Introduction
European health systems are in a continual state of regulatory tension with regard to drug needs and development. One of the most severe pressure points in this tension is the regulation and approval of new prescription drugs. For example, whereas the pharmaceutical industry views the creation of a new drug (or new molecular entity, NME) from a profit and market-oriented perspective, health organisations are under pressure to keep drug costs down and focus on the efficacy and safety of the drug, patients often want the latest new drug (often promoted via the media) to feel confident that they are getting the best care possible, while governments struggle to balance these competing interests and demands.
Is there a way to balance the needs of health actors, the pharmaceutical industry and patients regarding drug innovation and therapeutic advance? Or are European health systems condemned to oscillate between the varying perspectives? Moreover, what can the EU do about it?
This article will explore whether part of the answer to these difficulties lies in the creation of a ‘medical need clause’ (MNC) that redirects pharmaceutical research and activities towards the creation of NMEs which respond to a clear medical need as defined by health actors, agencies and patients. Variants of MNCs have been used in the past and had a clear impact on both prescription drug usage and expenditure. This article briefly discusses the background of the current situation, examines the definition, function and technical challenges of the MNC, explores some of the EU and national attempts to create MNC-like regulatory policies, and discusses the potential for MNC development in the EU.
Background
Getting the balance right in health policy is a difficult, political and continual process. In the field of prescription drug policy, the balance in Europe has increasingly tipped in favour of a more market-oriented approach, which has downplayed the importance of comparative efficacy and patient need. In 2001, a meeting of the International Society of Drug Bulletins (ISDB) drafted a Declaration on therapeutic advance in the use of new drugs. It stated that pharmaceutical regulation, conflating technological innovation with increased efficacy, does not take sufficient account of the added therapeutic value (ATV) of the medicines it assesses (ISDB, 2001: 1). Subsequent analysis noted that much of European pharmaceutical legislation was developed in the aftermath of the Thalidomide tragedy and consequently focuses primarily upon drug safety and, more recently, pharmacovigilance and adverse reaction reporting. New drugs must prove they have an acceptable risk–benefit balance but are not required to be compared with the prevailing alternative; comparative benefit, if a priority at all, is of secondary concern (Wieseler, Reference Wieseler2011: 2).
In their recent article, Light and Lexchin (Reference Light and Lexchin2012: 1) contend that, although the pharmaceutical industry insists that it is suffering from an ‘innovation crisis’ characterised by declining returns on research and development (R&D) investment, the ‘real innovation crisis’ lies in the lack of new drugs which have ATV. They argue that the measure of innovation preferred by the pharmaceutical industry and claimed to be in decline has, in fact, been relatively stable since the mid-1990s. What has declined, Light and Lexchin note, is the approval of drugs which offer clinical advantages over those already on the market. This position was supported by a 2002 report in La Revue Prescrire, which found that of the new drugs and indications approved in France between 1981 and 2001, only 12% represented a therapeutic advance (La Revue Prescrire, 2002: 58). By 2012, that figure had fallen to just 8%, while nearly 16% were judged to be more harmful than beneficial (La Revue Prescrire, 2012: 107). Further studies have shown the ratio of industry investment in R&D to expenditure on marketing to be 1:19, revealing a ‘hidden business model’ whereby minor variations on existing drugs are focused on and fiercely marketed to encourage prescription and consumption (Light and Lexchin, Reference Light and Lexchin2012: 2). These drugs are trialled on patients with little prospect of significant therapeutic advance and often against control groups administering a placebo (Wemos, 2013). The global price pursued by pharmaceutical companies is now commonly challenged by governments – see, for example, the 2-year moratorium and ‘claw back’ mechanisms introduced in the United Kingdom’s Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme (Wise, Reference Wise2013). It is also increasingly negotiated to reflect national circumstance, as in the case of Sofosbufir, a ‘blockbuster’ hepatitis C drug, which has been allocated country-specific pricing based on GDP per capita (Raftery, Reference Raftery2014). These downward pressures on price are certainly increasing in the prevailing financial climate, but the fundamental interest of the industry remains in manufacturing drugs which offer the most attractive profit margin and return on investment.
