Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T05:36:36.109Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Does Identity or Economic Rationality Drive Public Opinion on European Integration?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 July 2004

Liesbet Hooghe
Affiliation:
University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill
Gary Marks
Affiliation:
University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

How do citizens respond to the reallocation of authority across levels of government? This article investigates the relative importance of economic versus identity bases of citizen support for the most far-reaching example of authority migration—European integration.

Type
Symposium
Copyright
© 2004 by the American Political Science Association

How do citizens respond to the reallocation of authority across levels of government? This article investigates the relative importance of economic versus identity bases of citizen support for the most far-reaching example of authority migration—European integration.

Most scholars have explained preferences over European integration in terms of its economic consequences. We have precise expectations concerning how individual attributes (e.g., education, occupation, factor mobility, and sectoral location) affect support for international regimes. The search for plausible economic sources of preferences has widened to include economic perceptions (as well as objective conditions), group (as well as individual) utility, and national economic institutions that mediate individual interests.

But there is a new—or, rather, old—kid on the block. Its hard core is the assumption that citizen preferences are driven by group attachments, by the loyalties, values, and norms that define who a person is. This line of analysis is as old as the study of European integration (Deutsch 1957; Haas 1958; Inglehart 1970), but while the pioneers were chiefly concerned with how regional integration affects identity, recent research flips the causal arrow.1

Research on public opinion on trade liberalization has come up with an interesting and unexplained fact. Citizens who attest high levels of national attachment tend to oppose trade liberalization both in the United States and across OECD countries. National attachment appears to be a more powerful influence than conventional economic factors, a finding that is all the more “disturbing” because it has emerged in two independent tests of economic, not identity, theories (O'Rourke and Sinnott 2001; Mayda and Rodrik 2002).

One would expect European integration to convey home field advantage to both research programs. The European Union (EU) is a regional trade regime with sizeable distributional effects. It is also a system of multi-level governance in which national authority is pooled and limited. So we are conducting what Arend Lijphart describes as a crucial experiment, a case in which “all of the variables which the researcher tries to relate to each other are present” (1979, 444).2

An additional virtue is that data on public support for European integration are more comprehensive than for any other international body.

There need be no suspense concerning our conclusion. Citizens do indeed take into account the economic consequences of European integration, but conceptions of group membership appear to be more powerful.

We proceed in two steps. First, we set up an economic explanation of public opinion on European integration. We identify six lines of theorizing. We cannot sacrifice comprehensiveness to parsimony because our analysis will be convincing only to the extent that we bring the main economic contenders into the ring—and there are many.

Second, we theorize identity as a source of public opinion on European integration. What would one expect if group identity drove preferences? The answer is not obvious. Citizens who attest strong national identity are more, not less, likely to identify with Europe. We argue that the way a citizen conceives her national identity is decisive. Does a citizen conceive her national identity in exclusive or inclusive terms? Is that citizen positively or negatively oriented to multiculturalism?

Theorizing Support for European Integration

Political Economy

The main thrust of European integration has been to sweep away barriers to economic exchange, facilitate mobility of capital and labor, and create a single European monetary authority. So it is not surprising that explanations of public opinion on European integration have focused on economic factors.

The simplest expectation is that reducing trade barriers favors citizens with relatively high income, education, and occupational skills (Gabel 1998; Inglehart 1970). There are several reasons for this. International economic openness rewards those with high levels of human capital. It increases the international substitutability of labor as firms are more able to shift production across borders, and this intensifies job insecurity, particularly for less skilled workers. Finally, international economic openness puts pressure on welfare systems and shifts the burden of taxation from mobile factors of production (e.g., financial capital) to immobile factors (e.g., labor).

Economic internationalization also affects relative scarcity of assets. According to the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, trade benefits individuals who own factors with which the national economy is relatively well endowed and hurts individuals who own factors that are relatively scarce (Mayda and Rodrik 2002; O'Rourke and Sinnott 2001). Hence, in the wealthiest, most capital-rich member states we expect unskilled workers to be Euroskeptic and managers and professionals to be Eurosupportive, while in the poorest, most labor-rich member states we expect the reverse.3

Eurobarometer data do not allow us to test a Heckscher-Ohlin model, which hypothesizes that support for economic internationalization varies across exportcompeting and import-competing sectors. However, analysis of public opinion on trade protectionism suggests that the substantive effect of sectoral location is small (Mayda and Rodrik 2002).

