizations may also counter alleged biases or ‘insensitivities’ against ecological issues within the trade regime.Footnote 104
WTO members have endorsed this model of institutional interaction in certain contexts. WTO members, meeting through the General Council, are responsible for making ‘appropriate arrangements’ for effective cooperation and consultation with intergovernmental organizations and NGOs.Footnote 105 The General Council has entered into several cooperative agreementsFootnote 106 and has allowed certain organizations to observe some proceedings of WTO committees. Observership is to be considered by the respective WTO committee on a case-by-case basis, taking account of factors such as the nature of the work of the organization, its membership (including the number of WTO members who are members of the other organization), and reciprocity of access.Footnote 107 The General Council has also established guidelines for cooperation with NGOs.Footnote 108
In the Committee on Trade and Environment, where fisheries subsidies were first discussed, a number of international organizations, whose membership and objectives vary from the WTO,Footnote 109 have rights to observe proceedings. Organizations such as the FAO have directly reported on fisheries issues. Indeed, commentators have considered that the attendance by FAO representatives at CTE meetings influenced states' commitment to fisheries subsidies reform.Footnote 110
At the beginning of the Rules Group negotiations, the need for participants to learn from relevant intergovernmental organizations and NGOs was identified. The United States, for example, urged the Rules Group to ‘explore ways to draw upon information from other organizations’, including the FAO, RFMOs, and non-governmental groups and individuals.Footnote 111 The Chair of the Rules Group engaged in informal consultations on whether to extend observership to external participants.Footnote 112 However, proposals to ‘enrich’ the Rules Group in this way were met with criticisms from some members.Footnote 113 Perhaps the political contentiousness of the Rules Group negotiating agenda, which ranges from fisheries subsidies to more general subsidies and anti-dumping reform, led to a perception of possible ‘capture’ by special interests among the protectionist industries affected by anti-dumping reform.Footnote 114 The question of observers disappeared from the Rules Group agenda in early 2005, and the status quo of closed access remained.
The Rules Group's formal procedures for participation and observership can be contrasted to professed optimism by the WTO Secretariat about working with other intergovernmental organizations in the framing of the fisheries subsidies rules. Director-General Lamy, for example, claims that cooperation between the WTO and other organizations ‘depends very largely on goodwill and a common sense of problem solving rather than strict mandates’.Footnote 115 Given the restrictions on formal interaction between the Rules Group, intergovernmental organizations, and NGOs, it would seem that inter-regime learning must occur in alternative, informal settings. The next section considers a third model of information sharing where knowledge production about subsidies and sustainability allows stakeholders, including WTO members, to deliberate upon fisheries subsidies issues outside of the institutional strictures of the Rules Group.
Deliberation by affected actors
Learning and information sharing across regimes may occur outside of the formal structures established by WTO members, and instead through open deliberation by a range of actors who will be affected by the rules. These ‘stakeholders’ include environmental NGOs, fishing organizations and epistemic communities of experts, as well as states and intergovernmental organizations. Many of these groups and networks do not have the ‘representative’ functions of states in international law.Footnote 116
In contrast to formal restrictions within the Rules Group, there are several examples in the fisheries subsidies negotiations of intergovernmental organizations and NGOs promoting deliberation through informal institutional linkages, reporting, and information sharing. The WTO Secretariat has led some of these initiatives. For example, the WTO Secretariat has organized special symposia as part of the quest for synergies between trade and environment,Footnote 117 and has conducted regional seminars for members with the participation of international organizations.Footnote 118 Officials from the WTO have attended FAO expert consultations and meetings.Footnote 119 The WTO Secretariat has issued reports on the activities of intergovernmental organizations and NGOs, mainly in servicing the CTE discussions,Footnote 120 but also for the Rules Group.Footnote 121 There is also coordination between the CTE and the Rules Group.Footnote 122 More recently, representatives from the FAO secretariat have attended Rules Group negotiations in an informal capacity.Footnote 123
The WTO Secretariat website facilitates this deliberation to some degree.Footnote 124 Most importantly, the website disseminates the results of the Rules Group negotiations. Thus, although the Rules Group is formally closed, there is scope for external participants to access its decision making because country submissions are mostly posted online.Footnote 125 Secretariat summaries of Rules Group meetings are also made public, although they are usually limited in detail and there is sometimes a delay of several months between meeting and publication. Reporting by other organizations suggests, however, that the Secretariat responds to requests for general information and briefings.Footnote 126 In addition, the website includes a portal for non-state submissions, which are accessible for members as well as the general public, although the papers are not systematically catalogued.Footnote 127
Outside of the WTO, other opportunities for informal information sharing and learning have emerged. Organizations such as UNEP,Footnote 128 WWF,Footnote 129 and ICSTDFootnote 130 have offered a series of workshops.Footnote 131 Stakeholders from national governments (including officials from environment, trade, and fisheries agencies), intergovernmental organizations, RFMOs, NGOs, and academic institutions have participated. Such consultations are often timed to coincide with closed sessions of the Rules Group.Footnote 132
Rather than striving for consensus, the workshops have encouraged open experimentation and learning. In addition to information about subsidy effects and fisheries issues, the workshops have provided information on the laws and standards that operate within other international regimes.Footnote 133 For example, participants have discussed the relative breadth of acceptance of particular norms, such as the near universal application of the FAO Code of Conduct as compared to the very limited enforcement of the FAO IPOA-Capacity. This has allowed WTO members to learn about and interrogate intergovernmental organizations and standards that may be relevant to the proposed disciplines. Written conclusions from the workshops, which tend to demonstrate plurality of perspectives rather than agreement, are distributed directly to Rules Group participants by certain WTO membersFootnote 134 and are publicly disseminated via the UNEP and WWF websites.