Despite the absence of clinical superiority, expenditure on pharmaceuticals comprises a significant proportion of government health budgets, accounting for an average 17% of health expenditure across OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development) countries in 2011 and increasing by almost 50% in real terms since 2000 (OECD, 2011: 154; OECD, 2013: 160). Public funds for healthcare are therefore increasingly stretched by rising pharmaceutical expenditure, while public money is used to fund more than four-fifths of research to discover new medicines worldwide (Light and Lexchin, Reference Light and Lexchin2012: 2). Thus, pharmaceutical development in Europe has reached a point where public money is being used for the development of drugs which offer little clinical advantage and are a drain on the financial resources of national health systems. But is a MNC part of the answer?
What is a MNC? The Norwegian Model
A MNC might take many forms and be designed in a number of ways, but it can be explained by reference to its earlier configuration in Norwegian pharmaceutical law. The Norwegian MNC (behovsparagraf) stated that, ‘only products which are needed will be allowed on the Norwegian market’ and allowed the national authority to limit the number of products available, ‘based on the philosophy that a smaller number of rationally chosen drugs would be easier to manage and more effective. The authorities could insist that new drugs had a better benefit–risk ratio than those already on the market’ (Norris, Reference Norris1998: 69).
Whilst in place, the Clause resulted in a smaller market and reduced pharmaceutical expenditure (Håkonsen et al., Reference Håkonsen, Horn and Toverud2009: 278). For example, between 1981 and 1983, the MNC enabled Norwegian authorities to reject 40% of applications for market authorisation, citing the MNC in 60% of these decisions, and limited the number of drugs on the market to around 2200, compared with a range of 7000 to 25,000 in non-Nordic European countries (Jøldal, Reference Jøldal1986: 665; Andrew et al., Reference Andrew, Jøldal and Tomson1995: 46). However, upon joining the European Economic Area in 1994, Norway was forced to abandon its MNC in order to comply with the dominant regulatory framework in Europe. The resulting growth in the size of the drug market was less than feared but still led to some problematic drug usage and care outcomes (Lu et al., Reference Lu, Hernandez, Abegunde and Edejer2011: 17; Brooks and Geyer, Reference Brooks and Geyer2015).
As such, the aim of a MNC is to stop products that have no ATV from coming onto the market, by requiring that new drugs demonstrate such ATV, constitute a therapeutic advance or are clinically superior to existing alternatives. These terms are used interchangeably in the literature and embody roughly the same notion – that new drugs are not automatically an improvement on existing treatments. The extent of a new medicine’s improvement should be measured according to the added value for the patient, the healthcare system and society as a whole derived from consuming the new drug instead of the older alternative.
What might be the goal of a MNC?
In preventing unnecessary or less innovative medicines from coming onto the market, a MNC might serve a number of purposes.
From a health systems perspective, a MNC should help to control the level of pharmaceutical spending within a health system by limiting the development of so-called ‘me-too drugs’ – drugs that are ‘minor variations of drugs already on the market (Angell, Reference Angell2004: 21) and which consume R&D resources and diminish incentives for innovation (Hollis, Reference Hollis2004: 1). It can be argued that allowing me-too drugs, and therefore encouraging competition and duplication within the same therapeutic class of medicine, might increase doctor and patient choice, offer a drug more easily tolerated by certain groups of patients, or even reduce expenditure by encouraging price competition (Garattini, Reference Garattini1997). However, when these drugs are brought onto the market and heavily promoted as the originator drug goes ‘off patent’, the potential to increase consumption of the more expensive me-too drug is likely to outweigh potential cost savings (Morgan et al., Reference Morgan, Bassett, Wright, Evans, Barer, Caetano and Black2005). By encouraging the creation of a regulatory environment where it is less profitable to develop drugs that are unlikely to be therapeutic advances, socially responsible (rather than market-oriented) research and innovation would be incentivised (Nathan, Reference Nathan2007: 304).
There are also ethical considerations, such as reducing the number of unnecessary clinical trials (Simon, Reference Simon2000: 1; Garattini and Bertele, Reference Garattini and Bertele2007; Light et al., Reference Light, Lexchin and Darrow2013: 9). Moreover, a MNC might also go some way to addressing the ethics of using public money to fund research which does not lead to a clinically superior innovation. In the current system, most R&D money is spent developing drugs that are molecularly different but therapeutically similar, but this would seem to be an inefficient use of public health resources (Light and Lexchin, Reference Light and Lexchin2012: 2; Light, Lexchin and Darrow, 2013: 4).
Technical challenges when defining and measuring the value of new drugs
Central to the design and effective implementation of a MNC are the definitions given to ‘therapeutic advance’ and ‘medical need’.
