Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b6zl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T04:14:13.693Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Prices in Toledo (Spain): Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 March 2019

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Differences in material conditions are a determinant that explains the little divergence between northwestern and southern Europe. This article approaches the evolution of prices in early modern Toledo (Spain). The price index includes new items such as housing and employs different baskets over time, reflecting changes in consumption patterns. During the city’s golden age, prices grew faster than in London, Paris, or Amsterdam. Wine, urban rent, and food prices experienced a great increase, coinciding with demographic growth and the arrival of the American precious metals. Prices slowed in the first half of the seventeenth century, throughout Castile’s demographic and economic decay.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© Social Science History Association, 2019 

Introduction

Researchers have devoted major efforts to analyze standards of living because they bear on determining the pace of economic development and economic leadership before and after the Industrial Revolution (Allen Reference Allen2001). In the last two decades, a couple of discussions have generated a wave of works focused on living standards in the preindustrial era, along with an expansion of the geographic approach.

A first debate deals with the so-called great divergence between Europe and Asia (Pomeranz Reference Pomeranz2000). According to the classical economists and many modern scholars, European living standards surpassed those in Asia long before the Industrial Revolution. Revisionists have distrusted this traditional view, suggesting that Asian living conditions were comparable to those of Europe in the eighteenth century. Yet, the evidence that has led to this ongoing controversy remains fragile.

A second discussion approaches the forces that led to the beginning of a long-lasting little divergence between northwestern and southern European economies (Broadberry Reference Broadberry2013). Substantial economic disparities have been observed among countries, especially between 1500 and 1750 (Allen Reference Allen2001). In recent years, quantitative studies have shed new light on the timing, determinants, and effects of this process through series of real wages, urbanization rates, GDP,Footnote 1 and energy consumption (Malanima Reference Malanima2016). However, explanations on why some southern economies such as Spain fell behind remain unknown (Álvarez-Nogal et al. Reference Álvarez-Nogal, de la Escosura and Santiago-Caballero2016).

Examining differences in material conditions is feasible using Spanish primary sources. In this regard, the evolution of prices and wages sheds light on patterns of change throughout the preindustrial era. Long-term series of wages and prices allow scholars to enlarge their knowledge about real incomes in modern Europe, as well as to undertake comparisons among several economies (Clark Reference Clark2007).Footnote 2

This article presents a general price index for Toledo, one of the most relevant and populated cities in early modern Spain, between 1521 and 1650. To that end, I gather information on prices for up to 54 different goods, whose main sources are (1) Hamilton’s price series for New Castile (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1934); and (2) new values collected from Toledo’s civil and ecclesiastical institutions. These new sources provide long series of missing items in Hamilton’s work, cover gaps in the series already known, and allow for the contrast of prices from alternative sources. They also provide information on eating habits and consumption patterns of the Toledans in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries.Footnote 3

The new index offers two key improvements: (1) the inclusion of housing, an item often absent from the standard consumer basket,Footnote 4 and manufactured goods; and (2) the use of three different consumption baskets over time (1521–50, 1551–1600, and 1601–50), which reflect changes in the consumption patterns of the low-income families. These improvementes are determined by purchasing power trends, energy requirements, and literature on the European history of consumption.Footnote 5

Section 2 provides a brief foray into the economic and demographic context of Toledo in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. In Section 3, I review the literature on living standards and price indices in the modern age. Section 4 describes the sources and methodology used to construct the new price index. Section 5 teases out the main trends of the Toledan prices and its contrast with other Spanish and European indices. The conclusions are offered in Section 6.

Toledo in the Sixteenth and Seveteenth Centuries

During the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Toledo and its province took part in Castile’s economic and demographic performance, which underwent two different and long-lasting transitions: (1) an expansion that culminated about the 1580s; and (2) a decline that marked its nadir between 1630 and 1680 (García Sanz Reference García Sanz1985; González Agudo Reference González Agudo2017a; Marcos Martín Reference Marcos Martín2000; Sebastián Amarilla Reference Sebastián Amarilla, Llopis and Maluquer2013).

By the mid-sixteenth century, Toledo was the second most populated city in Castile, only surpassed by Seville. Prior to the establishment of Madrid as a permanent seat of the crown (1561), the monarchs used to spend long periods in Toledo, which also hosted many of the Cortes, the representative assemblies of the Castilian cities. Also, since the eleventh century, Toledo was considered as the religious center of Spain, whose archbishop held the primacy of all the Spanish kingdoms. This supremacy led the Toledan archbishopric to become one of the wealthiest and most influential dioceses in Christendom (Villaluenga Reference Villaluenga2005). The presence of a powerful clergy, nobles, merchants, craftsmen, artisans, and officials of the crown reinforced Toledo’s urban character (Martínez Gil Reference Martínez Gil and De La Cruz Muñoz2010; Martz Reference Martz1983).

Despite several agricultural and demographic crisis in the first three decades, the political rise of sixteenth-century Toledo was accompanied by a demographic and economic boom (Pérez Moreda Reference Pérez Moreda1980: 248–49). Some sources point to a major urban growth in the second third of the century. According to the 1528–30 census, Toledo had 5,898 hearths. This figure doubled in little more than 40 years: in 1571 the city population reached to 12,412 hearths, the equivalent to roughly 47,000 inhabitants.Footnote 6 Meanwhile, baptisms in 13 urban parishes registered a large increase between 1535 and 1560; and rose briefly in the eighties, despite the fact of being hit by a hard subsistence crisis (1580) and a plague episode (1583).Footnote 7 Several features reflect Toledo’s splendor: urban transformations, a strong immigration, the establishment of many religious institutions, the development of textile manufacturing based mainly on cloths and silks, the constitution of powerful guilds, and a “land-hunger” in the region (Vassberg Reference Vassberg1983).Footnote 8

Toledo’s decline began in the first decade of the seventeenth century, once the royal court was permanently settled in Madrid (1606). The plague of 1599, the subsistence crisis of 1606–7, the expulsion of the moriscos in 1609, and, above all, emigration to Madrid marked the beginning of a significant demographic loss. Parish city records indicate a gradual fall in population of about 30 percent between 1590 and 1607, and a sharp drop that lasted from 1605 to 1636 (Martz Reference Martz1983; Montemayor Reference Montemayor1996). By 1645, half of Toledo’s population had been lost in a dramatic process of deurbanization and depopulation that affected New Castile (Pérez Moreda and Reher Reference Pérez Moreda, Reher and Fortea Pérez1997). Some related facts have been given: a drop in agricultural production, technological backwardness, decapitalization, lack of raw materials, and an increasing tax burden imposed by the crown, especially severe in 1575 and 1591 (Ruiz Martín Reference Ruiz Martín1998). This also entailed a deep decline in the city’s textile and commercial sectors.

Price Indices and Living Standards in the Modern Age

Scholars have faced several constraints related to the composition of price indices in the modern period, including the noninclusion of certain products in the representative basket (e.g., housing, baked bread, goods from the New World); an undervaluation of other components (e.g., services, luxury goods, labor-intensive goods, retail goods, or nontraded goods) as a result of asymmetrical information (Llopis et al. Reference Llopis, García-Hiernaux, García Montero, González Mariscal, Hernández and García2009); and the assumption that consumption patterns did not change over the centuries (Van Zanden Reference Van Zanden, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005).

In an attempt to offer a second generation of price indices, methodological contributions are relevant in terms of calculating welfare ratios or including rent and bread prices in the baskets. Yet, estimates on living standards in preindustrial Europe and Asia are not beyond criticism. For instance, the use of the same representative basket to study the evolution of prices over a long period implies that low-income families shared similar and fixed consumption patterns.Footnote 9 Recent studies have also questioned Allen’s share of housing rent on the total familiar income (5 percent) for all the modern period (Allen Reference Allen2001). In Spain, some recent works give significantly higher percentages than Allen’s, urban rent being one of the most influential items on the price indices’ trend throughout the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries (Drelichman and González Agudo Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014; González Agudo Reference González Agudo2017b; González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015). As for comparative analysis, an explicit identification of each product composing the basket is needed, given the diversity and quality of goods lying behind a certain item (López Losa and Piquero Zarauz Reference López Losa and Piquero Zarauz2016).

Other disagreements deal with family size, the contribution of its members to the household income, and working time (García Zúñiga Reference García Zúñiga2011, Reference García Zúñiga, Maitte and Terrier2014; Garrido-González Reference Garrido-González2016; González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2013; Humphries Reference Humphries2013; Llopis and García Montero Reference Llopis and García Montero2011; Sarasúa Reference Sarasúa and Borrás2013). Recent studies on Spain have highlighted the relevance of child and female labor in sustaining living standards of families (Humphries and Sarasúa Reference Humphries and Sarasúa2012). Besides, an upward bias in the cost of the basket’s goods is possible due to taxes and excise duties.Footnote 10 Lastly, it is important to consider the information gaps. The lack of data could be solved by using alternative primary sources such as notarial or municipal registers. Gathering rural prices and wages is a feasible option for the purpose of comparison with those of urban areas (González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015).