The influence of informal deliberation by stakeholders in the fisheries subsidies negotiations is difficult to prove empirically. According to interviews with trade delegates, WTO secretariat staff, and FAO representatives, the informal consultations have been regarded as extremely useful opportunities for learning about fisheries subsidies issues.Footnote 135 In addition, an analysis of the written Rules Group submissions reveals a strong influence. Some of the proposals have closely followed the positions of external stakeholders, such as the WWF.Footnote 136 This is reflected in comments by the WTO Secretariat itself, which acknowledge that NGOs can influence the negotiating positions of Rules Group participants.Footnote 137 Indeed, the Director-General has attributed the inclusion of fisheries subsidies in the Doha agenda to the influence of civil society.Footnote 138
The activities described above suggest that a community of stakeholders has addressed fisheries subsidies issues at the WTO notwithstanding that they have been denied formal rights to participate and observe negotiations in the Rules Group. Interdisciplinary workshops and informal links between secretariats and other groups are spatially and temporally linked to the Rules Group negotiations and have had a material influence on proposals. The remainder of this section examines the proposed text of the subsidy disciplines and speculates upon the influence of stakeholder deliberation on the ongoing implementation of the rules, and in particular on the proposed collaboration between the WTO and other organizations. Section 3 then examines the normative and institutional impact of stakeholder deliberation on WTO rule making in the theoretical context of a fragmented legal order.
Inter-regime links in the proposed rules: three examples
The proposed WTO rules, as currently contained in the Chair's text,Footnote 139 incorporate norms from other regimes and entrench collaborative procedures in three main areas: (1) the classification of subsidies; (2) the benchmarks for fisheries management to which WTO members must adhere; and (3) the settlement of subsidy disputes. This is not the first time that WTO members have crafted rules that require ongoing interaction or collaboration with non-WTO regimes, and this subsection examines the proposals for fisheries subsidy disciplines in the context of practice resulting from other parts of the SCM Agreement and the SBS and TBT Agreements.
Classifying ‘good’ and ‘bad’ subsidies through fisheries standards
The Chair's text contains a list of negotiated prohibited subsidies (‘red box’) as well as exempted subsidies (‘green box’). The provisions utilize existing fisheries data, norms, and institutions in a variety of ways to classify fisheries subsidies.
One method is to expressly adopt an FAO standard. The proposed red box includes a prohibition on ‘subsidies the benefits of which are conferred on any vessel engaged in illegal, unreported or unregulated fishing’.Footnote 140 The provision directly incorporates the definition of IUU fishing from the FAO's international plan of action.Footnote 141 According to this definition, illegal fishing includes fishing by vessels flying the flag of states that are parties to a relevant RFMO, but that ‘operate in contravention of the conservation and management measures adopted by [the RFMO] and by which the states are bound, or relevant provisions of the applicable international law’. As a consequence, the implementation of the WTO subsidy rules depends upon an assessment of WTO members' compliance with relevant rules of an RFMO or other applicable international law.