Following in the footsteps of the ISDB, we define ‘therapeutic advance’ as more than just product innovation. As the ISDB argues, the term innovation covers three concepts: the commercial concept of any newly marketed me-too product; the technological concept of any industrial innovation, for example in biotechnology; and the concept of therapeutic advance – ‘a new treatment that benefits the patient when compared to previously existing options’ (ISDB, 2001: 1). This understanding encourages the identification of therapeutic advance as a separate value by, as the ISDB states, assessing the efficacy, safety and convenience of all new drugs, and considering these values in the broader context of cost and quality (ISDB, 2001: 2; Wieseler, Reference Wieseler2011: 1).
Therapeutic advance is also commonly embodied in the term ‘clinically superior’. The United States Food and Drug Administration defines clinically superior drugs as those that are ‘shown to provide a significant therapeutic advantage over and above that provided by an approved…drug’.Footnote 1 Similarly, within the EU framework, Regulation 847/2000 on orphan drugs defines such medicines as those which provide a ‘significant therapeutic or diagnostic advantage over and above that provided by an authorised orphan medicinal product’.Footnote 2 It goes on to provide that such advantage might be demonstrated in ‘greater efficacy than an authorised orphan medicinal product’, noting that ‘direct comparative clinical trials are generally necessary’.Footnote 3
As shown, when determining therapeutic advance, a regulatory body might take into account a range of factors. In addition to those mentioned above, these might also include: patient convenience, encompassing changes in the administrative route of a given drug; societal impact, for example where a drug tackles social challenges such as alcoholism; health systems impact, to put pharmaceutical spending in the context of health system financing and sustainability; individual impact, balancing the gains of individual affected patients against the opportunity cost of procuring a drug and; comparative effectiveness, requiring all drugs to be compared to the existing or next best alternatives.
Medical need builds on the notion of therapeutic advance, reflecting the public interest in medicines which treat the health scourges of modern society and improve the health outcomes of the population at large. Though definitions of the two concepts are interrelated, medical need can be considered a broader concept, embodying societal need as well as clinical benefit.
Though a MNC does not currently exist in Europe, tools for classifying drugs according to their therapeutic value have been developed by some medicines agencies and by journals such as Prescrire (Vitry et al., Reference Vitry, Shin and Vitre2013: 2). Some examples also exist at member state level and the Italian case is briefly elaborated below by way of illustration.
The Italian model
The model used by the Italian Medicines Agency (AIFA) to decide upon qualification for the reimbursement system first divides new drugs into three categories according to therapeutic target – those aimed at serious diseases (such as cancer), those aimed at risk factors for serious disease (such as hypertension) and those aimed at non-serious diseases (such as allergic rhinitis) (AIFA, 2007: 2). Once a severity class has been assigned, each drug is assessed on two criteria: (1) the availability of existing treatments, ranging from none currently available, to some resistant subgroups, to treatments already exist and (2) the extent of the therapeutic effect, ranging from greater benefit, to partial benefit, to minor or temporary benefit (AIFA, 2007: 3). The degree of innovation of a new drug is established by a combination of scores and weightings, which ensure that the label ‘innovative’ is only assigned to those medicines that offer the patient additional therapeutic benefits in relation to those already available. These are drugs that are considered to fulfil a medical need and serve the public interest.
How might an MNC fit into EU-level market authorisation policy?
The law and regulatory policy governing pharmaceuticals in Europe is a multi-level interaction of national, EU and international practices and principles (Hancher, Reference Hancher1990: 10; Abraham and Lewis, Reference Abraham and Lewis2000: 95; Hervey and McHale, Reference Hervey and McHale2004: 286). At the EU level, some MNC-style elements are already embodied in market authorisation regulation, where the EU has a strong competence.
Market authorisation of medicinal products for human use
Pharmaceutical companies that wish to put a product on the market of an EU member state must first obtain a market authorisation. There are two types of authorisation in the EU – community authorisations, which are issued by the Commission (supported by the European Medicines Agency EMA) for the entire territory via the ‘centralised procedure’, and national authorisations, which are issued by national competent authorities. In 2013, the EMA gave positive opinions on 79 out of 86 applications for market authorisation via the centralised procedure, compared with 57 out of 68 in 2012 (EMA, 2015).
