Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-f46jp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-04T16:08:49.524Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE ABSOLUTION OF HISTORY: CUBAN LIVING STANDARDS AFTER 60 YEARS OF REVOLUTIONARY RULE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 November 2020

John Devereux*
Affiliation:
City University of New Yorka
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Six decades ago, Cuba initiated a momentous social and economic experiment. This paper documents the effects of the experiment on Cuban living standards. Before the revolution, Cuban income per capita was on a par with Ireland or Finland. Indeed, Cuba was one of the richest of the Spanish-speaking societies. Growth is glacially slow after the revolution as GDP per capita increased by 40 per cent between 1957 and 2017 equal to an annual growth rate of 0.6 per cent—among the lowest anywhere. To be sure, other dimensions of well-being such as education and health improved, yet broader welfare measures do not change the conclusion that the revolution impoverished Cuba relative to any plausible counter factual.

Resumen

RESUMEN

Hace seis décadas Cuba inició un monumental experimento social y económico. Este estudio documenta los efectos de ese experimento sobre los estándares de vida cubanos. Antes de la revolución, el ingreso per cápita cubano estaba al nivel de Irlanda y Finlandia. De hecho, Cuba era una de las sociedades de habla hispana más ricas. Después de la revolución el crecimiento es glacialmente lento con solo cuarenta por ciento de crecimiento en PIB per cápita, igual a una tasa de crecimiento del 0.6 por ciento, entre los más bajos de todo el mundo. Sin duda, otras dimensiones más amplias del bienestar, como educación y salud, mejoraron, sin embargo esto no cambia la conclusión de que la revolución empobreció a Cuba en relación a cualquier otro contrafactual.

Type
Articles/Artículos
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Instituto Figuerola, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

«Condemn me, it does not matter: history will absolve me»

Fidel Castro (16 October 1953), closing words of speech delivered at his trial following the Moncada Barracks attack.

1. INTRODUCTION

The Cuban revolution is a defining event in 20th century Latin American history. For six decades, the revolution has fascinated intellectuals and academics producing an immense literature which continues to inspire debateFootnote 1. For the most part, social scientists have neglected the economic consequences of revolutionary ruleFootnote 2. The omission is surprising because to evaluate the successes and failures of Cuban communism, we need to have some notion of how the revolution changed Cuban living standards. One reason why economic questions are absent from the general literature on Cuba is data. Consider the following, we do not have a satisfactory GDP or consumption series for the revolutionary economy. Along similar lines, there is no purchasing power parity (PPP) adjusted GDP comparison for revolutionary Cuba so we have only a rough idea of how Cuban income compares to other economies. In sum, we are ignorant of the most basic contours of the revolutionary economy.

The gaps in our knowledge hamper economic research on Cuba. Two examples should suffice. Jales et al. (Reference Jales, Kang, Stein and Ribeiro2018) provide counterfactuals for the revolutionary economy. As a second example, Bologna Pavlik and Geloso (Reference Bologna Pavlik and Geloso2018) study Cuban healthcare using a similar approach. Both studies suffer from flaws in the existing GDP series.

This article fills in some of the blanks in the economic record. More precisely, I make «controlled conjectures» about Cuban living standards as measured by GDP, and consumption. I also investigate broader measures of capabilities including education and healthcare using the Human Development Index (HDI) of the United Nations. My goal is to place Cuban living standards, defined broadly, in proper comparative perspective. The results are tentative and subject to possibly large margins of error. Yet, I find enough information to render an unequivocal verdict on the Cuban experiment.

The core of the article takes data collected by Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987), the Central Intelligence Agency (henceforth the CIA) de-classified after the Cold War, and many other sources and uses it to construct GDP and consumption indices from 1957 to 1985. I do so by applying to Cuba various approaches developed by Western scholars to measure Soviet GDP. After 1985, I rely on the Cuban national accounts which are partly constructed along western lines. I say partly because Cuban indices differ in important respects from standard measures which require that I adjust the Cuban series to better approximate United Nations procedures.

To provide a GDP series for the six decades of revolutionary rule, I combine my GDP estimates for 1957-1985 with the adjusted Cuban national accounts after 1985. The resulting GDP series trace the evolution of the Cuban economy from initial revolutionary fervour, the rapprochement with the Soviet Union, the «special period» and its long aftermath to the alliance with Venezuela.

The results show disappointing growth. Income per capita fell in the early 1960s and it did not return to pre-revolutionary levels until 1976. From the early 1970s, the economy improves with massive Soviet aid and improved policy. By 1985, GDP per capita was 24 per cent above 1957. The late 1980s turned out to be a high-water mark for Cuba as the collapse of the Soviet Union and the cessation of Soviet aid produced a calamity—a 50 per cent fall in income during the «special period» of the early 1990s. In the aftermath of the special period, it has taken Cuba 30 years to regain the 1980s income peaks. Income per capita for recent years is about 15 per cent higher than the late 1980s—greatly helped by Venezuelan aid.

To sum up, Cuban GDP per capita increased by 40 per cent from 1957 to 2017 yielding an annual growth rate of 0.60 per cent. After 1970, the labour force participation rate increased due to slower population growth and the entrance of women to the labour force for earlier years. As a result, output per worker grows by less than income per capita. For recent years, it is slightly above its 1957 levels. In sum, Cuba has one of the slowest growth rates in the world economy over the six decades of revolutionary rule which means that Cuba has moved sharply down the world income distribution.

One way to grasp the extent of Cuba's relative decline is to compare Cuban living standards to the United States, Europe and Latin America before the revolution to its standing now. I show that Cuba of the late 1950s was, in relative terms, a fairly prosperous middle-income society with consumption on a par with Finland and Ireland and above Spain. Along with Puerto Rico and the Southern Cone, Cuba had the highest income of any Spanish speaking society. For recent years, Cuba is counted with Guatemala among the poor of the Western Hemisphere.

My estimates of Cuban GDP and PPP-adjusted living standards are tentative. More and better data will improve our knowledge. They are unlikely to change the finding that the revolution failed to improve Cuban living standards relative to any plausible counterfactual. Yet to render justice to the Cuban experiment, we must credit the revolution for its achievements in healthcare and education. The final section of the article sets the gains in health, and education against the stagnation in living standards where, following the lead of Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015a, Reference Prados de la Escosura2015b, Reference Prados de la Escosura2019), I apply a broader measure of well-being based on the HDI of the United Nations. Cuba does better in this setting but not by much.

The HDI covers education and health along with income. As currently constituted, the HDI does not allow us to pass judgment on revolutionary Cuba since it does not consider the destruction of civil society and the suppression of basic liberties at the hands of the revolution. Taking such matters into account is a daunting task as economists do not have an accepted framework with which to balance income, health and education against personal freedoms. Even if we did, the Cuban record for health and education is contested and its achievements in these areas depend on the coercive power of the Cuban state. I sidestep these difficulties by applying an approach borrowed from the Cuban economist Carlos Diaz Alejandro (Reference Diaz-Alejandro1973) based, in turn, upon insights associated with John Rawls. The results of this test are conclusive suggesting history will not absolve the revolution, or its guiding light—Fidel Castro.

2. TRACKING GDP AND CONSUMPTION

This section provides new GDP and consumption indices for 1957-1985. In addition, I modify Cuba's western-style national accounts, available at 1985, to bring them more in line with United Nations measures. The final step combines the 1957-1985 GDP series with the modified national accounts to cover the entire period of revolutionary rule. As will be clear, the resulting GDP series is tentative with potentially large errors. They are, however, sufficient for their purpose which is to determine broad trends in income and consumption after the revolution.

For the first three decades of the revolution, the Cuban authorities compiled their national accounts using the Soviet Bloc MPS (Material Product System). The estimates frustrated outside scholars as they were bedevilled by changes in methodology, lapses in publication, opaque documentation and uncertainties about deflationFootnote 3.

2.1 GDP: 1957-1985

Measuring GDP for revolutionary Cuba faces two obstacles. Most fundamentally, Cuban prices are set by planners and are unlikely to reflect resource costs or consumer valuationFootnote 4. A second issue is whether to trust data supplied by Cuba. The scholarly consensus is that the Cuban authorities do not falsify basic data in any systematic fashion. Rather, as Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago1969) and Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1991) show, data are not published when it might embarrass the authorities. An example of this occurs during the «special period» of the early 1990s when Cuba ceased publication of many series. On the other hand, there is also a consensus that Cuban indices—industrial production, GDP, the CPI, etc.—must be viewed sceptically as they often exaggerate economic performanceFootnote 5. Of course, this tendency is not confined to planned economics but, as shown by Martinez (Reference Martinez2019), appears to hold for autocratic regimes generally.

