Hostname: page-component-66644f4456-q629f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-13T10:39:39.167Z Has data issue: true hasContentIssue false

Congress and Community: Coresidence and Social Influence in the U.S. House of Representatives, 1801–1861

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 July 2021

WILLIAM MINOZZI*
Affiliation:
The Ohio State University, United States
GREGORY A. CALDEIRA*
Affiliation:
The Ohio State University, United States
*
William Minozzi, Associate Professor, Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University, United States, minozzi.1@osu.edu.
Gregory A. Caldeira, Distinguished University Professor, Dreher Chair in Political Communication and Policy Thinking, Professor of Law, Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University, United States, caldeira.1@osu.edu.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Legislators often rely on cues from colleagues to inform their actions. Several studies identify the boardinghouse effect, cue-taking among U.S. legislators who lived together in the nineteenth century. Nevertheless, there remains reason for skepticism, as legislators likely selected residences for reasons including political similarity. We analyze U.S. House members’ residences from 1801 to 1861, decades more than previously studied, and show not only that legislators tended to live with similar colleagues but also that coresidents with divergent politics were more likely to move apart. Therefore, we deploy improved identification strategies. First, using weighting, we estimate that coresidence increased voting agreement, but at only half of previously reported levels. Consistent with theoretical expectations, we find larger effects for weaker ties and those involving new members. Second, we study legislators who died in office, estimating that deaths increased ideological distance between survivors and deceased coresidents.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

Legislatures are clearly social places. Members not only collaborate purposively—on legislation (Fowler Reference Fowler2006; Kirkland Reference Kirkland2011), in committees (Ringe, Victor, and Gross Reference Ringe, Victor and Gross2013), through caucuses (Ringe, Victor, and Carman Reference Ringe, Victor and Carman2013)—but they also socialize informally, dining together (Steinhauer Reference Steinhauer2013), playing golf together (Booker Reference Booker2015), even living together (Bash Reference Bash2013). Elite socializing has deep roots in American political development and consequences for today’s politics. Young’s (Reference Young1966) classic The Washington Community identifies the social fabric created by shared residences as foundational in the early Republic. And contemporary critics partially attribute elite polarization to declines in informal socialization (Mann and Ornstein Reference Mann and Ornstein2006, 232).

Social ties can affect legislative behavior incidentally, for example via cues about roll-call votes passed between legislators who are merely physically proximate (Liu and Srivistava Reference Liu and Srivastava2015; Masket Reference Masket2008). In fact, Young (Reference Young1966) bases his claims about the importance of shared residences on high levels of voting agreement among coresidents, a phenomenon known as the “boardinghouse effect” (Bogue and Marlaire Reference Bogue and Marlaire1975; Kirkland and Gross Reference Kirkland and Gross2014; Parigi and Bergemann Reference Parigi and Bergemann2016). The implications of this research echo critics who link elite polarization to declines in socializing. For example, Parigi and Bergemann (Reference Parigi and Bergemann2016) conclude that “a possible cause of the current political polarization among political elites in Washington [is] the lack of time congressmen spend together informally” (527).

Yet, there remains reason for skepticism. The boardinghouse effect is a social influence process: one legislator’s actions change another’s. Opportunities for influence depend on existing relationships, which in turn depend on latent tendencies, including how members typically vote. Homophily—the propensity for people with similar traits to form ties (McPherson, Smith-Lovin, and Cook Reference McPherson, Smith-Lovin and Cook2001)—complicates efforts to infer influence from behavioral similarity (Fowler et al. Reference Fowler, Heaney, Nickerson, Padgett and Sinclair2011). Indeed, many boardinghouses developed regional, partisan, and ideological reputations. Existing studies attempt to address this issue using fixed effects or focusing explicitly on legislators who move midterm (Parigi and Bergemann Reference Parigi and Bergemann2016). But such designs are vulnerable to dynamic interrelationships between cause and effect (Imai and Kim Reference Imai and Kim2019), such as when legislators form or dissolve ties for political reasons (Noel and Nyhan Reference Noel and Nyhan2011).

More compelling research designs focus on moments of genuine randomization, though these are rare. Vexingly, such studies yield varying results, and none have focused on the boardinghouse effect. For example, Rogowski and Sinclair (Reference Rogowski and Sinclair2012) exploit the House’s randomized office lottery to identify the effects of office proximity on voting agreement; they find null effects. Likewise, Coppock (Reference Coppock2016) detects little evidence of spillovers among ideologically similar pairs. In contrast, Zelizer (Reference Zelizer2019) finds that state legislators responded to a randomized treatment that was exposed only to their officemates. As always, there are trade-offs for strong identification strategies, including conceptual slippage. Even though office proximity and ideological similarity increase the potential for cues, they may generate fewer opportunities for influence than living, dining, and socializing together.

We therefore return to the setting Young (Reference Young1966) made famous, the boardinghouses of early Washington. First, we argue that cue-taking due to socializing will be primarily incidental, and thus more likely with sustained contact and few competing sources of influence. Consistent with the “strength of weak ties” (Granovetter Reference Granovetter1973), legislators who have not lived together previously should be more likely to influence each other, especially when they share easily audited information. Further, new members may purposively select into residences with the intent of being influenced, essentially “choosing to be changed” (Santoro Reference Santoro2017), so influence should be larger for ties including newcomers.

We marshal evidence to probe these claims using a variety of methods. First, we use qualitative evidence from the historical record and secondary literature to argue that these conditions were satisfied in the decades before the Civil War. Living together during this period involved sustained contact and few competing sources of influence.

Next, we analyze the universe of extant evidence on congressional residences from 1801 to 1861, decades more evidence than in previous studies. We report strong evidence of political homophily in residence selection, a finding that is expected, yet surprisingly missing from the literature. Furthermore, we show that coresidents were more likely to move apart when their voting patterns diverged, an example of the “unfriending” problem that complicates inference about influence (Noel and Nyhan Reference Noel and Nyhan2011). These findings cast doubt on previous attempts to measure the boardinghouse effect.

In light of this evidence, we take multiple quantitative approaches to measure influence. First, we analyze longitudinal data on coresidence using inverse probability weighting. Conditional on identifying assumptions, we show that coresidence increased voting agreement but at rates below previous estimates. We also find evidence for hypotheses consistent with both “the strength of weak ties” and “choosing to be changed.” These findings illuminate the role of informal socialization in American political development. Effects peak in the late 1820s and early 1830s, before the consolidation of the second party system. Intriguingly, we find that informal socializing—in terms of social influence and boardinghouse culture itself—declined to its nadir coincident with the rising elite polarization of the 1850s and the advent of the Civil War.

Finally, to burnish our causal claims, we present what is, to our knowledge, the strongest identification strategy yet deployed to study the boardinghouse effect. We study legislators who died in office, identifying the effects of deaths on survivors’ behavior, and find that survivors drifted away from their deceased colleagues in ideological space. Taken together, our results strengthen the case that declines in informal socialization exacerbate elite polarization.

Social Influence and Legislative Behavior

Legislators have a difficult job. They deal with uncertainty and limited resources, yet participate in hundreds or thousands of votes per term. One coping strategy is to rely on cues (Kingdon Reference Kingdon1973; Matthews and Stimson Reference Matthews and Stimson1975). Cue-takingFootnote 1 is a diffusion process that subsumes an array of mechanisms, such as imitation, coercion, and learning (Lindstädt, Vander Wielen, and Green Reference Lindstädt, Wielen and Green2016). Cues may be purposively disseminated by parties (Hershberger, Minozzi, and Volden Reference Hershberger, Minozzi and Volden2018; Minozzi and Volden Reference Minozzi and Volden2013), interest groups (Box-Steffensmeier, Christenson, and Craig Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Christenson and Craig2019), senior colleagues (Box-Steffensmeier, Ryan, and Sokhey Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Ryan and Sokhey2015), member organizations (Ringe, Victor, and Carman Reference Ringe, Victor and Carman2013), or peers (Zelizer Reference Zelizer2019).

Cues may also be passed informally between legislators who socialize together. Such cue-taking is more likely to be incidental than purposive. Elites share many behaviors with members of the mass public (e.g., Sheffer et al. Reference Sheffer, Loewen, Suroka, Walgrave and Sheafer2018), among whom informal political discussion is often an incidental byproduct of opportunity (Minozzi et al. Reference Minozzi, Song, David, Neblo and Ognyanova2020). Contact provides opportunity for cues via informal discussion—even among elites. Indeed, physical proximity fosters social ties among legislators (Caldeira and Patterson Reference Caldeira and Patterson1987), and there is evidence of cue-taking between legislators who are merely proximate. Masket (Reference Masket2008) shows that California state legislators who were desk mates agreed on more votes, and Liu and Srivastava (Reference Liu and Srivastava2015) find that copartisan U.S. senators with proximate desks were more ideologically similar. Thus, informal, incidental cue-taking should be more likely given sustained contact.