WTO lawyers will be familiar with this form of express reference to other regimes in the classification of WTO-consistent behaviour. For example, the SPS and TBT Agreement rely on international standard-setting bodies to determine whether WTO members can be exempt from disciplines because their trade measures are ‘necessary’ for a legitimate domestic objective. According to the SPS Agreement, WTO members' measures are presumed to be ‘necessary’ if they conform to international standards promulgated by listed groups, such as the Codex Alimentarius Commission, or are preceded by proven scientific risk assessments.Footnote 142 According to the TBT Agreement, members' measures are presumed to be exempt from disciplines if they are ‘in accordance’ with international standards set by an open list of international standard-setting bodies.Footnote 143
The reference to international standards in the TBT and SPS Agreements has led to a number of criticisms. The standards may have a determinative role in WTO disputes, even if they were not intended to be binding in forums such as Codex.Footnote 144 This problem is exacerbated if a standard has been agreed without consensus between relevant participants in the standard-setting process.Footnote 145 As such, a WTO member may be required to be in conformity with a particular standard, even if it voted against the adoption of the standard in the relevant forum and even if the standard is not binding in that forum.Footnote 146
By contrast, an alternative method of subsidy classification has been proposed by the EC, possibly because as a respondent in much of the relevant case law it is particularly sensitive to the potential application of standards from other international regimes. Suspicious of referring expressly to the law of the sea and FAO regimes in the proposed subsidy disciplines, it has proposed a catch-all prohibition which would prohibit subsidies where the benefits ‘are conferred on any fishing vessel or fishing activity affecting fish stocks that are in an unequivocally overfished condition’.Footnote 147 The italicized phrase does not refer to any other international regimes. Yet this form has been heavily criticized by other WTO members, who have expressed concern that the ‘unequivocally overfished’ condition is too vague and obscure, and leaves an adjudicating body with too little guidance and too much discretion in interpreting the term.Footnote 148
A third method of standard setting appears in the proposed ‘green box’ exemptions, which refer to international fisheries management regimes, systems, and programs. The Chair's text exempts a range of subsidies, including those used for: (1) compliance with ‘fisheries management regimes aimed at sustainable use and conservation’;Footnote 149 (2) vessel decommissioning or capacity reduction programmes provided that fisheries management systems are in place;Footnote 150 and (3) ‘special and differential treatment’ provisions for developing countries.Footnote 151
The special and differential treatment builds on earlier proposals that sought to rely on non-WTO regimes to ensure that exempted subsidies maintained standards of sustainability. For example, Brazil initially proposed to allow developing countries that were part of an RFMO to grant capacity-enhancing subsidies, as long as the developing country's fishing capacity did not exceed the sustainable level of exploitation as defined by the particular RFMO.Footnote 152 Argentina initially proposed that developing countries wishing to qualify for special and differential treatment should implement national fisheries management systems ‘in keeping’ with the FAO Code of Conduct.Footnote 153 The European Union, on the other hand, sought to contain the issue of sustainable special and differential treatment entirely within the WTO. It proposed that developing countries be exempted from subsidy disciplines as long as their fishing capacity did not increase to an extent that it presented an ‘impediment to the sustainable exploitation of fishery resources worldwide’.Footnote 154
Instead, the Chair's text provides that developing countries may subsidize vessel construction, but only if the vessels are used within the member's relevant EEZ, if the fish stocks within that EEZ have been scientifically assessed ‘in accordance with relevant international standards’, and if the stock assessment has been subject to peer review by the FAO.Footnote 155 In addition, international organizations such as the FAO are to provide technical assistance to developing countries.Footnote 156 The final overarching safeguard to ensure that special and differential treatment and other exempted subsidies do not lead to overfishing is contained in the condition that any member seeking an exemption ‘shall operate a fisheries management system … designed to prevent overfishing’.Footnote 157
The conditionality regarding management systems is more fully described in the next subsection, but there are two remaining points to note about the proposed use of standards. The Chair's text does not endorse all standards of fisheries regimes. For example, the Chair's text rejects the major jurisdictional concept of these regimes: by attributing subsidies to members regardless of vessel flags or the application of rules of origin to the fish involved,Footnote 158 the text purposively avoids enduring problems of ‘flag’ jurisdiction in the law of the sea, as well as difficulties in assessing the origin of fish products.Footnote 159 This decision may well have been made after trade delegates learned from the experiences of fisheries delegates, international organizations, and NGOs, as described according to the third model of learning outlined above.Footnote 160 The other point to note is that the use of fisheries standards brings a different rationale to the WTO subsidies disciplines, which have been critiqued as economically irrational and incoherent.Footnote 161 The proposed approach focuses disciplines on subsidies that are harmful to the achievement of agreed global goods (albeit that such agreement occurs in non-WTO forums).
Conditionality through benchmarking and peer review
To safeguard fisheries sustainability, the Chair's text proposes an overarching condition that all WTO members seeking exemptions for their subsidy practices operate a particular kind of fisheries management system.Footnote 162 These management systems are to be based on ‘internationally-recognized best practices for fisheries management and conservation’ and are to include regular science-based stock assessments and capacity and management measures. Such best practices are said to be reflected in a non-exhaustive list of five international instruments: (1) the Fish Stocks Agreement; (2) the Code of Conduct; (3) the Compliance Agreement; (4) technical guidelines; and (5) plans of action.Footnote 163 Accordingly, instruments developed within the law of the sea and the FAO regime will have a contingent role in the WTO subsidies regime.