Citizens may be sensitive to their collective economic circumstances, as well as to those that affect them individually (Anderson 1998). It seems reasonable to expect that residents in countries that are net recipients of European Union spending will be inclined to support European integration, while those in donor countries will tend to oppose (Brinegar et al. 2004). The same logic is often at work in regional or federal states, where poorer regions champion centralization to increase the scope for redistribution while prosperous regions favor decentralization.

Subjective economic evaluations can be expected to influence public opinion on European integration alongside objective factors (Rohrschneider 2002; Eichenberg and Dalton 1993). European integration is perceived by most citizens to shape their economic welfare in a general sense. Citizens who feel confident about the economic future—personally and for their country—are likely to regard European integration in a positive light, while those who are fearful will lean towards Euroskepticism.

Finally, preferences may be influenced by institutions. The European Union encompasses countries with contrasting degrees of labor and business coordination, each of which is costly to change (Hall and Soskice 2001). We assume that the further a country is from the EU median (low labor coordination, relatively high business coordination), the greater the costs imposed on its citizens by EU legislation.

Political-economic institutions may interact with support or opposition to redistribution (Brinegar et al. 2004; Marks 2004; Ray 2004). If European integration converges on a mixed-market model, citizens in social democratic Scandinavian economies can expect to see their welfare systems diluted, while citizens in liberal market economies, such as Britain, can expect more redistribution. Hence in social democratic systems, the left will be opposed to European integration and the right will be supportive. In liberal market systems, the left will support integration and the right will be opposed.

Economic theories of preference formation work best when economic consequences are perceived with some accuracy, are large enough to matter, and when the choice a person makes actually affects the outcome. To the extent that these conditions are not present, group identities are likely to be decisive (Chong 2002; Elster 1990; Sears and Funk 1991; Young et al. 1991). What would one expect to find if public opinion were shaped by group identity?

National Identity

Humans and their ancestors evolved an emotional capacity for intense group loyalty long before the development of rational faculties, and such loyalties can be extremely powerful in shaping views toward political objects (Citrin et al. 1990; Massey 2002; Sears 1993). The strongest territorial identities are national, and we suspect that such identities constrain preferences on European integration.4

Recent work emphasizes how a clash of identities on issues such as immigration, multiculturalism, and European integration structures politics (Kriesi and Lachat 2004).

To understand the effect of national identity one must come to grips with a paradox. On the one hand, individuals often identify with several territorial communities simultaneously (Citrin and Sides forthcoming; Klandermans et al. 2003). It is not at all unusual for citizens to have multiple identities—to feel, for example, strongly Catalan, Spanish, and European—at one and the same time (Diez Medrano 2003; Marks 1999). Haesly (2001) finds positive, rather than negative, associations between Welsh and European identities and between Scottish and European identities. Klandermans and his co-authors (2003) detect a cumulative pattern of identities, in which farmers who identify with Europe tend also to identify with their nation. Risse (2003) conceptualizes the relationship as akin to a marble cake in which multiple identities are meshed together. Van Kersbergen (2000) conceives of European allegiance as embedded in national allegiance. Citrin and Sides find that “even in an era in which perceptions of the European Union as successful seemed to decline, the tendency to identify with both nation and Europe increased” (forthcoming, 8; also Hermann, Brewer, and Risse forthcoming).

But it is also true that opposition to European integration is often couched as defense of the nation against control from Brussels. Radical right-wing political parties in France, Denmark, Italy, and Austria tap nationalism to reject further integration, and since 1996 such parties have formed the largest reservoir of Euroskepticism in the EU as a whole (Hooghe et al. 2002; Taggart 1998). Christin and Trechsel (2002) find that the stronger the national attachment and national pride of Swiss citizens, the less likely they are to support membership in the European Union. Carey (2002) shows that national attachment combined with national pride have a significant negative effect on support for European integration.

To resolve these conflicting expectations, we need to theorize how national identity can both reinforce and undermine support for European integration. Diez Medrano argues that national histories are crucial. Constructing patterns of discourse in the UK, Spain, and Germany, Medrano finds that English Euroskepticism is rooted in Britain's special history of empire, that West German pro-Europeanism reflects World War II guilt, and that the Spanish tend to support European integration as proxy for modernization and democratization (Diez Medrano 2003). A research team led by Stråth and Triandafyllidou links party programs, public opinion, educational curricula, and media within nine EU and prospective EU countries. Such studies reveal the stickiness of national identity within unique national contexts.