Few studies are available on the price evolution in early modern Spain. Most research is based on Earl J. Hamilton’s price series for Andalusia, Aragon, Old and New Castile, Leon, Navarre, and Valencia (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1934, Reference Hamilton1936, Reference Hamilton1947, Reference Hamilton1983).Footnote 11 Javier Moreno provided new prices and wages series for Palencia between 1751 and 1851 (Moreno Lázaro Reference Moreno Lázaro2001, Reference Moreno Lázaro and Martínez Carrión2002). Thereafter, Llopis et al. (Reference Llopis, García-Hiernaux, García Montero, González Mariscal, Hernández and García2009) compared price indices between 1680 and 1800 in Madrid, Seville, and Palencia.Footnote 12 More recently, price and wage indices have been composed for eighteenth-century Madrid using registers from several charitable institutions (Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014). Also, remarkable efforts have been made gathering new price series and constructing price indices for early modern Seville and Toledo (González Agudo Reference González Agudo2017a, Reference González Agudo2017b; González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015). In Catalonia, Gaspar Feliú studied prices in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries and approached the cost of living in Barcelona between 1501 and 1807 (Feliú Reference Feliú1991a, Reference Feliú1991b, Reference Feliú1995, Reference Feliú and Fontana2004). There is, therefore, an open field for future research in Spain.

Sources and Methodology

The construction of a price index first requires the composition of consumption baskets. I first gather price series of up to 54 different products: 45 series are taken from Hamilton’s book, whose prices were obtained from Toledo and Alcalá de Henares (Madrid). Most of prices come from the daily expenses of Tavera, one of Toledo’s main hospitals, with available data since 1540. For previous decades, Hamilton offers few prices for 12 different goods in New Castile.Footnote 13 Some problems have already been identified by scholars (Allen Reference Allen2001; Feliú Reference Feliú1991a; Llopis Reference Llopis, Thompson and Yun1994; López Losa Reference López Losa2013; López Losa and Piquero Zarauz Reference López Losa and Piquero Zarauz2016; Nieto Reference Nieto2006). In the case of agricultural prices (wheat, barley, olive oil, etc.), Hamilton noted just the first three purchases of each trimester, regardless of the remaining transactions by the hospital.Footnote 14 Then, he determined the yearly price by calculating an arithmetic mean. This procedure gives the same relevance to both seedtime prices and harvest prices.

A patient search in the Toledan archives yielded 20 new and alternative price series for the period 1521–1650. The Cathedral ledgers offer prices for food (wheat, barley, hens, olive oil, and vinegar), clothing and footwear (linen, cotton, esparto, and shoes), housing and its conservation (urban rent, bricks, and tiles), fuel and lighting (charcoal, olive oil, and yellow wax), kitchenware and other (linen, esparto, hemp, and paper). Meanwhile, the city council ledgers provide information on wine prices.Footnote 15 The new series offer information on prices of nine products absent in Hamilton’s work (linen, cotton, esparto, shoes, housing rent, bricks, tiles, charcoal, and hemp) which are available for the first half of the sixteenth century.Footnote 16 This makes it possible to contrast between two alternative series for a given product, and fill in information gaps in the old series.

Unlike Hamilton’s data, the new prices consider the total annual purchases, weighted by the quantities purchased. However, this exercise does not always guarantee the preference for the new sources because they may contain some drawbacks. For instance, intervened wheat and barley prices seem to be more abundant in the Cathedral ledgers than in Hamilton’s series. This led me to discard the latter in favor of Hamilton’s wheat prices. Even so, there is no information on the grain prices that the lowest-income Toledans really faced.

Up to this point, it has not been possible to find records that offer solid and continuous bread prices in early modern Toledo.Footnote 17 The prices of bread were determined by the grain quotations as well as the elaboration cost (Nef Reference Nef1937). An alternative would have been Allen’s calculation of bread prices through a regression on grain prices, dummy variables for some European cities, and the mason’s wage rate: a stand-in for the baker’s income (Allen Reference Allen2001). Yet, because mason laborers’ wages are only available for the period 1551–1600 in Toledo (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1934) and require a critical analysis, conversion of wheat prices into bread ones is not feasible for the whole period 1521–1650. For the purposes of calculating an index for 1521 onward, I use wheat prices. As the construction of the index only relies on variations in prices rather than their levels, if bread prices have a reasonably strong correlation with wheat prices, this should not introduce a significant bias. Nonetheless, a new search for both wages and bread prices in the city is on its way.

Together with wheat/bread, wine was one of the most consumed products in southern Europe during the Old Regime. In Castile, this beverage became relevant for three main reasons: (1) wine covers a significant share of the daily human caloric needs; (2) grapevine productivity was higher than that of cereals; and (3) unlike grain, wine prices were not constrained by public intervention, thus its marketing possibilities were also stronger (Bernardos Reference Bernardos2014). Yet, wine prices are very controversial because they depended on several factors such as type, quality, measurement units, or consumption taxes (Allen Reference Allen2001; Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014; Feliú Reference Feliú1991b; Llopis Reference Llopis, Thompson and Yun1994; López Losa Reference López Losa2013). In this regard, Hamilton’s series for New Castile contains wholesale prices (expressed in arrobas) that only refer to “new” (seasonal) wine, without any other distinctions on types or qualities.Footnote 18

The alternative is municipal prices, available since 1565. The wine values used to be set by the Toledan council, together with some wine dealers representatives in the city (called Herederos del Vino). Two or three annual statements (posturas) on the public retail prices were made through a meticulous procedure based on rural prices. Each year, several city delegates were sent across the Toledan countryside, within 45 km from Toledo, to gather testimonies on the price at which wine was sold at public taverns. The depositions give information on the price of white, ordinary, and new (seasonal) wine, and sometimes on its quality, which used to be reasonable, good, very good, select, or “as good as what is shipped to Toledo.” Most of the posturas refer to the term vino de yema, which stands for delicate wine made from slightly crushed grapes. The monetary cost of wine in the city was, on average, slightly more expensive (seven maravedis) than that established in the countryside. Wine prices in Toledo include transportation costs and a possible profit margin for urban retailers, and they seem to be before consumption taxes. It has been argued that wine was one of the most taxed products in seventeenth-century Castile. Fraud was also frequent in terms of quality, measurement, and distribution (Andrés Ucendo Reference Andrés Ucendo2010). Thus, these reasons lead me to interpret the new data carefully.

Since food consumption covers human basic nutritional needs, I convert food prices into decimal metric units, and then into calories. In recent years, some accurate calculations have established the basic energy requirements for an average English person in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. These requirements would equal 76 percent of the average caloric needs of a male adult (Allen Reference Allen2013; Floud et al. Reference Floud, Fogel, Harris and Hong2011). Hence, the energy needs of three male adults would correspond to those of four individuals, including women and children. In Spain, the energy requirements of a low-income family of four members in modern Seville (7,400 calories) corresponded to 2.7 times those of a male family head (González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2013).

The next step is calculating the relative cost of acquiring 1,000 calories of food products with respect to the daily income earned by the family of a Toledan low-skilled worker (e.g., a mason laborer).Footnote 19 Then I set the budget constraint considering the average wage of a full-time Toledan mason laborer in 1520 and 1650, plus an additional 20 percent corresponding to complementary earnings (wages in kind, tips, proportional incentives, retributions from child and female labor, etc.).Footnote 20 This addition allows me to determine the household’s consumption possibilites for each good.

Nonfood prices have also been converted into decimal metric units. As for housing rent, yearly data are taken from a sample of 49 urban properties belonging to the Cathedral chapter in the Toledan “poor neighborhoods”: Arrabal, San Lorenzo, Santa Leocadia, San Marcos, San Miguel el Alto, and San Soles. For each property, I calculate the annual rent per square meter and I multiply the median value by 14.78, the average consumption area per inhabitant in the late sixteenth century (Drelichman and González Agudo Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014). Assuming that an urban hearth was composed, on average, of 3.5 individuals in early modern Toledo, rent would represent 7.35 and 8.75 percent of the family income in 1520 and 1650, respectively.Footnote 21 These shares are close to those recently calculated in Toledo by Drelichman and González Agudo (9.5 percent, on average, between 1489 and 1650) and Seville (between 6.8 and 17.4 percent in the sixteenth century; González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015). Also, they are significantly higher than those given by other scholars (an upper bound of 5 percent) for the early modern period (Allen Reference Allen2001; Horrell Reference Horrell1996; López Losa and Piquero Zarauz Reference López Losa and Piquero Zarauz2016).

In short, the consumer basket composition of a low-income Toledan family from 1521 to 1650 turns out to be determined by (1) basic energy requirements of a four-member family (≈ 7,400 calories); (2) the family’s budget constraint; (3) the consumption possibilities for each good; and (4) data on consumption expenditures, collected from several charitable and religious institutions in Toledo, and scattered references from the literature on the history of consumption in southern Europe.

Table 1 displays three different consumption baskets over time, each reflecting changes in the consumption patterns. Using time-varying baskets can result in lower calculated increases of the consumer price index, and hence in lower decreases in real wages and living standards. Nonetheless, this method is considered a more precise way of calculating a Consumer Price Index (CPI), is widely adopted by statistical agencies, and produces a more accurate picture of real wages and living standards. An index calculated with a single basket risks keeping products that consumers might have substituted away from long before, thus overstating the increase in the CPI.

TABLE 1. Consumption baskets in Toledo for 1521–50, 1551–1600, and 1601–50

Sources: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

Note: Wheat (2,940 kcal/kg), bacon (6,550 kcal/kg), beef (2,140 kcal/kg), mutton (2,125 kcal/kg), dried fish (3,220 kcal/kg), cheese (3,330 kcal/kg), eggs (1,570 kcal/kg), green grapes (681.4 kcal/kg), raisins (2,750 kcal/kg), almonds (6,100 kcal/kg), chesnuts (1,700 kcal/kg), honey (2,880 kcal/kg), lime, plaster, and charcoal are expressed in kilograms. Milk (620 kcal/kg), olive oil (9,000 kcal/kg), vinegar (40 kcal/kg), and wine (650 kcal/kg) are expressed in liters. Linen, esparto, and hemp are expressed in meters. Twine is expressed in hectograms. Bricks and tiles are expressed in units. Housing consumption is expressed in squared meters. Paper is expressed in hands.