To get around the first problem, I construct GDP with pre-revolutionary 1957 prices. The resulting measure is conceptually valid as 1957 prices measure resource costs and consumer valuation in an acceptable fashion. On the other hand, early period prices come with a cost as relative prices change with planning. Even if that were not the case, any set of relative prices become outdated after three decades. For future reference, note that 1957 prices will overstate growth through the «Gerschenkron effect» named after the Russian economic historian where early period prices lead to higher measured growth rates as compared to late period pricesFootnote 6. The bias from 1957 prices will therefore exaggerate Cuban growth, perhaps considerablyFootnote 7. For my purposes, however, this is not a serious handicap as I prefer that if a bias exists it overstates Cuban achievements. On the other hand, there are other biases, particularly for industrial production, which will understate growth, so the overall effects are uncertain.

Following the literature on planned economies, I measure Cuban GDP from the output side. Table 1 provides the 1957 value-added weights derived from various declassified CIA reports released after the Cold War (CIA 1968, 1970, 1972), Oshima (Reference Oshima1961) and Ward and Devereux (Reference Ward and Devereux2012). The sub-weights are discussed in the online Supplementary materials.

TABLE 1 GDP WEIGHTS

Sources: See online supplementary materials.

Agriculture and manufacturing dominated the Cuban economy before the revolution with sugar accounting for one half of agriculture and 40 per cent of manufacturing. To obtain GDP, I construct sectoral output indices and aggregate upwardsFootnote 8. The online Supplementary materials provide details. As discussed there, I apply a methodology developed by Nutter (Reference Nutter1962), Moorsteen and Powell (Reference Moorsteen and Powell1966) and Kaplan (Reference Kaplan1969) for the Soviet Union. Following their work, I construct sectoral gross output indices as a weighted average of quantity relatives using base year (1957) shares in value added (or gross output in the case of agriculture) as weights. GDP therefore rests on quantity data. For example, I measure sugar output by tons of sugar, steel by tons of steel and so on. Output data are widely available for Cuba and they are generally accepted by outside scholarsFootnote 9.

Equation [1] gives GDP in 1957 prices for year t where Q(.) is the GDP quantity index, θj is the share of jth sector in 1957 value added, and p and x are prices and quantities.

(1)$$Q\lpar {\,p^{1957}\comma \;x^t\comma \;x^{1957}} \rpar = \sum {\theta _j^{1957} } x_j^t /x_j^{1957} $$

From 1957 to 1965, I take data from various declassified CIA reports supplemented by Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984). Data are scarce for 1959 and 1960 due to the chaos in the Cuban statistical system. Things improve somewhat from 1961 to 1965. For example, Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984) provides some series but their provenance is unknown and should be viewed cautiously. After 1965, more data are available, and I rely on the painstaking work of Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987) supplemented by Locay and Roberts (Reference Locay and Roberts2012) along with the CIA annuals. Pérez-López collects data from a wide variety of sources starting at 1965 and ending at 1982. Locay and Roberts (Reference Locay and Roberts2012) draw on a narrower collection of sources related more to consumption taken mainly from Anuario Estadístico de Cuba, but their data extend to recent years.

As discussed in the online Supplementary materials, the GDP index faces difficult issues of quality change, the introduction of new products and changes in the ratio of value added to gross output in addition to the index number problems discussed earlierFootnote 10. The overall direction of possible biases in GDP is not clear, but they are potentially large.

2.2 The National Accounts 1985-2017

After the fall of the Eastern Bloc, Cuba switched to United Nations national accounting measures, albeit with distinctly Cuban features. The Cuban United Nations-style series start at 1985. They cover GDP from the expenditure and output sides. I focus on the output side measure to be consistent with the GDP index of the last section.

For most sectors, the output indices from the post-1985 national accounts seem to accord with standard United Nations procedures. Two problems remainFootnote 11. First, the authorities publish series with different base year prices and with different United Nations (1968 and 1993) methodologies. In addition, revisions are frequent and large. To date, I found it difficult to construct a consistent series using official publicationsFootnote 12.

Second, and more importantly, there are methodological problems with the Cuban national accounts. First, Cuba does not value government-provided services such as healthcare and education at cost—rather it uses «social valuation» where Cuba calculates the value of goods and services provided by the public sector at Cuban-determined prices (Pérez-López and Mesa-Lago Reference Pérez-López and Mesa-Lago2010).

The second problem is that, starting in the 2000s, Cuba obtains most of its foreign exchange from the export of services in the shape of doctors and other professionals to Venezuela, though Brazil was important to 2018. Cuba appears to count these exports as domestic production in the national accounts despite the fact the professionals are resident outside Cuba and hence revenue from this source might be better counted as factor income from abroad. As discussed in the online Supplementary materials, this biased GDP growth rates upward.

The solution to the first problem is straightforward—the United Nations provides a consistent series using data supplied by the Cuban authoritiesFootnote 13. How the United Nations estimates are constructed is not obvious, but they are probably the best that one can hope for. To solve the second problem, methodological incompatibility, I assume that output in the affected sectors moves with the aggregate of all other sectors. The online Supplementary materials explain and justify this assumption. As it turns out, the revised GDP series shows slower growth rates as compared to the official series as the official index is 20 per cent higher in 2017 than the modified series.

2.3 Growth and the Revolutionary Economy

Figure 1 provides GDP per capita for the six decades of revolutionary rule by combining the new GDP index from 1957 to 1985 and the modified national account GDP series described aboveFootnote 14. Although my focus in this article is on incomes rather than labour productivity, I also provide GDP per worker.

FIGURE 1 GDP PER CAPITA AND PER WORKER—1957 TO 2017 (1957 = 100).

Sources: Author's calculations. The annual series are in the data appendix.

The estimates show that GDP per capita holds up for 1959 and 1960. By 1963, GDP per capita falls by 15 per cent with collectivisation, the U.S. embargo, the exit of managerial and skilled workers and the chaos of the move to planning. There is a further decline in the late 1960s with the fiasco of the ten-million-ton sugar harvest. As a result, GDP per capita is below 1957 until 1976Footnote 15. Growth improves in the 1970s when the Soviet Union steps up aid and Cuba moves to orthodox Soviet-style planning. The economy expands at solid rates until 1985 where income per capita is 24 per cent above 1957. Growth slows after 1985 with the political upheavals associated with the «rectification» program.

I measure output per worker as GDP divided by the economically active population, the labour force, as employment statistics are questionable especially after the special period. The labour force numbers are rough estimates as it is difficult to put together a consistent series after the 1970s. Note that the share of the Cuban population in the labour force increased from the early 1970s as population growth slowed and the labour force participation of women increased up to around 2010Footnote 16. Figure 1 shows that output per worker is constant for the 1980s. By 2017, output per worker was only 5 per cent above 1957 levels, as labour productivity has hardly increased in over six decadesFootnote 17. Soviet assistance is crucial for the improved performance of the 1980s. As shown in the Supplementary materials, Soviet aid increases from 10 per cent of GDP in the early 1960s to 28 per cent in the early 1980sFootnote 18.

The good years for Cuba end when the demise of the Soviet Union halts Soviet aid and sets Cuban enterprises adrift from their Eastern Bloc suppliers. At the same time, the Cuban government was denied access to world capital markets or to loans from the IMF or World Bank. The combination of shocks produced an economic collapse—the «special period». GDP fell by 50 per cent between 1988 and 1993. The official national accounts show a 40 per cent decline.

The recovery from the «special period» is glacially slow as the Cuban economy picks up steam only with aid from Venezuela which starts in the early 2000s. Cuba reaches its 1985 GDP per capita (barely) in 2012. By 2017, GDP is 15 per cent above 1985. Another way of looking at the Cuban record is to observe that GDP per capita in Figure 1 is below 1957 levels for 33 of the 59 years of revolutionary rule.

