Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T08:35:55.784Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Supply of Policy Information in the World Trade Organization: Cross-National Compliance with One-Time and Regular Notification Obligations, 1995–2014

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 February 2019

Jan Karlas
Affiliation:
Department of International Relations and the Peace Research Center Prague, Institute of Political Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University
Michal Parízek*
Affiliation:
Department of International Relations and the Peace Research Center Prague, Institute of Political Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This text presents the first systematic quantitative descriptive and explanatory account of World Trade Organization (WTO) member states’ compliance with their one-time and regular notification obligations. The system of around 170 notifications, through which states are obliged to provide to the WTO relevant information on their policies, constitutes a key mechanism of transparency in the global trade regime. Based on data for the one-time and regular obligations from the years 1995–2014, we seek to map and explain the variation in the degree to which states comply with these obligations. Descriptively, we identify enormous differences in the compliance values of states, ranging from compliance well above 80% to below 20%. To explain those differences, we test five theoretical explanations that concentrate on the trade policy preferences of states and on their institutional characteristics. The empirical findings support four of the tested explanations. In particular, they highlight the relevance of states’ administrative capacities and membership in international organizations (IOs). In addition, the empirical analysis shows that compliance levels are strongly positively connected with the economic size of the members.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Jan Karlas and Michal Parízek 2019

1. Introduction

Policy transparency, defined as a state of affairs in which national trade policies are open and predictable, represents one of the key norms and objectives of the global trade regime (WTO, 2018; see also Hoekman and Kostecki, Reference Hoekman and Kostecki2009: 40–46). It establishes a crucial condition for business relations and investments across borders, as well as for the credibility of interstate cooperation (Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2012; Keohane, Reference Keohane1984; Plummer and Tafti, Reference Plummer, Tafti, Forssbaeck and Oxelheim2014). In order to increase policy transparency, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the World Trade Organization (WTO) as its successor have reinforced over the years the obligation of their members to publish their national laws and regulations, international obligations, and other political measures connected with trade (Collins-Williams and Wolfe, Reference Collins-Williams and Wolfe2010: 557).

One of the key tools in the WTO transparency toolbox is notifications that WTO member states are supposed to submit to the organization regarding new or changed laws and regulations associated with their trade policies. The volume of those notification requirements is really extensive and unique, comprising approximately 170 different obligations.Footnote 1 However, the fulfillment of notification obligations varies considerably across WTO members. A cursory look indicates that even though there are members with compliance rates of above 80%, the vast majority of states show a sizable compliance shortfall, and around half of WTO membership shows compliance of less than 50%, often significantly less than that. As we will discuss later, sizable compliance gaps are shown by some of the major trading nations. This contrasts with the fact that, as pointed out above, transparency is crucial for the development of international trade, as well as for effective cooperation between states in this area. The lack of compliance with notification obligations has been repeatedly declared to be an important problem by WTO Director-General in his annual report (World Trade Organization, 2017a: 106). In fact, recent internal WTO documents indicate that problems with the functioning of the transparency system are emerging as a major issue of political contention within the WTO, not least among the core actors of the system such as the United States (USA), the European Union (EU), and China.Footnote 2 The need to remove the deficiencies in the provision of notifications was also emphasized by 44 WTO member states that together formed the group known as the ‘Friends of the System’ (Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2017b).

In spite of the clear practical as well as theoretical relevance of the issue, research dealing with the transparency function of the WTO has not yet adequately addressed the existing cross-national variation in the compliance of WTO member states with their notification obligations. A large part of this research has concentrated on analysis of the Trade Policy Review Mechanism (TPRM), the WTO's central transparency platform. A number of contributions, written largely in the 1990s, examined the formal design of the TPRM (see e.g. Blackhurst, Reference Blackhurst, Hilf and Petersman1988; Mavroidis, Reference Mavroidis1991; Qureshi, Reference Qureshi1990). More recent literature has also explored the practical functioning of the Mechanism (Ghosh, Reference Ghosh2010; Laird and Valdés, Reference Laird, Valdés, Narlikar, Daunton and Stern2012; Karlas and Parízek, Reference Karlas and Parízek2017; Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2017a: 721–724). Concerning the committees of the WTO General Council and their role in transparency, Andrew Lang and Joanne Scott explored their practical functioning, but without analyzing the variation in the submission of notifications (Lang and Scott, Reference Lang and Scott2009). So far, the only coherent and more in-depth analysis of the delivery of notifications by WTO member states has been carried out by Robert Wolfe. In several papers, Wolfe gives a thorough analysis of the workings of the WTO notification system, paying explicit attention to state compliance with notification requirements (e.g. Collins-Williams and Wolfe, Reference Collins-Williams and Wolfe2010; Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2013). Wolfe's work made a seminal and highly valuable contribution to the study of the fulfillment of WTO notification obligations. Still, his analysis does not, in empirical terms, cover quantitatively a large number of notification obligations across all WTO members, but rather looks at some selected areas, groups of states, and periods of time. Nor does he test the effects of factors that might influence the submission of notifications using a more sizeable amount of quantitative empirical data.

In this paper, we seek to help fill this gap. We concentrate on an analysis of the variation in the fulfillment of notification requirements by WTO member states, or more specifically the so-called one-time and regular notification obligations for which compliance can be established in a quantitative manner. As we elaborate further in the text, it is not possible to systematically measure compliance with the ad-hoc notification obligations, which constitute around half of the body of obligations. Our quantitative analytical framework also does not consider the quality of the content of the submitted information. Yet, what we do provide is the first systematic mapping of the submissions of all the approximately 22,000 regular and one-time notifications over the first 20 years of the WTO (1995–2014).

To explain the variation in the fulfillment of these one-time and regular notification obligations, we test several theoretical explanations. To a large extent, we formulate these explanations by drawing on the existing literature on the provision of information by states to international institutions. One of the perspectives offered by this literature highlights the role of the commitment of states to a respective international institution (Mitchell, Reference Mitchell1998). Accordingly, one part of our theoretical framework concentrates on the interest of states in trade liberalization and, hence, also in a proper functioning of the global trade regime. We understand trade dependence and trade openness as core manifestations of states’ interest in trade liberalization and, hence, also in the proper functioning of the global trade regime. Furthermore, we also take into account the perspectives that focus on the institutional characteristics of states. Following these perspectives, we expect compliance to be associated with the states’ levels of democracy (Hollyer et al., Reference Hollyer, Rosendorff and Vreeland2011) and administrative capacity (Chayes and Chayes, Reference Chayes and Chayes1993). In addition to these accounts, we hypothesize that compliance should be associated with the membership of states in international organizations (IOs), given that membership is likely to enhance adaptation of states to active participation in multilateral cooperation. We assess the explanatory power of these factors using OLS and panel regression analysis. The empirical results confirm the validity of four of the five tested explanations, and they especially highlight the relevance of states’ administrative capacities and involvement in IOs. We understand both these variables as being connected with the states’ capacities to respond to tasks and demands associated with their membership in IOs. In addition, the empirical findings show that the level of compliance also strongly correlates with one of the control variables – the size of national GDP.

The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we provide a short introduction to the system of notification obligations in the WTO. In Section 3, we formulate a set of hypotheses explaining the variation in compliance with the obligations. In Section 4, descriptive evidence on compliance, cross-country and sectoral, is provided. Finally, in Section 5 we present the results of our empirical assessment of the hypotheses.