Contact alone is not sufficient for proximity-based cue-taking, however. The ambient political environment includes an array competing sources of cues (parties, interest groups, etc.). Competition limits the chances that a single source has an effect. Regardless of the mechanism, a multiplicity of cues makes it less likely that any single vector carries much signal. Not only does competition pose a theoretical challenge to any particular sort of cue-taking, it complicates the inferential problem, since weaker signals are more difficult to detect. Consequently, cue-taking should be more likely to occur and be observable in environments with less competition.

Although the theoretical case for social influence among legislators is compelling, uncovering empirical evidence of influence is complicated by its causal complement: homophily. Homophily refers to tie formation between similar individuals, the tendency for “birds of feather to flock together” (McPherson, Smith-Lovin, and Cook Reference McPherson, Smith-Lovin and Cook2001). Influence and homophily are confounded (Fowler et al. Reference Fowler, Heaney, Nickerson, Padgett and Sinclair2011). The most inferentially threatening sorts of homophily occurs if legislators establish relationships because of their tendency to vote together or terminate relationships because of their tendency to vote differently, as in the “unfriending” problem (Noel and Nyhan Reference Noel and Nyhan2011). Not all relationships form because of homophily, but the primary challenge to measuring social influence is specifying conditions under which the distribution of ties is ignorable.

Yet, there is also a third theoretical possibility that combines homophily and anticipated influence. Individuals may form ties with the explicit purpose of changing their own future behavior, in effect “choosing to be changed” (Santoro Reference Santoro2017). For example, a new member may seek out a senior colleague as a role model because of both perceived homogeneity and the intent to learn and thus change future behavior. This phenomenon blends elements of homophily and influence, implying that individuals not only select into relationships for nonrandom reasons but also subsequently change because of those relationships. Insofar as individuals bear the seeds of the change that follows, the process resembles homophily. Insofar as they were unlikely to change in the absence of the relationship, it is also unmistakably influential.

Cue-taking depends on qualities of social ties more generally. Ties vary in terms of strength—whether the relationship entails close, frequent, and durable interactions rather than casual, novel contact. Granovetter (Reference Granovetter1973) famously argues that the latter, “weaker” ties are actually the source of a network’s “strength.” While strong ties often develop in tightly knit groups, weak ties are more likely to bridge structural holes between different groups (Burt Reference Burt2009). Within tightly knit groups, information is shared quickly and exhaustively. In contrast, weak ties transmit more novel information. Scholars have documented the strength of weak ties between legislators, with consequences for legislative success (Kirkland Reference Kirkland2011), legislative effectiveness (Battaglini, Sciabolazza, and Patacchini Reference Battaglini, Sciabolazza and Patacchini2020), and information exchange (Ringe, Victor, and Gross Reference Ringe, Victor and Carman2013) in a variety of contexts (Wojcik Reference Wojcik2018). In the case of legislative cues, these weak ties should be better at transmitting easily audited information, such as party calls (Minozzi and Volden Reference Minozzi and Volden2013) or the positions of allies and opponents, than technical information that would fall prey to cheap talk-like impediments to information flow.

We identify both weak ties and “choosing to be changed” with certain relationships. First, ties between legislators should be weaker when the ties are newer and stronger when they have been repeated often. Second, when members enter a legislature for the first time, they may be more likely to form relationships with peers or senior colleagues whose traits they seek to emulate. During the boardinghouse era, the first decision made by many new members will have been where—and with whom—to live. The resulting relationships will be nascent and thus both relatively weak and chosen with the intent for future change.

To summarize, informal cue-taking should be more prominent under certain conditions. First, actors must have sustained contact. Second, actors must have limited capacity to curate relationships. Third, there must be relatively few competing sources of influence. Fourth, weaker ties should convey more information than stronger ties, and cue-taking should be more common for ties including new members who “choose to be changed.” In the next section, we use the historical record and secondary sources to argue that conditions for social influence were satisfied by the boardinghouse culture of Washington DC before the Civil War.

Elite Social Life in Early Washington

Before the Civil War, elite social life in Washington was marked by intense, sustained contact. Members were socially concentrated yet physically isolated from the rest of the country. In 1801, serving in Congress meant isolation from everything familiar and comforting: families, friends, and associates (Riley Reference Riley2014; Zagarri Reference Zagarri2013). Postal service was slow; a letter would take a week to travel from Washington to New England and even longer to the westernmost part of the country (Young Reference Young1966). Washington itself was exceptionally limited (Earman Reference Earman1992). At the dawn of the century, there were only about 400 buildings (Green Reference Green1962, 4ff.). Yet the city grew quickly. A complicated system of etiquette emerged (Cooley Reference Cooley1829), including the pivotal role of women in establishing informal social ties with new arrivals (Allgor Reference Allgor2002; Earman Reference Earman2000).

Practically speaking, joining Congress meant finding somewhere to live and eat. Limited choices meant that most members lacked fine control over the selection of housemates. Options included boardinghouses, hotels, and private residences, in order of increasing cost (Earman Reference Earman1992; Shelden Reference Shelden2013, 102ff.; Young Reference Young1966). Boardinghouses were the most common selection, with many located near Capitol Hill (Earman Reference Earman2000). They varied in size, expense, quality, and social composition. Coresidents typically shared meals with each other. In some, dining companions included military officers, professionals, and travelers; in others, legislators had separate dining rooms (Earman Reference Earman1992). All told, boardinghouse life featured sustained contact and frequent opportunities to interact with coresidents but incomplete control over selection.

These opportunities were literally illustrated by Rep. Amasa Parker (D-NY), who included a drawing of his boardinghouse, Mrs. Pittman’s, in a letter to his wife (December 31, 1837; see Figure 1). Seated at the dining table were representatives and senators, including future president Millard Fillmore. The dining room and parlor for legislators and their spouses were separate from those for other boarders, permitting members to talk politics over meals in privacy. The oval table encouraged conviviality, and the company and environment were conducive to informal socialization. This example highlights the limits—or disinclination—of at least some legislators to select coresidents. Parker’s messmates included members of both chambers and major parties, Northerners, and Southerners. Few such illustrations remain, but evidence suggests that Parker’s experience was not atypical (see, e.g., Shelden Reference Shelden2013).

Figure 1. A Map of Seating at Mrs. Pittman’s from a Letter from Rep. Amasa Parker to His Wife, December 31, 1837, 25th Congress

Note: Clockwise from the top, they are Rep. Hugh Anderson (D-ME), Rep. John Fairfield (D-ME), Rep. Heman Allen (W-VT), Rep. Hopkins Holsey (D-GA), Rep. Millard Fillmore (W-NY), Mrs. Fillmore, Rep. Zadock Pratt (D-NY), Mrs. Pratt, Mrs. Prentiss, Sen. Samuel Prentiss (W-VT), Rep. John H. Prentiss (D-NY), Mrs. Knight, Sen. Nehemiah Knight (W-RI), Mrs. Birdsall, Rep. Samuel Birdsall (D-NY), Rep. Robert McClelland (D-NY), Rep. Amasa Parker (D-NY), Rep. Albert White (W-IN), and Rep. Andrew Buchanan (D-PA). Finding aid retrieved from http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.mss/eadmss.ms008132.

Outside the boardinghouse, the ambient political environment included relatively few competing sources of information, especially early in the period. Parties were not solidly entrenched as institutions, leaders, and sources of influence until the 1830s, and partisan labels and attachments were not as meaningful as they later became (Aldrich Reference Aldrich2011). Sectional conflict often counteracted partisanship (Poole and Rosenthal Reference Poole and Rosenthal1997), and standing committees did not fully emerge until the 1820s (Gamm and Shepsle Reference Gamm and Shepsle1989). To the extent that presidents lobbied, they did so informally, over dinners and on social occasions.Footnote 2 Outside interests were similarly undeveloped. Organized interests did not exist even in vestigial state until after Reconstruction (Jacob Reference Jacob2010; Thompson Reference Thompson1985; but see Peart Reference Peart2018), and newspapers were controlled by party entrepreneurs rather than independent interests (Carson and Hood Reference Carson and Hood2014; Pasley Reference Pasley2002).