The amended Directive 2001/83/EC on the Community code relating to medicinal products consolidates and clarifies the provisions relating to authorisations via the mutual recognition procedure (MRP). This is used where an authorisation has already been granted in one member state and the company wishes to market the product in other member states without submitting identical applications. Article 26 states that authorisation shall be refused if:
(a) “The risk–benefit balance is not considered to be favourable; or
(b) Its therapeutic efficacy is insufficiently substantiated by the applicant; or
(c) Its qualitative and quantitative composition is not as declared”.Footnote 4
Although therapeutic efficacy must be demonstrated by the pharmaceutical company, it is not required to be of any given advantage or improvement on existing treatment.
Regulation 726/2004Footnote 5 gives more detailed and specific guidance on the market authorisation processes and establishes the centralised (Community) authorisation procedure. Centralised authorisations are compulsory only for certain types of drugs. Currently, these include:
“orphan medicinal products and any medicinal product for human use containing an entirely new active substance…for which the therapeutic indication is the treatment of acquired immune deficiency syndrome, cancer, neurodegenerative disorder or diabetes…also…products… for which the therapeutic indication is for the treatment of auto-immune diseases and other immune dysfunctions and viral diseases”.Footnote 6
The following paragraph makes the Community procedure optional for medicinal products, which:
“…although not belonging to the abovementioned categories, are nevertheless therapeutically innovative. It is also appropriate to allow access to this procedure for medicinal products which, although not innovative, may be of benefit to society or to patients if they are authorised from the outset at Community level”.Footnote 7
Similarly, a medicinal product may be granted an authorisation if ‘the medicinal product constitutes a significant therapeutic, scientific or technical innovation or…is in the interests of patients…at Community level’.Footnote 8 Furthermore, Regulation (EC) 507/2006Footnote 9 recognises that if there is an ‘unmet medical need’ and the product provides a major therapeutic advantage then the EU may grant marketing authorisations on the basis of less complete data and subject to specific ‘conditional marketing authorisations’.Footnote 10Footnote 11
These excerpts demonstrate that some notion of medical need is already embodied in EU pharmaceutical policy. Drugs that target certain categories of diseases, in particular those representing some of the greatest scourges on European health systems, are given priority on the basis that they are ‘worth more’. Similarly, the idea that new drugs might be ‘in the interest’ of patients or of value to society is explicitly referenced – existing legislation prioritises drugs fulfilling these criteria only in the context of the centralised procedure, but by institutionalising such categories lays the foundations for their potential operation in other parts of the legislative framework.
Conclusions from the EU level: a feasible role for a MNC?
As mentioned above, the EU has already legislated concepts of ‘therapeutic efficacy’, ‘risk–benefit balance’ and a centralised structure for encouraging ‘therapeutically innovative’ or ‘socially beneficial’ health technologies. It even has concepts of ‘medical need’. In other areas, such as clinical trials and orphan drug regulation, concepts of a comparative, ‘significant therapeutic or diagnostic advantage over and above that provided by an authorised…product’Footnote 12 have also been introduced. However, despite all of these developments, establishing a MNC remains a politically fraught process. Attempts to establish MNC-like regulations in clinical trials have been blocked on several occasions within the European Parliament (Garattini and Bertele, Reference Garattini and Bertele2004: 89). The earlier Clinical Trials Directive, for instance, promisingly stated that trials could only be conducted if anticipated therapeutic benefit outweighed risk but this provision failed to stem the proliferation of trials for me-too drugs and might even be argued to have encouraged production of drugs within the same, pre-tested therapeutic area. In 2014 a new Clinical Trials Regulation was adopted – though, on balance, it weakened the role of therapeutic value, during the legislative process a number of amendments posed contained elements of MNC- and ATV-related ideas, indicating continued political support for these concepts.Footnote 13
How might a MNC fit into national-level pricing and reimbursement policy?
The EU governs a substantial portion of pharmaceutical regulation but does not have exclusive control. It is implicit in Article 168 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the EU (TFEU) that national health policy in those matters covered by the Treaty cannot develop along totally separate national lines, but that some elements of multi-level coordination are required (Hervey, Reference Hervey2001: 1). Moreover, the core area of financing and organisation remains a national competence – for pharmaceuticals, this is most crucially reflected in the regulation of pricing and reimbursement, where some elements of a MNC can also be seen.
A 2007 report by the Pharmaceutical Forum found that assessment methods among member states remain very different, with each having developed its own model for evaluating the therapeutic value of new drugs and taking account of this in the setting of drug prices (European Commission, 2007: 6). The report identified two main approaches:
“In some countries…prices are freely set upfront by the applying companies. The set price is then one of the input factors for the assessments that follow…In other countries the process starts with an upfront assessment…which in first place focuses on therapeutic/clinical benefits. This assessment is the basis for fixing prices”.