The GDP growth rates of this article are below Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984), Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987), Zimbalist and Brundenius (Reference Zimbalist and Brundenius1991) and the Cuban national accounts. To illustrate the differences, I combine Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984) for 1957-1965, Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987) from 1965 to 1982 and the unadjusted national accounts to 2017. I term this series Alternative I. The second series, Alternative II, substitutes Zimbalist and Brundenius (Reference Zimbalist and Brundenius1991) for Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987)Footnote 19. It shows yet higher growth rates.

Figure 2 compares the earlier GDP series with my estimates. The first series, Alternative I, shows a ratio of income per capita in 2017 to 1957 of 2.35 compared to my estimate of 1.43. The second series, Alternative II, shows a ratio of 3.05, close to the average growth rate among all economies in the Penn World Tables (PWT) for the period.

FIGURE 2 GDP PER CAPITA—1957 TO 2017 ALTERNATIVE ESTIMATES (1957 = 100).

Sources: see data appendix for sources. Note for Series I Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987) reaches only to 1982. For 1982 to 1985 I use National Accounts.

Below are growth rates for GDP per capita over sub-periods from the various sources (Table 2):

TABLE 2 COMPARING GROWTH RATES FOR GDP PER CAPITA

Notes: The estimates for Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984) cover from 1965 to 1981.

The online Supplementary materials (Table A6) reconcile my GDP estimates with earlier series. To summarise, the differences with Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987) arise because he shows higher growth rates for services and agriculture while omitting slow-growing sectors such as housing. In addition, I show that industrial production growth from Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984) and Zimbalist and Brundenius (Reference Zimbalist and Brundenius1991) is too high. They also rely on flawed official Cuban indices for other sectors which further overstates growthFootnote 20. Finally, and as mentioned earlier, the official national accounts since 1985 exaggerate growth for health, education and government services.

The implausibility of earlier GDP series can be seen in a simple fashion. Suppose that some version of the alternate GDP series is correct. From Figure 2, GDP per capita for 1993, the worst year of the «special period», is equal to 1957 using Alternative series I and is 30 per cent above 1957 using Alternative series II. These results are close to impossible. After all, Cuba experienced terrible hardships during the «special period». Calories were below 2,000 (Sixto Reference Sixto2002) as Cuba came close to mass starvation. The crisis decimated public transportation and public utilities. Cars disappeared from the streets. Sales of clothing and consumer durables ceasedFootnote 21. Thus, it is hard to see how GDP per capita for 1993 could be above the relatively prosperous late Republic. In contrast, my estimates for 1993 show income per capita is 40 per cent below 1957—consistent with what we know about the special period.

To summarise, Cuba has grown at slow rates since the revolution. To put the Cuban record into comparative perspective, I turn to Version 9.0 of the PWT which provides data on GDP per capita for 110 economies from 1960 and 2014Footnote 22. From 1960 to 2014, Cuban GDP per capita increases by 36 per cent using the GDP index of this articleFootnote 23. For Taiwan and Korea, GDP increased by multiples of fifteen. For Spain and Portugal, income increased fourfold. For most developing economies, income increased three to fourfold. For the United States, income per capita trebled. For slow-growing economies such as Argentina and Uruguay, income per capita doubled. In terms of growth rates, Cuba comes in at 100 out of the 111 casesFootnote 24. In short, revolutionary Cuba has an exceptionally poor economic record.

2.4 Consumption

There are three reasons to consider consumption separately from GDP. First, the consumption estimates are largely independent of the GDP measures of the last section. Second, consumption is more closely related to welfare than GDP. Finally, consumption avoids some of the difficult conceptual problems associated with Cuban GDP. Most notably, consumption is not distorted by terms of trade changes and it better reflects the receipt of Soviet aid.

I measure consumption from 1957 to 1985 using 1957 prices. Throughout, I follow the procedures developed by CIA analysts in their work on Soviet consumption (Schroeder and Denton Reference Schroeder and Denton1982). The consumption index consists of quantity relatives weighted by base year shares in consumption. I create the sub-indices using quantities such as food measured in kgs, passenger kms for travel, etc. Data are mostly from the sources used for the GDP index.

I provide two measures of consumption, household consumption which is spending by households and total consumption which adds publically supplied education and healthcare to household consumption.

Figure 3 traces the series for consumption per capita from 1957 to 1985.

FIGURE 3 CONSUMPTION PER CAPITA—1957 TO 1985.

Sources: Author's calculations. The annual series are in the data appendix.

The results differ from GDP. Household consumption drops by 20 per cent in the early 1960s compared to a 15 per cent drop for GDP as the revolutionary authorities increase investment and government spending at the expense of consumption. It recovers its 1957 levels by 1973 and increases thereafter. Household consumption peaks in 1985 where it is 20 per cent above the late republic. As discussed in the online Supplementary materials, the increase in personal consumption is largely underwritten by Soviet aidFootnote 25.

The improvements in household consumption understate consumer well-being as Cuba increased spending on healthcare and, especially, education after the revolution. Including education and healthcare, total consumption falls by 12 per cent in the early 1960s. Moreover, total consumption is back to its 1957 levels by 1968. By 1985, it is 40 per cent above 1957.

The official series for consumption begins in 1985. I was unable to modify the national accounts to provide a useable series for consumption after 1985. But there is little reason to suppose that the performance of consumption differs much from income.

To sum up, Cuba has seen anaemic GDP growth over the 60 years of the revolution. Slow growth means that revolutionary Cuba has slipped down the world income distribution. The next section makes this point directly.

3. AN EUROPEAN MIRROR

I compare Cuban income and consumption to the outside world for 1955 and 2011. The comparisons sharpen the picture of Cuba's relative decline. They also provide an independent estimate of Cuban growth. Finally, they are a vital ingredient to the broader welfare comparisons, covering education, health and personal liberties, that follow.

As a standard, I compare Cuba to Iberia and Latin America. I also compare Cuba to Western Europe. The European mirror brings into sharper focus the fact that Cuba and the Southern Cone once shared similar living standards with middle-income European economies. Finally, the advanced economies of Europe were once the countries to which Republican Cuba aspired (Speck Reference Speck2005).

3.1 The Comparisons

I compare income and consumption. I chose 1955 as this year has the widest coverage prior to the Cuban revolution while 2011 is the latest round of the International Comparison Program (ICP). The comparisons cover thirty-eight countries. There are three sources for 1955. The high-quality estimates of Gilbert and Kravis (Reference Gilbert and Kravis1954, Reference Gilbert and Kravis1958) cover the major European economies. Latin America is from Braithwaite (Reference Braithwaite1968) and is of somewhat lower quality. Dewhurst et al. (Reference Dewhurst, Coppock and Yates1961) provide rough estimates for other European economies prepared for, but not reported in, Gilbert and Kravis (Reference Gilbert and Kravis1958). In addition, I use Bergson (Reference Bergson and Daly1972) for the Soviet Union. For Cuba, I use the Ward and Devereux (Reference Ward and Devereux2012) estimate for 1955.

For 2011, I use ICP estimates with the exception of Puerto Rico and Cuba. My source for Cuban 2011 PPP-adjusted income per capita is the United Nations Human Development Report (HDRO). The HDI report puts 2011 Cuban GNI per capita at $6,821. This is one-half of Costa Rica ($14,006) and is below Jamaica ($8,350). As discussed in section 4 of the online Supplementary materials, it may overstate Cuban income. Again, if there is a bias, I prefer it to work in the direction of overstating Cuban incomeFootnote 26. For both years, Puerto Rico is from Devereux (Reference Devereux2019)

I compare income using GDP rather than GNI as I do not have GNI for 1955. There are, however, three countries where I use GNI: Cuba, Puerto Rico and Ireland. GNI makes more sense because of large factor income outflows for Ireland and Puerto Rico and inflows for Cuba. I discuss the relationship between GDP and GNI for Cuba in section 6 of the online Supplementary materials. Finally, all comparisons compare income using the relative prices of the comparison yearFootnote 27. The 1955 comparisons are bilateral Fisher Ideal indices while the 2011 ICP comparisons are generalised Fisher Ideal indices.

As we might expect, the United States has a commanding lead for 1955. Western European income/consumption averages 50-60 per cent of U.S. levels. Next are the middle-income economies, Argentina, Cuba, Puerto Rico and Uruguay in Latin America and Ireland, Finland, and Italy in Europe. For these economies, income/consumption is 30-35 per cent of the United States, that is, 60-70 per cent of Western Europe.

