Hostname: page-component-6bf8c574d5-h6jzd Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2025-02-21T05:51:02.576Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

New Directions in Legislative Research: Lessons from Inside Congress

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 July 2016

Michael H. Crespin
Affiliation:
University of Oklahoma
Anthony J. Madonna
Affiliation:
University of Georgia
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Politics Symposium: The Transformed Congressional Experience
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2016 

Over the last several decades, we have watched power and control over public policy flow away from the legislative branch towards the executive and judicial branches. Critics of the federal government lament the perceived increased use of unilateral presidential tools—including executive orders and agreements, signing statements, recess appointments, and presidential proclamations—claiming an out of control imperial presidency. Others worry that judges insulated from electoral pressure are effectively making policy with rulings in cases such as Shelby Counter v. Holder and Citizens United v. Federal Election Commission. Meanwhile, Congress moves from crisis to crisis.

In order to learn why these changes happened, we asked several members of Congress to reflect on these changes in long-form essays. Four current or former members answered our call—three Democrats in the House and one Republican in the Senate. Two of the House members, Representatives David Price (D-NC) and Dina Titus (D-NV) have PhDs and were faculty in political science departments at Duke and the University of Nevada, Las Vegas, respectively. Representative John Barrow (D-GA), who was finally defeated in 2014 after several attempts to gerrymander him out of his district, is serving as the first Scholar in Residence at the University of Georgia’s School of Public and International Affairs. Senator Mike Lee (R-UT) holds a BA in Political Science and JD from Brigham Young University and has written several pieces on congressional reform. Members were asked to write essays before it was clear how the transition away from Speaker Boehner would play out, so they did not have the benefit of seeing the start of the Ryan speakership.

Despite some diverse backgrounds, the members were in agreement on several points. All the essays concurred with the sentiment that Congress is weakening and that the Executive, Judiciary, and state governments are benefiting. Footnote 1 The essays supported the view that this weakness stems from congressional gridlock. And they all concurred this has negative normative implications for American democracy. Finally, all agreed that both ideological changes external to Congress and internal congressional rules and processes—specifically the centralization at the hands of chamber leaders—were to blame.

As expected, there were some disagreements as well. The Democratic members focused more on changes in the ideology of Republican members. And the House members were generally more concerned about their chamber than the lone senator. There were also disagreements over the extent to which congressional dysfunction was internal as opposed to being influenced by electoral factors. Perhaps most notably, there was little consensus about internal procedural reforms. In what follows, we provide an overview of the essays and conclude by offering some comments and highlighting avenues for future political science research. For clarity, we divide the arguments into two categories: those focused on external ideological changes and those focused on internal process issues.

EXTERNAL IDEOLOGICAL CHANGES

While the essays primarily focus on internal congressional procedures, all four members argue that one external cause of congressional weakness stems from changes in the ideology of elected officials. This increasing polarization has been well-documented by political scientists. Footnote 2 Not surprisingly, the members do point to differing causes for these ideological changes. For example, the Democratic members focused more on asymmetric ideological changes in the Republican Party. Representative Price suggests that the libertarian movement within the Republican Party has made compromises on public goods particularly difficult to achieve. In contrast, Senator Lee argues that there is a lack of moderate members on both sides and that this problem is particularly complicated by the centralization of internal procedures.

Representatives Titus and Barrow suggest that increased polarization goes hand in hand with changes in the electorate. Specifically, they argue that fewer competitive seats have led to more ideologically extreme members. Representative Titus notes that “according to CQ Weekly (9/28/2015), only 32 seats of 435 are in play in 2016.” They move beyond the simple gerrymandering explanation for this and argue that “partisan sorting” plays a part as well. Specifically, Representative Barrow suggests voters have moved into different communities of interest.

Whether caused by geographic sorting or simply gerrymandering districts in a way that favors one political party over the other, Representative Titus notes the effect is still the same. The lack of a competitive general election challenger leads incumbents to be more concerned about potential primary challengers, forcing them to the ideological extremes. Additionally, when moderates do get elected, Representative Titus reasons they become electoral targets and rarely serve long enough to build seniority or power within the institution.