2. The System of Notifications in the WTO

Notification obligations as the central issue addressed in this paper represent one of the key means to increasing transparency of trade policy. In general terms, transparency in a political environment is usually understood as the state of affairs when entitled or interested actors dispose with relevant information about a respective political action (e.g. Forssbaeck and Oxelheim, Reference Forssbaeck and Oxelheim2014: 5–10). In the field of trade, policy transparency is concerned with the availability of information on the provisions and processes related to national trade policies (Plummer and Tafti, Reference Plummer, Tafti, Forssbaeck and Oxelheim2014). The WTO as such relates transparency to the degree to which national trade policies are open and predictable (World Trade Organization, 2018).

Transparency constitutes a factor that significantly affects the behavior of both firms and governments. Concerning firms, a key precondition of their involvement in international trade is their knowledge of the conditions in foreign markets, particularly of foreign tariffs and the rules applying to their products. Consequently, transparency in national trade policies decreases the resources that firms need to invest to obtain information about foreign markets (Handley and Limão, Reference Handley and Limão2012). In this way, transparency facilitates their entry into those markets and, therefore, also the growth of international trade. Furthermore, policy transparency reduces concerns that governments may have regarding respective compliance with the agreed terms of cooperation (Keohane, Reference Keohane1984: 92–96). When governments maintain their markets open, they do so with the precondition that their counterparts reciprocate. Hence, a government will normally view having information about the trade policies of other states as a precondition for its own cooperative behavior. This problem is exemplified by the current high-profile conflict between China, the USA, and the EU concerning the steel industry, and the lack of transparency of the various subsidy schemes and anti-dumping measures that states apply in this industry (World Trade Organization, 2017b, 2017d).

Let us describe the notification system that underpins the activity of Council committees in more detail, as it lies at the very core of our interest. WTO member states have a duty to notify the organization about the laws and regulations they adopt, and which either have something to do with the organization's treaties or affect other member states (Collins-Williams and Wolfe, Reference Collins-Williams and Wolfe2010; Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2013; World Trade Organization, 2017c). The principle of notifying about trade policy changes was introduced already by Article X of the GATT in 1947 (GATT, 1947). This principle was re-emphasized in 1979 by the ‘Understanding Regarding Notification, Consultation, Dispute Settlement, And Surveillance’ (GATT, 1979). Article 3 of the Understanding stipulates that member states should notify their counterparts about the adoption of trade measures affecting the operation of the GATT. Notification should occur before the respective decisions are taken. In case this is not possible, states are expected to provide notification of their measures ex-post. The contemporary system of notification obligations was further elaborated by the WTO decision ‘On Notification Procedures’ adopted in 1994 (World Trade Organization, 1994). The decision delimited a list of particular measures for which notification should be given. In addition, it also established a central registry of notifications.

The overall number of notification obligations currently reaches approximately 170, although for only around 120 of them it is possible to locate at least some submitted notification documents in the WTO online database system. Three basic types of notifications exist: one-time, regular, and ad-hoc. One-time notifications are submitted by member states only at the beginning of the notification process; practically speaking, they are due shortly after WTO accession. They provide an overview of the legislative measures that apply to a specific area of national trade policy, but also, for example, identify the relevant administrative contact points for business inquiries. Concerning some aspects of trade policy, states need to announce any changes made on a regular basis, by means of regular notifications. These are delivered semi-annually, once a year, or every other year. Ad-hoc notifications are used for the provision of information about changes in governments’ trade legislation and policies in selected areas. The rare hybrid form of ‘one-time and ad-hoc’ notifications then combines the initial one-time and the later ad-hoc component. The set-up of notification obligations reflects the WTO's general principle of special and differentiated treatment (SDT). The duty of individual countries to notify depends on their development status. While the majority of notifications concerns all members, some notification obligations are concerned only with the trade policies of developed countries and some others are related only to developing countries.

Figure 1 shows the distribution of the notification requirements, by types and main thematic areas of the WTO agenda. With regard to notification types, ad-hoc notifications account for 56.2% of all notification requirements. One-time and one-time and ad-hoc notifications follow with a share of 28.4%. The remaining 15.4% of obligations are represented by regular notifications. However, these figures do not correspond to the actual volume of submitted notifications, as for example regular notifications are submitted typically every year, and thus constitute a much larger share of all notification activity. Two thematic areas characterized by the highest number of notification obligations are trade in textiles (17%) and the protection of intellectual property rights (12%). These are followed by safeguards and services (9% each), agriculture (7%), and subsidies and countervailing measures (also 7%). Nevertheless, the use of the three types of notification requirements also varies across the individual thematic fields. To mention the most outstanding examples: whereas a large majority of notifications related to administrative border measures (such as customs valuation) are one-time notifications, the prevailing part of obligations connected with textiles, services, and intellectual property rights are ad-hoc notifications. Agriculture is the only area in which the majority of obligations are regular (periodic).

Notes: Ad-hoc obligations are depicted in the lightest color (bottom), one-time and ‘one-time and ad-hoc’ obligations in light color (middle) and regular obligations in dark color (top). The following thematic abbreviations are used: ADP – anti-dumping, AG – agriculture, BOP – balance-of-payments, GATS – services, LIC – licensing, MA – market access, PSI – preshipment inspection, RO – rules of origin, RTAs – regional trade agreements, SCM – subsidies and countervailing measures, SG – safeguards, SPS – sanitary and phytosanitary measures, STR – state trading enterprises, TBT – technical and safety regulations, TEX – textile goods, TPR – Trade Policy Review Mechanism, TRIMS – investment measures, TRIPS – intellectual property rights, VAL – valuation

Figure 1. All notification obligations – types and thematic areas

3. Theoretical Explanations

Let us now move to the theoretical core of our article, namely the identification of factors that we expect to influence states’ overall levels of compliance with their notification obligations. As we outlined in the introduction, since this is the first study to systematically quantitatively map compliance with one-time and regular notifications, we primarily seek to identify and explain the variation in the submission of notifications across WTO members. Our theoretical framework is thus designed with this purpose in mind. In contrast, we do not systematically explore the possible variation across policy areas of the WTO agenda. This task would require a rather different theoretical framework and a separate analysis.

We base our synthetic theoretical framework on explanations from the literature on the provision of information by states to international institutions. Our first two hypotheses are concerned with the trade policy preferences of states, whereby we consider the degree of their interest in the liberalization of trade to be particularly decisive for the level of their compliance with notification obligations (in line with the more general reasoning put forward by, e.g., Mitchell, Reference Mitchell1998). The relationship between interest in trade liberalization and compliance with notification obligations is relatively straightforward and simple. It stems from the fact that the WTO represents the basic institutional framework for the reduction of trade barriers on a global scale. As a result, those states that are characterized by a stronger interest in trade liberalization should be particularly determined to support the proper functioning of the WTO. For this reason, they should also display greater discipline in the fulfillment of notification obligations.

Of course, it is notoriously difficult to assess empirically the preferences of actors (e.g. Zürn, Reference Zürn1997), especially when the need to do so covers a large number of states – in our case, all WTO members. Hence, we resort to two key long-term, structural conditions of states’ involvement in the global trade regime to approximate their interests and preferences. These are trade dependence, or the trade–GDP ratio, and trade openness, reflecting the degree of tariff protection. Trade dependent countries should be particularly interested in trade liberalization as their economic welfare considerably depends on trade (Simmons, Reference Simmons1997: 188–189). Concerning trade openness, a low level of trade barriers indicates that a state has a strong interest in open trade.Footnote 3 After all, it has been argued that open trade policy leads to the strengthening of liberal preferences of key domestic constituencies, and thus strengthens the overall liberal orientations of states’ foreign economic policies (Milner, Reference Milner1987). Neither of these two proxies measures directly states’ preference for trade liberalization, but in combination they provide a very solid account of which states have direct material interests in the maintenance of a relatively open global trade.