Some boardinghouses developed distinct political reputations. For illustration, consider Carroll Row, sometimes called “Six Buildings” or “Duff Green’s Row,” on First Street between East Capitol and A Streets SE. Daniel Carroll built these row houses on speculation before the government relocated (Bryan Reference Bryan1904). Over the decades, tenants included boardinghouses, hotels, and businesses, including an apothecary and a pub. In 1834, the easternmost house of Carrol Row became Mrs. Sprigg’s boardinghouse, which quickly emerged as a haven for abolitionists, earning the name “Abolitionist House” (Winkle Reference Winkle2013, Chap. 2). Residents included ardent antislavery advocate Joshua Giddings of Ohio, legislative allies William Slade of Vermont and Seth Gates of New York, and journalists Theodore Dwight Weld and Joshua Leavitt, who were publicists for abolition. Although Mrs. Sprigg had once been a slaveholder, by then she was a quiet abettor of the Underground Railroad.

Mrs. Sprigg’s most famous resident was Abraham Lincoln, who lived there during his single term in Congress in 1847–8. This choice of lodging placed the future president in the midst of abolitionists and may have shaped his views on slavery (Paullin Reference Paullin1921). In 1847, Lincoln was one of three first-term representatives who chose to live at Mrs. Sprigg’s. The other two were Elisha Embree (W-IN), and P.W. Tompkins (W-MS), the lone Southerner in the house. All five other coresidents, including Giddings, were Whigs who had previously lived in the boardinghouse.Footnote 3 But not all would remain. By the second session, Embree and Tompkins had departed for different accommodations, Embree to a different boardinghouse, and Tompkins to Brown’s Hotel. The others—including Lincoln—all returned to Mrs. Sprigg’s. Given Lincoln’s later actions, this example is consistent with the possibility that he selected, chose to remain among, and may even have been influenced by his senior coresidents.

Congressional Residences, 1801–1861

To systematically analyze influence based on coresidence, we collected data from the 58 extant editions of the Congressional Directory from 1801 to 1861,Footnote 4 recording each member’s residence and where they “messed,” or took their meals, when available.Footnote 5 In all, we have residential and/or mess data for 11,775 legislator-residence-sessions.Footnote 6

For each member, we coded whether they lived in a Boardinghouse , Hotel , or Private residence based on contextual information. Many editions of the Directory specifically labeled private residences, hotels included the word “hotel” in their names, and most boardinghouses were named after their proprietors. In our initial pass, we categorized 88% of 3,589 residences. All but 65 of the remaining locations included only one resident, suggesting they were private residences; at least, they will not affect our analysis of coresidence. We resolved remaining ambiguities on a case-by-case basis, using other editions of the Directory. Footnote 7

We matched this information to data on legislators and votes.Footnote 8 Our unit of analysis is an undirected dyad of legislators in a session (n > 1.32 million). Our key causal variable is an indicator for Coresidence for a dyad.Footnote 9 To match residency information to voting records, we split roll-call votes into periods corresponding to editions of the Congressional Directory.

Our outcome measures focus on roll-call votes. Consistent with the literature, our primary outcome measure is voting Agreement , the fraction of votes on which members of a dyad voted similarly out of the number on which both voted. These scores are employed to measure similarity because they include information omitted by ideal point estimation (Masket Reference Masket2008). Since Agreement scores are logically impossible when comparing a legislator with a deceased colleague, we later rely on ideal point estimation, as described below.

To model coresident selection, we augmented these data with indicators for dyadic similarity in Party , State , or Region (North or South)Footnote 10 ; Occupation ; whether they were in their First Session or Returning from the most previous sessionFootnote 11 ; service in the Military ; graduation from College ; Age ; and Seniority . Finally, absenteeism was common, reaching more than a third of votes in the 1840’s, perhaps because of the prevalence of alcohol (Shelden Reference Shelden2013). Therefore, we also track Coabsence , the fraction of votes for which neither voted or was present.Footnote 12 Ultimately, we estimate the following regression model:

$$ \mathrm{\Pr}\left({\boldsymbol{Coresidence}}_{ij t}=1\right)={\mathrm{logit}}^{-1}\left({X}_{ij t}b+{W}_{ij}g+{Z}_{ij\left(t-1\right)}d+{a}_t\right), $$

where i and j index legislators, t indexes sessions, at refers to session-specific fixed effects, Xijt to time-varying covariates, Wij to time-invariant covariates, and Zij(t-1) to lagged covariates.

Our data and analysis improve on previous studies in several ways. The quantitative evidence Young (Reference Young1966) presents is remarkable for its time, but limited to 116 roll-call votes from 1800 to 1821, largely serving to corroborate qualitative evidence. Bogue and Marlaire (Reference Bogue and Marlaire1975) use regression to analyze the 17th, 22nd, and 27th Congresses (1821–2, 1831–2, 1841–2), but they find no association between voting and coresidence. Parigi and Bergemann (Reference Parigi and Bergemann2016) analyze data from 1825 to 1841 using fixed-effects analysis, reporting a positive relationship between agreement and coresidence. In a second study, they focus on members who moved midterm, finding that they voted less often with their erstwhile colleagues. Each design relies on assumptions to identify effects, assuming that the forces that bring legislators together are independent of potential outcomes, no time-varying unobservables confound inference, or no dynamic relationships exist between coresidence and voting. As we shall see, all these assumptions are incorrect.

The Rise and Fall of Boardinghouse Culture

During the six decades before the Civil War, boardinghouse culture emerged, quickly became the dominant feature of social life, and then slowly declined (Figure 2). To anchor inferences, we split the period into five eras: the Jeffersonian (1801–17), Era of Good Feelings (1817–1825), Early Jacksonian before the Whig party emerged (1825–37), Late Jacksonian (1837–49), and Antebellum (1849–61). These breakpoints are useful but to some extent arbitrary, but all inferences are robust to small changes in definitions of eras.

Figure 2. Counts of Residences of Members of the House of Representatives (left panel) and Residents Themselves (right panel) by Year and Type of Residence

Note: Both panels reveal that boardinghouses were the dominant residence type for members, emerging early on. Yet by the Late Jacksonian (1837–1849) and into Antebellum era, boardinghouses fell out of favor, gradually being replaced by hotels.

When looking for shelter, legislators had many options (left panel, Figure 2). Boardinghouses were most common. At the peak in 1855, members collectively resided in 75 different boardinghouses. Boardinghouses were also the dominant selection (right panel). Of our nearly 12,000 cases, more than 77% chose a boardinghouse. In 12 sessions—about 20% of cases—more than 90% of legislators lived in one of these buildings. But by the end of this period, boardinghouse culture was moribund. As late as 1855, 57% of legislators still lived in boardinghouses, but that number declined to 26% by 1861. Simultaneously, the number of colleagues one could expect to live with had also dwindled. Between 1801 and 1846, a boardinghouse resident could expect to live with an average of 4 to 7 other legislators. By 1861, that number fell to 1.5. These trends reveal how the social role of the boardinghouse waned with the advent of the Civil War.Footnote 13

Who Lived with Whom, and Why?

With whom did legislators choose to live? To answer this question, we estimated logistic regressions of Coresidence . Given the over-time variation we show above, we fit separate models by era, with fixed effects at the period (i.e., congressional session) level. For inference, we bootstrap at the congressional session level, which is a common procedure used in networks, as dyads themselves are not exchangeable (see, e.g., Leifeld, Cranmer, and Desmarais Reference Leifeld, Cranmer and Desmarais2018).

Based on the logic of homophily, we hypothesized that similarity would explain who lived with whom. Indeed, Same Party , State , or Region all reliably predict who lived with whom (see Table 1).Footnote 14 These estimates are substantial and persistent. The estimates for Party , in particular, cohere with conventional wisdom. The strongest relationships appear during the first and second party systems, the Jeffersonian and Late Jacksonian. In the Jeffersonian era, legislators from the Same Party had a predicted probability of Coresidence that was 4.4 percentage points larger than that of noncopartisans (95% interval [3.8%, 5.6%]).Footnote 15 This difference is larger than it may seem. The overall rate of Coresidence in this era was only 3.9%, meaning copartisanship almost doubles the chances of living together. Other similarity measures also predicted Coresidence , albeit more sporadically. Overall, the models strongly suggest homophily in coresident selection.

Table 1. Logistic Regression Models of Coresidence

Note: The table presents the results of logistic regression models for each era. Standard errors are based on 1,000 bootstrap resamples over congressional sessions. Models also include indicators for each congressional session and for availability of covariates. *p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.

More troubling for inference about influence, homophily also appears between Coresidence and Lagged Agreement . Through all eras, Lagged Agreement strongly predicts whether members lived together. In substantive terms, the estimates are smaller than those for Same Party . For example, in the Jeffersonian era, the average marginal difference in predicted probabilities for Lagged Agreement is 1.2% (see Figure 3, left panel). Despite this small size, the estimates are precisely estimated; all 95% intervals exclude zero. Thus, as with party and geography, there is clear evidence of homophily in voting and coresidence.