This group of five fisheries instruments is relevant to other proposed exemptions and in the assessment of actionable subsidies. Subsidies relating to the procurement of access rights to foreign fisheries in developing country WTO members are not prohibited provided that the terms of access include provisions designed to prevent overfishing ‘based on internationally-recognized best practices … as reflected in’ this group of five fisheries instruments.Footnote 164 The ‘amber-box’ test for actionable subsidies, which may be subject to member complaints based on their adverse effects,Footnote 165 also refers to the group of five fisheries instruments as relevant evidence. Information about the subsidizing member's implementation of ‘internationally-recognized best practices for fisheries management and conservation’ will assist in establishing whether a member is causing, through the use of a subsidy, depletion of straddling or migratory fish stocks or stocks in which another WTO member has identifiable fishing interests.
One of the difficulties of using these five instruments as benchmarks is the potential for WTO members to adopt management systems on paper without adequately implementing or enforcing them. To address this, the Chair's text requires members to ‘adopt and implement’ domestic legislation and judicial enforcement mechanisms with full transparency. Information about these and other aspects of the fisheries management system is to be made publicly accessible and subject to peer review.
Review of WTO members' fisheries management systems takes place in three ways. First, members are to notify the existence and operation of their fisheries management systems, including the results of stock assessments, to the FAO.Footnote 166 The FAO will determine the specific information it requires and then subject the management system to peer review before the subsidy is granted. The Chair's text recognizes that not all WTO members are members of the FAO. In that event, it provides that the relevant WTO member's fisheries management information shall be notified to ‘another relevant international organization’.Footnote 167 Secondly, information about the fisheries management system, including the outcome of the FAO peer review, is to be notified to the SCM Committee,Footnote 168 an internal committee made up of member representatives that currently reviews subsidy notifications.Footnote 169 Thirdly, WTO members are to maintain a domestic ‘enquiry point’, to which WTO members and other interested parties may direct their scientific or trade questions.Footnote 170
The role of the FAO as a peer reviewer of relevant aspects of WTO members' fisheries management systems appears to be a useful harnessing of the FAO's expertise, particularly on stock assessments. There is some evidence that the FAO was involved in the inclusion of this role in the Chair's text,Footnote 171 suggesting that the regime interaction in the framing of the rules had a substantive effect on the development of ongoing interaction in the rules' implementation. However, some WTO members have expressed suspicion about the proposed collaboration between the WTO and other regimes. Taiwan, which is not a member of the UN, apparently objects to the involvement of an international organization to which not all WTO members belong. Norway, supported by some developing country members, would delete the peer review function and require simple notifications to the FAO or other relevant organizations.Footnote 172 Other WTO members have noted their ‘systemic concerns’ with another intergovernmental organization ‘passing judgment’ on the adequacy of WTO members' management systems.Footnote 173
In response to these concerns, the Chair of the Rules Group has emphasized the continuing role of the SCM Committee in maintaining a dialogue with the FAO, and proposed that the peer review process be considered as similar to the existing Trade Policy Review Mechanism (TPRM).Footnote 174 The Chair's emphasis on the continuing role of the SCM Committee in maintaining an inter-regime dialogue can be compared to a set of existing and potential arrangements with another rather controversial intergovernmental organization: the OECD.