Can one generalize about the connection between national identity and public opinion? We begin with the basic distinction between exclusive and inclusive national identity, and we hypothesize that citizens who conceive of their national identity as exclusive of other territorial identities are likely to be considerably more Euroskeptical than those who conceive of their national identity in inclusive terms. We know, for example, that individuals who identify themselves exclusively as Belgian or exclusively as Flemish oppose multi-level governance, while those who identify themselves as both Belgian and Flemish support it (Maddens et al. 1996). We expect to find something similar at the supranational level.

Under what circumstances will citizens perceive their national identity as exclusive or inclusive? While national identities are normally formed before adolescence (Druckman 1994), we hypothesize that their consequences for particular political objects, such as European integration, are continuously constructed through socialization and political conflict (Stråth and Triandafyllidou 2003; Diez Medrano 2003). But who does the framing? Literature on American public opinion suggests that public opinion may be cued by political elites (Zaller 1992, 97–117). The sharper the divisions among national elites on the issue of European integration, the greater the scope for national identity to be mobilized, and the more we expect exclusive national identity to bite. One sign of such division is the existence of a radical right political party. Parties like the Vlaams Blok in Belgium and the French Front National make a fetish of exclusive national identity with slogans such as “Boss in Our Own Country” and “We give them our factories; they give us their immigrants. One solution: The Nation.” Such sentiments reinforce Euroskepticism.5

Our hypothesis would be tautological if elites follow citizens, or if citizens vote for radical right parties because they are Euroskeptic. Neither concern has empirical validity.

In countries where the elite is squarely behind the European project, we expect national identity to lay dormant or to be positively associated with support for integration. In countries where the political elite is divided on the issue, national identity is likely to rear its head.

Analysis

To measure support for European integration we combine three complementary elements of support: the principle of membership, the desired speed of integration, and the desired direction of future integration. The results reported below are robust across these component measures. This and other variables in our analysis are detailed in the appendix.6

Data are from Eurobarometer 54.1 (fieldwork in the fall of 2000). The dataset was made available by the Mannheim Zentrum für Umfragen, Methoden und Analysen (ZUMA).

We use multilevel analysis to probe variation at the individual, party, and country level.7

Multi-level analysis is preferable to standard OLS regression when cases are clustered in groups (Steenbergen and Jones 2002). Our full multilevel model explains about 38% of the total variance among 7,641 respondents across the EU minus Luxembourg (http://www.unc.edu/~hooghe). We weight countries equally in all results reported here.

Table 1 presents unstandardized coefficients and standard errors for variables of interest.8

We control for gender, age, occupation, opinion leadership, knowledge of European politics, partisanship, left-right self-identification, and attachment to Europe (see www.unc.edu/~hooghe for details).

Figure 1 illustrates the relative effect of the most powerful variables. The solid boxes encompass the inter-quartile range and the whiskers indicate the 5th to the 95th percentiles, holding all other independent and control variables at their means. For example, an individual at the 5th percentile on Multiculturalism has a score of 65.9 on Support for European Integration on a 0–100 scale, and an individual at the 95th percentile scores 74.3. The variables towards the left of Figure 1 have the largest effect across their inter-quartile range.

Effects of Independent Variables

Citizens do appear to take economic circumstances into account. The EU redistributes money from rich to poor countries, and this gives rise to a predictable pattern of opposition and support. Fiscal Transfer is the most powerful economic influence that we find. A citizen of Greece, the country with the highest per capita net receipts from the EU, will be 15% more supportive of European integration than a citizen from Germany, the country with the highest net contribution, controlling for all other variables in our analysis. The differing length of the 95% whiskers in Figure 1 for this variable indicates that its association with support for European integration is not linear. Fiscal Transfer sharply delineates four countries (Greece, Portugal, Spain, and Ireland) that receive the bulk of cohesion funding and which tend to be pro-EU.

We also confirm the effect of Type of Capitalism. Support for European integration is higher in countries whose economic institutions are less likely to be challenged by EU legislation because they are close to the EU median.9

Some observers argue that there is convergence on liberal market capitalism. This hypothesis fares worse in our empirical test than the one specified here.

Together, seven variables that tap individual and group economic interest (listed in the appendix) account for 15% of total variance in public opinion, which is in line with previous studies. The surprise is that these economic influences are overshadowed by identity.

Three variables that tap identity—Exclusive National Identity, Multiculturalism, and National Attachment—together explain 20.8% of the variance in Support for European Integration. These variables also account for more than two-thirds of the variance across countries.