The basket for 1521–50 contains 17 different products, gathered into 12 items (see appendix, notes on consumer baskets). The budget constraint for that period is 8,025 maravedis, that is the daily salary of a Toledan mason laborer in 1520 (26.8 maravedis) multiplied by 250 working days (= 6,687.5 maravedis), plus an additional 20 percent corresponding to complementary earnings. Regarding prices, for each period I consider the average quotations of the central decade (1530–40).

The amount of available goods is greater in the basket for 1551–1600, comprising up to 26 different price series arranged into 21 items. This basket also reflects changes in the consumption patterns of the Toledan low-income families. The international literature points to an overall decline in Europe’s urban real wages during the second half of the sixteenth century (Allen Reference Allen2001; Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014). Given their alleged loss of purchasing power, families might have responded (1) by increasing their additional income (earnings from child and female labor, agricultural income, etc.); and (2) by modifying their consumption patterns (i.e., acquiring more relatively cheaper products in caloric terms, and consuming fewer nonfood items). Thus, the quantity of wheat has increased, whereas those related to beef, mutton, cheese, olive oil, linen, and fuels has reduced. This basket provides 2,728.5 calories for an adult male laborer—and more than 7,000 calories for the whole family.

Finally, the slightly different composition of the 1601–50 basket is justified two ways: (1) a possible deterioration of real wages and the purchasing power of the Toledan low-income families in the two first decades of the seventeenth century (Allen Reference Allen2001; Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014; Cipolla Reference Cipolla1967; González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2013; Hernández Andreu Reference Hernández Andreu1996); and (2) the lack of price series for certain products belonging to the previous basket, such as beef and cheese. This time, the share of the cheapest food items in caloric terms (wheat and wine) has increased. This change responds to a declining trend in the relative price of this type of goods (see Table 2). Besides, the share of the most expensive items in caloric terms (meat, dried fish, and dairy) has decreased. The basket provides 2,806 calories for an adult male laborer.

TABLE 2. Relative price ratios for wheat and wine in Toledo, 1601–50 (maravedis/1,000 kcal)

Source: AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

Price Evolution

Once defined the three consumption baskets, their respective indices have been assembled by a chain index method.Footnote 22 This methodology first requires some sensitivity tests. The average differences between the Toledo Price Index (TPI) and its alternatives based only on the first (1521–50) or the second basket (1551–1600) are 0.01 percent and 2 percent, respectively. The findings are remarkably robust to variations in the consumption basket. Therefore, the distinct trends of the new TPI are driven in the new price series, rather than in any assumptions regarding the specific choice of weights.

Figure 1 shows that prices in Toledo multiplied by a factor of 5.5 between 1521–29 and 1642–50. There was a substantial increase in prices in the first half of the sixteenth century (63 percent between 1521–29 and 1542–50), whereas the TPI doubled in the second half, with a growth of 116.8 percent between 1551–59 and 1592–1600. The latter stage apparently coincides with the arrival of the American precious metals (Drelichman Reference Drelichman2005; Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983; Martz Reference Martz1983). However, the greatest inflationary pressures in the city took place by 1561 (see yearly rates at Table 3), some decades before any significant amounts of American silver had reached Spain.Footnote 23

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983.

FIGURE 1. Toledo Price Index (TPI), 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Index numbers and nine-year moving averages.

TABLE 3. Yearly rates of increase of the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650 (%)

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908, AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

This evidence seems to fit better with Toledo’s demographic boom in the second third of the century, and with Jordi Nadal’s assertions on the price revolution in Spain: inflation rates started to slow in 1560–65 (Nadal Reference Nadal1959). This research holds that the demographic increase contributed to Spain’s growth in prices during the sixteenth century, as it did regarding the decline in real wages.

By offering a perspective based on a monetary approach to the balance of payments, Flynn (Reference Flynn1978) contends that the lack of synchronicity between treasure flows and intervals of price inflation in various European countries does not invalidate the monetary explanation of the price revolution. Still, years later, Munro (Reference Munro2007) gathered several works to reconcile both the monetary and the demographic explanations. He stressed that population growth might have influenced the potential velocity of money, another feature of the price revolution. In such an approach, urban growth would have played a relevant role in the expansion of urban markets and the use of credit instruments. After all, Flynn demonstrates that fiscal, financial, and banking developments in sixteenth-century Spain were, in part, responsible for driving out specie.

Recent work on early modern Madrid shows that indirect taxes raised price levels by 15 to 20 percent (Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014). In Toledo, some signs point to a growing and severe tax burden during the sixteenth century.Footnote 24 Yet, further research is required to fully comprehend this phenomenon in the city.

Housing (143 percent), wine (140.8 percent), and, to a lesser extent, food (114.7 percent) were the products whose prices increased the most in sixteenth-century Toledo.Footnote 25 At this point, the influence of housing on the index was noteworthy. In fact, if urban rents were excluded, the Toledan prices would multiply by 3.1 instead of 3.5 between 1521–29 and 1592–1600 (see figure 2).

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983.

FIGURE 2. Toledo Price Index and Toledo Price Index without housing, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Things changed in the first half of the seventeenth century. The TPI rose by 40 percent between 1601–9 and 1642–50. Clothing and footwear doubled in price (100.8 percent), whereas food and wine values grew by 46 percent and 49.1 percent, respectively. Within the food subcategory, the cost of wheat and olive oil registered their lowest increase (around 33 percent in both cases). Fuels prices barely ascended by 18 percent, while housing was the only item that cheapened in absolute terms (–8.1 percent). Consequently, these two last categories became less expensive with respect to a basic food such as grain. This seems to match the trend followed by relative prices in several modern European cities and regions (Hoffman et al. Reference Hoffman, Jacks, Levin and Lindert2002).

Both the significant fall in urban rent and the decrease in the relative price of wheat and wine would have been caused by the demographic decline of Toledo, especially intense in the first third of the century (Martz Reference Martz1983; Montemayor Reference Montemayor1996). This population loss seems to be evidenced, in turn, by a decrease in the region’s agricultural production (Sebastián Amarilla et al. Reference Sebastián Amarilla, García Montero, Zafra Oteyza and Bernardos Sanz2008), the incidence of some mortality crises (Pérez Moreda Reference Pérez Moreda1980; Pérez Moreda and Reher Reference Pérez Moreda, Reher and Fortea Pérez1997), a drop of competitiveness in the manufacturing sector (Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo, Lanza García, Truchuelo, López Vela and Torres Arce2015), and the emigration to Madrid, once the court was definitely settled in that city in 1606 (Drelichman and González Agudo Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014; Martz Reference Martz1983; Ringrose Reference Ringrose1973, Reference Ringrose1985).

The inclusion of urban rent also seems to be noticeable when contrasting the evolution of the TPI with that of Reher and Ballesteros for New Castile (figure 3), taken from Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983). Prices, expressed in grams of silver, grew by 282.6 percent in Toledo between 1521–29 and 1642–50, whereas they increased by 277.6 percent in New Castile. The greatest divergence between both indices took place at the end of the sixteenth century.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983; and Reher and Ballesteros Reference Reher and Ballesteros1993.

FIGURE 3. Toledo Price Index and Reher-Ballesteros Price Index for New Castile, 1521–1650, in grams of silver. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Figure 4 displays the trend of the TPI compared to that of Allen’s for New Castile. To do so, I reconstruct Allen’s respectability and subsistence baskets in this region, and replace Hamilton’s prices for wine, olive oil, linen, housing, charcoal, and yellow wax by the new Toledan quotations.Footnote 26 Between 1551–9 and 1642–50, the rise in prices was significantly higher in Toledo (132 percent) than in New Castile with the respectability basket (106.2 percent, and 107.8 percent when adding the rental cost of housing to the overall index). The growth of the TPI was also greater in comparison to Allen’s replicas with the subsistence basket (by 114.5 percent, and up to 117.2 percent with urban rent). Large gaps remain in the early and middle sections. These are likely the result of Allen’s eliminating several important staples from the consumption basket.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; Hamilton (1983); and www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/Biography.aspx. Fuels prices in Toledo are expressed in BTUs.

FIGURE 4. Toledo Price Index and Allen’s Price Indices for New Castile, 1551–1650, in grams of silver. Base 100 = 1551–60 average. Nine-year moving averages.

The new index allows for a contrast with that of Seville (SPI), the most recent of the second-generation indices in Spain, which uses a similar methodology and includes urban rent in its consumption baskets.Footnote 27 As figure 5 shows, the growth of the SPI was greater than the TPI between 1521–29 and 1642–50 (525 percent vs. 453 percent). The evolution of both indices was quite similar until the eighties. After that, a divergence in favor of Seville began, coinciding with a period of increasing imports of precious metals from America that reached their peak in the last decade of the century. It is also remarkable, as revealed in figure 5, the slight delay of the Toledan price fluctuations with respect to the Sevillian until the 1640s. This could be explained by the commercial supremacy of Seville, where the American treasure began to circulate. Soon after, it influenced the economy of New Castile, the closest region to Andalusia in trading terms (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983).

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983). Data on Seville are courtesy of Manuel González Mariscal.