Figure 3. Average Marginal Effects of Lagged Agreement on the Probability of Coresidence in Percentage Points

Note: Bars depict 95% intervals based on bootstrapping over congressional sessions.

Whatever the reason for cohabitation, members who lived together were likely to repeat the arrangement. The strongest predictor of Coresidence is Lagged Coresidence . About 40% of cases of Lagged Coresidence were repeated, ranging from 38% to 44% across eras, revealing a potential problem. Legislators who usually disagreed may have sought alternative lodging, while those that agreed continued living together. Longitudinal designs can mistake the dissolution of ties for different levels of influence, conflating influence with the underlying causes of such “unfriending” (Noel and Nyhan Reference Noel and Nyhan2011). If dissimilarity explains moves, then comparing coresident dyads to noncoresident ones will overestimate influence. Fixed effects models assume away such dynamic relationships between treatment and outcome (Imai and Kim Reference Imai and Kim2019), so a complete picture requires analysis of repeated Coresidence .

Therefore, we analyzed dyads who lived together in the previous session, focusing on repeated Coresidence .Footnote 16 The results tell a different story from the full sample (see Table 2). The roles of State , Party , and Region are weaker, though intermittently predictive. In contrast, homophily based on similar voting not only remains important, but the relationship between agreement and coresidence is also more pronounced. The coefficients on Lagged Agreement are substantial and significant in the first four eras. Differences in predicted probabilities are about 10 times larger (Figure 3, right panel) than in the overall model, with an average increase of 7 percentage points. We conclude that legislators were likely to rely on political views not only to choose coresidents but also to choose whether to dissolve social relationships. As a consequence, fixed effects are inappropriate for identifying the effect of Coresidence on Agreement .

Table 2. Logistic Regression Models of Repeated Coresidence

Note: The table presents the results of logistic regression models for each era on the subsamples of dyads who were coresidents in the previous period. Sessions are excluded when no evidence exists for the relevant prior session. Standard errors are based on 1,000 bootstrap resamples over congressional sessions. Models also include indicators for each congressional session and for availability of covariates. *p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

Dynamic Identification of Coresidence Effects

Given that Coresidence is predicted by previous voting Agreement , research designs such as fixed effects do not plausibly identify the effects of the former on the latter. An alternative identification strategy is to use inverse probability weighting (Blackwell and Glynn Reference Blackwell and Glynn2018) to explicitly account for dynamic relationships between treatment and outcome. This strategy relies on strong identifying assumptions, most notably sequential ignorability conditional on previous Coresidence and covariates, including Lagged Agreement . An important cost is that we no longer adjust for unobservable, time-invariant covariates, as with fixed effects. Although the cost is steep, our strategy is to offset it by pairing our aggregate analysis with a better-identified subsequent study based on legislator deaths, described below.

We used models with similar forms to those from above to estimate the probability of Coresidence , including fixed effects at the congressional session.Footnote 17 Because the selection processes for previously coresident and noncoresident dyads were different, we analyze these groups separately. For weights, we took predicted probabilities of Coresidence and assigned the inverse probability to coresident dyads and the inverse of its complement to noncoresident dyads.Footnote 18 Doing so substantially improved balance (see Appendix, A8–A9). Finally, we estimated weighted linear models of Agreement on Coresidence . For statistical inference, we bootstrapped at the congressional session level, resampling 1,000 times over sessions, testing the null hypothesis of zero average effect.

The results of our analysis appear in Figure 4. The black bars depict estimates of the effect of Coresidence on Agreement for dyads who did not live together in the previous session; the gray bars display the same for previous coresidents. In both cases, results are shown by era. Since Agreement ranges from 0 to 100%, results can be understood in terms of the percentage point increase in roll-call voting agreement due to Coresidence .Footnote 19

Figure 4. Estimated Effects of Coresidence on Agreement in Percentage Points

Note: Bars depict 95% intervals. Estimates are calculated using inverse probability of treatment weighting, with the block bootstrap over sessions.

In all cases, our estimates of the effects of Coresidence on Agreement are positive and, in the case of previous noncoresidents, statistically significant.Footnote 20 The appendix presents several robustness checks, including a specification that adjusts for whether both members of a dyad chose to live in a boardinghouse and another in which we include fixed effects at the level of the individual legislator (see Appendix, A14–A15). In both cases, inferences are similar to those reported in the main text.

On balance, these findings suggest that social influence and cue-taking occurred regularly throughout the decades before the Civil War. On average, effect estimates were about 4.6 percentage points for dyads who lived apart in the previous session and about a third of that among pairs who previously lived together.Footnote 21

These results depart from previous work. Parigi and Bergemann (Reference Parigi and Bergemann2016) analyze the period from 1825–41, roughly equivalent to the Early Jacksonian era, using fixed effects to find estimates of 10 to 13 percentage points. For previous noncoresidents, we do see our largest estimated effect in that era—but our estimate is only half as large as is theirs. Given the evidence of homophily, this difference may be due to the improved research design.

We go beyond previous studies to test hypotheses about different sets of dyads. Based on the logic of “choosing to be changed” (Santoro Reference Santoro2017), we expected new members to have chosen coresidents with influence in mind and thus to have larger effects. Further, tie strength should increase with shared history. Based on the “strength of weak ties” (Granovetter Reference Granovetter1973), we expected effects to be small for previous noncoresidents who had lived together in the more distant past; smaller still for previous coresidents who lived together only once, in the most previous session; and smallest for previous coresidents who lived together more than once.

Figure 5 displays the conditional effects of Coresidence for each of these subgroups. In general, the results support both that new members may select into residences that are likely to influence them and that influence declines with tie strength. There is a clear, statistically significant difference between dyads with at least one new member and dyads with two returning members who had never lived together.Footnote 22 Moreover, there is a two-percentage-point difference between the estimate for those returning members who had never lived together and those for the strongest ties, legislators who had previously lived together (two-tailed p < 0.001).Footnote 23

Figure 5. Estimated Effects of Coresidence on Agreement in Percentage Points

Note: Bars depict 95% intervals. The subgroups of dyads differ in terms of both tie strength and presence of a new member.

Once we adjust for the dynamic relationship between residence selection and voting behavior, there is robust evidence of social influence among legislators throughout the six decades prior to the Civil War. Our results further suggest that existing studies, which have focused on subsets of this period, have also overestimated these effects. Finally, our estimated effects are smallest in the years just before the Civil War, coincident with the decline in boardinghouse culture we documented above.

But our research design still relies on strong identifying assumptions, including that Coresidence is sequentially ignorable, conditional on covariates. This assumption has varying plausibility. For example, it is less plausible when we lack lagged Agreement scores, as with new members. We are reassured by the evidence of declining influence with increasing tie strength. Yet, despite the clear improvement in identification, this research design does not rival those that exploit randomization, such as Rogowski and Sinclair’s (Reference Rogowski and Sinclair2012) study of the office lottery. Next, we offer one last study to better approximate randomization.

Identifying Coresidence Effects with Legislator Deaths

We leverage occasions when a legislator died in office to identify the effect of his sudden absence on surviving coresidents.Footnote 24 , Footnote 25 Using the Biographical Directory of the United States Congress, we identified legislators who died during congressional terms between 1801 to 1861. We include such legislators when they had at least one coresident. Further, to permit reliable measurement, we included only deceased legislators who cast at least 20 roll-call votes before their deaths and survivors who cast at least 20 votes before and 20 votes after. Ultimately, we identified 60 deceased legislators.Footnote 26

These deceased legislators were representative of their population. Their deaths occurred throughout the period. The earliest was Rep. Charles Johnson (R-NC), who died on July 23, 1802; the latest, Rep. Silas Burroughs (R-NY), who died on August 3, 1860. The average deceased legislator resided in a boardinghouse, served two terms, and lived with about six coresidents. Twenty hailed from the South. More Virginians are included in the sample than denizens of any other state, but members of 20 delegations are included. The set includes Democrats, Federalists, Republicans (in both party systems), Whigs, and members of several third parties. The surviving coresidents are similarly representative.

Because legislators do not vote after their deaths, we cannot rely on Agreement scores. Therefore, we estimate changes in ideological distances between survivors and their deceased colleague before and after his death. If any legislator exerts influence on his coresidents, he would have had an attractive effect on the ideal points of his coresidents. After death, we should see those survivors move away from their erstwhile coresident’s ideal point, perhaps now more influenced by their own preferences, constituencies, parties, state delegations, or remaining or even new coresidents. The result should be that the distance between deceased legislator’s and survivors’ ideal points increases after death.