The paradox that we identified earlier is apparent: national identity both contributes to and diminishes support for European integration. Attachment to one's country is positively correlated with Support for European Integration in bivariate analysis.10

The association between National Attachment and Support for European Integration is usually insignificant under controls, and becomes negative when we control for European Attachment.

But national identity is Janus-faced: under some circumstances it collides with European integration.

The extent to which national identity is exclusive or inclusive is decisive. A Eurobarometer question compels respondents to place either European or national identity above the other, and separates those who say they think of themselves as “only British (or French, etc.)” from those who say they have some form of multiple identity. Estimates for Exclusive National Identity are negative, substantively large, and significant in the presence of any and all controls we are able to exert.11

To ensure that our measure of Exclusive National Identity does not tap absence of European identity, we control for European Attachment. This imposes conservatism in estimating the effect of our identity variables.

On average, an individual in our sample who claims an exclusive national identity scores 53.3 on our thermometer scale for support for European integration, compared to 72.8 for a person who does not. The difference, 19.5%, is the baseline in Figure 2.12

The bars in Figure 2 are empirical Bayes estimates derived from a random coefficients multi-level model using MLwiN.

In some countries, citizens who have exclusive national identity are only slightly more Euroskeptical than those with multiple identities. In others, exclusive national identity is powerfully associated with Euroskepticism. In Portugal, exclusive national identity depresses a citizen's support by just 9.5%. In the UK, at the other extreme, the difference is 29.5%.

Exclusive National Indentity and Support for European Integration

How can one explain this variation? Our hunch, derived from what we know about American public opinion, seems to be on the right track. The more divided a country's elite, and the more elements within it mobilize against European integration, the stronger the causal power of exclusive national identity. Political parties are decisive in cueing the public, and the wider their disagreement, the more exclusive identity is mobilized against European integration. Divisions within political parties are positively correlated with the causal power of exclusive national identity, as is the electoral strength of radical right parties. These two variables account for an estimated 57% of the country variance illustrated in Figure 2.

We have argued that there is no necessary connection between national identity and support or opposition to European integration. The dots have to be filled in, and we find that the connection is stronger when elites, particularly those leading political parties, are polarized on the issue.13

See http:\\www.unc.edu/~marks for details. Data on party divisions and the radical-right vote are from an expert survey conducted by Marks and Steenbergen in 1999. Our data do not allow us to evaluate the direction of influence between voters and political parties. Here we make the contestable claim that parties cue the implications of exclusive national identity for citizens (Carrubba 2001).

Conclusion

It is fruitless to seek general validity in either economic or identity theories of preferences. We need to inquire into their relative causal power. In this article, we do this for a single object: public opinion on European integration. Most scholars have conceptualized European integration as an economic phenomenon, and the bulk of research has therefore theorized public opinion as a function of the distributional consequences of market liberalization. But the European Union is also a supranational polity with extensive authority over those living in its territory. It is therefore plausible to believe that European integration engages group, and above all, national identities.

Both theories bite. A multi-level model that combines both sources of preference can explain around a third or more of the variance across individual citizens in the EU, and the bulk of variation across countries. However, we find that identity appears to be the more powerful influence. To understand how the public views European integration, one needs to consider how individuals frame their national identity. Do citizens consider national identity as something that can go hand in hand with European integration, or do they believe that European integration limits or threatens their national identity? There is nothing mechanistic or inevitable about one or the other position.

Identity is simple and complex. Citizens can answer the question “What is your nationality” with much greater ease and validity than they can tell you for which party or candidate they voted in the previous election. Like some in-group/out-group identities, national identities are formed early in life. Children as young as six know full well whether they are British, German, or Swedish. Yet the political implications of national identity emerge from debate and conflict. Whether a person is Belgian or British is (usually) a simple fact, but what does this national identity imply for the political choices one makes?

To understand the political implications of identity one therefore has to probe how identity is constructed and mobilized. Political elites and parties appear to be key. Exclusive national identity is mobilized against European integration in countries where the elite is polarized on European integration, where political parties are divided, and where radical right parties are strong. Data over time would help scholars probe further.

In terms of deductive sophistication, identity theory cannot compete with economic theory—yet. But this is like comparing a gasoline engine, honed over decades, with a hydrogen engine. If group identities are decisive for preferences over a wide range of political objects, as recent research suggests, then we can safely predict that the theories of group identity will become more sophisticated and more powerful.