At 35 per cent of the United States, Cuban consumption for 1955 equals Ireland. It exceeds Italy, Greece, Spain and Portugal in Europe. It is close to Austria and the Netherlands. Thus, Cuba shares with Puerto Rico and the Southern Cone the highest consumption level for Spanish-speaking societies.

The 1955 Cuban ranking is not controversial. Oshima (Reference Oshima1961), for example, provides an early PPP-adjusted measure of Cuban GDP for 1953 which placed Cuban income levels at those of ItalyFootnote 28. Using a «short cut» methodology, Locay (Reference Locay2009) also reached similar rankings to Table 3. Finally, contempory observers for the 1950s saw the island as a middle-income economyFootnote 29.

TABLE 3 GDP AND CONSUMPTION PER CAPITA—1955 AND 2011 (United States = 100)

Notes and Sources: The table compares real income and consumption using current prices. I use GDP per capita to measure income for all countries except Cuba, Ireland and Puerto Rico in 2011 where I replace GDP with GNI. The 1955 comparisons are Fisher Ideal comparisons of income and consumption while 2011 is a multilateral generalisation of the Fisher Ideal called the Elteto Koves and Szulc (EKS) index. The 1955 benchmarks are from Ward and Devereux (Reference Ward and Devereux2012) with the following exceptions. For Puerto Rico, I use Devereux (Reference Devereux2019). For Austria, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and Portugal, I use Dewhurst et al. (Reference Dewhurst, Coppock and Yates1961). For Cuba in 2011, I use the UN Human Development Report estimates. This relates to GNI. I assume that it also holds for relative consumption. I take the 2011 results from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/ICPEXT/Resources/ICP_2011.html, as data necessary to calculate the Fisher Ideal for 2011 are not available. Argentina is not in the 2011 ICP and I take income from the UN HDI where I assume relative income equals consumption. The final column gives the ratio of Cuban GDP per capita in 2011 to 1955 as implied by the GDP comparisons and growth rates from the Penn World Tables where I measure growth using the rgdpe measure which is expenditure-side real GDP at chained PPPs (in US$2011 million). I use rgdpna which is real GDP at constant 2011 national prices (in US$2011 million) for Argentina and El Salvador for reasons explained in the text.

By 2011, Norway leads in income while the United States leads in consumption. The Western European economies have partly caught up to the United States while Spain and Ireland are closer to the European leaders. For Cuba, the striking feature of Table 3 is relative decline. Cuba is no longer a middle-income economy and income per capita equals Guatemala or Paraguay. Thus, Cuba has fallen behind Greece, Spain and Ireland, Portugal and most of Latin America. Indeed, the only remaining Latin economies with lower incomes are Bolivia, Honduras and Nicaragua.

3.2 Implied Growth Rates

The series for Cuban GDP of the last section are tentative with unknown, but potentially large, margins of error. Fortunately, Table 3 provides a crosscheck. Suppose for the moment, that the income comparisons in Table 3 are without error and that all comparisons are transitive. It is easy to show that if we know relative Cuban income in 1955 and 2011 and if we have a GDP series for each partner country, then we can calculate an implied Cuban GDP growth rate which can cross-check the results of previous sections.

To see how this works, take Uruguay. For 1955, the ratio of income per capita for Uruguay to Cuba from Table 3 is 1.25. For 2011, the ratio is 2.5. Using the PWT, the ratio of Uruguayan GDP per capita in 2011 to 1955 is 2.29. A simple calculation shows that the implied ratio of Cuban GDP per capita in 2011 to 1955 is 1.15 as compared to a ratio of 1.34 using the Cuban GDP series of the last sectionFootnote 30.

There are thirty-eight comparisons in Table 3. The PWT provides GDP series for thirty-five of these economies yielding thirty-five implied Cuban growth rates in the final column of Table 3Footnote 31. The results show some differences in implied growth rates as the standard deviation of the comparisons is 0.32. This is expected given the complexities of comparing GDP over time and across spaceFootnote 32. On the other hand, we expect errors in the comparisons to partly offsetFootnote 33. The point is that Cuba does poorly in all comparisons. At the extremes, Nicaragua implies a Cuban income ratio of 0.57 while Austria has an implied income ratio of 1.95. Thus, upper and lower bounds imply glacially slow growth by international standards.

To summarise, I define the implied growth rate of Cuban GDP per capita from 1955 to 2011 (Gc) as the simple average of implied growth rates from all possible calculations (gc,i) in Table 3.

(2)$$G_c = 1/n\sum {g_{c\comma i}} $$

Across all comparisons, the ratio of implied Cuban GDP per capita for 2011 to 1955 is 1.23Footnote 34. The GDP series of the last section implies a ratio of 1.34 for Cuban income in 2011 to 1955. The close correspondence while pleasing is coincidental. More generally, one should interpret the results as being consistent with claims of slow Cuban growth. Of course, a lower estimate of relative Cuba income for 1955 in Table 3 or a higher estimate for 2011 will change the results but it is unlikely to change them by much since the 1955 comparison is conservative and the 2011 comparison likely overstates income.

Once we accept that income growth since the revolution is, at best, mediocre then the case for the revolution rests on healthcare and education.

4. CAPABILITIES

Well-being does not depend solely on income or consumption. Accordingly, this section enlarges the discussion to include healthcare and education. One measure of health is life expectancy. Cuban life expectancy is impressive (79 years for 2011) given its low income. The island also performs well on measures of educational attainment such as average years of education. The broader comparisons turn out to improve Cuba's standing for 2011, but not by much.

The most widely accepted broad measure of development is the HDI of the United Nations where the HDI measures «capabilities» by considering education and health in addition to income. The HDI is the geometric index, given by equation [3], of income (Y) as measured by Gross National Income (GNI), health as given by life expectancy (H) and education given by average years of education (E) and expected years of education (not included).

(3)$${\rm HD}{\rm I}_i = \lpar {{\rm Y}.{\rm H}.{\rm E}} \rpar ^{1/3}$$

The UN scales the sub-indices to ensure they are bounded between zero and one using the transformation of the ith element given by [4].

(4)$$\eqalign{&{\rm Inde}{\rm x}_i = \lpar {{\rm Actual}\,{\rm Valu}{\rm e}_i\ndash {\rm Minimum}\,{\rm Valu}{\rm e}_i} \rpar /\cr&\lpar {{\rm Maximum}\,{\rm valu}{\rm e}_i\ndash {\rm Minimum}\,{\rm Valu}{\rm e}_i} \rpar} $$

I use the HDI as my organising framework. To begin, I provide standard HDI measures for 2 years, 1955 and 2011, for the economies of the last sectionFootnote 35. As mentioned, I lack GNI for 1955 so I use GDP. For 2011, I measure income with GNI for Cuba, Ireland and Puerto Rico for reasons explained earlier. In addition, I use average years of education only as expected years of education are not available for 1955. Finally, I follow the United Nations by measuring income using logs. I will return to this assumption later.

Table 4 provides the HDIs for 1955 and 2011. To ease interpretation, I give rankings from the highest to the lowest. For 1955, the United States leads followed by Western Europe. Cuba is a respectable twentieth of thirty-eight economies. It trails Uruguay and Argentina in Latin America—principally because Cuban life expectancy (62.3) is below Uruguay (67) and Argentina (64.5)Footnote 36.

TABLE 4 CUBA AND HUMAN DEVELOPMENT—1955 AND 2011

Notes and Sources: The table compares income from Table 3 by using U.S. GDP per capita from the PWT to scale the results. Life expectancy and average years of education for 1955 are from the Clio website at https://clio-infra.eu/. Life expectancy and years of education for 2011 are from the UN HDI dataset at: http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/human-development-index-hdi. For Puerto Rico, I use Devereux (Reference Devereux2019).

The Cuban standings for education and life expectancy for 1955 were lower than its income would suggest. By 2011, the opposite holds. Cuban life expectancy at 79 equals the United States. It is above Latin America except Costa Rica. Cuba (11.3) also leads Latin America in years of education except for Puerto Rico (13). Indeed, Cuba ranks higher than Portugal (7.8) or Spain (8.5). The Cuban outcomes for health and education are therefore characteristic of a wealthy society—impressive for a poor island. For 2011, Cuba ranks third in the index for Latin America below Puerto Rico (13th!) and a little behind Chile. It is above Portugal. These findings are similar to Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015a) who found Puerto Rico and Cuba with the highest human development for Latin AmericaFootnote 37.