To estimate changes that occurred when a legislator died, we need separate measures for each survivor before and after his colleague’s death. Therefore, we used bridging (Poole Reference Poole2005, Chap. 6). First, for each deceased legislator, we built a dataset of votes and legislators. For legislators who died between sessions, we included the sessions immediately before and after the death; for those who died within a session, we restricted attention to that session. In both cases, we included the deceased legislator and all noncoresidents who served in the House both before and after the death date. We also included each survivor twice: once for votes before his colleague’s death and once for after. Noncoresidents are the bridges that identify distances between ideal points before and after death.Footnote 27 We observed both before- and after-death ideal points for all surviving coresidents, so the attrition rate in this study is zero.

For each deceased legislator, we simulated two-dimensional ideal points using item response theory (Clinton, Jackman, and Rivers Reference Clinton, Jackman and Rivers2004).Footnote 28 While multidimensional ideal point models suffer from nonidentification of several sorts, we are interested in distances between points rather than nominal values. Therefore, our measure is already invariant to rotation and translation. For nonidentification due to the scale of the policy space, we standardized each set of ideal points with respect to the bridge observations. Nevertheless, combining measures from different models means comparing sessions with different scales and thus the assumption that the policy space does not expand or contract. It is plausible, however, to make comparisons between different sets of ideal point distances in proportional terms using logs—effectively gauging the ratio by which the distances between legislators grew or shrank relative to the average distance between pairs of (bridge) legislators. Our outcome is therefore log Ideal Point Distance between a deceased legislator and surviving coresident, measured both before and after death.

To provide an effective contrast for residences in which legislators died, we used a similar strategy to estimate ideal point drift in residences that experienced no deaths.Footnote 29 That is, for each of the remaining residences that housed more than one resident, we used the same technique as described above on each resident—essentially treating all residents from these residences as control cases—that is, nondecedents. We calculated the (log) distances before and after that legislator’s “death,” which we set at the break between sessions, to yield a comparable outcome variable. The result is a set of 28,362 (directed) dyads over 967 residence-terms.

Our analysis plan focuses on the changes in log Ideal Point Distance aggregated to the level of the residence.Footnote 30 Thus, we regard each residence as either having been treated to a resident’s death or not. First, we calculate the change in log Ideal Point Distance after each legislator death or session break, based on treatment status. Second, we calculate the average of those changes at the level of the residence (so n = 60 residences with deaths + 967 residences without deaths = 1,027). Finally, we estimate a weighted least squares model of the mean change in log Ideal Point Distance , weighted by the number of dyads in each residence to track the amount of information provided by each observation. The main model specification is mean change in log Ideal Point Distance rt = Resident Death rt + at ,

where r indexes residences; t indexes congressional terms; Resident Death is the treatment variable, which is 1 if and only if a resident of residence r died within term t; and at represents fixed effects for era. This model emphasizes the focal role of the residence, though other designs are reasonable and yield similar results.Footnote 31 We also report on specifications including an indicator for Within Session , which indicates whether death occurred midsession (1) or between sessions (0); an indicator for Boardinghouse , which indicates whether a residence was a boardinghouse (1) or not (0); and a count of the Number of Legislator Residents in that residence-term.

Identification relies on one primary assumption. We assume that deaths occurred as though at random, so that each boardinghouse was equally likely to have experienced a legislator’s death.Footnote 32 While legislators died of many different causes (Maltzman, Sigelman, and Binder Reference Maltzman, Sigelman and Binder1996), we regard this assumption as at least facially plausible. For statistical inference, we use bootstrapped standard errors, resampling over residence-terms, with two-tailed p-values.Footnote 33

Survivors Drift Away from Deceased Colleagues

As we hypothesized, surviving legislators drifted away from the ideological positions of their deceased colleagues. Overall, the estimated effect of Resident Death on mean change in log Ideal Point Distance was 0.072, with 95% interval [0.002, 0.140] and p = 0.04. Effects are interpretable in proportional terms, so this result means that a colleague’s death causes the distance between his ideal point and that of his deceased coresident to grow by about 7%, similar to the magnitude reported in the IPW study above.Footnote 34

To vet the efficacy of this design, we deploy a placebo study, focusing exclusively on the 967 residences that did not experience a death, effectively treating residents of such residences as, alternately, “placebo decedents” and “placebo survivors,” with “placebo death” occurring at the break between sessions. Here, we randomly sample 60 residences—none of which experienced an actual death—and recode Resident Death to be equal to 1 only in those cases. We then use the weighted least squares procedure described above, bootstrapping for statistical inference.

We repeat this placebo test procedure 1,000 times to yield a distribution of placebo estimates and p-values.Footnote 35 Given that none of the residences in this test experienced death, if the design is unbiased, we would expect to see (1) a flat, uniform distribution of placebo p-values and (2) that our estimated effect appears as an outlier in the distribution of placebo effects. Figure 6 confirms both of these expectations. Exactly 5% of placebo p-values were less than or equal to 0.05, and only 1.6% of placebo estimates were greater than or equal to the actual estimated effect of 0.072. We conclude that this design does not suffer from overrejection of the null or bias.

Figure 6. Results of 1,000 Simulated Placebo Tests Using All Residences That Did Not Experience a Death of a Resident

Note: Residences that did experience a death are excluded. The panel on the left displays a histogram of the (bootstrapped) p-values from these tests. The vertical dashed line indicates p = 0.05. The panel on the right displays a histogram of the estimated placebo effects, and the solid vertical line indicates the observed estimate of 0.072. Consistent with the design assumptions, only 5% of placebo p-values are less than or equal to 0.05, and only 1.6% of placebo estimates exceed the actual estimated effect.

We also examined several alternative models. First, we used the same design to estimate effects on mean change in (unlogged) Ideal Point Distance , which yields an estimated effect of Resident Death of 0.042 [–0.029, 0.109], in a similar direction to the effect for logged distance but not statistically significant. The result is therefore sensitive to transformation of the outcome variable. However, as we argued above, logging is more appropriate in this case, given that Ideal Point Distance is positive-valued, and that the ideal points are measured separately by congressional term. Second, we estimated a model including the multiplicative interaction of Resident Death and Boardinghouse , along with the constituent terms, expecting that deaths in boardinghouses would have larger effects due to the more close-knit ties such residences fostered. The interaction term was positive though imprecisely estimated, 0.068 [–0.072, 0.214]. However, the effect for boardinghouse residents is represented by the sum the coefficients on the interaction term and the main effect of Resident Death , and this quantity remains significant (0.970 [0.007, 0.186], p = 0.032). Similarly, we estimated two more interaction models, one with Within Session and a second with Number of Legislator Residents . In each case, the interaction terms were small and imprecisely estimated.

For robustness, we also estimated a version of this model at the dyad-level, rather than at the residence-level. Specifically, the model specification in this case is

log Ideal Point Distance dt = After Death dt + Resident Death dt × After Death dt +gd ,

where d indexes dyads, t indexes congressional term, After Death indicates whether the outcome is measured before (0) or after (1) death/session break, and gd is a dyad fixed effect. The main coefficient for Resident Death is subsumed by the fixed effects, and the quantity of interest is now the coefficient on the interaction term. The main model specification only differs by including fixed effects for era, which would also have been subsumed by the dyad fixed effects. If we omit era fixed effects from the main specification, the two models are identical. The estimates from the dyadic model are similar to those from the residence-level model, though the p-value increases slightly (0.060 [-0.007, 0.128], p = 0.078); see Appendix Table A11 (A20). Therefore, it appears that dyad-level analysis, and the concomitant omission of era-level fixed effects, decreases the point estimate, suggesting overtime variation consistent with that seen in the IPW study.

Finally, to judge whether extreme outliers are responsible for these results, we reestimated our residence-level main specification, replacing mean change in log Ideal Point Distance with median change, which is more robust to outliers. In this case, the point estimate is slightly higher, and the p-value decreases slightly (0.078 [0.007, 0.153], p = 0.034). Based on this model, it appears that, if anything, outliers may dampen the estimated effect.

We conclude from the analyses that the evidence from legislators’ deaths largely confirms that from the IPW study, both in terms of sign and magnitude, while noting that this result extends only to log distances and the associated changes in proportional terms.

Conclusion

We reported on the most systematic collection of evidence on residences and social influence in U.S. House of Representatives before the Civil War and have made several contributions. With evidence from both secondary historical sources and primary sources, we showed the role of boardinghouse culture in the social milieu of Washington. While previous analyses have been limited in scope, never analyzing more than two decades, we examined 60 years’ worth of evidence. We further documented the important and heretofore unexamined role of homophily in both selection of residences and, more troubling for inference, “unfriending” (Noel and Nyhan Reference Noel and Nyhan2011), in which conflicting coresidents move apart. These results cast doubt on previous studies.