H1:

A state's compliance with WTO notification obligations increases with its trade dependence.

H2:

A state's compliance with WTO notification obligations increases with its trade openness, i.e. with the lowering of trade barriers.

Our second line of theorizing is concerned with the institutional characteristics of the WTO members. First, we draw on an argument that generally links the level of democracy with greater policy transparency (Hollyer et al., Reference Hollyer, Rosendorff and Vreeland2011). In democratic systems, the survival of the government depends on the election result and, therefore, on the welfare of voters. For this reason, political representatives in democracies are more likely to make their policies transparent in order to provide the voters with information about the relationship between policy decisions and their welfare. In line with this, we would expect countries with a higher level of democracy to be more active in the WTO notification system:

H3:

A state's compliance with WTO notification obligations increases with the level of democracy.

Third, we introduce two other variables that are also connected with the institutional characteristics of states, but enhance the ability of states to respond to their procedural obligations in international institutions. The first of these variables is domestic administrative capacity. As was underlined by one theoretical stream in the research on compliance with international commitments, this compliance can be shaped considerably by the (lack of) bureaucratic capacity of the state (Chayes and Chayes, Reference Chayes and Chayes1993). To be sure, a limited administrative capacity decreases the ability of a state to implement policy significantly more than its ability to report on this implementation. However, since poorly functioning administrative systems are characterized by general deficiencies, they are likely to also have shortcomings related to information obligations. In fact, the idea that deficiencies in bureaucratic capacity can influence the submission of notifications has already been pointed out by Wolfe in his analysis of notifications delivery (Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2013: 18). As he notes, some member states fail to deliver their notifications due to a lack of knowledge or data, or to an inability to engage in cross-departmental cooperation. This reasoning leads to the next hypothesis:

H4:

A state's compliance with WTO notification obligations increases with its domestic administrative capacity.

As notification obligations documents in the WTO are not prepared by a country's Geneva diplomatic mission, but rather by various domestic agencies, domestic administrative capacity is especially relevant concerning compliance with notification obligations.

In addition, we hypothesize that a state's compliance with notification obligations is also likely to increase with the extent to which it is exposed to institutionalized multilateral policy-making through its membership in IOs. This expectation is grounded in organizational theory, which claims that state behavior is shaped by its long-term institutional adaptation (Powell and DiMaggio, Reference Powell and DiMaggio1991). Membership in IOs exposes states to this type of adaptation. It entails for a state a rather extensive range of policy and administrative tasks and opportunities. These tasks involve procedural obligations that a state has to fulfill, e.g. by the formulation of negotiation positions or the provision of reports. However, participation in multilateral policy-making also provides a state with institutional opportunities to advance its interests, or to seek to resolve some policy problems. States that are relatively more exposed to multilateral policy-making need to react more frequently and intensively to tasks and opportunities related to this policy-making. As a result, participation in various forms of multilateral policy-making becomes part of the standard operating procedures of their foreign policy-making systems (Allison, Reference Allison1971). This implies that they regard various activities associated with IO membership, including the preparation and supply of reports and notifications, as rather standard and routine operations.Footnote 4 Consequently, they are also likely to participate more in such activities:Footnote 5

H5:

A state's compliance with WTO notification obligations increases with the size of its membership in IOs.

These are the five factors that we deem theoretically most relevant and interesting. Nonetheless, in our explanatory analysis we also control for several other potentially relevant factors. The first of these factors is the overall size of the economy (GDP). This factor reflects the fact that states differ in the size of their economies by (several) degrees of magnitude, thus distinguishing between the principal economic powers, mid-sized economies, and smaller states. We find it more suitable to treat economic size as a control variable, rather than one of the key explanatory variables, since it can be immediately associated with various lines of reasoning. First, it is plausible to view it as a factor that captures state support for the existence and preservation of the trade regime. Countries with larger markets and bigger volumes of exports could be more interested in constructing trade institutions (Baccini et al., Reference Baccini, Dür and Elsig2015: 768; Krasner, Reference Krasner1976). This interest may also manifest itself through their better discipline in the submission of notifications. Second, the exact opposite reasoning can be put forward, whereby states with larger markets are, ceteris paribus, less concerned with open trade and access to other markets.Footnote 6 Finally, the size of the economies of states captures not only their economic interests but, equally importantly, also their power in the international system. Hence, large economies might also display a stronger discipline in their submission patterns, simply due to their possession of greater economic resources. Given its theoretical indeterminacy, we do not include economy size as a well-theorized predictor. Nevertheless, in our empirical analysis we of course control for it as a variable of major potential relevance.

The second factor we will control for is the overall level of the country's development and the level of GDP per capita, as its conventional proxy. Highly economically developed countries generally have better capacity to fulfill the transparency obligations connected with their participation in international institutions, as stated in hypothesis H4. In this vein, we use GDP per capita in one of the models as an alternative measure of state administrative capacity. However, the catch-all variable of GDP per capita captures much more than that, and its inclusion enables us to control for a broader range of phenomena connected with economic development. The third and fourth factors we control for are the length of a state's membership in the WTO and the number of obligations that apply to each of the states. For the former, an intuitive expectation could be that new members might have difficulties with the notifications system at the beginning, and that a certain learning period might be necessary for them to comply fully. On the other hand, latecomers may be required to compile relevant notification information in their accession process, and hence find it unproblematic to comply at least with their one-time notifications to start with.Footnote 7 In the face of this indeterminacy, we again resort to treating this variable as a control rather than a well-theorized predictor. For the latter, we simply want to control for the overall magnitude of the notifications submissions task.

4. Sectoral and Cross-National Variation in Compliance Rates, 1995–2014

In this section, we proceed to the presentation of descriptive empirical evidence with regard to states’ compliance levels. As we mentioned, there are in total around 170 obligations. Out of these, for 121 obligations it is possible to identify positively at least some submitted documents in the WTO database. Since we focus in this paper on a quantitative analysis of states’ compliance with their obligations, we only include in this analysis one-time and regular notifications. For these, establishing compliance is possible and fairly straightforward, as we can rely on the information provided by the Secretariat itself. There are in total 39 notification obligations for which compliance is actually systematically traced by the Secretariat of the WTO.Footnote 8 The authoritative information on compliance or failure to comply with these 39 obligations is made available via the regular publication of annexes to the G/L/223 documents series. These documents, published yearly, each contain between 40 to 80 pages of tables detailing, for each of the tracked obligations, whether or not the obligation was applicable to a concrete WTO member in the given year and whether the member fulfilled it. The tables also trace compliance over time, so it is possible to establish whether a certain obligation was fulfilled with a delay. Hence, our measure of compliance is a direct translation and aggregation of the data provided by the WTO itself.