The report concludes that many member states offer fast-track procedures for medicines considered to bring ATV and that in both of the approaches identified above, where therapeutic value is identified, ‘a price premium vs comparator products can be allowed and reimbursed. The assessments are usually used to define the size of this price premium’.
In recent years, value-based pricing (VBP) has emerged as a more transparent and comprehensive way of determining the price at which drugs should be purchased within a given health system. In essence, VBP equates value in health to the health outcome achieved per euro (or relevant currency) spent on the intervention employed. Furthermore, a recent European Parliament study on access to and costs of pharmaceuticals also recommends that VBP be incorporated into the reimbursement schemes at member state and, where applicable, EU level (European Parliament, 2011: 72).
Drug prices are currently published by pharmaceutical companies, using calculations based on the US market. Since drug companies are keen to maintain the same prices in all countries, to avoid parallel importing, this system automatically out-prices governments in less developed countries and puts pressure on the healthcare budgets of any countries with a lower income per head than the United States (which is all bar Norway, Switzerland and Luxembourg). In response to this unsustainable practice, governments have sought to encourage generics, establish price controls and, more recently, move towards a model of clinical and cost-effectiveness assessment (Raftery, Reference Raftery2013: 1). The United Kingdom was, until recently, leading the way in the development of a VBP model to take account of the social benefits of drugs, such as the relief on the burden of carers (Raftery, Reference Raftery2013; Hawkes, Reference Hawkes2014). However, the system is currently stalled, pending consensus among the parties involved.
A recent study on the definition of ‘value’ in 14 member countries of the OECD found that the way in which value is determined differs markedly between states. Of particular relevance is whether or not the country uses economic evaluation – those that do (such as Sweden, Norway and the United Kingdom) tend also to take account of patient utility, whereas those who do not (such as Italy and France) tend not to consider it (Paris and Belloni, Reference Paris and Belloni2013: point 147). The report also found that, in practice, wider social perspectives are often not taken into account, with the exception of the Swedish system and that most countries use VBP as a way of encouraging innovation (Paris and Belloni, Reference Paris and Belloni2013: point 150). Fundamentally, the conclusions reached suggest that it is not yet possible to determine the impact that VBP is having, but that ‘the practice of VBP often appears to be more of an art than a science’ and that this could be damaging to the encouragement of true innovation (Paris and Belloni, Reference Paris and Belloni2013: 157).
Examples from the national level: the German case
The German pharmaceutical market has historically been seen as an early launch market, but the reforms enacted in 2011 have cast uncertainty on this position. The pricing and reimbursement system within the German healthcare reform – AMNOG – imposes substantial change upon the pharmaceutical industry, favouring innovative medicines producers and putting a greater focus on evidence-based medicine. The new parameters impact significantly on the potential pricing of medicines. Whereas companies used to set the price of reimbursement freely, this price is now subject to negotiation if the regulatory authority finds the drug to be worth less. Drugs that are considered to have a therapeutic benefit – receiving a score of one to four – will be accepted for price-negotiation, meaning that the pharmaceutical company may secure a price premium above that of the relevant therapeutic alternative. Meanwhile, drugs that are rated five or six on the scale will not qualify for negotiation and the company must accept the price offered by the German reference-pricing system. The final price may be set higher than the imposed reimbursement price but any difference would have to be paid by the patient. Implementation of the AMNOG is underway – preliminary data reveal that in the 78 judgements made in the period to September 2013, 1% of the drugs evaluated had less benefit than existing treatments, 55% offered no additional benefit, 24% provided minor additional benefit and 12% had considerable additional benefit; no drugs were found to offer a major benefit to patients (Buko Pharma, 2013: 7).
Conclusions from the national level: a feasible role for a MNC?
Similar to the EU, there are a number of aspects that clearly link to some form of MNC. National systems of pricing and reimbursement are evaluating and comparing the clinical and therapeutic value of drugs in order to determine their price, reimbursement level and/or inclusion on a recommended list of drug products. Value-based pricing represents the latest development of this trend. Moreover, many states are actively fast-tracking drugs that are identified has having ‘significant added therapeutic value’ through the regulatory process. Furthermore, similar to actions at the EU level, some member states are also willing to give a ‘price premium’ to stimulate the development of these drugs. Hence, though there is obvious variety at the national level, the general regulatory tendency towards greater openness of data, increased comparative analysis, improved balancing between ATV and price and growing use of VBP shows that there is a surprising degree of convergence between the EU and member state levels.