To cope with selection, we presented two quantitative studies. First, we used a weighting strategy designed to account for dynamic relationships between treatment (coresidence) and outcome (voting behavior). In so doing, we found that coresidence had identifiable, positive effects on voting agreement—but at only about half of the levels reported in previous studies. Nevertheless, we also found support for key hypotheses. Our estimates of effects were highest for new members, who are likely to have both the weakest social ties (Granovetter Reference Granovetter1973) and the most interest in “choosing to be changed” (Santoro Reference Santoro2017), and smallest for members who had previously and repeatedly lived together.

Despite the improvement yielded by this strategy, it still requires strong identifying assumptions. Thus, in our second study, we examined legislators who died in office. Assuming such events occurred as though at random, we showed that surviving coresidents drift away from their erstwhile colleagues, increasing ideological distance by 7%. This identification strategy is stronger than that in any previous study of this era and represents the strongest evidence yet of social influence among elites before the Civil War.

That said, there remain some important limitations to our study. The primary limitation is that we lack experimental manipulation. All our analyses are based on observational data and therefore depend on strong identifying assumptions. Furthermore, we lack some key evidence, including data on the prices of lodging in different residences, as well as their capacities. Finally, at times we cannot discriminate between competing explanations. For example, we cannot say whether the estimated effect of coresidence on coabsence is due to contagious diseases spreading through residences or due to strategic abstention on key roll-call votes.

Nevertheless, on balance our analysis suggests that the six decades before the Civil War were characterized by some stable regularities and some temporal changes. Coresidence was persistently predicted by similarity in party, state, region, and voting agreement. Repeated coresidence was even more strongly predicted by such agreement. But the aggregate analysis based on dynamic identification indicates changes over time, especially for first-time coresidents. We observed the largest effects in the Early Jacksonian era, at the apex of boardinghouse culture, with smaller estimates of influence earlier and later.

This period is important in its own right and as a near-ideal opportunity to study cue-taking, but our analysis also offers important inferences for the modern era. Intriguingly, our results are consistent with the idea that informal socializing counteracts elite polarization. While we certainly lack direct evidence on this point, we have illustrated trends that are coherent. Boardinghouse culture—in terms of the number of residences, the number of legislators who lived in them, and the number of coresidents one could expect—sharply declined in the 1850s, although the homophily we document does not. Further, our estimates of social influence decline to their nadir during the elite polarization of the late 1850s. There is a clear similarity between the declining informal socializing and increasing polarization of that period, and similar trends in the modern era.

Supplementary Materials

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055421000630.

Data Availability Statement

Research documentation and/or data that support the findings of this study are openly available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/LIJSWE.

Acknowledgments

A previous version of this paper was presented at the 2015 Congress and History Conference, Vanderbilt University. We thank Michael Neblo, David Bateman, Richard Bensel, Skyler Cranmer, Matt Hitt, Ira Katznelson, Danny Lempert, Seth Masket, Charles Stewart, Craig Volden, and Jon Woon for comments and conversations, and Jakob Miller for research assistance.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

Ethical Standards

The authors affirm this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

1 For brevity, we refer to both sending and receiving cues as “cue-taking.”

2 Jefferson was the most ambitious in his pursuit of organized congressional action, holding regular dinners several times a week throughout his tenure (Scofield Reference Scofield2006; Young Reference Young1966).

3 The other returning members were John Blanchard (W-PA), John Dickey (W-PA), A.R. McIlvaine (W-PA), James Pollock (W-PA), and John Strohm (W-PA).

4 Directories exist from as early as the first Congress, but editions from before the 7th Congress (before March 1801) correspond to legislatures that met in Philadelphia and New York. Until 1840, private printers produced the directories. Because they were not government documents, they are fugitive; some are entirely missing to history (Colket Reference Colket1953–1956). Our sourcing of documents ranged widely. Goldman and Young (Reference Goldman and Young1973) present evidence from many directories before 1840, although we located some that eluded them. We obtained others from Google Books, ProQuest, and various libraries and archives. We engaged a third-party vendor to transcribe them. Finally, the authors and research assistants corroborated transcriptions.

5 Each session had only one edition of the Directory, with the exception of the 1st session of the 29th Congress, which had two. We split this session at the date of the second edition.

6 Data are missing for both residence and mess in 1,094 legislator-sessions, for an overall missingness rate of 8.5%. Missingness is most likely for legislators who arrived in DC after the Directory was printed or who served the remainder of terms of others who left office.

7 We could not code 42 observations, all of which are vague: “Georgetown” or “the Navy Yard.” Members who both resided at one of these vague addresses were not classified as coresidents.

8 Roll-call evidence comes from voteview.com. We cleaned these data for dates, party labels, and votes. During the collapse of the first party system, Poole and Rosenthal (Reference Poole and Rosenthal1997) do not provide party labels, so we followed Martis, Rowles, and Pauer (Reference Martis, Rowles and Pauer1989), coding legislators by faction in the 1824 presidential election. Biographical data are from McKibbin (Reference McKibbin1992).

9 Starting in the 27th Congress, the Directory reported both messes and residences, comprising about 30% of cases from those terms. In the vast majority, 97%, where both are listed, members messed where they resided. In the remaining cases, members lived and ate at different locations. It is plausible that social influence via cue-taking operated in both locales. Therefore, we combine residence and mess; by Coresidence , we mean either literal coresidence or attendance at the same mess. Results are robust to excluding mess information.

10 We identified region by secession. Results are robust to alternative definitions of the South.

11 We use these measures rather than freshman status because the norm of rotation meant that many members had previously served but did not immediately return (see, e.g., Kernell Reference Kernell1977).

12 Descriptive statistics are presented in Appendix Table A1.

13 A change in data quality is very unlikely to have driven this change. Data quality is poorer in the earlier years of our dataset. After about 1825, quality is much improved because the government formalized the printing of the Congressional Directory.

14 Our results are robust to many alternative specifications. Results are similar if we use dyadic cluster-robust standard errors (Aronow, Samii, and Assenova Reference Aronow, Samii and Assenova2015; see Appendix, A2–A3). Similar results also emerge when adjusting for legislator-level fixed effects (Appendix, A4–A5). One might also object that legislators did not choose coresidents, but residences, in which case the data constitute a bipartite network. We therefore estimated bipartite exponential random graph models (Wang, Pattison, and Robins Reference Wang, Pattison and Robins2013), which again yielded similar inferences. See Appendix (A6–A7).

15 Differences in predicted probabilities are calculated with numerical derivatives for continuous covariates and differences for dichotomous ones, using coefficients from bootstrap resamples.

16 We exclude two sessions for which we lack evidence from the previous session.

17 Balance was considerably improved by adding second-order interactions to the models from the previous section. In the case of the Antebellum era, we also included higher-order interaction terms with Same Party . Use of these complicated models is warranted because our goal is to yield weights that eliminate imbalance rather than to make inferences about specific covariates.

18 Following recommended practice, we stabilized weights by multiplying by average Coresidence for treated dyads and its complement for the untreated.

19 At the legislator-dyad level, we are missing a small fraction of Agreement scores (about 0.4%). Further, a substantial number of legislators did not case votes on specific roll calls, meaning there is attrition in this study. In the Appendix (A10–A13), we report details on analyses of worst-case scenarios at both levels to bound the point estimates of the effect of Coresidence . At the legislator-level, worst case bounds very tightly bound the results presented in the paper. At the roll-call vote-level, worst-case bounds remain positive in most cases.

20 We also estimated the effects on Agreement (with Coabsence) , which includes all votes for which both legislators in a dyad are eligible, counting mutual absences as agreement, and on Agreement (Imputed ), which uses ideal point estimation to impute missing roll-call votes, and then recalculates Agreement . In both cases, results are similar to those in the text. Moreover, we estimated the effects on Coresidence on the rate of Coabsence , which were small in magnitude in all cases (<1%), insignificant in all cases for previous coresidents, and insignificant in three of five cases for previous noncoresidents. These significant effects may be due to many factors, including, e.g., coresidents suffering from communicable diseases, though it could also be due to strategic nonvoting. See the Appendix (A14–A15).

21 We also tested the sharp null hypothesis of no effect by permuting the Coresidence vector. For previous coresidents in the Early Jacksonian era, the p-value is 0.530 and we fail to reject the sharp null. In all other cases, p-values are 0.022 or less.