The OECD has a special role in the granting of existing exemptions for export subsidies that are otherwise prohibited. The SCM Agreement exempts export subsidies for certain export credit practices, if they are in conformity with provisions of a certain undertaking or ‘successor undertaking’ on official export credits.Footnote 175 The infamous Annex I(k) provision refers to an arrangement concluded in the OECD in 1978 and revised most recently in 2008.Footnote 176 The arrangement is self-defined as a ‘Gentlemen's Agreement among the Participants’.Footnote 177 Current participants are Australia, Canada, the EC, Japan, Korea, New Zealand, Norway, Switzerland, and the United States. Other OECD members and non-members may be invited to become participants by the current participants.Footnote 178
The term ‘successor undertaking’ allows the participants of the OECD Export Credit Arrangement to continually update the terms of the exemption as it applies to themselves and to the rest of the WTO membership. In the face of a challenge that it was unreasonable for a subgroup of WTO members to ‘perpetually legislate on behalf of the overwhelming majority of the membership’ in this way,Footnote 179 a WTO panel has considered that such a delegation is justifiable in order to share necessary expertise.Footnote 180 The Panel noted, however, that if the participants to the OECD Export Credit Arrangement ‘were to abuse their power to modify the scope of the safe haven, the recourse of other WTO members would be to renegotiate’ the relevant provision of the SCM Agreement.Footnote 181
Indeed, the Rules Group has since examined the operation of the exemption for official export credit practices, as part of its mandate for general subsidies reform.Footnote 182 The Chair's text contains a proposal that the undertaking be notified to the SCM Committee.Footnote 183 It further stipulates that the SCM Committee shall examine the notified undertaking on the request of a WTO member. This role will add to existing institutional arrangements, whereby the WTO Secretariat has observer status in the OECD export credit group, the OECD Secretariat has observer status within the SCM Committee, and panels may seek information during disputes.Footnote 184
The existing and proposed collaborative practices of the WTO and OECD secretariats change the position of the OECD Export Credit Arrangement as a benchmark of conduct in the SCM Agreement. These practices require a level of transparency and openness in the OECD procedures to frame and update the benchmark, as scrutinized by SCM Committee. A similar development has occurred in the context of the TBT and SPS Agreements, probably as a response to the perceived problems in the interpretation of standards by adjudicating bodies.Footnote 185 The TBT Committee, for example, has encouraged standard-setting bodies to operate with open, impartial, and transparent procedures.Footnote 186 The SPS Committee has adopted a peer review role of member activities,Footnote 187 while the WTO Secretariat, seeking to address deficiencies in compliance with SPS notification obligations, has conducted workshops on transparency and created an on-line searchable database.Footnote 188
These procedures emphasize transparency, accessibility and ongoing scrutiny of norms and benchmarks from international regimes, and are suggestive of emerging factors for WTO members to ensure appropriate regime interaction, a theme developed in Section 3. Such factors are important not only in the fishery subsidies negotiations and resulting disciplines, but also for the proposed regime interaction in the settlement of subsidies disputes.
Settling disputes through consultation
The third area of entrenched and ongoing links between the WTO and other international organizations is in proposals for the settlement of disputes about fisheries subsidies. The Chair's text adopts two procedures for dispute settlement. For disputes about prohibited subsidies, panels are constituted according to the current procedure of the SCM Agreement.Footnote 189 For other disputes, panels are constituted according to the DSU.Footnote 190 In both cases, if the dispute raises ‘scientific or technical questions related to fisheries’, the panel must seek advice from ‘fisheries experts’.Footnote 191 These experts are to be chosen by the panel in consultation with the disputing parties. The panel also has discretion to consult with international organizations.Footnote 192
The provision for panel consultations with experts and international organizations is virtually identical to the dispute settlement provision adopted by the SPS Agreement,Footnote 193 which was drafted after substantial disagreement between negotiators. The Cairns group of agriculture-producing WTO members wished to ensure that any consultation was in a personal capacity, because it wanted to minimize the role of international standardizing bodies in dispute settlement.Footnote 194 Subsequent application of the SPS Agreement reveals that there is some uncertainty about whether international organizations should be consulted only on the specific selection of expertsFootnote 195 or on a wider set of issues.Footnote 196
One of the ways that SPS negotiators sought to balance the role of international standards was to remind WTO members of their unimpaired rights to resort to the good offices or dispute settlement mechanisms of these international agreements.Footnote 197 Such a reminder is reproduced in the Chair's text,Footnote 198 a provision that sits rather uneasily with the SCM Agreement's stipulation that no other specific action can be taken against a subsidy of another member.Footnote 199
WTO members could have gone much further in designing inter-regime enforcement. An early proposal from the WWF, for example, promoted much closer interaction between a WTO dispute settlement panel and international organizations.Footnote 200 The WWF proposed that a permanent group, comprised of experts from the FAO, UNEP, RFMOs, and NGOs, would sit at the WTO and would have the authority to make binding rulings on matters outside of the traditional competence of the WTO.Footnote 201 This proposal reflects other suggestions for shared adjudicative capacities made in the general trade and environmental context.Footnote 202
The WWF suggestion was not accepted by the Rules Group, but even current arrangements could promote authority sharing with other regimes to some extent. For example, if a panel adjudicating on an alleged prohibited subsidy is required to assess whether subsidies are benefiting fishing activity for stocks that are in an ‘unequivocally overfished condition’,Footnote 203 it could consult the existing Permanent Group of Experts (PGE) for a binding determination. The PGE has the discretion to draw on a wide range of sources for assistance;Footnote 204 depending on the PGE's initiative, this could include consultations between the PGE and international organizations, scientific experts, and NGOs. In addition, there are a number of other methods by which a WTO adjudicating body can seek information from other regimes in resolving fisheries subsidies disputes. This includes information from amicus briefs and from the submissions of the disputing parties themselves.