For comments and advice we are grateful to Stefano Bartolini, Tanja Börzel, Christophe Crombez, Gerda Falkner, Rusanna Gaber, Peter Hall, Elizabeth Gerber, Adrienne Héritier, Ken Kollman, David Lake, Christiane Lemke, Ivan Llamazares, Jane Mansfield, Thomas Risse, Edeltraud Roller, Dieter Rucht, Alexander Trechsel, Anna Triandafyllidou, Bernhard Wessels, and to the Steiner political science discussion group at the University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill. Earlier versions were presented at the European University Institute, Florence; the Center for European Studies at Harvard University; Humboldt University, Berlin; the University of Michigan, Ann Arbor; the Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna; The Social Science Research Center, Berlin; and the 2003 APSA Meeting, Philadelphia. We received institutional support from the Center for European Studies at the University of North Carolina, the Alexander von Humboldt Foundation, and the Social Science Research Center, Berlin. We alone are responsible for errors.

References

Anderson Christopher J. 1998. “When in Doubt, Use Proxies: Attitudes Toward Domestic Politics and Support for European Integration.Comparative Political Studies 31: 569601.Google Scholar
Brinegar Adam, Seth Jolly, and Herbert Kitschelt. 2004. “Varieties of Capitalism and Political Divides over European Integration.” In European Integration and Political Conflict, eds. Gary Marks and Marco Steenbergen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 6289.Google Scholar
Carey Sean. 2002. “Undivided Loyalties: Is National Identity an Obstacle to European Integration?European Union Politics 3: 387413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrubba Clifford J. 2001. “The Electoral Connection in European Union Politics.Journal of Politics 63: 14158.Google Scholar
Christin Thomas, and Alexander Trechsel. 2002. “Joining the EU? Explaining Public Opinion in Switzerland.European Union Politics 3: 41543.Google Scholar
Citrin Jack, and John Sides. Forthcoming. “Can There be Europe without Europeans? Problems of Identity in a Multinational Community.” In Identities in Europe and the Institutions of the European Union, eds. Richard Herrmann, Marilynn Brewer, and Thomas Risse. Lanham, MD.: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Citrin Jack, Beth Reingold, and Donald P. Green. 1990. “American Identity and the Politics of Ethnic Change.Journal of Politics 52: 112454.Google Scholar
Commission of the European Union. 2001. Allocation of 2000 EU Operating Expenditure by Member State. European Commission, Budget Directorate, September 2001.Google Scholar
Deutsch Karl W. 1957. Nationalism and Social Communication. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Diez Medrano Juan. 2003. Framing Europe: Attitudes to European Integration in Germany, Spain, and the United Kingdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Druckman Daniel. 1994. “Nationalism, Patriotism, and Group Loyalty: A Social Psychological Perspective.Mershon International Studies Review 38: 4368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichenberg Richard, and Russell Dalton. 1993. “Europeans and the European Community: The Dynamics of Public Support for European Integration.International Organization 47: 50734.Google Scholar
Elster Jon. 1990. “When Rationality Fails.” In The Limits of Rationality, eds. Karen Schweers Cook and Margaret Levi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1951.Google Scholar
Gabel Matthew. 1998. Interests and Integration: Market Liberalization, Public Opinion, and European Union. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gourevitch Peter, and Michael Hawes. 2001. “Understanding National Production Systems: Comparative Capitalism in the Globalized Economy.” Paper presented at the APSA Annual Meeting, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Haas Ernst. 1958. The Uniting of Europe. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Haesly Richard. 2001. “Euroskeptics, Europhiles and Instrumental Europeans: European Attachment in Scotland and Wales.European Union Politics 2: 81102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall Peter A., and David Soskice, eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hartung Harald. 2002. Eurobarometer 54.1: Building Europe and the European Union: The European Parliament, Public Safety, and Defense Policy, November-December 2000. Brussels: Commission of the European Community.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hermann Richard, Marilynn Brewer, and Thomas Risse, eds. Forthcoming. Identities in Europe and the Institutions of the European Union. Lanham, MD.: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Hjerm Mikael. 1998. “National Identities, National Pride and Xenophobia: A Comparison of Four Western Countries.Acta Sociologica 41: 33547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe Liesbet, Gary Marks, and Carole Wilson. 2002. “Does Left/Right Structure Party Positions on European Integration?Comparative Political Studies 35: 96589.Google Scholar