22 For example, comparing “New Coresidents, Both New Members” and “New Coresidents, Both Returning Members” yields a two-sided bootstrapped p < 0.001.

23 We also estimated subgroup effects for boardinghouse residents and for hotel residents, expecting larger effects for the former group. We observe statistically significant differences in that direction for the Early and Late Jacksonian Eras, but not in other cases. See Appendix Table A8 (A15).

24 Azoulay, Zivin, and Wang (Reference Azoulay, Zivin and Wang2010) use a similar research design to study the effect of academic authors’ deaths on their coauthors’ productivity.

25 The estimated effects we report are local to boardinghouse and hotel residents, as private residents did not (typically) have coresidents.

26 One boardinghouse experienced the deaths of two legislators: Jonathan Cilley (D-ME), who famously died in a duel, and Timothy Carter (D-ME). Both died while residing at Mr. Birth’s. Our research design assumes no changes other than (a single) death, so we exclude these cases.

27 Bridging strategies are criticized for using incommensurate votes from different contexts, small numbers of bridging legislators, or placing legislators on a common scale over large timescales. Our application suffers from none of these issues. We do not use votes from different contexts, our number of bridges is large, and we never bridge more than two sessions from one term.

28 For each, we use the pscl package in R (Jackman Reference Jackman2017) to simulate ideal points, with 5,000 burn-in iterations and 1,000 posterior samples. We rely on the typical assumption that absences are missing at random.

29 In previous versions of this paper, our analysis plan focused only on residences in which a death occurred. However, a placebo test revealed that that design suffered from bias. A potential source is that different sorts of votes are scheduled earlier vs. later in a term, creating correlation with before and after death. We thank an anonymous reviewer for recommending the placebo test.

30 See the Appendix for a detailed description of our analysis plan (A16).

31 For example, this design is similar to a dyad-level fixed effects model; see below.

32 Another assumption that would identify this design is that legislators do not anticipate their coresidents’ deaths and change their behavior as a consequence.

33 Results are similar when using heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors; see Appendix Table A10 (A19).

34 See Appendix Table A9 (A17) for details on regressions.

35 We replicated this placebo test using classical estimation and heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors; results are similar. See Appendix Figure A2 (A18).