The source documents of the G/L223 series, available in pdf and doc formats, were manually translated into table format by the authors of this article, in cooperation with a group of research assistants. The validity of the procedure was verified by double-checking our records from the Secretariat reports with the information available in the WTO Documents Online database. The resulting dataset totals 22,121 country-year obligations, each of which is marked as either unfulfilled, fulfilled with a delay, or fulfilled. From that information we calculate directly the compliance rate, which takes on the values 0 (unfulfilled), 0.5 (fulfilled with delay), and 1 (fulfilled as prescribed).Footnote 9 For regular notifications, the aggregate compliance value is calculated as the arithmetic mean over all the years in which notification applied. For one-time notifications, this value of 0/0.5/1 is simply the final compliance rate.

The strength of this approach is that we use for our calculation the authoritative information by the WTO secretariat, we do not need to rely on own estimates. There are caveats, however. First, we need to stress that this information does not portray the substantive quality of the content of the submitted documents. Even if a state submits a notification, its content may not be factually accurate or complete. The member may either fail to provide accurate and exhaustive information, or intentionally choose not to do so. After all, the ‘quality’ of the submitted notification information constitutes an important part of the discussions between the US and China in the high profile case of the steel industry and its subsidies, mentioned earlier.Footnote 10

As a second caveat, it should be noted that the G/L/223 series only covers notifications pertinent to trade in goods.Footnote 11 Hence, to complement these data, we also collected information on the number of submissions pertinent to all the other regular and one-time obligations not covered in the G/L/223 series. There are further 24 such obligations. For these, we can assess the number of individual notification submissions, but not, strictly speaking, the states’ compliance levels (as we cannot judge with certainty if a specific notification applied to a specific state in a given year). For the sake of conceptual clarity, we focus in the explanatory part on the 39 obligations for which positive authoritative information on state compliance is available. However, we also run a separate analysis including these additional 24 obligations and, as we show later, the results are virtually identical.Footnote 12

Finally and importantly, as already indicated, our analysis of compliance omits the sizable group of ad-hoc notifications. The assessment of members’ compliance with these notifications is not compatible with our quantitative focus. For one-time and regular notifications, there is a clear specification available of when they should be delivered. This specification is provided by the very nature of these obligations and by the authoritative information published by the WTO Secretariat, as elaborated above. This paves the way for the analysis of these two types of obligations on a quantitative, large-scale basis. By contrast, fulfillment of the ad-hoc notifications requirements is conditioned by a deep, qualitative analysis of individual cases. To judge the submission of ad-hoc notifications, one would first need to identify, by looking in a detailed way into the changes in the policies, regulations, or legislation of the given state, the situations in which these notifications were actually due.Footnote 13 Such an approach cannot be apparently applied on a large scale. Hence, we concentrate on the quantitative analysis of one-time and regular notifications and leave the analysis of compliance with ad-hoc notifications obligations for further research.

Having said that, for the sake of completeness of the empirical overview of notifications submissions we also collected the data on the numbers of all submitted ad-hoc notifications. There are in total more than 43,000 such submissions, pertaining to 63 obligations.Footnote 14 The submissions were extracted from the WTO Documents Online database. While we cannot meaningfully include them in the analysis of compliance, we at least provide, in our additional models, a basic comparison of the ad-hoc notifications submissions with the identified patterns of compliance with regular and one-time obligations. By providing this overview, we hope to facilitate any further (most likely qualitative) research on ad-hoc notifications, which is certainly a worthwhile agenda. Yet, to be clear, these are not included in our measure of compliance.

Having defined our core concept and the dependent variable, let us proceed to basic descriptive results. The average compliance rate of WTO members with the regular and one-time notifications obligations, over the entire period and across all states, is equal to 0.52 (median 0.54, standard deviation (sd) 0.24). This value is calculated as an unweighted average across obligations, not obligation-years, hence it gives equal weight to one-time and to regular notifications. This procedure is also applied in the calculation of compliance rates used in the explanatory analysis. As an alternative, we can also calculate the average across obligation-years, and thus count multiple values for regular obligations. If we adopt this procedure, the value of the overall compliance rate would drop to 0.39 (median 0.33, sd 0.23). The difference is due to the fact that regular obligations have systematically lower compliance values (mean 0.37) than one-time obligations (mean 0.59), a matter we return to later on in our explanatory analysis. In spite of the significant difference in the overall values obtained with this procedure, the actual cross-state variation is very similar, and the two procedures produce highly correlated results (r = 0.91***).

The temporal perspective on the compliance rates is provided in Figure 2. Figure 2(a) shows that there is virtually no development in the overall compliance rate over a period of 20 years. While we do see some fluctuation in average compliance rates, no trend can be discerned. This is equally the case when we only consider regular obligations, as in Figure 2(b). Having said that, the de facto composition of compliance obligations has changed over time, as most one-time notifications had been due in late 1990s, right after the creation of the WTO. In the more recent periods, the non-periodic obligations covered in our dataset only concern the newly acceding members. For regular obligations, this is of course not the case, as they are supposed to be submitted continuously.

Figure 2. Overall compliance rates (a) and compliance rate across regular obligations only (b)

Table 1 depicts the sectoral variation in compliance rates. The first column captures the overall compliance across both regular and one-time obligations falling within a certain area, combined. Columns 2 and 3 then do so individually for regular and onetime notifications. The column “No. of data points” gives, for each area, the number of instances in which an obligation existed in a given year for a given state. This is the number of situations in which a notification should have been submitted, indicating the overall magnitude of the obligation. The sectors with the highest compliance in regular and one-time notifications are sanitary and phytosanitary measures (SPS) and safeguards, both with compliance rates above 0.85. In addition, a high compliance of above 0.6 is shown in trade-related investment measures, agriculture, rules of origin, and anti-dumping. In contrast, a low compliance of below 0.5 is obtained in customs valuation, import licensing, and state trading enterprises. The one regular obligation falling into the broad category of market access (the obligation is on the reporting of quantitative restrictions) shows a compliance rate of less than 10%. This extremely low value, but also low compliance scores in other sectors, has recently been highlighted by some members as a sign of problems in the transparency system in the WTO (cf. document (World Trade Organization, 2017e: 1). We should stress again, though, that these compliance scores do not cover ad-hoc notifications, which in some sectors (particularly SPS and TBT) are quantitatively dominant.

Table 1. Compliance rates and obligations (regular and onetime) across sectors

It is not our goal to explain this cross-sectoral variation in detail in this paper, as a very different theoretical framework and data set would be needed for that. However, we find that a part of this variation can be explained by considering the volume of the individual notification obligations. On the level of the 39 individual obligations, there is a clear negative relationship between the number of obligation instances and compliance (r = −0.47**), i.e. primarily yearly regular obligations have, on average, lower compliance.Footnote 15 A good deal of variation across the 13 sectors of obligations can then be explained with the types of obligations within each sector. Having said that, one example of a sector that clearly does not fit this pattern is agriculture, as it has at the same time by far the highest volume of notification obligation instances, and one of the highest compliance rates with one-time and regular notifications obligations.Footnote 16 Somewhat similarly, obligations in areas of anti-dumping and subsidies and countervailing measures also show relatively high compliance rates of 0.6 or more, for regular and one-time notifications, while at the same time also imposing on the states a relatively high burden.

Let us now turn to the variation in compliance across WTO members, as mapping and explaining this variation is at the core of our interest. In Table 2, we provide the compliance rates for all WTO members as a cross-section over the entire period 1995–2014. Once again, the measure is directly translated from the compliance evaluations provided by the Secretariat. What we see is an enormous level of variation across WTO membership, in fact with an almost uniform distribution of states in the range of between approximately 0.2 and 0.8.