The institutional provision for panel consultation on fisheries issues is of course interrelated with the normative status of the fisheries regimes in the disciplines. For example, for a self-contained standard, such as the ‘equivocally overfished’ standard proposed by the EC, dispute settlement bodies retain full discretion to interact with other regimes. For standards that directly incorporate the norms of international organizations, such as the FAO international plan of action on IUU fishing, adjudication inevitably requires WTO adjudicating bodies to refer to those regimes. This gives further complexity to the regime interaction in the implementation of the disciplines and the adjudication of potential violations, as is explored in the next section.
3. Implications for the WTO and international law
Section 2 contrasted three models of information sharing and documented the influence of the third model, where deliberation by state and non-state actors influenced the fisheries subsidies negotiations. The section then described three proposed arrangements for collaboration with other regimes in the implementation of the rules: the classification of subsidies, the imposition of fisheries management conditionality, and the settlement of disputes. Comparisons with the SCM Agreement's provision on export credit practices and the TBT and SPS Agreements' reliance on external standards demonstrated the ongoing need for information sharing and inter-regime scrutiny. This section places these findings in theoretical context and discusses wider implications, both at the level of detail of the implementation and adjudication of the subsidy disciplines themselves, and more generally with respect to the fragmented international legal system.
Regime interaction as deliberation and scrutiny
The current responses to the Chair's text suggest that incorporating the law of the sea and FAO regimes into the fisheries subsidies disciplines will be as controversial as the WTO's previous adoption of norms and benchmarks from international standard-setting bodies and the OECD. This controversy resides, in part, on the concern by WTO members to retain full control over the rules, and the view that the legitimacy of the rules arises only if all WTO members have agreed to them.
As described in Section 2, the extreme form of these views imposes a prerequisite of parallel membership between interacting institutions, as demonstrated by Taiwan's rejection of the role of the FAO in the fisheries subsidies disciplines. It also leads to the view that the WTO should refrain from disciplining ecologically harmful fisheries subsidies because of its lack of expertise in assessing fisheries sustainability.Footnote 205 This extreme position, which has been manifest in other areas of WTO law, is impossible to maintain in both theoretical and practical terms.Footnote 206 Such disconnect between legal regimes does not exist in real-world problems, where economic decisions of subsidizing states have undeniable environmental effects.
In response, I suggest that WTO members' concerns can be addressed by procedures that ensure that, if fisheries regimes are accorded authority by WTO rules, ‘authority and contestability go hand in hand’.Footnote 207 Procedures that direct WTO members to scrutinize the rule making and operation of non-WTO regimes, or at least counteract current WTO structures that preclude such scrutiny, are of particular interest. There is growing evidence of the interest of WTO members in these procedures, both in the actual practice in the TBT and SPS CommitteesFootnote 208 and in the proposed roles for the SCM Committee (in generalFootnote 209 and in fisheries subsidies reform). For the fisheries subsidies disciplines, in particular, the SCM Committee will maintain surveillance over the FAO's peer review of WTO members' fisheries management practices.Footnote 210
These techniques suggest an emerging role for regime interaction by WTO bodies in the implementation of rules, and point to further scope for ongoing scrutiny. The SCM Committee may have a greater role, for example, in scrutinizing the operation of the fisheries organizations that are instituting the relevant fisheries ‘best practices’. The reference in the Chair's text to the Fish Stocks Agreement, the FAO Code of Conduct, and the Compliance Agreement is attractive not only because these instruments were developed in an accessible and transparent way, but also because they seek to promote substantive openness and transparency in fisheries management.Footnote 211 The Code of Conduct, for example, was developed in a spirit of collaboration and is subject to ongoing review,Footnote 212 and emphasizes the need for ongoing collaboration by stakeholders in the Code's implementation.Footnote 213 Less convincing, perhaps, are the references in the Chair's text to technical guidelines and plans of actions for the implementation of these instruments. The development of these standards is a rather more closed affair.
The Chair's text is currently silent on requiring instruments such as technical guidelines to be publicly accessible, transparent in their development, or inclusive in membership for all relevant WTO members. Such a requirement would be especially valuable, especially if indigenous management institutions are to replace international best practices in special and differential treatment, as has been proposed by some developing countries.Footnote 214 Although indigenous institutions are potentially useful in recognizing the special conditions of artisanal fisheries, they still require scrutiny to ensure that sustainability in fisheries is being maintained.