FIGURE 5. Toledo Price Index and Seville Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. R2 = 0.93.

The growth of the Toledan prices was also significant when contrasted with those of some European cities (see figures 6.a and 6.b). Once transformed into grams of silver, both the TPI and Allen’s (Reference Allen2001) replica show higher increases (120.7 percent and 90.4 percent, respectively) than some European cities and regions’ indices between 1551 and 1596 (see figure 6a), such as London (88 percent), Antwerp (53.1 percent), Centre-North Italy (52.3 percent), and Amsterdam (29.6 percent). The only exception is Paris (103.2 percent).

Source: www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/biography.aspx, ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

FIGURE 6a. Price indices in several European cities and regions, in grams of silver, 1551–1650. Base 100 = 1551–60 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/biography.aspx, ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

FIGURE 6b. Price indices in several European cities and regions, in grams of silver, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Figures 7 and 8 display the volatility of prices in Toledo.Footnote 28 The moments of greater instability are found at the beginning of the series. Several factors could explain this high level of volatility: (1) a more limited number of products in the consumer basket for 1521–50; (2) poor market integration during this period (Marcos Martín Reference Marcos Martín2000); and (3) the possible disruption of existing commercial traffic following the revolt of the Castilian Comunidades (1520–21). Standard deviation declined since the beginning of the period, recording a minimum value in 1552–81. From then on, fluctuations grew as far as 1581–1610, and fell again until 1610–39. Although instability rose significantly between the 1610s and 1650, it would never reach the maximum levels of the previous century.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

FIGURE 7. Standard deviations of the logarithmic variation rates for the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–0 average. Index numbers and thirty-year moving periods.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1983).

FIGURE 8. Standard deviations of the logarithmic variation rates for the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–0 average. Index numbers and thirty-year moving periods.

Focusing on the composition of the Toledan baskets, the most variable prices were, by far, those of wine and wheat (see figure 8), whereas housing rent was the most stable component. A declining instability in grain prices, although not necessarily continuing, has also been observed in other European cities (Persson Reference Persson1999). Regarding mutton prices, their volatility was the only one that rose over the period. As for linen prices, they became more variable since the 1610s, after a decreasing tendency. Such sharp movement in textile prices should be interpreted carefully; a possible change in its quality or in its units of measurement should not be discarded.

Lastly, Allen’s welfare ratios for unskilled construction wages have been computed for Toledo.Footnote 29 With the TPI and the new consumption baskets, the average welfare ratio for 1551–1600 is 0.57. This is significantly lower than the one obtained by using Allen’s data (0.71): a difference of 13.5 percent.Footnote 30 Bearing in mind the need for more wage registers in the city and the cautions noted by Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014) on Allen’s assumptions, these results confirm the fact that a low-income laborer would have barely afforded a subsistence basket during the golden age of Toledo, had he not relied on complementary earnings such as those from alternative activities and/or female and child labor.

Conclusion

The construction of a general price index for Toledo between 1521 and 1650 has been useful to analyze the price trend in one of the most relevant Spanish cities during a period for which literature on living standards is scarce. The new data collected from two different institutions (city council and Cathedral chapter) not only allow for the addition of new items in the consumer baskets but also the coverage of information gaps and the replacement of some “problematic” series from Earl J. Hamilton’s book on the price revolution in Spain. The main contribution in this regard is the inclusion of new prices for of food (olive oil), wine, manufactured products (linen, esparto, hemp, and paper), housing rent, construction materials (bricks and tiles), and fuels and lighting (charcoal and olive oil). The TPI is based on a greater number of price series (from 17 to 26, depending on the period) compared to the preceding indices for New Castile, whose data were mainly taken from Toledan institutions.

The new index provides two key improvements with respect to the so-called second-generation price indices. First is the construction of three different baskets (1521–50, 1551–1600, and 1601–50) that reflect possible variations in the consumption patterns of low-income families. To do so, several primary sources and the European literature on the history of consumption have been considered. Second is the inclusion of housing in the baskets. Rent expenditure represented 7.35 percent and 8.75 percent of the family income in 1520 and 1650, respectively. These shares are not far from those recently calculated by Drelichman and González Agudo on Allen’s indices (9.5 percent on average), and by González Mariscal for Seville (6.8–17.4 percent) in the sixteenth century. However, they are significantly higher than those proposed by Horrell, Allen, or López Losa, with an upper bound of 5 percent for the early modern period.

Prices in Toledo multiplied by 5.5 between 1521–29 and 1642–50. In the sixteenth century, the growth of the Toledan index is slightly higher than that of Reher and Ballesteros for New Castile, once quotations are translated into grams of silver. These differences confirm the importance of including new items in the consumer baskets.

In Toledo, the greatest inflationary pressures took place in the second third of the sixteenth century, coinciding with the economic and demographic rise of the city. Housing, wine, and food were the products whose prices increased the most. During this stage, the influence of housing was remarkable: if urban rents are omitted, the Toledan index multiplies by 3.1 instead of 3.5 between 1521–9 and 1592–1600. The growth in prices, together with a possible decrease in urban real wages in the second half of the sixteenth century, could force low-income families to increase their additional earnings and to readjust their consumption patterns.

The situation changed notably in the first half of the seventeenth century. Prices in Toledo barely rose by 40 percent between 1601–9 and 1642–50. Relative quotations of basic foods such as grain or wine declined with respect to those of more expensive products in caloric terms. In the meantime, housing and fuels cheapened in relation to grain, matching the trend followed in other parts of Europe. The city’s depopulation seems to be, in part, behind these trends, especially during the first third of the century.

Although there was a trend toward stability between 1521 and 1650, the greatest moments of price volatility in Toledo took place during the first half of the sixteenth century. The most volatile quotations corresponded to wheat and wine, while housing was the most stable item.

During this period, some differences can be observed when contrasting the evolution of Toledo with that of different European cities and regions. On the one hand, prices grew less in Toledo than in Seville between 1521–29 and 1642–50. The gap between both cities occurred in a period of increasing imports of precious metals from America, which would peak in the late sixteenth century. On the other hand, the rise in prices during the Toledan golden age was higher than in some other western European cities such as London, Amsterdam, or Antwerp.

Urban growth seems to help explain the price trends from more than a single viewpoint, although the debate on the price revolution requires to be split in two, as suggested by Nadal (Reference Nadal1959): (1) identifying all possible causes and (2) determining their degree of responsibility and interaction. Other than population growth and the arrival of the American treasure, are there any additional causes involved in the price movement? Urbanization inferences in close-by cities seem to exert a substantial grip on the matter. Thus, new insights in such respects must be necessarily given for further research, especially in early modern manufacturing cities such as Toledo.

Finally, the recalculation of welfare ratios with the new TPI suggests that a low-income laborer in Toledo would have barely afforded a subsistence basket during the golden age of the city if he had not relied on the family’s complementary earnings. Seeking to set some basic conditions to allow for comparative analysis is one of the main goals of welfare ratios. Yet, as price-index construction improves for modern Europe, estimating more realistic standards of living at the local level also becomes desirable. Thus, starting from the point that this work has reached, future inquiries will be carried out on both real wages and the contribution of female and child labor in Toledo.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ssh.2019.2.

Footnotes

I am especially grateful to Mauricio Drelichman, Dr. Marina Adshade, María Jesús Fuente, and Enrique Llopis for encouraging me to submit this article. I also thank Philip T. Hoffman, Ernesto López Losa, Ramón Lanza, Jacob Weisdorf, and seminar participants at Carlos III University, the 2017 AEHE conference, Sapienza University, University of the Basque Country, Vancouver School of Economics, and the 2016 SSHA meetings for useful exchanges and suggestions. I acknowledge the assistance of Mariano García Ruipérez at the Archivo Municipal de Toledo, as well as that of staff at the Archivo y Biblioteca Capitulares de Toledo. All errors remain my own.

1. Among others, Allen (Reference Allen2001), Federico and Malanima (Reference Federico and Malanima2004), Malanima (Reference Malanima2003, Reference Malanima2011), Van Zanden (Reference Van Zanden, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005), Álvarez Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (Reference Álvarez Nogal and de la Escosura2007, Reference Álvarez Nogal and de la Escosura2013), Van Zanden and van Leeuwen (Reference Van Zanden and Van Leeuwen2012), Freire Costa et al. (Reference Freire Costa, Palma and Reis2014), Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and van Leeuwen2015), Llopis et al. (Reference Llopis, Sebastián, Abarca and Velasco2016), and López Losa and Piquero Zarauz (Reference López Losa and Piquero Zarauz2016). Vancouver School of Economics, University of British Columbia.