Can education and health rescue the revolution? Not necessarily. There are four objections to the Cuban HDI rankings. First, there are questions about Cuban healthcare and education. For healthcare, Gonzalez (Reference Gonzalez2015) makes a persuasive case that biased reporting reduced measured Cuban infant mortality rates hence overstating life expectancy, perhaps by a year or so. Even making this adjustment, Cuba does well relative to Latin America. If life expectancy is overstated by 2 years, an upper bound, then the Cuban ranking for 2011 falls to 21. On the positive side, Cuba provides access for all Cubans to basic healthcare without racial or income disparities and most scholars accept that the gains in healthcare are realFootnote 38.

For education, the Cuban performance at the elementary level at first glance is excellentFootnote 39. Most notably, UNESCO (2008) shows that Cuba had the highest third and sixth grade math and reading scores for Latin America and the Caribbean which has impressed many observers. But recent work by Peterson (Reference Peterson2020) has gone some distance to undermining these results. In addition, the evidence for high school and college education is mixed. Universities lack proper facilities with poor libraries, few textbooks and little connection to the Internet. The quality of instruction is also questionable. On the other hand, Locay and Devereux (Reference Locay and Devereux2018) use U.S. labour market outcomes to provide evidence on Cuban educational quality which suggests that the quality of education is at least equal to the late Republic.

Second, it might be argued that we should compare the revolutionary outcomes to the counterfactual of what would have occurred had the Republic survived. Income per capita would surely be higher in the absence of revolution. Sceptics might also claim that health might not be much different given the well-developed Cuban health system of the 1950s as evidenced by the low levels of infant mortality in Republican Cuba (McGuire and Frankel Reference McGuire and Frankel2005)Footnote 40. For education, I suspect that the arguments for the revolution are stronger—at least at the primary level. It should also be kept in mind that the revolutionary state likely realised the gains in education and health sooner than would alternative governments and that it also allowed better access to disadvantaged groups such as Afro-Cubans and the rural poor.

Third, the HDI results require diminishing returns to income. As the United Nations states:

The idea is to emphasize the diminishing marginal utility of transforming income into human capabilities. This means that the concave logarithmic transformation makes clearer the notion that an increase of GNI per capita by $100 in a country where the average income is only $500 has a much greater impact on the standard of living than the same $100 increase in a country where the average income is $5,000 or $50,000Footnote 41.

There is, to be sure, empirical support for diminishing marginal utility of income, (Layard et al. Reference Layard, Mayraz and Nickell2008). One might, however, use the same argument for education and for health as measured by longevity. One extra year of education, when average years of education are four, is likely to have a larger impact on capabilities compared to where average years of education are fifteenFootnote 42. Yet, the HDI requires diminishing returns to income as without it, income dominates the rankings. Suppose that per capita income is an input that produces capability. It follows that per capita income enters the index at a declining rate since its return in terms of capabilities must diminish as education and health are boundedFootnote 43. In what follows I assume diminishing returns as without it capabilities do not matter.

The final, and in my view the most important, objection to the HDI for Cuba is that it ignores personal freedoms. Over its six decades, revolutionary Cuba has exercised close control over its citizens at the block and household level working through local Committees for the Defense of the Revolution and its large and well-funded security forcesFootnote 44. Revolutionary Cuba remains a society where dissent is criminalised, and where the authorities enforce compliance with the dictates of the state apparatus. Moreover, the Cuban institutions also appear to be outliers in their all-encompassing natureFootnote 45.

A further complicating factor is that the reduction in Cuban inequality for the first decades of the revolution along with the improvements in health and education owes much to the regimes ability to control the behaviour of its citizens through harsh coercive means. One way to see this is with healthcare where the Cuban successes for life expectancy are partly due to the astonishing number of Cuban doctors. Any relaxation in the power of the state will lead to an outflow of doctors to countries where they are better paid. A more controversial question is whether the Cuban authorities reduced infant mortality through forced abortions and the confinement of expectant mothers in maternity homesFootnote 46. If the high Cuban levels of education and health depend on coercion, many of the achievements of the revolution will perish with relaxation in state control.

Suppose personal freedom is as important for human capabilities as income, education and healthcare. The HDI becomes [5] where F measures personal freedoms and where HDI II refers to the extended HDIFootnote 47.

(5)$${\rm HDI}\,{\rm II} = \lpar {{\rm Y}.{\rm H}.{\rm E}.{\rm F}} \rpar ^{1/4}$$

There is no agreement on how to measure personal freedom and many possible measures exist. I prefer the Heritage Foundation index of economic freedom as it encompasses economic and personal freedoms. The choice is debatable. Yet, the results will not change using alternative indices as Cuba scores low on allFootnote 48. To show this, I also use the Freedom House index of political rights. The Supplementary materials (Table A10) provide the results using a third measure—the Polity index.

Table 5 provides the 2011 results with the extended HDI. The first panel gives the results with the Heritage index as HDI IA while the second panel HDI IB gives the Freedom House results. In each case, Puerto Rico leads Latin America. As we might expect, Cuba does poorly. It comes in at 34 out of 38 using the Heritage index. The only countries below Cuba are Guatemala, Bolivia, Honduras and Nicaragua. Cuba is last using the Freedom House index.

TABLE 5 HUMAN DEVELOPMENT FOR 2011 INCLUDING FREEDOM

Notes: The first panel uses the Heritage index obtained at https://www.heritage.org/index/. The second panel gives the freedom house results using the index for 2014 at https://freedomhouse.org/.

5. THE VERDICT OF HISTORY

Progressive circles hailed the Cuban revolution in the belief it would raise living standards for the Cuban masses. Over the succeeding decades, these hopes have fadedFootnote 49. Unlike the twenty-fifth anniversary of the revolution, nowadays one hears few positive evaluations of the Cuban economy. The reason is straightforward. Before the revolution, Cuba was a prosperous economy by the standards of its time. Six decades later, it is one of the poorest economies in Latin America. In short, the revolution impoverished Cubans at least in a relative and perhaps in an absolute sense. Given the high expectations that greeted its birth, the economic record of the revolution is profoundly disappointingFootnote 50.

The case for the regime therefore rests on health and educationFootnote 51. Cuban life expectancy is impressive given current Cuban income levels. The Island also performs well on some educational outcomes. These achievements are real. But to evaluate the revolution along these dimensions, we must compare the revolutionary outcomes to the counterfactual of what would have occurred had the Republic survived. Any counterfactual which attempts to chart the progress of Cuban income, education and health over the six decades after the revolution is fraughtFootnote 52. Even if we could construct such counterfactuals, there is no agreement how to incorporate personal freedoms into broader measures of development.

Fortunately, there is a way to render a verdict on the Cuban experiment that avoids such intractible problems. Four decades ago, the distinguished Cuban economist Carlos Diaz Alejandro (Reference Diaz-Alejandro1973, p. 91) showed how to evaluate the effects of the Cuban revolution on the welfare of Cubans without a counterfactual. Drawing on the insights of John Rawls, he suggested the following thought experiment: «Consider a mental experiment in which one is to choose where to be reborn as a new baby, but without knowing where that miracle will occur in a rich or poor family in city or country…. Would one choose Guatemala, Brazil or Cuba?».

His choice was Cuba. The problem with his choice lies in his comparison countriesFootnote 53. To see why, suppose the comparison is done today and countries on the list are Cuba on the one hand and Chad and the Central African Republic on the other, then the choice would surely be Cuba. The result tells us less about Cuba than it does about the poverty of the comparison countries. Similarly, suppose the choice is between Cuba and Latin American economies that currently score low on the HDI of Table 4, Honduras, Guatemala or Nicaragua. It is again possible for the choice to be Cuba. A better approach is to restrict comparisons to countries with similar initial conditions before the Cuban revolution. From Tables 3 and 4, the relevant comparisons are Argentina/Chile/Uruguay/Puerto Rico-Cuba or Italy/Spain-Cuba or Ireland/Finland-Cuba. It is hard to see how Cuba could be preferred in any of these comparisons. Thus, history is more likely to condemn than to absolve the Cuban revolution.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0212610920000233.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

I am grateful to the editor and to the referees for suggestions which greatly improved this article. I also received helpful comments from Roger Betancourt, Ernesto Hernández-Catá, Vincent Geleso and the participants at the annual meetings of the American Economic Association ASCE session. Finally, I especially thank Jorge Pérez-López, Luis Locay and Bryan Roberts for sharing their data.