Similarly, the proposed use of the FAO definition for IUU fishing may be appropriate if the relevant RFMO conservation measures remain transparent and subject to ongoing scrutiny, and if the plan of action continues its current emphasis on participation, coordination, and non-discrimination.Footnote 215 The absence of a requirement for consensus in the adoption of the FAO plan of action does not eliminate its role; rather, such an absence might lead to a more in-depth scrutiny of its internal procedures by the SCM Committee or an adjudicating body. This has the added benefit of removing the risk of a vacuum of fisheries and conservation standards created due to the seemingly impossible aim of reaching consensus for their adoption.
It is tempting to conclude that the deliberation and scrutiny by the SCM Committee and adjudicating panels will ensure appropriate regime interaction between the WTO and the FAO and other fisheries bodies. However, one of the major findings of my analysis of the three models of negotiations in Section 2 was that inter-regime learning depended on an additional set of actors besides states and international organizations. This suggestion that regime scrutiny will be undertaken by a network of interested parties has implications for the notion of regimes and their participants, both for the WTO disciplines and for international law.
Revised conceptions of regimes and their participants
Regime interaction is not limited to official members of regimes, such as WTO members and the states that are members of the FAO (many, but not all, of whom are the same states).Footnote 216 Contestation of fisheries regimes by non-state actors has occurred in the negotiations to date, and the third model of inter-regime learning described in Section 2 referred to a range of deliberative forums spatially and temporally linked to the Rules Group that have influenced the Chair's text. Inter-regime contestation will also occur in the enforcement of the disciplines through consultative and amicus arrangements with WTO panels, notwithstanding the rejection by the Chair's text of novel proposals for authority-sharing arrangements between experts from a range of intergovernmental and non-state organizations.
An enhanced role for non-state actors in inter-regime scrutiny is absent from much of the literature responding to the need to link ‘non-trade’ interests with the WTO. One prescription, for example, suggests institutional reform of the WTO that includes the establishment of new ‘departments’ with different competencies, such as environment or competition.Footnote 217 While enhancing regime interaction, such reform assumes that all relevant interests are ascertainable and conveyed by WTO members.
By contrast, recent literature on governance within the European Union and other jurisdictions has given increased attention to the involvement in law making of actors without ‘representative’ functions, who are nonetheless ‘affected’ by policy areas.Footnote 218 The ‘new governance’ literature investigates how laws are made and shaped by practices and processes that fall outside traditional conceptions of regulation. The literature includes analysis of inclusive decision making by state and non-state parties and calls attention to ‘governing councils’ that collect and distribute experiences gathered within a variety of networks to promote mutual learning.Footnote 219 Such insights are increasingly applied to supranational and international law as well as international standard setting.Footnote 220 Similarly, the idea of ‘adaptive governance’ promotes attention to the learning and review functions of bodies such as the WTO.Footnote 221 Some even claim that such governance should be termed ‘post-sovereign’, because it is non-exclusive, non-hierarchical and post-territorial.Footnote 222
This theoretical framework is supported by various examples in the negotiation of WTO disciplines on fisheries subsidies. In the framing of the rules, UNEP and the WWF acted as ‘governing councils’ that shared crucial information and promoted learning to further democratic experimentalism. These workshops were open to all stakeholders and sought to provide forums for political debate. The deliberations were documented and forwarded to the Rules Group, and there was an apparent reliance by WTO members on the deliberations in the drafting of text. This was a kind of ‘public–civil society partnership’ influencing the development of WTO law,Footnote 223 and may suggest an inclusivity in WTO decision making for which there is significant demand.Footnote 224 The evidence also confirms UNEP's role in encouraging ‘mutual supportiveness’ of trade and environment policies.Footnote 225
Contestability, accountability, and stability
The conception of information sharing, inter-regime scrutiny, and experimentalism described here promotes deliberation by state and non-state actors that will be affected by the new rules. It also recognizes the need for expertise to be shared to enhance understanding of existing processes and to counter cultural and disciplinary differences and insensitivities of particular regimes. Such a conception accords with mainstream accounts of law making. It is more controversial, however, to apply this conception to the ongoing implementation of disciplines and the adjudication of disputes. Indeed, the emphasis in this article on the contestation of norms may seem counter-productive for a legal system.
Authority is usually given as a guarantee of order and the law's role is to provide stability and predictability. Yet my conclusions call for ongoing regime interaction and scrutiny by WTO members and non-state actors. Informed by existing arrangements between the WTO and organizations such as the OECD and product standard-setting bodies, I have pointed to potential sites of contestation within bodies such as the SCM Committee. I have suggested, for example, that internationally recognized best practices for fisheries management and conservation may be appropriate as benchmarks for the fisheries subsidies rules if they can be contested by such bodies. Moreover, the openness, transparency, and accountability of these processes are more important in ensuring legitimacy than attempts to ensure parallel membership or consensual institutional interaction by WTO members.