2. On price history, see Elsas (Reference Elsas1936/1940), Posthumus (Reference Posthumus1946, Reference Posthumus1964), Pribram (Reference Pribram1938), Phelps Brown and Hopkins (Reference Phelps Brown and Hopkins1956, Reference Phelps Brown and Hopkins1957, Reference Phelps Brown and Hopkins1959, Reference Phelps Brown and Hopkins1981), Van der Wee (Reference Van der Wee and Schöffer1978), Feinstein (Reference Feinstein1998), Van Zanden (Reference Van Zanden1999, Reference Van Zanden, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005), Pomeranz (Reference Pomeranz2000), Allen (Reference Allen2001, Reference Allen2003, Reference Allen, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005, Reference Allen, Hatton, O’Rourke and Taylor2007, Reference Allen, Durlauf and Blume2008, Reference Allen2013), Vries (Reference Vries2001, Reference Vries2003), Allen et al. (Reference Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005, Reference Allen, Basssino, Ma, Moll-Murata and Van Zanden2011), Özmucur and Pamuk (Reference Özmucur and Pamuk2002), Malanima (Reference Malanima2003, Reference Malanima2006, Reference Malanima2013), Hoffman et al. (Reference Hoffman, Jacks, Levin, Lindert, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005), Broadberry and Gupta (Reference Broadberry and Gupta2006), Bassino and Ma (Reference Bassino and Ma2006), Gupta and Ma (Reference Gupta, Ma, Broadberry and O’Rourke2010), Pamuk and Van Zanden (Reference Pamuk, Van Zanden, Broadberry and O’Rourke2010), Challú (Reference Challú, Salvatore, Coatsworth and Challú2010), Dobado-González and García-Montero (Reference Dobado-González and García-Montero2014), Kelly and Ó Gráda (Reference Kelly and Ó Gráda2013), Arroyo Abad (Reference Arroyo Abad2014), Blakeway (Reference Blakeway2015) and González Mariscal (Reference González Mariscal2015).

3. ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Colegio de Nuestra Señora de los Infantes, 227, 237, 251, 277 and Gasto Ordinario 1610; and A.B.C.T., Obra y Fábrica, Hospital de Nuestra Señora de la Visitación, also known as Hospital del Nuncio, 532–40.

4. There is still little indication of rental costs for early modern Europe, with the exception of a few European countries. For England, see Lindert and Williamson (Reference Lindert and Williamson1983) and Ormrod et al. (Reference Ormrod, Gibson and Lyne2011). For Scotland, Blakeway (Reference Blakeway2015). For the Netherlands, Lesger (Reference Lesger1986), Van Zanden (Reference Van Zanden, Allen, Bengtsson and Dribe2005) and Eichholtz et al. (Reference Eichholtz, Straetmans and Theebe2011). For Flanders, Mason (Reference Mason and Verlinden1959), Scholliers (Reference Scholliers1962), van Ryssel (Reference Van Ryssel1967) and Avondts (Reference Avondts1971). For Italy, Barbot and Perocco (Reference Barbot and Perocco2013). For Spain, Llopis and García Montero (Reference Llopis and García Montero2011), Llopis et al. (Reference Llopis, García-Hiernaux, García Montero, González Mariscal, Hernández and García2009), Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014) and González Mariscal (Reference González Mariscal2015). A first attempt to study the housing market in Edirne (Turkey) during the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries can be found in Karagedikli and Tunçer (Reference Karagedikli and Tunçer2016).

6. Martz (Reference Martz1983: 93). I use a coefficient of 3.78 inhabitants per hearth. For a detailed discussion, see Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014: 42).

7. In 1580, baptisms fell by around 30 percent. Between 1571 and 1591, censuses show a population lost of roughly 1,500 hearts. See Ringrose (Reference Ringrose1973), Weisser (Reference Weisser1973), Martz (Reference Martz1983) and Montemayor (Reference Montemayor1996).

8. On the Toledan guilds and the relevance of textile manufacturing in modern Toledo, see Martínez Gil (Reference Martínez Gil and De La Cruz Muñoz2010: 290–98) and Nombela (Reference Nombela2003).

10. The use of economic sources belonging to urban institutions is very common when reconstructing living standards in this period. In modern Castile, taxes and excise duties on consumption goods (sisas) tended to grow faster in the largest and most prosperous cities (Andrés Ucendo Reference Andrés Ucendo1999).

11. For New Castile, Martín Aceña (Reference Martín Aceña1992) and Reher and Ballesteros (Reference Reher and Ballesteros1993). For Old Castile, Llopis et al. (Reference Llopis, Jerez, Álvaro and Fernández2000). For Andalusia, New Castile, Old Castile-Leon, and Valencia, see Drelichman (Reference Drelichman2005). López Losa (Reference López Losa2013) recovered several price series never published by Hamilton on Old Castile-Leon, Andalusia, and Valencia between 1650 and 1800.

12. Llopis and García Montero (Reference Llopis and García Montero2011) offered a price index for Madrid during the same period.

13. Available price series for the first half of the sixteenth century correspond to wheat, barley, wine, beef, mutton, hooves, cheese, lime, linen, olive oil, yellow wax, and plaster (Hamilton Reference Hamilton1983: 201, 211, 227).

14. The hospital used to purchase its grains at the alhóndiga, the Toledan public granary, Archivo del Hospital de Tavera (AHT), Libros de Botillería, 1566–67.

15. For the Cathedral chapter, Archivo y Biblioteca Capitulares de Toledo (ABCT), Obra y Fábrica, Carta Cuenta, Posesiones, Protocolos y Libros de la Obra. For the city council, Archivo Municipal de Toledo (AMT), Caja de Vino, Posturas y Registros, 2400 and ss. On urban rents, see Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014). The price series have been gathered according to the current guidelines of the Spanish Statistics Institute (INE) for elaborating the Consumer Price Index. This method is also applied in González Mariscal (Reference González Mariscal2013). On sources for the study of food prices in the Municipal Archive of Toledo, see García Ruipérez (Reference García Ruipérez2017).

16. Esparto is any of various grasses of Southern Europe and Northern Africa that yield a fiber used for making ropes, mats, etc.

17. On the relevance of cereals and bread in the economic balance of the modern European family, see Livi-Bacci (Reference Livi-Bacci1988). On the intervention in Castilian wheat prices, see De Castro (Reference De Castro1987).

18. Nevertheless, there is no evidence of a wide divergence between the evolution of wholesale and retail prices in the long run (Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García Reference Andrés Ucendo and Lanza García2014; Feinstein Reference Feinstein1998).

19. A debate has recently arisen on the number of working days in modern Spain. Some scholars have pointed out an increase in the number of potential working days per year, from about 270 in the mid-fifteenth century to 280 at the end of the eighteenth century (García Zúñiga Reference García Zúñiga2011, Reference García Zúñiga, Maitte and Terrier2014). Still, as López Losa and Piquero Zarauz (Reference López Losa and Piquero Zarauz2016) points out, more data are required “to build up reliable estimations over time.” This scholar considers Allen’s 250-day year as “not far from being an acceptable conjectural average.” Because there is no information on working time in modern Toledo, I consider some scattered references about the eighteenth-century Madrilean masons, which establish an interval of 225–50 working days (Llopis and García Montero Reference Llopis and García Montero2011; Nieto Reference Nieto2006). I assume the upper limit as a conjectural benchmark for Toledo.

20. Wage data in Toledo are very scarce and disperse for the study period. For now, there is virtually no long series available for the first half of the sixteenth century. A new research project in which I am involved is now underway to fill this gap. I am also aware of the criticism on the excessive degree of dependence on the wages of urban mason laborers when it comes to analyzing standards of living (González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015). Recent studies on eighteenth-century New Castile and Andalusia have shown the relevance of child and female labor, whose participation rates were increasingly significant (Garrido-González Reference Garrido-González2016; Humphries and Sarasúa Reference Humphries and Sarasúa2012; Sarasúa Reference Sarasúa and Borrás2013). Moreover, a regular income in early modern Seville (i.e., without an additional 20 percent) could meet the basic energy requirements of the family, but it would do so at the expense of having a very poor diet (González Mariscal Reference González Mariscal2015). This does not seem to match with the literature on the history of consumption.

21. Although a coefficient of 3.78 is considered by Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014) as “more reflective of sixteenth century conditions” in Toledo, that value was a maxima around 1591 in New Castile, coinciding with a period of demographic growth. Moreover, the number of individuals per hearth might have been lower in urban areas than in the countryside. On this coefficient in New Castile and Toledo, see López-Salazar (Reference López-Salazar1976), Carasa Soto (Reference Carasa Soto1993) and Martín Galán Reference Martín Galán1985.

22. The values of a given index (e.g., that of 1551–1600) are related to the values of its preceding index (1521–50), resulting in an index for the given period expressed against the preceding one = 100.

23. An evolution of both private and public Spanish imports of the American treasure is offered in Drelichman (Reference Drelichman2005).

24. The alcabala, a kind of value added tax that affected the sales of meat, fish, textiles, and craft items, tripled in Toledo from 1536 to 1575. Moreover, in 1590, Philip II of Spain imposed the servicio de millones, an indirect tax on food (originally levied on wine, vinegar, meat, and olive oil) that was initially intended as a temporary measure to replace the Royal Armada’s loss in attacking England. On top, the Crown requested a new rise of the alcabalas in 1621 (Martínez Gil Reference Martínez Gil and De La Cruz Muñoz2010).

25. For several reasons already mentioned on taxation, units of measurement, and fraud, the strong growth of wine prices should be interpreted with caution.

26. Allen’s respectability basket refers to the standard of living to which a Southern English laborer aspired (2,103 daily calories per person). It contains 182 yearly kg of bread, 34 kg of legumes, 26 kg of meat, 5.2 kg of cheese, 5.2 liters of olive oil for cooking, 52 eggs, 68.25 l of wine, 2.6 kg of soap, 5 meters of linen, 2.6 kg of tallow candles, 2.6 l of olive oil for lighting, and 5 million BTUs of fuels. The subsistence basket (2,099 daily calories per person) is based on a diet in which most calories come from the cheapest available food items. It consists of 170 kg of grain, 20 kg of legumes, 5 kg of meat, 3 l of olive oil for cooking, 1.3 kg of soap, 3 meters of linen, 1.3 kg of soap, 3 meters of linen, 1.3 kg of tallow candles, 1.3 l of olive oil for lighting, and 2 million BTUs of fuels (Allen Reference Allen2013).