Footnotes

a

Department of Economics, CUNY. john.devereux@qc.cuny.edu.

1 One way to gauge general academic interest in Cuba is from the programs of the annual meetings of LASA, the Latin American Studies Association. Even a cursory examination of LASA programs for most years shows as many articles on Cuba as there are on the Latin giants, Brazil and Mexico.

2 Consider the fiftieth anniversary of the revolution in 2009 where Brundenius (Reference Brundenius2009) and Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago2009) are among the few articles marking the fiftieth anniversary who discuss the Cuban economy over the entire course of revolutionary rule. To be sure, there is a large volume of economic research on Cuba which mostly appears in the proceedings of the Association for the Study of the Cuban Economy (ASCE) but this work has had little impact on other social scientists.

3 See Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago2000) or Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1991).

4 To avoid this issue for Soviet Union, Abram Bergson developed adjusted factor cost prices, see Bergson (Reference Bergson1961). There are no adjusted factor cost prices for Cuba.

5 These conclusions mirror the consensus in the literature on the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe, see Gregory and Harrison (Reference Gregory and Harrison2005).

6 There is strong evidence that the Gerschenkron effect holds for planned economies, see Bergson (Reference Bergson1961).

7 Bergson (Reference Bergson1961) provides the classic discussion of how to interpret GDP for a planned economy where he cautions against seeing GDP as a measure of welfare. Sanguinnetty (Reference Sanguinnetty2019) discusses further limitations of GDP in the Cuban context.

8 Ideally, I would calculate GDP by deflating nominal magnitudes by appropriate deflators. This is not possible for Cuba.

9 The best known example of the quantity approach is the Soviet Union where CIA analysts used it to provide the standard GDP measures used by Western researchers with generally well-regarded results, see Maddison (Reference Maddison1998). Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López1987) applied a variant of the quantity approach to Cuba. For recent years, Maddison and Wu (Reference Maddison and Wu2008) provide applications to China. Of course, there is also a long tradition of output GDP measures in economic history. Examples include Feinstein (Reference Feinstein1972) for the UK and Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Campbell, Klein, Overton and Van Leeuwen2015) over the very long run for England.

10 The problems are marked for industry and this index may well understate output growth.

11 How accurate are the Cuban National Accounts given the distortions of a dual currency and rationing? The short answer is we do not know. Many of the problems are with nominal GDP, but these issues are less pressing for the output side indices considered in this article.

12 The Cuban data may be found at http://www.onei.gob.cu/.

14 Vidal (Reference Vidal2017) provides Cuban GDP in current international prices corresponding to GDP measures used in earlier versions of the Penn World Tables (PWT). His estimates use the Cuban national account series which I believe to be flawed along with various times series adjustments which mean they are not comparable to standard volume measures of GDP.

15 The GDP index is consistent with Mesa-Lago's early account of the period from 1960 to the mid-1970s, Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago1972, Reference Mesa-Lago1981). Dominguez (Reference Dominguez and Bethell1993) provides an equally harsh verdict on the revolutionary economy for these years while Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago2000) is a definitive overview.

16 Female labour force participation dropped after 2010. The latest (2018) edition of Anuario Estadístico de Cuba shows a drop in the female labour force participation rate from 60.5 in 2010 to 49.5 in 2018. The ratio of the labour force to population fell from 46 to 40 per cent during this period.

17 Given that human capital increased it is tempting to infer that total factor productivity fell over these years. But the data do not allow me to make that statement. The estimates of employment are problematic. In addition, I do not have satisfactory estimates of the capital stock since the investment data is poor. A further problem is that much of the capital stock becomes obsolete after the special period when access to spare parts, etc., declines.

18 For early discussions of Soviet aid, see Ritter (Reference Ritter1990) and Pérez-López (Reference Pérez-López2001).

19 Cuban growth generated heated debates during the 1970s and 1980s. Jorge Pérez-López, along with Carmelo Mesa-Logo, was subjected to harsh attacks for allegedly understating GDP growth and more generally the achievements of revolutionary Cuba, see Zimbalist (Reference Zimbalist1988) and Zimbalist and Brundenius (Reference Zimbalist and Brundenius1991) where the work of Pérez-López and Mesa-Lago is derided as «Cubanology».

20 Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago2000) provides a careful overview of this literature along with much of the data.

21 Then, as now, Cuba imported most of its food, consumer durables and industrial inputs. Imports in real terms fell by 70 per cent between 1989 and 1993 underlying the magnitude of the crisis.

22 I start with 1960 rather than 1959 as PWT coverage increases dramatically after 1960.

23 Cuba is not in the current PWT.

24 In terms of growth, from 1960 to 1989, Cuba does poorly relative to other planned economies where GDP per capita on average doubled.

25 As the revolution re-distributed income, it is certainly possible, and perhaps probable, that the consumption of the poorest segments of society, particularly the rural poor, increased in the early 1960s.

26 Cuba has two currencies—the CUC and the Peso. Vidal (Reference Vidal2017) provides a formula to calculate an average exchange rate based on the share in GDP of each sector of the island's economy that handles CUCs or pesos. He estimates GDP per capita for 2011 at $5,973 PPP adjusted, below the $6,821 of this study. The more general point is that there is now wide agreement that Cuba is a relatively poor economy by Latin American standards.

27 There are strong theoretical arguments in favour of the current price measure, see Feenstra et al. (Reference Feenstra, Inklaar and Timmer2015).

28 This view is not shared by some scholars sympathetic to the revolution. For example, Eckstein (Reference Eckstein and Levine1993, Table 1) puts income per capita for Cuba at the time of the revolution at tenth in Latin America. Brundenius (Reference Brundenius1984, Table 6.1, p. 123) puts 1960 GDP below Mexico and Peru.

29 The seminal studies of the World Bank (1951) and the U.S. Department of Commerce (1956) took it for granted that Cuba in the 1950s was a middle-income economy—the wealthiest country of the tropics.

30 The PWT provides two income measures. rgdpe is expenditure-side real GDP at chained PPPs (in US$2011 million). rgdpna is real GDP at constant 2011 national prices (in US$2011 million). The correct series for the calculations is rgdpe. For Argentina and El Salvador, the rgdpe series show income per capita increased sixfold and tenfold, respectively. This is an error. In their stead, I use the rgdpna series for these economies which shows income per capita doubles.

31 Cuba and Puerto Rico are not in the latest PWT. There are no GDP series connecting the Soviet Union with Russia.

32 The explanation of why comparisons over space, between countries, and over time, within countries, are not transitive is that they rely on different sets of prices and weights and use different procedures, see Feenstra et al. (Reference Feenstra, Ma and Prasada Rao2009) and Deaton and Aten (Reference Deaton and Aten2017).

33 This calculation is closely related to the projection procedure used by Maddison (Reference Maddison1995, Reference Maddison2007) to compare income over time and space. Maddison (Reference Maddison2007) starts with an estimate of relative income levels for his base year 1990 and growth rates for all comparison countries. He uses GDP growth rates to calculate income levels in the past. In contrast, I have income levels for 2 years and growth rates for the partner countries but not Cuba. This allows me to calculate the implied growth rate for Cuba rather than the GDP level in the past. The underlying logic is, of course, the same.

34 Using the rgdpna series, I obtain lower implied Cuban growth rates as the average ratio of implied income in 2011 to 1955 for Cuba is 0.95. In other words, Cuban growth rate is negative suggesting that Cuban GDP per capita for 2011 is below the late 1950s. The conclusion that income declined over this period is in line with Mesa-Lago's (Reference Mesa-Lago2009) verdict on the revolutionary economy.

35 I draw on Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015a, Reference Prados de la Escosura2015b, Reference Prados de la Escosura2019) for micro foundations. He provides a variant of the UN HDI measure, the Historical Human Development Index, which is more suited to really long-run historical comparisons.