References

REFERENCES

Aldrich, John. H. 2011. Why Parties? A Second Look. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Allgor, Catherine. 2002. Parlor Politics: In Which the Ladies of Washington Help Build a City and a Government. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.Google Scholar
Aronow, Peter M., Samii, Cyrus, and Assenova, Valentina A.. 2015. “Cluster-Robust Variance Estimation for Dyadic Data.” Political Analysis 23 (4): 564–77.Google Scholar
Azoulay, Pierre, Zivin, Joshua S., and Wang, Jialan. 2010. “Superstar Extinction.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (2): 549–89.Google Scholar
Bash, Dana. 2013. “The Real ‘Alpha House’: Yes, This Is Where Some Senators Actually Live.” CNN.com, December 4. https://www.cnn.com/2013/12/04/politics/real-alpha-house/index.html.Google Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, Sciabolazza, Valerio Leone, and Patacchini, Eleonora. 2020. “Effectiveness of Connected Legislators.” American Journal of Political Science 64 (4): 739–56.Google Scholar
Blackwell, Matthew, and Glynn, Adam N.. 2018. “How to Make Causal Inferences with Time-Series Cross-Sectional Data under Selection on Observables.” American Political Science Review 112 (4): 1067–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bogue, Allan G., and Marlaire, Mark Paul. 1975. “Of Mess and Men: The Boardinghouse and Congressional Voting, 1821-1842.” American Journal of Political Science 19 (2): 207–30.Google Scholar
Booker, Brakkton. 2015. “On Links as in Life, D.C. Bipartisan Relations Are Deep in the Rough.” NPR, April 20. https://www.npr.org/sections/itsallpolitics/2015/04/17/400362232/on-links-as-in-life-d-c-bipartisan-relations-are-deep-in-the-rough.Google Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet, Ryan, Josh M., and Sokhey, Anand E.. 2015. “Examining Legislative Cue-Taking in the US Senate.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 40 (1): 1353.Google Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet, Christenson, Dino P., and Craig, Alison W.. 2019. “Cue-Taking in Congress: Interest Group Signals from Dear Colleague Letters.” American Journal of Political Science 63 (1): 163–80.Google Scholar
Bryan, Wilhelmus B. 1904. “Hotels of Washington Prior to 1814.” Records of the Columbia Historical Society 7: 71106.Google Scholar
Burt, Ronald. 2009. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Caldeira, Gregory A., and Patterson, Samuel C.. 1987. “Political Friendship in the Legislature.” Journal of Politics 49 (4): 456–87.Google Scholar
Carson, Jamie L., and Hood, M. V. III. 2014. “Candidates, Competition, and the Partisan Press: Congressional Elections in the Early Antebellum Era.” American Politics Research 42 (5): 760–83.Google Scholar
Clinton, Joshua, Jackman, Simon, and Rivers, Douglas. 2004. “The Statistical Analysis of Roll Call Data.” American Political Science Review 98 (2): 355–70.Google Scholar
Colket, Meredith B. 1953–1956. “The Early Congressional Directories.” Records of the Columbia Historical Society, Washington, DC 53/56: 7080.Google Scholar
Cooley, E. 1829. A Description of the Etiquette at Washington City. Philadelphia, PA: LB Clarke.Google Scholar
Coppock, Alexander. 2016. “Information Spillovers: Another Look at Experimental Estimates of Legislator Responsiveness.”—Corrigendum. Journal of Experimental Political Science 3 (2): 206–8.Google Scholar
Earman, Cynthia D. 1992. “Boardinghouses, Parties and the Creation of a Political Society: Washington City, 1800–1830.” Master’s Thesis. Louisiana State University.Google Scholar
Earman, Cynthia D. 2000. “Remembering the Ladies: Women, Etiquette, and Diversions in Washington City, 1800-1814.” Washington History 12 (1): 102–17.Google Scholar
Fowler, James H. 2006. “Connecting the Congress: A Study of Cosponsorship Networks.” Political Analysis 14 (4): 456–87.Google Scholar
Fowler, James H., Heaney, Michael T., Nickerson, David W., Padgett, John F., and Sinclair, Betsy. 2011. “Causality in Political Networks.” American Politics Research 39 (2): 437–80.Google Scholar
Gamm, Gerald, and Shepsle, Kenneth. 1989. “Emergence of Legislative Institutions: Standing Committees in the House and Senate, 1810-1825.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 14 (1): 3966.Google Scholar
Goldman, Perry M., and Young, James Sterling. 1973. The United States Congressional Directories, 1789–1840. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark S. 1973. “The Strength of Weak Ties.” American Journal of Sociology 78 (6): 1360–80.Google Scholar
Green, Constance M. 1962. Washington; Village and Capital, 1800–1878. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hershberger, Ethan, Minozzi, William, and Volden, Craig. 2018. “Party Calls and Reelection in the U.S. Senate.” Journal of Politics 80 (4): 1394–99.Google Scholar
Imai, Kosuke, and Kim, In Song. 2019. “When Should We Use Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference in Longitudinal Data?American Journal of Political Science 63 (2): 467–90.Google Scholar
Jackman, Simon. 2017. pscl: Classes and Methods for R Developed in the Political Science Computational Laboratory. R package version 1.5.2. United States Studies Centre, University of Sydney. Sydney, Australia. https://github.com/atahk/pscl/.Google Scholar
Jacob, Kathryn Allamong2010. King of the Lobby: The Life and Times of Sam Ward, Man-about-Washington in the Gilded Age. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John. 1973. Congressmen’s Voting Decisions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H. 2011. “The Relational Determinants of Legislative Outcomes: Strong and Weak Ties between Legislators.” Journal of Politics 73 (3): 887–98.Google Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H., and Gross, Justin H.. 2014. “Measurement and Theory in Legislative Networks: The Evolving Topology of Congressional Collaboration.” Social Networks 36: 97109.Google Scholar
Kernell, Samuel. 1977. “Toward Understanding 19th Century Congressional Careers: Ambition, Competition, and Rotation.” American Journal of Political Science 21 (4): 669–93.Google Scholar
Leifeld, Philip, Cranmer, Skyler J., and Desmarais, Bruce A.. 2018. “Temporal Exponential Random Graph Models with btergm: Estimation and Bootstrap Confidence Intervals.” Journal of Statistical Software 83 (6). https://www.jstatsoft.org/article/view/v083i06.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindstädt, René, Wielen, Ryan J. Vander, and Green, Matthew. 2016. “Diffusion in Congress: Measuring the Social Dynamics of Legislative Behavior.” Political Science Research & Methods 5 (3): 511–27Google Scholar
Liu, Christopher C., and Srivastava, Sameer B.. 2015. “Pulling Closer and Moving Apart: Interaction, Identity, and Influence in the U.S. Senate, 1973 to 2009.” American Sociological Review 80 (1): 192217.Google Scholar
Maltzman, Forrest, Sigelman, Lee, and Binder, Sarah. 1996. “Leaving Office Feet First: Death in Congress.” PS: Political Science and Politics 29 (4): 665–71.Google Scholar
Mann, Thomas E., and Ornstein, Norman J.. 2006. Broken Branch: How Congress is Failing America and How to Get It Back on Track. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Martis, Kenneth C., Rowles, Ruth Anderson, and Pauer, Gyula. 1989. The Historical Atlas of Political Parties in the United States Congress, 1789-1989. New York: Macmillan Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Masket, Seth E. 2008. “Where You Sit Is Where You Stand: The Impact of Seating Proximity on Legislative Cue-Taking.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 3: 301–11.Google Scholar
Matthews, Donald R., and Stimson, James A.. 1975. Yeas and Nays: Normal Decision-Making in the U.S. House of Representatives. New York: Wiley InterScience.Google Scholar
McKibbin, Carroll R. 1992. “Biographical Characteristics of Members of the United States Congress, 1789-1979.” ICPSR 7428. http://www.icpsr.umich.edu/icpsrweb/ICPSR/studies/7428.Google Scholar
McPherson, Miller, Smith-Lovin, Lynn, and Cook, James M.. 2001. “Birds of a Feather: Homophily in Social Networks.” Annual Review of Sociology 27: 415–44.Google Scholar
Minozzi, William, and Volden, Craig. 2013. “Who Heeds the Call of the Party in Congress?Journal of Politics 75 (7): 787802.Google Scholar
Minozzi, William, Song, Hyunjin, David, M. J. Lazer, Neblo, Michael A., and Ognyanova, Katherine. 2020. “The Incidental Pundit: Who Talks Politics with Whom, and Why? American Journal of Political Science 64 (1): 135–51.Google Scholar
Noel, Hans, and Nyhan, Brendan. 2011. “The ‘Unfriending Problem’: The Consequences of Homophily in Friendship Retention for Causal Estimates of Social Influence.” Social Networks 33: 211–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parigi, Paolo, and Bergemann, Patrick. 2016. “Strange Bedfellows: Informal Relationships and Political Preference Formation within Boardinghouses, 1825–41.” American Journal of Sociology 122 (2): 501–31.Google Scholar
Pasley, Jeffrey L. 2002. The Tyranny of Printers: Newspaper Politics in the Early American Republic. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.Google Scholar
Paullin, C. 1921. “Abraham Lincoln in Congress, 1847-1849.” Journal of the Illinois State Historical Society (1908-1984) 14 (1/2): 8589.Google Scholar
Peart, Daniel2018. Lobbyists and the Making of US Tariff Policy, 1816−1861. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T. 2005. Spatial Models of Parliamentary Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Santoro, Lauren Ratliff. 2017. “Choosing to be Changed: How Selection Conditions the Effect of Social Networks on Political Attitudes.” PhD diss. The Ohio State University.Google Scholar
Riley, Padraig. 2014. “The Lonely Congressmen: Gender and Politics in Early Washington, DC.” Journal of the Early Republic 34 (2): 243–73.Google Scholar
Ringe, Nils, Victor, Jennifer Nicoll, and Carman, Christopher J.. 2013. Bridging the Information Gap. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Ringe, Nils, Victor, Jennifer Nicoll, and Gross, Justin H.. 2013. “Keeping Your Friends Close and Your Enemies Closer? Information Networks in Legislative Politics.” British Journal of Political Science 43 (3): 601–28.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Jon C., and Sinclair, Betsy. 2012. “Estimating the Causal Effects of Social Interaction with Endogenous Networks.” Political Analysis 20 (3): 316–28.Google Scholar
Scofield, Merry Ellen. 2006. “The Fatigues of His Table: The Politics of Presidential Dining during the Jefferson Administration.” Journal of the Early Republic 26 (3): 449–69.Google Scholar
Sheffer, Lior, Loewen, Peter John, Suroka, Stuart, Walgrave, Stefaan, and Sheafer, Tamir. 2018. “Nonrepresentative Representatives: An Experimental Study of the Decision Making of Elected Politicians.” American Political Science Review 112 (2): 302–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shelden, Rachel A. 2013. Washington Brotherhood: Politics, Social Life, and the Coming of the Civil War. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press Books.Google Scholar
Steinhauer, Jennifer. 2013. “A Lunchroom Called Capitol Hill.” New York Times, March 5.Google Scholar
Thompson, Margaret Susan. 1985. The “Spider Web”: Congress and Lobbying in the Age of Grant. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Wang, Peng, Pattison, Philippa, and Robins, Garry. 2013. “Exponential Random Graph Model Specifications for Bipartite Networks: A Dependence Hierarchy.” Social Networks 35 (2): 211–22.Google Scholar
Winkle, Kenneth J. 2013. Lincoln’s Citadel: The Civil War in Washington, DC. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Wojcik, Stefan. 2018. “Do Birds of a Feather Vote Together, or Is It Peer Influence?Political Research Quarterly 71 (1): 7587.Google Scholar
Young, James Sterling. 1966. The Washington Community, 1800–1828. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Zagarri, Rosemarie. 2013. “The Family Factor: Congressmen, Turnover, and the Burden of Public Service in the Early American Republic.” Journal of the Early Republic 33 (2): 283316.Google Scholar
Zelizer, Adam. 2019. “Is Policy-Making Contagious? Evidence of Cue-Taking from Two Field Experiments in a State Legislature.” American Political Science Review 113 (2): 240–52.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. A Map of Seating at Mrs. Pittman’s from a Letter from Rep. Amasa Parker to His Wife, December 31, 1837, 25th CongressNote: Clockwise from the top, they are Rep. Hugh Anderson (D-ME), Rep. John Fairfield (D-ME), Rep. Heman Allen (W-VT), Rep. Hopkins Holsey (D-GA), Rep. Millard Fillmore (W-NY), Mrs. Fillmore, Rep. Zadock Pratt (D-NY), Mrs. Pratt, Mrs. Prentiss, Sen. Samuel Prentiss (W-VT), Rep. John H. Prentiss (D-NY), Mrs. Knight, Sen. Nehemiah Knight (W-RI), Mrs. Birdsall, Rep. Samuel Birdsall (D-NY), Rep. Robert McClelland (D-NY), Rep. Amasa Parker (D-NY), Rep. Albert White (W-IN), and Rep. Andrew Buchanan (D-PA). Finding aid retrieved from http://hdl.loc.gov/loc.mss/eadmss.ms008132.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Counts of Residences of Members of the House of Representatives (left panel) and Residents Themselves (right panel) by Year and Type of ResidenceNote: Both panels reveal that boardinghouses were the dominant residence type for members, emerging early on. Yet by the Late Jacksonian (1837–1849) and into Antebellum era, boardinghouses fell out of favor, gradually being replaced by hotels.

Figure 2

Table 1. Logistic Regression Models of Coresidence

Figure 3

Figure 3. Average Marginal Effects of Lagged Agreement on the Probability of Coresidence in Percentage PointsNote: Bars depict 95% intervals based on bootstrapping over congressional sessions.

Figure 4

Table 2. Logistic Regression Models of Repeated Coresidence

Figure 5

Figure 4. Estimated Effects of Coresidence on Agreement in Percentage PointsNote: Bars depict 95% intervals. Estimates are calculated using inverse probability of treatment weighting, with the block bootstrap over sessions.

Figure 6

Figure 5. Estimated Effects of Coresidence on Agreement in Percentage PointsNote: Bars depict 95% intervals. The subgroups of dyads differ in terms of both tie strength and presence of a new member.

Figure 7

Figure 6. Results of 1,000 Simulated Placebo Tests Using All Residences That Did Not Experience a Death of a ResidentNote: Residences that did experience a death are excluded. The panel on the left displays a histogram of the (bootstrapped) p-values from these tests. The vertical dashed line indicates p = 0.05. The panel on the right displays a histogram of the estimated placebo effects, and the solid vertical line indicates the observed estimate of 0.072. Consistent with the design assumptions, only 5% of placebo p-values are less than or equal to 0.05, and only 1.6% of placebo estimates exceed the actual estimated effect.

Supplementary material: Link

Minozzi and Caldeira Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Minozzi and Caldeira supplementary material

Minozzi and Caldeira supplementary material

Download Minozzi and Caldeira supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 267.2 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.