27. González Mariscal (Reference González Mariscal2013) calculates the evolution of the cost of living in early modern Seville. This author also includes housing rent and uses three baskets of goods (1521–50, 1551–1600, and 1601–50) according to identified changes in the consumption patterns. I assume, however, slight differences in the basket composition between Seville and Toledo, mainly based on the price availability for certain items.

28. I compute the first differences of the natural logarithms (ln x1 - ln x2) in the index. Then I calculate the standard deviations for moving periods of 30 years.

29. According to Allen (Reference Allen2001), the welfare ratio of an individual is calculated by dividing his yearly earnings by the required annual expenses to support a typical family at subsistence levels. Allen’s welfare ratio for Madrid takes Hamilton (Reference Hamilton1934)’s unskilled construction wages from a Toledan hospital during the second half of the sixteenth century. With a welfare ratio of one, a family is above the poverty line. Values lower than one would indicate that the family is in poverty.

30. This calculation also corrects two computational issues on Allen’s welfare ratios (Allen Reference Allen2001). See Drelichman and González Agudo (Reference Drelichman and González Agudo2014: 43).

References

Allen, R. C. (2001) “The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War.” Explorations in Economic History 38: 411–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C.. (2003) “Poverty and progress in early modern Europe.” Economic History Review 56 (3): 403–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C.. (2005) “Real wages in Europe and Asia: A first look at the long-term patterns,” in Allen, R. C., Bengtsson, T., and Dribe, M. (eds.) Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 111–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C.. (2007) “India in the great divergence,” in Hatton, T. J., O’Rourke, K. H., and Taylor, A. M. (eds.) The New Comparative Economic History. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press: 932.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C.. (2008) “Real wage rates (historical trends),” in Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.) New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C.. (2013) “Poverty lines in history, theory, and current international practice.” Working paper 685, Discussion Paper Series, University of Oxford, Oxford.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C., Basssino, J. P., Ma, D., Moll-Murata, C., and Van Zanden, J. L. (2011) “Wages, prices, and living standards in China, 1738–1925: In comparison with Europe, Japan and India.” Economic History Review 64 (S1): 838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C., Bengtsson, T., and Dribe, M., eds. (2005) Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C., Murphy, T. E., and Schneider, E. B. (2012) “The colonial origins of the divergence in the Americas: A labour market approach.” Working paper 402, IGIER–Bocconi University, Milano.Google Scholar
Álvarez Nogal, C., and de la Escosura, L. Prados (2007) “The decline of Spain (1500–1850): Conjectural estimates.” European Review of Economic History 11: 319–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Álvarez Nogal, C.. and de la Escosura, L. Prados (2013) “The rise and fall of Spain (1270–1850).” Economic History Review 66 (1): 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Álvarez-Nogal, C., de la Escosura, L. Prados , and Santiago-Caballero, C. (2016) “Spanish agriculture in the little divergence.” European Review of Economic History 20 (14): 452–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrés Ucendo, J. I. (1999) La fiscalidad en Castilla en el siglo XVII: los servicios de millones, 1601–1700. Bilbao: Universidad del País Vasco.Google Scholar
Andrés Ucendo, J. I.. (2010) “¿Quién pagó los tributos en la Castilla del siglo XVII? El impacto de los tributos sobre el vino de Madrid.” Studia historica. Historia moderna 32: 229–57.Google Scholar
Andrés Ucendo, J. I., and Lanza García, R. (2014) “Prices and real wages in seventeenth-century Madrid.” Economic History Review 67 (S3): 607–26.Google Scholar
Andrés Ucendo, J. I.. and Lanza García, R. (2015) “Trabajar y vivir en el Madrid de los Austrias, 1561–1700,” in Truchuelo, S., López Vela, R., and Torres Arce, M. (eds.) Civitas: expresiones de la ciudad en la Edad Moderna. Santander, Spain: Universidad de Cantabria: 173226.Google Scholar
Arroyo Abad, L. (2014) “Failure to launch: Cost of living and living standards in Peru during the 19th century.” Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 32 (1): 4776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avondts, G. (1971) “De Huishuren Te Brussel, 1500–1800, Brussels.” PhD diss., Vrije Universiteit Brussel.Google Scholar
Barbot, M., and Perocco, M. (2013) “A good neighborhood is not always for free: Housing prices and the rise of social interactions in early modern Milan (1560–1670).” unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Bassino, J. P., and Ma, D. (2006) “Japanese unskilled wages in international perspective, 1741–1913.” Research in Economic History 23: 229–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernardos, J. (2014) “La conformación del mercado interior castellano a través del sistema de abastecimiento madrileño de productos básicos (1560–1850).” Minius: Revista do Departamento de Historia, Arte e Xeografía 22: 5380.Google Scholar
Blakeway, A. (2015) “The sixteenth-century price rise: New evidence from Scotland, 1500–85.” Economic History Review 68 (1): 167–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, S. (2013) “Accounting for the great divergence.” LSE Economic History Working Papers 184/2013.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B., Klein, A., Overton, M., and van Leeuwen, B. (2015) British Economic Growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S., and Gupta, B. (2006) “The early modern great divergence: Wages, prices and economic development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800.” Economic History Review 59 (1): 231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carasa Soto, P. (1993) “Introducción” Censo de Ensenada 1756. Madrid: Centro de Gestión Catastral y Cooperación Tributaria: Tabapress.Google Scholar
Challú, A. E. (2010) “The great decline: Biological well-being and living standards in Mexico, 1730–1840,” in Salvatore, R. D., Coatsworth, J. H., and Challú, A. E. (eds.) Living Standards in Latin American History: Height, Welfare, and Development, 1750–2000. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University: 2367.Google Scholar
Cipolla, C. M. (1967) Money, Prices, and Civilization in the Mediterranean World: Fifth to Seventeenth Century. New York: Gordian Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Gregory (2007) A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Castro, C. (1987) El pan de Madrid. El abasto de las ciudades españolas en el Antiguo Régimen. Madrid: Alianza Editorial.Google Scholar
De Vries, Jan (2009) La revolución industriosa: consumo y economía doméstica desde 1650 hasta el presente. Barcelona: Crítica.Google Scholar
Dobado-González, R. (2015) “Pre-independence Spanish Americans: Poor, short and unequal … or the opposite?”, Revista de Historia Económica 33: 1559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobado-González, R., and García-Montero, H. (2014) “Neither so low nor so short: Wages and heights in Bourbon Spanish America from an international comparative perspective.” Journal of Latin American Studies 46: 291321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drelichman, M. (2005) “The curse of Moctezuma: American silver and the Dutch disease, 1501–1650.” Explorations in Economic History 42 (3): 349–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drelichman, M., and González Agudo, D. (2014) “Housing and the cost of living in early modern Toledo.” Explorations in Economic History 54: 2747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichholtz, P., Straetmans, S., and Theebe, M. (2011) “Housing market rents and the economy.” University of Amsterdam Working Paper, Amsterdam, 15501850.Google Scholar
Elsas, M. J. (1936/1940) Umriss einer Geschichte der Preise und Löhne in Deutschland. Leiden, The Netherlands: Sijthoff.Google Scholar
Federico, G., and Malanima, P. (2004) “Progress, decline, growth: Product and productivity in Italian agriculture, 1000–2000.” Economic History Review LVII (3): 437–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feinstein, C. H. (1998) “Pessimism perpetuated: Real wages and the standard of living in Britain during and after the Industrial Revolution.” The Journal of Economic History 58 (3): 625–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feliú, G. (1991a) Precios y salarios en la Cataluña Moderna. Volumen I: Alimentos. Madrid: Servicio de Estudios del Banco de España.Google Scholar
Feliú, G.. (1991b) Precios y salarios en la Cataluña Moderna. Volumen II: Combustibles, productos manufacturados y salaries. Madrid: Servicio de Estudios del Banco de España.Google Scholar
Feliú, G.. (1995) “Precios andaluces y precios catalanes en la Edad Moderna.” Actas del II Congreso de Historia de Andalucía, 1991. Vol. 8. Sevilla Consejería de Cultura y Medio Ambiente: 297308.Google Scholar
Feliú, G.. (2004) “Aproximació a un índex del cost de la vida a Barcelona, 1501–1807,” in Fontana, Josep (ed.) Història i projecte social. Barcelona: Crítica: 151–70.Google Scholar
Flandrin, Jean-Louis, and Montanari, M., eds. (2013) Food: A Culinary History from Antiquity to the Present. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Floud, R., Fogel, R., Harris, B., and Hong, S.C. (2011) The Changing Body: Health, Nutrition, and Human Development in the Western World since 1700. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, D. O. (1978) “A new perspective on the Spanish price revolution: The monetary approach to the balance of payments.” Explorations in Economic History 15: 388406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freire Costa, L., Palma, N., and Reis, J. (2014) “The great escape? The contribution of the empire to Portugal’s economic growth, 1500–1800.” European Review of Economic History 19 (1): 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García Sanz, A. (1985) “Auge y decadencia en España en los siglos XVI y XVII: Economía y sociedad en Castilla.” Revista de Historia Económica 1: 1127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García Zúñiga, M. (2011) “La evolución de los días de trabajo en España, 1250–1918.” Paper presented at the X Congreso Internacional de la Asociación Española de Historia Económica, Carmona, Spain, September 8–10.Google Scholar
García Zúñiga, M.. (2014) “Fêtes chômées et temps de travail en Espagne (1250–1900),” in Maitte, C., and Terrier, D. (eds.) Les temps du travail Normes, pratiques, évolutions (XIVe–XIXe siècle). Rennes, France: Presses Universitaires de Rennes: 6380.Google Scholar
García Ruipérez, M. (2017) “Fuentes para el estudio de los precios de los alimentos en los archivos municipales españoles en la Edad Moderna: los libros del juzgado de fieles ejecutores de Toledo.” Cuadernos de Historia Moderna 42 (1): 261290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrido-González, L. (2016) “La tasa de actividad femenina en el siglo XVIII en dos municipios andaluces: Laujar de Andarax (Almería) y Úbeda (Jaén).” Investigaciones de Historia Económica–Economic History Research 12: 144–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González Agudo, D. (2017a) Población, precios y renta de la tierra en Toledo, siglos XVI–XVII, PhD diss., Universidad Complutense de Madrid.Google Scholar
González Agudo, D.. (2017b) “Prices in Toledo, sixteenth and seventeenth centuries.” Paper presented at the XII Congreso de la Asociación Española de Historia Económica, Salamanca, Spain, September 7–9.Google Scholar
González Mariscal, M. (2013) “Población, coste de la vida, producción agraria y renta de la tierra en Andalucía Occidental, 1521–1800.” PhD diss., Universidad Complutense de Madrid.Google Scholar
González Mariscal, M.. (2015) “Inflación y niveles de vida en Sevilla durante la Revolución de los Precios.” Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 33 (3): 353–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, B., and Ma, D. (2010) “Europe in an Asian Mirror: The great divergence,” in Broadberry, S., and O’Rourke, K. H. (eds.) The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe, 1700–1870, Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 264–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, E. J. (1934) American Treasure ad the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, E. J.. (1936) Money, Prices, and Wages in Valencia, Aragon, and Navarre, 1351–1500. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, E. J.. (1947) War and Prices in Spain, 1650–1800. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, E. J.. (1983) El tesoro americano y la revolución de los precios en España, 1501–1650. Barcelona: Ariel.Google Scholar
Hernández Andreu, J., ed. (1996) Historia monetaria y financiera de España. Madrid: Síntesis.Google Scholar