Table 2. Overall compliance rates across all WTO members, 1995–2014

Notes: The column “Compl.” indicates the overall compliance rate, across all one-time and regular obligations. State name abbreviations are the standard ISO 3166-1 alpha-3 codes.

For the list of countries and their abbreviations, see: https://unstats.un.org/unsd/tradekb/knowledgebase/country-code.

The top of the rankings is occupied by the most export-oriented WTO members, namely Taiwan and Hong Kong, with Singapore close behind them. Very high compliance scores are also obtained by some of the largest members, most notably the EU, Canada, Japan, and later also Australia and the USA. From the major ‘non-Western’ trading powers, China is absent from the top of the rankings, while India ranks only 35th, with a compliance score of just over 0.7 (for a discussion on China and transparency in the WTO, see Wolfe, Reference Wolfe2017a). In contrast, Brazil and especially Russia score much higher. The top of the ranking also includes several smaller Latin American countries, while others, such as South Korea or the wealthy oil-exporting United Arab Emirates and Saudi Arabia, score surprisingly low.

5. Explanatory Findings

We now proceed to the empirical test of the hypotheses regarding states’ compliance. The core tests we present are based on a cross-sectional OLS regression analysis. This choice is justified by three facts. First and most importantly, only regular notifications have a meaningful time-dimension, as one-time notifications were mostly due in 1990s. Hence, there is no obvious way to aggregate regular and one-time notifications in a panel-data structure. Second, we do not observe any major changes in compliance rates over time that would indicate a need to systematically study the time-dimension of the phenomenon. Third, most of the variation in our predictors is across states, not over time. In spite of long-term changes in, for example, administrative capacity or in trade dependence in some countries, the systematic stable differences across countries are empirically much more prominent. Hence, a fixed effects model specification, for example, would be rather unsuitable for modeling the effects of our predictors of interest. Yet, as robustness assessments, and to bring in the time dimension at least for regular obligations, we also include in our results two pooled OLS and random effects panel regression models.

How do we operationalize our predictors of interest? The degree of trade dependence (H1) is operationalized as the share of exports and imports, combined, in GDP (variable Trade dependence). Trade openness (H2) is operationalized as the applied tariff rate (variable Trade openness, all data are from the World Bank World Bank, 2015). Of course, in the interpretation, the variable needs to be reversed, as high tariffs indicate low openness. The level of democracy (variable Democracy) is measured with the Polity IV democracy score (data from Polity IV Project, 2010) and, as a robustness test, with the transparency index of Hollyer et al. (Reference Hollyer, Rosendorff and Vreeland2011). Domestic administrative capacities are measured using the Worldwide Governance Indicators of the World Bank (2015), specifically the indicator measuring government effectiveness (variable Administrative capacity). The connection of states to the network of IOs is calculated as the number of IOs the state is a member of (variable IOs membership), based on data from the Correlates of War dataset (Pevehouse et al., Reference Pevehouse, Nordstrom and Warnke2004). Finally, data on GDP and GDP per capita (variables Log (GDP) and Log (GDPpc), respectively) are taken, again, from the World Bank (2015). For all the cross-sectional OLS models, we use country averages across the full 20 years period. The exception is IO membership, where we only use the data for year 2005.Footnote 17 For the estimation of the panel regression models, we of course use the full panel data.

So do our hypotheses find support in the empirical evidence? In Table 3, we present the results of six OLS regression models testing the hypotheses, with various specifications. All variables have been standardized to allow for a direct comparison of the magnitude of their effects on compliance. In all the models, we show (in brackets) robust standard errors and the models have been subjected to standard post-regression diagnostics. All the models show solid explanatory power, accounting for around two thirds of variation in states’ compliance.

Table 3. Regression analysis results

Notes: *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01; †p < 0.001; robust standard errors in brackets.

Model 1 includes the five core variables capturing the five hypotheses and the control for economic size (Log (GDP)). The model supports all our five hypotheses, although variables Trade dependence, Administrative capacity, and Democracy only show a significant effect at the 10% level of confidence. That means compliance rates increase with a state's Trade dependence and Trade openness, with Administrative capacity, with Democracy, and with IOs membership. Regression residuals suggest that the effect of the variable Trade dependence may be largely due to two extreme observations, Hong Kong and Singapore, a matter we will return to shortly.

In Model 2, we add the two additional control variables: the length of country membership in the WTO and the overall number of its notification obligations. Neither of these variables shows a significant association with compliance. However, their introduction leads all our hypothesized predictors except Trade dependence to show a fully statistically significant association with compliance at the standard 5% confidence level (Trade dependence maintains significance at the 10% confidence level). These results remain stable across the further model specifications presented below.

Model 3 replicates Model 2 but here we proxy the overall capacities of a state with its level of economic development (Log (GDPpc)). With this variable, we seek to assess two sets of problems. First, as mentioned, we use it as a broader proxy for state capacities. In addition, though, it helps us control for other phenomena connected to the overall levels of states’ economic development, beyond the factors already included in our previous models. The variable shows the expected positive effect on compliance, but it fails to reach the standard significance level. This suggests that while administrative capacities, narrowly defined, are systematically significant for states’ compliance, a broad level of economic development is not, all other things held equal. The same result holds also when we replace GDP per capita with the World Bank classification of countries by income group; no association of the level of economic development and compliance is discernible. In addition to this substitution, we have also replaced our measure of democracy – the Democracy score based on the Polity IV data – with the Transparency index introduced earlier (results are not reported in the table). This variable also shows a significant association with compliance, like the variable Democracy, but it has a significantly lower coverage of countries, so we prefer to stick to the Democracy score.

Model 4 again replicates model 2, but with the exclusion of Hong Kong and Singapore, with extremely high values of Trade dependence. As expected, the variable Trade dependence shows no effect in this model, as its power has indeed been driven to a large extent by these extreme observations. This testifies to the fact that trade dependence may be relevant in some specific cases, but does not seem to play a systematic role.

Comparing the relative magnitudes of the substantive effects, we see that the strongest predictor of compliance (in Model 4) is the economic size. If the (logged) size of the economy increases by one standard deviation, there is an associated rise in compliance of 0.45 standard deviations. The variable IOs membership has approximately half of the explanatory power, with a coefficient size of 0.23; Administrative capacity is somewhat weaker, with a coefficient size of just below 0.2. Finally, the effect of a change in compliance for the variables Trade openness and Democracy is just above 0.1 standard deviation, for a change in the predictor of one standard deviation. That means, from our five hypothesized predictors, IOs involvement and Administrative capacity have the strongest effect, while Trade openness and Democracy have weaker, yet still significant association with compliance.

In Models 5 and 6, we show the results separately for compliance with regular obligations only (Model 5) and with one-time obligations only (Model 6). While the previous insights mostly hold, across the models we identify two differences. First, while for regular obligations Administrative capacity is a major predictive factor, for non-regular obligations no systematic association of compliance with this variable is discernible. On the other hand, for non-regular obligations we see an association with states’ IOs membership, a factor that is not linked to compliance with regular obligations.

To provide greater insight into the observed compliance patterns, we present, in Table 4, a series of robustness tests and additional analyses. They mostly confirm the main findings but also point at some limitations and avenues for further research.

Table 4. Additional multiple regression tests

Notes: *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01; †p < 0.001; robust standard errors in brackets.