36 I use the following upper and lower bounds taken from the United Nations.

37 Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015a) uses a different measure of education and as well as a different transformation of education and health.

38 Berdine et al. (Reference Berdine, Geloso and Powell2018) provide a more negative evaluation of the Cuban healthcare system than I do. It is true that Cuban healthcare is deficient in many respects. Corruption is endemic. Infrastructure is decaying and patients resort to black or grey markets. Since the early 2000s, many doctors were diverted abroad. In early 2019, matters worsened as even the most basic medicines such as aspirins and basic hygienic items are no longer available. But other adjustments will raise Cuba's standing. For example, Ghislandi et al. (Reference Ghislandi, Sanderson and Scherbov2019) compare countries in terms of inequality in life expectation where Cuba does very well.

39 See Carnoy and Wertheim (Reference Carnoy and Wertheim1975) and Carnoy et al. (Reference Carnoy, Gove and Marshall2007).

40 McGuire and Frenkel (Reference McGuire and Frankel2005) and especially Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015a) show the Cuban healthcare paradox is long standing. There are two possible explanations for this. First, Cuba had a large and well-developed private healthcare system early on. Indeed, Oshima (Reference Oshima1961) suggests that private spending on health was 10 per cent of private consumption for the early 1950s—high by international standards. The second explanation is the public health system put in place under American rule. Something similar seems to have occurred with U.S. health interventions in Puerto Rico, see Marein (Reference Marein2020).

42 The assumption of diminishing returns to income sometimes produces counter-intuitive results. For example, in the 2011 rankings, Puerto Rico ranks above France, Italy and Spain.

43 See the discussion by Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2015b, Reference Prados de la Escosura2019).

44 For Cuba, personal freedoms have waxed and waned. Recent years have seen a relaxation and the growth of a nascent civil society, see Betancourt (Reference Betancourt2019). The Committees for the Defense of the Revolution may no longer inspire fear, but the security services are still going strong.

45 Mesa-Lago (Reference Mesa-Lago1998) points out that Cuba had remarkably high levels of collectivisation and centralisation relative to other communist states. Indeed, he goes further to suggest that Cuba led most Communist regimes in these categories.

46 Kath (Reference Kath2006) and Hirschfeld (Reference Hirschfeld2007a, Reference Hirschfeld2007b) are among the few sociologists to observe the Cuban health system at close quarters. Their reports are troubling as they provide instances of what appeared to be compulsory abortion and sterilisation.

47 Independently, Prados de la Escosura (Reference Prados de la Escosura2019) provides an extended HDI. His approach is to mine in that he addresses the general question of how to incorporate personal freedoms into broader measures of development whereas my approach relates specifically to Cuba and has less relevance in other contexts.

48 The other index which emphasises economic as well as personal freedoms, the Economic Freedom of the World index from the Fraser Institute, does not include Cuba.

49 Even scholars sympathetic to the revolution concede Cuban economic performance over the last six decades is disappointing, see Brundenius (Reference Brundenius2009) or Thompson (Reference Thompson2005).

50 With hindsight, the relative prosperity of the 1980s came largely from Soviet support. The recovery after the special period is facilitated by Venezuelan largesse.

51 Cuban redistributive policies likely increased the incomes of the poor and particularly the rural poor relative to their levels of the late 1950s for the opening decades of revolution. These trends were reversed after the «special period» where access to foreign exchange from relatives abroad and employment in tourism-related activities are not equally distributed and where rationing becomes less important.

52 Jales et al. (Reference Jales, Kang, Stein and Ribeiro2018) provide counterfactuals for GDP growth using difference-in-differences, synthetic controls, factor models and panel data forecasting approaches. There are two problems with their approaches. First, they rely on deeply flawed measures of Cuban GDP. Second while their counterfactuals may be informative for the first decade or so of revolutionary rule, their usefulness for 60 years is more open to question since it is doubtful that any statistical procedure can accurately predict growth over a 60-year horizon. Bologna Pavlik and Geloso (Reference Bologna Pavlik and Geloso2018) provide an application of this methodology to healthcare.

53 Rawls (Reference Rawls1971, p. 60) also assumed that the following liberties exist before any choice can be made—«political liberty (the right to vote and hold public office) and freedom of speech and assembly; liberty of conscience and freedom of thought; freedom of the person, which includes freedom from psychological oppression and physical assault and dismemberment (integrity of the person); the right to hold personal property and freedom from arbitrary arrest and seizure as defined by the concept of the rule of law.» Revolutionary Cuba does poorly on this list.