Hoffman, P. T., Jacks, D. S., Levin, P. A., and Lindert, P. H. (2002) “Real inequality in Europe since 1500.” The Journal of Economic History 62 (2): 322–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, P. T.. Jacks, D. S., Levin, P. A., and Lindert, P. H. (2005) “Sketching the rise of the real inequality in early modern Europe,” in Allen, R. C., Bengtsson, T., and Dribe, M. (eds.) Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 131–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horrell, S. (1996) “Home demand and British industrialization.” The Journal of Economic History 56 (3): 561604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphries, J. (2013) “The lure of aggregates and the pitfalls of the patriarchal perspective: A critique of the high wage economy interpretation of the British industrial revolution.” The Economic History Review 66 (3): 693714.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphries, J., and Sarasúa, C. (2012) “Off the record: Reconstructing women’s labour force participation in the European past.” Feminist Economies 18 (4): 3967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karagedikli, G., and Tunçer, C. (2016) “The people next door: Housing and neighbourhood in Ottoman Edirne, 1734–1814.” www.ehs.org.uk/dotAsset/34efc745-f459-4754-ba87-37f8de58a071.pdf (accessed March 1).Google Scholar
Kelly, M., and Ó Gráda, C. (2013) “Numerare Est Errare: Agricultural output and food supply in England before and during the Industrial Revolution.” The Journal of Economic History 73 (4): 1132–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lesger, C. (1986) Huur En Conjunctuur: De Woningmarkt in Amsterdam, 1550–1850. Amsterdam: Historisch Seminarium van de Universiteit van Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Lindert, P., and Williamson, J. G. (1983) “English workers’ living standards during the Industrial Revolution: A new look.” Economic History Review 36 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Livi-Bacci, M. (1988) Ensayo sobre la historia demográfica europea. Población y alimentación en Europa. Barcelona: Ariel.Google Scholar
Llopis, E. (1994) “Castilian agriculture in the seventeenth century: Depression, or ‘readjustment and adaptation’?,” in Thompson, I. A., and Yun, B. (eds.) The Castilian Crisis of the Seventeenth Century: New Perspectives on the Economic and Social History of Seventeenth-Century Spain. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 77100.Google Scholar
Llopis, E., García-Hiernaux, A., García Montero, H., González Mariscal, M., Hernández, R., and García, R. (2009) “Índices de precios de tres ciudades españolas, 1680–1800: Palencia, Madrid y Sevilla.” América Latina en la Historia Económica 32: 2980.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llopis, E., and García Montero, H. (2011) “Precios y salarios en Madrid, 1680–1800.” Investigaciones de Historia Económica-Economic History Research 7: 295309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llopis, E., Jerez, J. M., Álvaro, A., and Fernández, E. (2000) “Índices de precios de la zona noroccidental de Castilla y León, 1518–1650.” Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 3: 665–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llopis, E., Sebastián, J. A., Abarca, V., and Velasco, A. (2016) “¿Retrocedió el producto agrario por habitante en la Europa moderna? El caso castellano.” AEHE Working paper 1611. www.econpapers.repec.org/paper/ahedtaehe/1611.htm.Google Scholar
López Losa, E. (2013) “The legacy of Earl J. Hamilton: New data for the study of prices in Spain, 1650–1800.” Investigaciones de Historia Económica-Economic History Research 9: 7587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López Losa, E., and Piquero Zarauz, S. (2016) “Spanish real wages in the north-western European mirror, 1500–1800: On the timings and magnitude of the little divergence in Europe.” AEHE Working paper 1607. www.econpapers.repec.org/paper/ahedtaehe/1607.htm.Google Scholar
López-Salazar, J. (1976) “Evolución demográfica de la Mancha en el siglo XVIII.” Hispania: Revista Española de Historia 36 (133): 233300.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2003) “Measuring the Italian economy, 1300–1861.” Rivista di Storia Económica 19 (3): 265–95.Google Scholar
Malanima, P.. (2006) “An age of decline: Product and income in eighteenth–nineteenth century Italy.” Rivista di Storia Económica 22 (1): 91133.Google Scholar
Malanima, P.. (2011) “The long decline of a leading economy: GDP in central and northern Italy, 1300–1913.” European Review of Economic History 15: 169219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malanima, P.. (2013) “When did England overtake Italy? Medieval and early modern divergence in prices and wages.” European Review of Economic History 17: 4570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malanima, P.. (2016) “Energy consumption in England and Italy, 1560–1913: Two pathways toward energy transition.” Economic History Review 69 (1): 78103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marcos Martín, A. (2000) España en los siglos XVI, XVII y XVIII. Economía y sociedad. Barcelona: Crítica.Google Scholar
Martín Aceña, P. (1992) “Los precios en Europa durante los siglos XVI y XVII: estudio comparativo.” Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 3: 359–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martín Galán, M. (1985) “Nuevos datos sobre un viejo problema. El coeficiente de conversión de vecinos en habitantes.” Revista Internacional de Sociología 4: 593632.Google Scholar
Martínez Gil, F. (2010) “El Antiguo Régimen,” in De La Cruz Muñoz, J. (ed.) Historia de Toledo. De la Prehistoria al Presente. Toledo: Tilia Editorial: 265443.Google Scholar
Martz, L. (1983) Poverty and welfare in Habsbourg Spain: The example of Toledo. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, F. (1959) “Huishuren Te Brugge (1500–1796),” in Verlinden, C. (ed.) Dokumenten Voor de Geschiedenis van Prijzen En Lonen in Vlaanderen En Brabant. Vol. 3. Bruges: De Tempel: 394.Google Scholar
Montemayor, J. (1996) Tolède, entre fortune et déclin (1530–1640). Limoges: Presses Universitaires de Limoges.Google Scholar
Moreno Lázaro, J. (2001) “Precios de las subsistencias, salarios nominales y niveles de vida en Castilla la Vieja. Palencia, 1751–1861,” AEHE Working paper 0101.Google Scholar
Moreno Lázaro, J.. (2002) “¿Fomentó el capitalismo agrario la desigualdad? Salarios y niveles de vida en Castilla la Vieja, 1751–1861,” in Martínez Carrión, J. M. (ed.) El nivel de vida en la España rural, siglos XVIII–XX. Salamanca: Publicaciones de la Universidad de Alicante: 75112.Google Scholar
Munro, J. H. (2007) “Classic” review of Earl Hamilton, American treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. eh.net/bookreviews/library/munro.Google Scholar
Nadal, J. (1959) “La revolución de los precios españoles en el siglo XVI. Estado actual de la cuestión.” Hispania 1: 503–29.Google Scholar
Nef, J. U. (1937) “Prices and industrial capitalism in France and England, 1540–1640.” The Economic History Review 7 (2): 155–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nieto, J. A. (2006) Artesanos y mercaderes: una historia social y económica de Madrid: 1450–1850. Madrid: Fundamentos.Google Scholar
Nombela, J. M. (2003) Auge y decadencia en la España de los Austrias. La manufactura textil de Toledo en el siglo XVI. Toledo: Ayuntamiento de Toledo.Google Scholar
Ormrod, D., Gibson, J. M., and Lyne, O. (2011) “City and countryside revisited: Comparative rent movements in London and the South-East, 1580–1914.” University of Kent Discussion Paper 1117. kar.kent.ac.uk/29641/.Google Scholar
Özmucur, S., and Pamuk, S. (2002) “Real wages and standards of living in the Ottoman Empire, 1489–1914.” Journal of Economic History 2: 293321.Google Scholar
Pamuk, S., and Van Zanden, J. L. (2010) “Standards of living,” in Broadberry, S., and O’Rourke, K. H. (eds.) The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe. Vol. 1, 1700–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 217–34.Google Scholar
Pérez Moreda, V. (1980) Las crisis de mortalidad en la España interior (siglo XVI–XIX). Madrid: Siglo XXI.Google Scholar
Pérez Moreda, V., and Reher, D. (1997) “La población urbana española entre los siglos XVI y XVIII. Una perspectiva demográfica,” in Fortea Pérez, J. I. (ed.) Imágenes de la Diversidad. El mundo urbano en la Corona de Castilla (s. XVI–XVIII). Santander: Universidad de Cantabria: 129–64.Google Scholar
Persson, K. G. (1999) Grain markets in Europe, 1500–1900: Integration and deregulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps Brown, E. H., and Hopkins, S. V. (1956) “Seven centuries of prices of consumables, compared with builder’s wage-rates.” Economica 23: 296314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps Brown, E. H.. and Hopkins, S. V. (1957) “Wage-rates and prices: Evidence for population pressure in the sixteenth century.” Economica 24: 289306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps Brown, E. H.. and Hopkins, S. V. (1959) “Wage-rates, prices and population: Some further evidence.” Economica 26: 1838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps Brown, E. H.. and Hopkins, S. V. (1981) A Perspective of Wages and Prices. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Pomeranz, K. (2000) The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Posthumus, N. W. (1946) Inquiry into the History of Prices in Holland. Vol. 1. Leiden, The Netherlands: E. J. Brill.Google Scholar
Posthumus, N. W.. (1964) Inquiry into the History of Prices in Holland. Vol. 2. Leiden, The Netherlands: E. J. Brill.Google Scholar
Pribram, A. F. (1938) Materialien zur Geschichte der Preise und Löhne in Osterreich. Band I, Wien: Carl Ueberreuters Verlag.Google Scholar
Ramos Palencia, F. C. (2003) “La demanda de textiles en las familias castellanas a finales del Antiguo Régimen, 1750–1850: Aumento del consumo sin industrialización?,” in Llopis, E., Torras, J., and Yun, B. (eds.) El consumo en la España pre-industrial. Madrid: Marcial Pons-Centro de Estudios Políticos y Constitucionales-Caja Madrid: 141–80.Google Scholar
Reher, D. S., and Ballesteros, E. (1993) “Precios y salarios en Castilla la Nueva: la construcción de un índice de salarios reales, 1501–1991.” Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 1: 101–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ringrose, D. (1973) “The impact of a new capital city: Madrid, Toledo and New Castile, 1560–1660.” The Journal of Economic History 33 (4): 761–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ringrose, D.. (1985) Madrid y la economía española, 1560–1850: ciudad, corte y país en el antiguo régimen. Madrid: Alianza Editorial.Google Scholar
Ruiz Martín, F. (1998) “Las finanzas del Rey,” in Iglesias, C. (coord.) La monarquía hispánica. Felipe II, un monarca y su época, Real Monasterio de San Lorenzo de El Escorial. Madrid: Sociedad Estatal para la Conmemoración de los Centenarios de Felipe II y Carlos V: 387408.Google Scholar
Sarasúa, C. (2013) “¿Activos desde cuándo? La edad de acceso al mercado de trabajo en la España del siglo XVIII,” in Borrás, J. M. (ed.) El trabajo infantil en España, 1700–1950. Barcelona: Universidad de Barcelona: 6390.Google Scholar
Scholliers, E. (1962) “Un indice du loyer: les loyers anversois de 1500 à 1873,” in Studi in onore di Amintore Fanfani. Milan: Giuffrè: 595617.Google Scholar
Sebastián Amarilla, J. A. (2013) “El largo siglo XVII. Crisis en España, depresión en Castilla,” in Llopis, E., and Maluquer, J. (eds.) España en crisis: las grandes depresiones económicas 1348–2012. Barcelona: Pasado y Presente: 5996.Google Scholar
Sebastián Amarilla, J. A., García Montero, H., Zafra Oteyza, J., and Bernardos Sanz, J. U. (2008) “Del crecimiento a la decepción. La producción agrarian en Castilla-La Mancha en la Edad Moderna, una primera aproximación.” Paper presented at the IX Congreso de la Asociación Española de Historia Económica, Murcia, September 10–12.Google Scholar
Van der Wee, H. (1978) “Prices and wages as development variables: A comparison between England and the Southern Netherlands, 1400–1700,” in Schöffer, I. (ed.) Acta Historiae Neerlandicae X: 5878. Leiden: E.J. Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Ryssel, D. (1967) “De Gentse Huishoren Tussen 1500 En 1795: Bijdrage Tot de Kennis van de Konjunktuur van de Stad.” Pro Civitate Historische Uitgaven 8 (15): 101105.Google Scholar
Van Zanden, J. L. (1999) “Wages and the standard of living in Europe, 1500–1800.” European Review of Economic History 3 (2): 175–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Zanden, J. L.. (2005) “What happened to the standard of living before the Industrial Revolution? New evidence from the western part of the Netherlands,” in Allen, R. C., Bengtsson, T., and Dribe, M. (eds.) Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 179–94.Google Scholar
Van Zanden, J. L., and Van Leeuwen, B. (2012) “Persistent but not consistent: The growth of national income in Holland 1347–1807.” Explorations in Economic History 49 (2): 119–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vassberg, D. E. (1983) La venta de tierras baldías. El comunitarismo agrario y la corona de Castilla durante el siglo XVI. Madrid: Servicio de Publicaciones Agrarias.Google Scholar
Villaluenga, S. (2005) “La aparición de la partida doble en la Iglesia: el diario y mayores de la catedral de Toledo, 1533–1539.” De Computis. Revista Española de Historia de la Contabilidad 3: 147216.Google Scholar
Vries, P. H. H. (2001) “Are coal and colonies really crucial? Kenneth Pomeranz and the great divergence.” Journal of World History 12 (2): 407–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vries, P. H. H.. (2003) Via Peking Back to Manchester: Britain, the Industrial Revolution and China. Leiden, The Netherlands: CNWS Publications.Google Scholar
Weisser, M. R. (1973) “The decline of Castile revisited: The Case of Toledo.” Journal of European Economic History 2: 614–90.Google Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1. Consumption baskets in Toledo for 1521–50, 1551–1600, and 1601–50