First, Model 7 simply replicates the analysis from Model 4 but with unstandardized coefficients, allowing for the assessment of the substantive significance of the effects. A lowering of the applied tariff rate by 10 percentage points (i.e. a rise in Trade openness) is associated with an increase in compliance of 0.06, i.e. 6 percentage points.Footnote 18 An increase in the IOs membership of 10 is associated with a compliance increase of 3 percentage points. Since the variable IOs membership has an average of 61 and a standard deviation of 17, this is highly relevant. A unit rise in the Administrative capacity score (ranging from around –2 to around 2) is associated with a 6-percentage-points increase in compliance, again a relatively large difference. A unit rise in the Democracy score (ranging from –10 to 10) is associated with a 0.5-percentage-point increase in compliance.

Second, models 8 and 9 are panel regression estimates replicating model 5. Within our framework, panel estimation is only meaningful for regular notifications, as one-time notifications do not have a substantial time dimension. While Model 8 is a pooled OLS, Model 9 is based on random effects estimation. Due to the dominant variation across countries, rather than over time, in most of our predictors and certainly the dependent variable, a fixed effects estimation would not be feasible (e.g. Bell and Jones, Reference Bell and Jones2015). Both panel regression models support the results presented earlier in the cross-sectional Model 5, showing a positive association between compliance with regular notification obligations and Administrative capacity and Democracy. The only difference is that the panel regression models do not show an association with Trade openness, which in the cross-sectional model was significant at a 10% level. As in Model 5, these are very intuitive results, where for the more demanding regular notifications the key predictors are Administrative capacity and Democracy.

Finally, Models 10 and 11 are substantively very different from all the other models in the analysis. Here our dependent variable is not compliance as such – the core interest in our paper. Instead, the dependent variable here is the aggregate number of submitted notifications by the respective state. In Model 10, it is the submission of all its one-time and regular notifications. In Model 11, we explore the submissions of ad-hoc notifications.

First, the purpose of Model 10 on one-time and regular notifications is to verify whether the results that we obtain when analyzing compliance as such are similar for the broader set of all one-time and regular notifications, including those that are not tracked by the Secretariat in the G/L/223 series (see our discussion in Section 4). That is, we also include the one-time and regular obligations for which we do not have authoritative information on compliance. In spite of this principal difference in the nature of the dependent variable in this model, the associations with the hypothesized explanatory factors are almost identical to the other models.Footnote 19 This suggests that also in the areas not covered by the G/L/223 series the patterns of regular and one-time notifications submissions are similar.

Second, for Model 11, the situation is different. The dependent variable in this model – the number of submissions of ad-hoc notifications – cannot be quantitatively associated with compliance, for reasons we discussed earlier. Hence, we only provide the model to offer a comparison with the previous results for regular and one-time notifications. The results indicate that indeed the patterns behind the submissions of ad-hoc notifications (not their compliance, as we cannot assess it) are significantly different. The only predictors that show an association with submissions are Trade openness and the size of the economy (Log (GDP)). Democracy, IOs membership, and Administrative capacity do not show a significant association with submissions. In addition to stressing the different nature of the dependent variable, we should highlight that the results may be also driven by the fact that the vast majority of the submitted ad-hoc notifications are in the SPS and TBT areas, and hence the patterns may be driven by the specificities of these sectors.

This is related to a more general point regarding the sectors. Our results, as presented in Tables 3 and 4, explain overall compliance patterns for the aggregates across all the sectors combined. The identified patterns, however, do not all hold in each individual sector and the relative explanatory power of the predictors varies across sectors. An explanatory framework that would seek to address compliance patterns within individual sectors would need to consider their specificities, the types of obligations in them, as well as the substantive demands of the individual notifications. These would then, most likely, also need to be modeled empirically with the use of additional sector-specific predictors.

Overall, the multiple regression results presented above support the validity of the theoretical reasoning presented in Section 3. There we hypothesized that compliance is likely to be connected with Trade dependence (H1), Trade openness (H2), Democracy (H3), Administrative capacity (H4), as well as IOs membership (H5). The subsequent empirical analysis supports all but the first hypotheses. It holds that Trade openness, Democracy, Administrative capacity, and Involvement in IOs are statistically significant factors in the majority of the four basic OLS models. The analysis of their substantive effects reveals that the level of compliance is relatively more strongly determined by Administrative capacity and IOs membership. In addition, we also identify a pattern whereby administrative capacities matter particularly for compliance with the more administratively demanding regular notifications, while adaptation to membership in IOs has a relatively greater effect on the compliance with one-time notifications. Finally, the fulfillment of notification obligations is connected with the simple economic size of the countries.

6. Conclusions

Policy transparency is one of the core norms of the global trade regime. For cooperation on trade matters to be durable, states need relevant information about the policies and behavior of their partners. In the WTO, the system of notification obligations serves this purpose; however, so far we have lacked a systematic descriptive and explanatory account of the compliance of WTO members with these obligations. This paper is an attempt to fill this gap. In order to uncover submission patterns that could be examined in an explanatory way, we first carried out a complex description, embracing all one-time and regular notification obligations. We find that compliance levels vary across states considerably, from compliance rates as low as below 20% to rates above 80%. The very low number of submitted notifications by a high number of the member states clearly shows that there are rather big gaps in the information that states actually provide through the WTO about their national policies. This is in line with the recently increasing prominence of the transparency mechanism in the discussions among WTO members (cf. JOB/GC/148).

To explain the variation in the level of compliance with notification obligations across states, we tested five theoretical explanations that incorporate as the key explanatory factors trade policy preferences of states and their institutional characteristics. The empirical analysis confirmed the validity of four of these explanations. In terms of substantive significance, states’ institutional characteristics – namely their administrative capacities and sizable membership in IOs – show a particularly strong effect. Furthermore, each of these two variables substantially contributes to the compliance with one of the two types of notifications. While adaptation to membership in IOs is strongly associated with the compliance with one-time notifications, administrative capacities contribute particularly to compliance with regular notifications. This pattern has a very meaningful interpretation. One-time notifications are prepared just once and, therefore, they do not require states to be generally administratively efficient to meet these obligations. The preparation of regular notifications is more demanding on the administrative capacity of the state, as it is based on the ability of the state to perform well not only occasionally, but in a repeated, enduring manner.

Taken together, these results enable us to provide also a more parsimonious interpretation, facilitated by the mutual affinity of the causal mechanisms related to administrative capacity and states’ membership in IOs. The influence of these two variables on the fulfillment of notifications requirements stems from the capacities of states to respond to their obligations arising from participation in international institutions. States characterized by strong administrative capacity are empowered to fulfill notifications requirements due to their competent administrative staff and functioning administrative mechanisms. States involved in a high number of IOs achieve a higher compliance with notification obligations because the preparation of inputs into multilateral policy-making has become part of the standard operating procedures of their foreign policy-making systems.

In practical terms, these findings suggest a possible direction for the efforts to improve the supply of notifications. Many states that have relatively higher deficits in the provision of notifications lack strong administrative capacities or are not exposed extensively to membership in IOs. This implies that non-compliance with notification obligations may result from the practical inability of states to meet their obligations rather than from their politically motivated unwillingness to do so. If this is the case, the scope of missing notifications could be at least partly decreased by further capacity building. After all, one of the functions of the WTO is to enhance the ability of countries lacking resources, i.e. developing countries, to understand the rules of the multilateral trade regime and to actively participate in it. In this way, it also seeks to improve the compliance with notification obligations, e.g. through the dissemination of information or by offering capacity-building training. The persisting deficiencies in the submission of notifications show that these activities have not been so far completely successful. Further capacity building efforts could help low capacity states increase their ability to submit notifications. Of course, no such positive effects can be expected when states chose not to comply.