General conclusion and implications: what role for a MNC in Europe?
In examining the academic literature and legislative framework concerning a potential EU MNC, a number of interesting aspects emerge.
Despite the remarkable diversity of EU and national legislation, there seems to be a growing convergence within the EU and member state regulation towards various forms of MNC-type provisions and policies. This is clearly evident at the EU level and from the small selection of member state provisions explored. A full exploration of member state regulation would be necessary to confirm this.
Though often seen as a form of ‘negative’ regulation inhibiting the development of non-innovative ‘me-too’ drugs (as in the Norway case above), much of the existing EU regulation is actually ‘positive’ regulation – attempting to stimulate the activities of the pharmaceutical industry towards more therapeutically valuable research, innovation and development activities. This is particularly true at the EU level where the ‘carrot’ of one unified regulatory mechanism for the entire EU can be used to stimulate the development of new therapeutically innovative and socially beneficial drug products. In addition, at the national level, the use of ‘premium pricing’ arrangements would obviously have a stimulating effect as well. Hence, one must view the creation of a new EU MNC as a ‘carrot and stick’ approach to pharmaceutical regulation.
For the foreseeable future, due to continual technological changes, innovations and the need to regulate them, the arena of drug regulation at the EU and national levels will continue to be a politically divisive and difficult one, pitting economically concentrated interests against large scale public actors (national health systems), patient interest groups and the needs of society as a whole. A MNC will do little to resolve this fundamental tension. In general, using James Q. Wilson’s classic definitions of regulatory politics (Wilson, Reference Wilson1980), European drug regulation policy exhibits elements of both entrepreneurial politics, where the costs of regulation are concentrated on the pharmaceutical industry (inability to make profits from ‘me-too’ drugs, greater advertising activity, etc.) but the benefits are diffused throughout society (healthier drug usage and better health outcomes), and interest group politics, where the costs and benefits of regulation are concentrated and large political/economic actors have a great deal at stake (the pharmaceutical industry vs national health system actors, for example).
It is this combination of interests and actors, which defines the policy process in pharmaceuticals, giving the Commission and the industry lobby primacy. With regard to a MNC, the focus on larger societal health needs and the bringing together of diffuse strands of EU drug regulation policy are clearly a way of strengthening the public voice in EU health policy and it is no surprise that MNC-style provisions are being advocated by an increasing number of entrepreneurial EU public health organisations (Wemos, 2013).
The final questions to ask are, how would it be implemented and will it work? As discussed in the introduction, EU pharmaceutical legislation forms the central hub of regulation and governance in drug development, but it must operate in accordance with the broader EU principles (free movement, competition, etc.), must respect national competence, particularly in the areas of pricing and reimbursement, and must balance with related policy areas (single market, patents, etc.). Hence, a European MNC could take a variety of forms and be linked in to a range of policy areas. For example, a MNC could be introduced as part of most of the legislative provisions concerning pharmaceuticals. At the point of market authorisation, as in the Norwegian model, it could be contained within Directive 2001/83/EC and Regulation 726/2004, providing an additional requirement which new drugs must satisfy and demonstrate their fulfilment of in order to be marketed in the EU. A review of how innovation is defined in pharmaceutical regulation and policy could achieve many of the goals of a MNC, as could a provision stating that public money can only be used to fund research on drugs with ATV. A provision in the EU clinical trials framework, or national pricing and reimbursement policies, could have a similar effect.
Fundamentally, its potential for success depends upon the continual ability of entrepreneurial EU public health actors to work with large national health actors and European institutions to form an alliance that can continually pressure the European and global pharmaceutical industry to recognise the importance of public health needs and interests. Maintaining this alliance over a longer period of time is the best way to make certain that any form of EU MNC will have a significant and long-term impact in the evolving labyrinth of EU health policy.
Acknowledgements
This paper is based on a project commissioned by Wemos and undertaken by the European Public Health Alliance. The authors would like to thank Annelies den Boer, Ella Weggen, Leonardo Palumbo, Zoltán Massay-Kosubek and Katrine Holt for their input into the original project and their kind support in its further development. Eleanor Brooks is kindly supported by a grant from the Economic and Social Research Council.