Note: Wheat (2,940 kcal/kg), bacon (6,550 kcal/kg), beef (2,140 kcal/kg), mutton (2,125 kcal/kg), dried fish (3,220 kcal/kg), cheese (3,330 kcal/kg), eggs (1,570 kcal/kg), green grapes (681.4 kcal/kg), raisins (2,750 kcal/kg), almonds (6,100 kcal/kg), chesnuts (1,700 kcal/kg), honey (2,880 kcal/kg), lime, plaster, and charcoal are expressed in kilograms. Milk (620 kcal/kg), olive oil (9,000 kcal/kg), vinegar (40 kcal/kg), and wine (650 kcal/kg) are expressed in liters. Linen, esparto, and hemp are expressed in meters. Twine is expressed in hectograms. Bricks and tiles are expressed in units. Housing consumption is expressed in squared meters. Paper is expressed in hands.
Figure 1

TABLE 2. Relative price ratios for wheat and wine in Toledo, 1601–50 (maravedis/1,000 kcal)

Figure 2

FIGURE 1. Toledo Price Index (TPI), 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Index numbers and nine-year moving averages.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton 1983.
Figure 3

TABLE 3. Yearly rates of increase of the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650 (%)

Figure 4

FIGURE 2. Toledo Price Index and Toledo Price Index without housing, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton 1983.
Figure 5

FIGURE 3. Toledo Price Index and Reher-Ballesteros Price Index for New Castile, 1521–1650, in grams of silver. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; Hamilton 1983; and Reher and Ballesteros 1993.
Figure 6

FIGURE 4. Toledo Price Index and Allen’s Price Indices for New Castile, 1551–1650, in grams of silver. Base 100 = 1551–60 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; Hamilton (1983); and www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/Biography.aspx. Fuels prices in Toledo are expressed in BTUs.
Figure 7

FIGURE 5. Toledo Price Index and Seville Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. R2 = 0.93.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (1983). Data on Seville are courtesy of Manuel González Mariscal.
Figure 8

FIGURE 6a. Price indices in several European cities and regions, in grams of silver, 1551–1650. Base 100 = 1551–60 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/biography.aspx, ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (1983).
Figure 9

FIGURE 6b. Price indices in several European cities and regions, in grams of silver, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–30 average. Nine-year moving averages.

Source: www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/People/sites/Allen/SitePages/biography.aspx, ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (1983).
Figure 10

FIGURE 7. Standard deviations of the logarithmic variation rates for the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–0 average. Index numbers and thirty-year moving periods.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (1983).
Figure 11

FIGURE 8. Standard deviations of the logarithmic variation rates for the Toledo Price Index, 1521–1650. Base 100 = 1521–0 average. Index numbers and thirty-year moving periods.

Source: ABCT, Obra y Fábrica, Libros de la Obra, 796–908; AMT, Caja de Vino, 2405–9; and Hamilton (1983).
Supplementary material: PDF

González Agudo supplementary material

González Agudo supplementary material 1

Download González Agudo supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 776.1 KB