As pointed out earlier, this paper does not cover all the aspects of the compliance with notification obligations in the WTO. In particular, it does not delve into the substantive quality of notifications and it does not explore compliance with the obligations to submit ad-hoc notifications. Concerning the substantive quality of notifications, further research should examine their accuracy and completeness by conducting a content analysis of the selected samples of notifications. This examination would enable us to analyze whether the states that comply with the obligations to submit notifications also provide in their notifications factually correct and exhaustive information. With regard to ad-hoc notifications, this paper only offered a basic description of the variation in the number of the submitted ad-hoc notifications, and not compliance with the requirements to provide them. The results show that the patterns behind the quantity of the submitted ad-hoc notifications are different from those behind the fulfillment of the obligations related to one-time and regular notifications. This only underscores the need to investigate to what extent and why WTO members submit ad-hoc notifications when they are due. This research task would be best conducted by in-depth case studies that would, by tracing the changes in national trade policies, identify the moments where ad-hoc notifications were due and subsequently analyze their actual provision.

Footnotes

Acknowledgments: This research was supported by research grant GA15-12533S ‘Member states in the WTO – preferences, compliance, and monitoring’, from the Czech Science Foundation (GA ČR).

1 What further increases the importance of the WTO notification system is that some free trade agreements (FTAs) have only weak or no notification requirements. This stresses the key role of the WTO in supplying information about national trade policies. We thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.

2 See the recent communications circulated by the USA, ‘Procedures to enhance transparency and strengthen notification requirements under WTO agreements’ (JOB/GC/148, October 2017), and by the EU, ‘Improving disciplines on subsidies notifications’ (TN/RL/GEN/188, May 2017), both identifying severe compliance gaps with notification requirements among WTO members. See also a related circulation by China on transparency in anti-dumping and countervailing proceedings, from June 2017 (TN/RL/GEN/190).

3 Let us reiterate that we regard trade dependence and trade openness as the best proxies for liberal trade preferences in the contemporary global regime for which, importantly, systematic empirical data are available. At the same time, we do not claim that, in empirical terms, all states that are important supporters of the reduction of trade barriers are highly dependent on trade or maintain low trade barriers. Our explanations are based on a deductive logic rather than on a historical experience or concrete empirical observations. We thank an anonymous reviewer of WTR for pointing this nuance out.

4 Alternatively, we could also link the fulfillment of notification obligations to the multilateral involvement of those domestic ministries that are primarily responsible for the issues related to WTO agreements. However, since the quantitative data on such a variable are not available, we limit our analysis of the country's general multilateral involvement.

5 It could be argued that IO membership itself reflects some further underlying causes that may also impact on compliance, i.e. that the relationship between IO membership and compliance is partially endogenous (we would like to thank the editor of WTR for pointing this to us). The existing literature identifies two factors as systematically contributing to higher IO membership, namely political regime and the level of economic development (Boehmer and Nordstrom, Reference Boehmer and Nordstrom2008; see also Shanks et al., Reference Shanks, Jacobson and Kaplan1996). To check the possible endogeneity problem, we include both the political regime and the level of economic development in our models, thus isolating the ‘net’ effect of IO membership. Furthermore, a correlation analysis reveals that statistically the relationship between IO membership and political regime (r = 0.2) and level of economic development (GDP per capita, logged, r = 0.35*) are rather weak.

6 We would like to thank an anonymous reviewer of the WTR for this point.

7 We are grateful for this point to an anonymous reviewer of the WTR.

8 The Secretariat identifies these as ‘notification obligations of a regular/periodic nature (i.e. semi-annual, annual, biennial or triennial) and notifications required on a “one-time-only” basis’ (document G/L/223/Rev. 23, p. 2).

9 We have also calculated compliance levels using an alternative procedure whereby belated submissions are given the score corresponding to the share of years for which they were reported as notified, over the sum of all the reported years. That is, if the Secretariat reported the given notification overall in ten yearly reports, and the submission was delayed by two years, the score would be 0.8 (instead of 0.5). The disaggregated country-obligation level compliance values across these two procedures are correlated extremely strongly (r = 0.96***), so the particular choice of calculation algorithm does not affect the results.

10 A good example is the exchange between China, the US, and the EU, regarding steel industry subsidies at the April 2017 meeting of the Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, as recorded in articles 138–144 of the minutes of the meeting G/SCM/M/101. We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for pointing us to this specific exchange.

11 In 1996 and 1997, corresponding documents were published as G/L/112 and G/L/112/Add. Since 1998, the document G/L/223/, with subsequent revisions, contains the data. The document traces ‘notification obligations of a regular/periodic nature (i.e. semi-annual, annual, biennial or triennial) and notifications required on a “one-time only” basis. It does not include ad-hoc notifications, that is, those which must be provided only if a certain action is taken. It also does not include those regular/periodic or “one-time” notification obligations listed in document G/NOP/W/2/Rev.1, relating to Rules of Origin (page 50, item 8), Regional Arrangements (page 52, item 13 and page 55, item 7), Balance of Payments (page 54, item 5) and the Integrated Database (page 52, item 15)’ (G/L/223, p. 2).

12 There are other sources of information about states’ notification activity. For example, the Secretariat reports for the Trade Policy Reviews (TPRs) of individual WTO members contain information about submitted notifications. Similarly, the WT/TPR/OV series of yearly overviews of the trading environment contains an overview of notification submissions. The same holds for the Integrated Trade Intelligence Portal (I-TIP) database. Yet, even these documents may only indicate compliance or non-compliance for regular and one-time notifications. For ad-hoc notifications, the documents contain information on the number of submitted notifications, including in separate sections for the very numerous SPS and TBT notifications (e.g. World Trade Organization, 2017a, sections 3.3 and 3.4). Yet, it naturally does not indicate compliance.

13 One example of such an approach is the recent detailed analysis of Chinese subsidy schemes in the steel industry, conducted by the United States and the EU, working through the annual reports of a set of relevant Chinese steel producers (document G/SCM/Q2/CHN/70).

14 However, out of the more than 43,000 submissions, in fact almost 38,000 pertain to only two obligations, one in the SPS (almost 18,000) and one in the TBT area (close to 20,000).

15 While one-time notifications can be technically simpler to fulfill, continuous, yearly monitoring of the relevant policies may be relatively more demanding. We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for highlighting the importance of this.

16 But that does not mean there are no laggards in this area either. For example, Turkey, an important agricultural producer, only shows compliance of just above 30% in this area (see also the report of the TPRM on Turkey, WT/TPR/S/331, p. 30). More broadly, even relatively higher levels of compliance, in cross-sectoral comparison, do not necessarily mean that the compliance levels in this area are seen as satisfactory (cf. G/AG/GEN/86/Rev.30).

17 The dataset covers the period 1995–2005. Hence, to maintain the symmetry of our analysis, we use the most recent data point (2005), which is also in the middle of our time frame.

18 Applied tariff is measured in units of per cent, i.e. a 100% tariff would be indicated with a value of 100, not 1.

19 The overall numbers of submitted one-time and regular notifications correlates strongly with the compliance rates proper (r = 0.87***).