Inglehart Ronald. 1970. “Cognitive Mobilization and European Identity.Comparative Politics 3: 4570.Google Scholar
Klandermans Bert, Jose Manuel Sabucedo, and Mauro Rodriguez. 2003. “Inclusiveness of Identification among Farmers in the Netherlands and Galicia.” Unpublished ms.Google Scholar
Kriesi Hanspeter, and Romain Lachat. 2004. “Globalization and the Transformation of the National Political Space: Switzerland and France Compared.” Paper prepared for a Workshop on the Analysis of Political Cleavages and Party Competition, Duke University.Google Scholar
Lijphart Arend. 1979. “Religious vs. Linguistic vs. Class Voting: The Crucial Experiment of Comparing Belgium, Canada, South Africa, and Switzerland.American Political Science Review 73: 442458.Google Scholar
Lipset Seymour Martin. 1981 [1960]. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics, 2nd ed. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Marks Gary. 1999. “Territorial Identities in the European Union.” In Regional Integration and Democracy: Expanding on the European Experience ed. Jeffrey J. Anderson. Lanham, MD.: Rowman and Littlefield, 6991.Google Scholar
Marks Gary. 2004. “Conclusion: European Integration and Political Conflict.” In European Integration and Political Conflict, eds. Gary Marks and Marco Steenbergen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 235259.Google Scholar
Marks Gary, and Ivan Llamazares. Forthcoming. “Multi-level Governance in Southern Europe: European Integration and Regional Mobilization.” In The Changing Functions of the State in the New Southern Europe, eds. P. Nikiforos Diamandouros, Richard Gunther, and Gianfranco Pasquino. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Massey Douglas. 2002. “Presidential Address: A Brief History of Human Society: The Origin and Role of Emotion in Social Life.American Sociological Review 67: 129.Google Scholar
Mayda Anna Maria, and Dani Rodrik. 2002. “Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist than Others?” Unpublished ms.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Rourke Kevin H., and Richard Sinnott. 2001. “The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence.” Paper presented at the Brookings Trade Policy Forum.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray Leonard. 2004. “Don't Rock the Boat: Expectations, Fears, and Opposition to EU Level Policy Making.” In European Integration and Political Conflict, eds. Gary Marks and Marco Steenbergen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 5161.Google Scholar
Risse Thomas. 2003. “Nationalism and Collective Identities. Europe versus the Nation-State?” In Developments in West European Politics, eds. Paul Heywood, Eric Jones, and Martin Rhodes. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rohrschneider Robert. 2002. “The Democracy Deficit and Mass Support for an EU-wide Government.” American Journal of Political Science 46: 46375.Google Scholar
Sears David O. 1993. “Symbolic Politics: A Socio-Psychological Theory.” In Explorations in Political Psychology, edited by Shanto Iyengar and William J. McGuire. Durham: Duke University Press, 11349.Google Scholar
Sears David O., and Carolyn Funk. 1991. “The Role of Self-Interest in Social and Political Attitudes.Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 24: 191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shulman Stephen. 2002. “Challenging the Civic/Ethnic and West/East Dichotomies in the Study of Nationalism.Comparative Political Studies 35: 55485.Google Scholar
Spence Jacqueline. [s.d., 1997]. The European Union: A View from the Top. Waver, Belgium: EOS Gallup Europe.Google Scholar
Steenbergen Marco, and Bradford S. Jones. 2002. “Modeling Multilevel Data Structures.American Journal of Political Science 46: 21837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stråth Bo, and Anna Triandafyllidou, eds. 2003. Representations of Europe and the Nation in Current and Prospective Member States: The Collective State of the Art and Historical Reports. Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General for Research, EUR 20736.Google Scholar
Taggart Paul. 1998. “A Touchstone of Dissent: Euroscepticism in Contemporary Western European Party Systems.European Journal of Political Research 33: 36388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Kersbergen Kees. 2000. “Political Allegiance and European Integration.European Journal of Political Research 37: 117.Google Scholar
Young Jason, Cynthia J. Thomsen, Eugene Borgida, John L. Sullivan, and John H. Aldrich. 1991. “When Self-Interest Makes a Difference: The Role of Construct Accessibility in Political Reasoning.Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 27: 27196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Explaining Support for European Integration-A Multi-Level Analysis

Figure 1

Effects of Independent Variables

Figure 2

Exclusive National Indentity and Support for European Integration

Figure 3

Appendix: Variable Descriptions