These processes are open-ended and have no obvious conclusions. Such uncertainty risks the stability guaranteed by law, and arguably exposes the fisheries subsidies disciplines to a case-by-case approach that is more vulnerable to the power relations within particular disputes. Indeed, in the domestic context, democratic experimentalism has been criticized as jeopardizing stabilizing democratic institutions, such as the rule of law.Footnote 226
The risk to stability posed by ongoing deliberation and scrutiny is real. In response, however, it is important not to analogize too closely the domestic and international legal contexts and the assumptions each make about authority. By contrast to domestic liberal democracies, the international system lacks overarching norms and is instead dominated by multiple and sometimes fragmented norms and institutions. As such, a departure from domestic constitutional ideals and towards open and accountable procedures of regime interaction may be justified. Close empirical engagement is required to understand and theorize such procedures; admittedly, the present study will be richer after the rules are agreed and the complex work by multiple actors has progressed. The premise, and hope, of this article is that the inter-regime scrutiny and contestation it describes represents a new and effective approach to global problems, such as fisheries depletion, that involve multiple legal regimes.
These findings also highlight the need for greater attention to the role, institutional support, and continued viability of participants in the making and implementation of international law across a number of regimes. For secretariat staff and other informal groupings of officials, there is a need for further analysis of their accountability and transparency.Footnote 227 Similarly, the role of experts in transnational governance requires extended analysis, in particular to forestall a ‘managerial’ approach to questions of fragmentation.Footnote 228 For example, if fisheries experts are to facilitate learning and the ongoing scrutiny of various legal responses to declining fish stocks, it is important that they maintain, at the very least, openness about the sources of their information and research methodologies. Similarly, although the standards of accountability for non-governmental organizations advocating for ecological preferences are different from the standards expected of states,Footnote 229 it is important that they are open about whom (or what) they seek to represent.Footnote 230 It is equally important to recognize the transitory nature of ‘crisis’ advocacy networks, and the risk that the groups that have coalesced around the issue of fisheries subsidies may well move on to address other sustainability goals after the completion of the negotiations.Footnote 231
Conclusion
The proliferation and fragmentation of rules and institutions in international law has given rise to a number of challenges for those seeking to address global problems, such as fisheries depletion. Much scholarly attention has been given to challenges relating to resolving conflicting norms,Footnote 232 but this article has instead focused on the challenges for international law making and implementation.
My analysis of WTO members' attempts to make and implement fisheries disciplines rejects rhetorical suggestions that interaction between the WTO and other legal regimes depends upon the express or implied consent of regime members. It instead confronts problems of fragmentation by promoting deliberation, information sharing, learning, the use of benchmarks and institutional interaction by a wider set of participants. Informed in part by existing arrangements between the WTO and the OECD and standard-setting bodies, it suggests that the legitimacy of the involvement of this wider set of participants, which includes intergovernmental organizations, NGOs, and fisheries advocacy groups that do not have representative functions, is based on the need for deliberation and on-going inter-regime scrutiny. In this vein, I have shown that the Chair's text containing proposed fisheries subsidies disciplines has been influenced by a ‘governing council’ that included a wider number of participants than just WTO members.
These findings recast current attempts to understand legal fragmentation and may even contain the potential to pre-empt further fragmentation. First, the coordination between international regimes cannot rest solely on the initiatives of states, notwithstanding innovative attempts at domestic policy coordination. Secondly, historic attention on the coordination between international organizations demands reinvigoration,Footnote 233 especially to confront legal questions about their implied powers.Footnote 234 Thirdly, the participants of regime interaction must include stakeholders, such as non-state advocacy groups and epistemic communities, to provide much-needed deliberative engagement. This suggests a different legal framework than the ‘traditional, State-centric international law’ considered by the International Law Commission in its seminal study.Footnote 235
Historically, international lawyers responded to potential situations of legal fragmentation by proposing wide-ranging consultations before the drafting of new instruments. They urged state representatives to ‘form the habit of regarding proposed new instruments from the standpoint of their effect on the international statute book as a whole’.Footnote 236 This article has similarly endorsed inter-regime consultation and coordination, but it has gone further. The fisheries subsidies negotiations show that it is not sufficient for trade delegates to have regard to other international regimes. Instead, a wide range of participants must learn, scrutinize and contest norms and standards relating to fisheries management in an ongoing process of regime interaction. Whether this process is conceived as legal wrangling between regimes, or as political contestation about the definitions of regimes themselves,Footnote 237 this article suggests a need for a greater awareness of how knowledge is produced and by whom, and how legal oversight will continue and by whom, in crucial issues of fisheries governance and beyond.