References

Allison, GT (1971) Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis. London: Little, Brown & Company.Google Scholar
Baccini, L, Dür, A, and Elsig, M (2015) The Politics of Trade Agreement Design: Revisiting the Depth–Flexibility Nexus. International Studies Quarterly 59, 765775.Google Scholar
Bell, A and Jones, K (2015) Explaining Fixed Effects: Random Effects Modeling of Time-Series Cross-Sectional and Panel Data. Political Science Research and Methods 3, 133153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blackhurst, R (1988) Strengthening GATT Surveillance of Trade Related Policies. In Hilf, M and Petersman, E-U (eds.), The New GATT Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations: Legal and Economic Aspects. The Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers.Google Scholar
Boehmer, C and Nordstrom, T (2008) Intergovernmental Organization Memberships: Examining Political Community and the Attributes of International Organizations. International Interactions 34, 282309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chayes, A and Chayes, AH (1993) On Compliance. International Organization 47, 175205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins-Williams, T and Wolfe, R (2010) Transparency as a Trade Policy Tool: The WTO's Cloudy Windows. World Trade Review 9, 551581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forssbaeck, J and Oxelheim, L (2014) The Oxford Handbook of Economic and Institutional Transparency. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GATT (1947) General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. Available at https://treaties.un.org/doc/Publication/UNTS/Volume%2055/volume-55-I-814-English.pdf.Google Scholar
GATT (1979) Understanding Regarding Notification, Consultation, Dispute Settlement, and Surveillance. (L/4907), Available at www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/tokyo_notif_e.pdf.Google Scholar
Ghosh, A (2010) Developing countries in the WTO Trade Policy Review Mechanism. World Trade Review 9, 419455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handley, K and Limão, N (2012) Trade and Investment under Policy Uncertainty: Theory and Firm Evidence. NBER Working Paper No. 17790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoekman, B and Kostecki, M (2009) The Political Economy of the World Trading System: The WTO and Beyond. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hollyer, JR, Rosendorff, BP, and Vreeland, JR (2011) Democracy and Transparency. The Journal of Politics 73, 11911205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlas, J and Parízek, M (2017) Peer-Reviewing in International Institutions: States’ Activity in WTO Trade Policy Review Mechanism. Presented at the 10th Political Economy of International Organizations Conference, 12–14 January 2017, Bern, Switzerland.Google Scholar
Keohane, RO (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Krasner, SD (1976) State Power and the Structure of International Trade. World Politics 28, 317347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laird, S and Valdés, R (2012) The Trade Policy Review Mechanism. In Narlikar, A, Daunton, M, and Stern, RM (eds.), The Oxford Handbook on The World Trade Organization. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 463484.Google Scholar
Lang, A and Scott, J (2009) The Hidden World of WTO Governance. European Journal of International Law 20(3): 575614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mavroidis, PC (1991) Surveillance Schemes: The GATT's New Trade Policy Review Mechanism. Michigan Journal of International Law 13, 374.Google Scholar
Milner, H (1987) Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: Industry and the Making of Trade Policy in France and the United States during the 1970s. International Organization 41(4): 639665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, RB (1998) Sources of Transparency: Information Systems in International Regimes. International Studies Quarterly 42(1): 109130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pevehouse, JC, Nordstrom, T, and Warnke, K (2004) The COW-2 International Organizations Dataset Version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science 21(2): 101119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plummer, MG and Tafti, A (2014) ‘Transparency in International Trade Policy’, in Forssbaeck, J and Oxelheim, L (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Economic and Institutional Transparency. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 166178.Google Scholar
Polity IV Project (2010) Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2010, Center for Systemic Peace, www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity06.htm (accessed 30 September 2012).Google Scholar
Powell, WW and DiMaggio, PJ (eds.) (1991) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (1st edn), Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qureshi, A (1990) The New GATT Trade Policy Review Mechanism: An Exercise in Transparency or Enforcement. Journal of World Trade 23(3): 147160.Google Scholar
Shanks, C, Jacobson, HK, and Kaplan, JH (1996) Inertia and Change in the Constellation of International Governmental Organizations, 1981–1992. International Organization 50(4): 593627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, BA (1997) Who Adjusts?: Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy During the Interwar Years. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wolfe, R (2013) ‘Letting the Sun Shine in at the WTO: How Transparency Brings the Trading System to Life’, World Trade Organization, Staff Working Paper ERSD-2013-03, https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2229741 (accessed 1 September 2017).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfe, R (2017a) Sunshine over Shanghai: Can the WTO Illuminate the Murky World of Chinese SOEs?. World Trade Review 16(4): 713732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfe, R (2017b) ‘America is Right about the WTO, but for the Wrong Reasons’, Financial Times, 20 December 2017, www.ft.com/content/ef8598c6-e4ad-11e7-a685-5634466a6915 (accessed 4 March 2018).Google Scholar
World Bank (2015) World DataBank, http://data.worldbank.org/.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (1994) ‘Decision on Notification Procedures’, www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/33-dnotf_e.htm (accessed 3 September 2017).Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2017a) ‘Overview of Development in the International Trading Environment: Annual Report by Director-General (WT/TPR/OV/20), www.wto.org/english/news_e/news17_e/trdev_04dec17_e.pdf (accessed 20 March 2018).Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2017b) ‘Steel Concerns Continue to Dominate Discussions on Anti-Dumping at WTO’, www.wto.org/english/news_e/news16_e/anti_01nov16_e.htm (accessed 13 November 2017).Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2017c) ‘E-Campus WTO: Transparency and the WTO: Notification Obligations’, https://ecampus.wto.org/admin/files/Course_712/Module_3356/ModuleDocuments/Module%203_print.pdf.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2017d) ‘Subsidies – Questions from the United States and the European Union to China Pursuant to Article 25.8 of the Agreement’, Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures, G/SCM/Q2/CHN/70.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2017e) ‘Procedures to Enhance the Transparency and Strengthen Notification Requirements under WTO Agreements’, Council for Trade in Goods, JOB/GC/148.Google Scholar
World Trade Organization (2018) ‘WTO Glossary: Transparency’, www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/glossary_e/glossary_e.htm (accessed 2 October 2018).Google Scholar
Zürn, M (1997) Assessing State Preferences and Explaining Institutional Choice: The Case of Intra-German Trade. International Studies Quarterly 41(2): 295320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. All notification obligations – types and thematic areas

Notes: Ad-hoc obligations are depicted in the lightest color (bottom), one-time and ‘one-time and ad-hoc’ obligations in light color (middle) and regular obligations in dark color (top). The following thematic abbreviations are used: ADP – anti-dumping, AG – agriculture, BOP – balance-of-payments, GATS – services, LIC – licensing, MA – market access, PSI – preshipment inspection, RO – rules of origin, RTAs – regional trade agreements, SCM – subsidies and countervailing measures, SG – safeguards, SPS – sanitary and phytosanitary measures, STR – state trading enterprises, TBT – technical and safety regulations, TEX – textile goods, TPR – Trade Policy Review Mechanism, TRIMS – investment measures, TRIPS – intellectual property rights, VAL – valuation
Figure 1

Figure 2. Overall compliance rates (a) and compliance rate across regular obligations only (b)

Figure 2

Table 1. Compliance rates and obligations (regular and onetime) across sectors

Figure 3

Table 2. Overall compliance rates across all WTO members, 1995–2014

Figure 4

Table 3. Regression analysis results

Figure 5

Table 4. Additional multiple regression tests