References

REFERENCES

Berdine, G., Geloso, V., and Powell, B. (2018): «Cuban Infant Mortality and Longevity: Health Care or Repression?» Health Policy and Planning 33 (6), pp. 755-757.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bergson, A. (1961): The Real National Income of Soviet Russia Since 1928. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bergson, A. (1972): «The Comparative National Income of the USSR and the United States», in Daly, J. (ed.), International Comparisons of Prices and Output. New York: NBER, Columbia University Press, pp. 145-224.Google Scholar
Betancourt, R. (2019): «Cuba's ‘Structural’ Reforms: Missed Opportunities and Lower Living Standards». Working Paper, University of Maryland.Google Scholar
Bologna Pavlik, J., and Geloso, V. (2018): «The Cuban Revolution and Infant Mortality, 1959-1974». Working Paper, Texas Tech University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braithwaite, S. N. (1968): «Real Income Levels in Latin America». Review of Income and Wealth 14 (2), pp. 113182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B., Klein, A., Overton, M., and Van Leeuwen, B. (2015): British Economic Growth, 1270-1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brundenius, C. (1984): Revolutionary Cuba, the Challenge of Economic Growth with Equity. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Brundenius, C. (2009): «Revolutionary Cuba at 50: Growth with Equity Revisited». Latin American Perspectives 36(2), pp. 31-48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carnoy, M., and Wertheim, J. (1975): Cuba: Economic Change and Education Reform 1955-1974. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Carnoy, M., Gove, A. K., and Marshall, J. H. (2007): Cuba's Academic Advantage: Why Students in Cuba do Better in School. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Central Intelligence Agency (1968, 1970, 1972): Cuba—Intelligence Handbook. Previously classified, released in 1999.Google Scholar
Deaton, A., and Aten, B. (2017): «Trying to Understand the PPPs in ICP 2011: Why Are the Results So Different?» American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 9 (1), pp. 243-264.Google Scholar
Devereux, J. (2019): «Arrested Development? Puerto Rico in an American Century». The Journal of Economic History 79 (3), pp. 708-735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewhurst, J., Coppock, J., and Yates, L. (1961): Europe's Needs and Resources. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
Diaz-Alejandro, C. (1973): «Review». Journal of Economic Literature 11 (1), pp. 89-93.Google Scholar
Dominguez, J. (1993): «Cuba Since 1959», in Bethell, L. (ed.), Cuba: A Short History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 95-148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, S. (1993): «The Cuban Revolution in Comparative Perspective», in Levine, D. (ed.), Constructing Culture and Power in Latin America. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, pp. 429-455.Google Scholar
Feenstra, R., Ma, H., and Prasada Rao, D. S. (2009): «Consistent Comparisons of Real Income Across Countries and Over Time». Macroeconomic Dynamics 13 (Suppl. 2), pp. 169-193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R., Inklaar, R., and Timmer, M. (2015): «The Next Generation of the Penn World Table». The American Economic Review 105 (10), pp. 3150-3182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feinstein, C. H. (1972): National Income, Expenditure and Output of the United Kingdom, 1855-1965. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ghislandi, S., Sanderson, W., and Scherbov, S. (2019): «A Simple Measure of Human Development: The Human Life Indicator». Population and Development Review 45 (1), pp. 219-233.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gilbert, M., and Kravis, I. (1954): An International Comparison of National Products and the Purchasing Power of Currencies. Paris: Organization for European Economic Cooperation.Google Scholar
Gilbert, M., and Kravis, I. (1958): Comparative National Products and Price Levels. Paris: Organization for European Economic Co-operation.Google Scholar
Gonzalez, R. M. (2015): «Infant Mortality in Cuba: Myth and Reality». Cuban Studies 42 (1), pp. 19-39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, P., and Harrison, M. (2005): «Allocation under Dictatorship: Research in Stalin's Archives». Journal of Economic Literature 43 (3), pp. 721-761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschfeld, K. (2007a): Health, Politics, and Revolution in Cuba Since 1898. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Hirschfeld, K. (2007b): «Re-examining the Cuban Health Care System: Towards a Qualitative Critique». Cuban Affairs 2 (3), pp. 1-27.Google Scholar
Jales, H., Kang, T. H., Stein, G., and Ribeiro, F. (2018): «Measuring the Role of the 1959 Revolution on Cuba's Economic Performance». The World Economy 41 (8), pp. 2243-2274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, N. (1969): The Record of Soviet Economic Growth, 1928-1965. (No. RM-6169). Santa Monica, California: Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
Kath, E. (2006): «Father Knows Best? Cuba's Proactive Approach to Healthcare». Cuba in Transition, Papers and Proceedings of ASCE. Volume 16, pp. 351-365.Google Scholar
Layard, R., Mayraz, G., and Nickell, S. (2008): «The Marginal Utility of Income». Journal of Public Economics 92 (8-9), pp. 1846-1857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Locay, L. (2009): «Cuban Socioeconomic Indicators before the Revolution: An International Comparison». In Cuba in Transition, Papers and Proceeding of ASCE. Volume 19, pp. 146-152.Google Scholar
Locay, L., and Devereux, J. (2018) «Comparing the Quality of Education in Pre and Post-Revolutionary Cuba». Cuba in Transition, Papers and Proceeding of ASCE. Volume 25, pp. 149-154.Google Scholar
Locay, L., and Roberts, B. (2012): «Cuban Household Consumption: An Update». Working Paper, University of Miami.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (1995): Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992. Paris: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (1998): «Measuring the Performance of a Communist Command Economy: An Assessment of the CIA Estimates for the U.S.S.R». Review of Income and Wealth 44 (3), pp. 307-323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. (2007): The World Economy: Vol II Historical Statistics. Paris: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development.Google Scholar
Maddison, A., and Wu, H. X. (2008): «Measuring China's Economic Performance». World Economy 9 (2), pp. 1-32.Google Scholar
Marein, B. (2020): «Economic Growth, Public Health, and the First Mortality Transition in the Tropics: Puerto Rico, 1923-1945». Working Paper, University of Colorado.Google Scholar
Martinez, L. (2019): «How Much Should We Trust the Dictator's GDP Growth Estimates?» Unpublished. University of Chicago.Google Scholar
McGuire, J. W., and Frankel, L. B. (2005): «Mortality Decline in Cuba, 1900-1959: Patterns, Comparisons, and Causes». Latin American Research Review 40 (2), pp. 83-116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (1969): «Availability and Reliability of Statistics in Socialist Cuba (Part One)». Latin American Research Review 4 (1), pp. 53-91.Google Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (ed.). (1972): Revolutionary Change in Cuba. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (1981): The Economy of Socialist Cuba: A Two-Decade Appraisal. Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico Press.Google Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (1998): «Assessing Economic and Social Performance in the Cuban Transition of the 1990s». World Development 26 (5), pp. 857-876.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (2000): Market, Socialist, and Mixed Economies: Comparative Policy and Performance: Chile, Cuba, and Costa Rica. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Mesa-Lago, C. (2009): «Economic and Social Balance of Fifty Years of Cuban Revolution». In Cuba in Transition, Papers and Proceeding of ASCE. Vol 18, pp. 316-381.Google Scholar
Moorsteen, R. H., and Powell, R. P. (1966): The Soviet Capital Stock, 1928-1962. Homewood, IL: RD Irwin.Google Scholar
Nutter, G.W. (1962): The Growth of Industrial Production in the Soviet Union. Princeton, NJ: NBER, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Oshima, H. (1961): «A New Estimate of the National Income and Product of Cuba in 1953». Food Research Institute Studies 2 (3), pp. 213-227.Google Scholar
Pérez-López, J. F. (1987): Measuring Cuban Economic Performance. Austin, TX: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Pérez-López, J. F. (1991): «Bringing the Cuban Economy Into Focus: Conceptual and Empirical Challenges». Latin American Research Review 26 (3), pp. 7-53.Google Scholar
Pérez-López, J. F. (2001): «Waiting for Godot: Cuba's Stalled Reforms and Continuing Economic Crisis». Problems of Post-Communism 48 (6), pp. 43-55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pérez-López, J. F., and Mesa-Lago, C. (2010): «Cuban GDP Statistics under the Special Period: Discontinuities, Obfuscation and Puzzles». Cuba in Transition. Papers and Proceeding of ASCE. Vol 19, pp. 153-167.Google Scholar
Peterson, P. (2020): «Cuban Schools—Too Good To Be True». Working paper available at https://www.educationnext.org/cuban-schools-too-good-to-be-true-what-explains-castros-educational-excellents-unabridged/#.Google Scholar
Prados de la Escosura, L. (2015a): «World Human Development, 1870-2007». Review of Income and Wealth 61 (2), pp. 220-247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prados de la Escosura, L. (2015b): «Human Development as Positive Freedom: Latin America in Historical Perspective». Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 16 (3), pp. 342-373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prados de la Escosura, L. (2019): «Human Development in the Age of Globalization». Working Paper, Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971): A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ritter, A. (1990): «The Cuban Economy in the 1990s». Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs 32 (3), pp. 117-149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanguinnetty, J. (2019): «The Cuban Economy Sixty Years Later». Working Paper, Association for the Study of the Cuban Economy.Google Scholar
Schroeder, G. E., and Denton, M. E. (1982): «An Index of Consumption in the U.S.S.R.», in Joint Economic Committee, USSR: Measures of Economic Growth and Development 1950-1980. Washington D.C. U.S Congress, pp. 317-401.Google Scholar
Sixto, F. (2002): «An Evaluation of Four Decades of Cuban Healthcare», in Cuba in Transition. Papers and Proceeding of ASCE. Vol 12, pp. 325-343.Google Scholar
Speck, M. (2005): «Prosperity, Progress, and Wealth: Cuban Enterprise during the Early Republic, 1902-1927». Cuban Studies 36 (1), pp. 50-86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, F. (2005): «Cuban Economic Performance in Retrospect». Review of Radical Political Economics 37 (3), pp. 311-319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UNESCO (2008): Student Achievement in Latin America and the Caribbean. Santiago, United Nations.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Commerce (1956): Investment in Cuba. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Vidal, A. (2017): «¿Qué lugar ocupa la economía cubana en la región?: Una medición a la tasa PPA de las brechas de ingreso y productividad. Resumen de políticas del BID» (Departamento de Investigación y Economista Jefe); IDB-PB-269.Google Scholar
Ward, M., and Devereux, J. (2012): «The Road Not Taken: Pre-Revolutionary Cuban Living Standards in Comparative Perspective». Journal of Economic History 72 (1), pp. 104-132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (International Bank for Reconstruction and Development) (1951): Report on Cuba. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Zimbalist, A. (1988): Cuban Political Economy: Controversies in Cubanology. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Zimbalist, A., and Brundenius, C. (1991): The Cuban Economy: Measurement and Analysis of Socialist Performance. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1 GDP WEIGHTS

Figure 1

FIGURE 1 GDP PER CAPITA AND PER WORKER—1957 TO 2017 (1957 = 100).Sources: Author's calculations. The annual series are in the data appendix.

Figure 2

FIGURE 2 GDP PER CAPITA—1957 TO 2017 ALTERNATIVE ESTIMATES (1957 = 100).Sources: see data appendix for sources. Note for Series I Pérez-López (1987) reaches only to 1982. For 1982 to 1985 I use National Accounts.

Figure 3

TABLE 2 COMPARING GROWTH RATES FOR GDP PER CAPITA

Figure 4

FIGURE 3 CONSUMPTION PER CAPITA—1957 TO 1985.Sources: Author's calculations. The annual series are in the data appendix.

Figure 5

TABLE 3 GDP AND CONSUMPTION PER CAPITA—1955 AND 2011 (United States = 100)

Figure 6

TABLE 4 CUBA AND HUMAN DEVELOPMENT—1955 AND 2011

Figure 7

TABLE 5 HUMAN DEVELOPMENT FOR 2011 INCLUDING FREEDOM

Supplementary material: File

Devereux supplementary material

Devereux supplementary material

Download Devereux supplementary material(File)
File 670.2 KB