Further, the members argue that problems stemming from ideological changes are compounded by relatively small majorities where control of the House and Senate can fluctuate from election to election. In the current electoral environment neither party has the type of control over the legislative branch that the Democrats enjoyed for so long after WWII. Consistent with scholarship by Frances Lee (Reference Lee2009), Representative Price rightly claims that the competitiveness between the two parties provides little reason for cooperation and giving a win to the other side. Senator Lee builds on this, suggesting that electoral competition and a desire to maintain their majority status has led to further centralizing of policy-making on the party of leadership. After all, leadership has the most to lose if majority status changes hands.

Regardless of its cause, members note that changes in the ideology of members has led to depressed cooperation and the ability to pass needed legislation.

Regardless of its cause, members note that changes in the ideology of members has led to depressed cooperation and the ability to pass needed legislation. Senator Lee notes the increased polarization is especially harmful in the US Senate, where bipartisanship is necessary due to the lack of a simple majority rule for ending debate. This is consistent with a great deal of scholarly work on the Senate, which has argued that chamber rules have resulted in both an expansion of the gridlock interval and an increased likelihood that legislation will fail. Footnote 3

The members also pointed to several policy areas that were once bipartisan that no longer function as well as they once had. As a long-term member of the appropriations committee, Rep. Price maintains that the committee previously could hold the executive accountable when it came to spending and traditionally displayed restrained partisanship. Now, policy riders added to appropriations bills at the last minute make bipartisan action more difficult. Footnote 4

Undoubtedly, gridlock has advantaged the Executive Branch. For example, although Democrats and Republicans in the Senate worked to pass immigration legislation, it did not make it out of the Republican controlled lower chamber. As a result, President Obama saw an opening and signed a series of executive orders that established the Deferred Action for Childhood Arrivals (DACA) program.

INTERNAL LEGISLIATVE PROCESSES

Consistent with their views on ideological changes, the members all agreed with the broad view that internal legislative processes share a good amount of blame for the state of congressional politics. Senator Lee, for example, argues the “real source of congressional dysfunction and weakness is within Congress itself.” Moreover, all four essays suggest changes to internal processes have served to centralize lawmaking at the hands of chamber leaders. This point is best addressed in the “conditional party government” theory of legislative organization (Rohde Reference Rohde1991). Despite this broad agreement, just like with ideological changes, the essays differed over the degree to which internal processes were problematic, which processes were most detrimental and how to strike the right balance with leadership.

All three House Democrats took issue with the increased power of the Speaker of the House. Representative Price pointed to the centralization of power sparked by the “Gingrich Revolution” of 1994 and continued by leaders ever since has come at the expense of the committee system. Footnote 5 Representative Barrow smartly argues that one reason why some of the Republicans wanted to fire their Speaker was precisely because he was so powerful. Representative Price comments that Speaker John Boehner was backed into a corner with the Hastert Rule—only allowing votes on legislation with the support of the majority of the majority party. He could either move legislation without the support of his party or face the consequences of a government shutdown or worse, failing to service the federal debt. Arguably, several of the violations of the Hastert Rule resulting in majority party rolls were indications of the overall strength of Speaker Boehner, and a weakness in the rank-and-file over the leadership.

Price additionally argues that the relationship between committees and leadership strength is not necessarily zero-sum. He also concedes that some curbing of committee chair power was necessary. However, nearly all essays suggest centralization has come at the expense of committee autonomy. Titus argues that committees are virtually “rubber stamps” for the leaders’ positions. She notes that: “Committee chairmen have little power when it comes to setting agendas, moving bills, or considering amendments.” Further, consistent with Curry (Reference Curry2015), she points out that many bills are written directly by party leadership.

Senator Lee points out that centralization is not confined solely to the House. He notes that chamber leaders in the Senate have used their procedural abilities to bar floor amendments in an effort to save their rank and file members from having to take “tough votes.” Lee concedes that these amendments are often not intended to improve legislation, but rather to put members of the opposing party on the record as being “on the wrong side of public opinion.” He believes leaders then use hard “cliff” deadlines as excuses to block these amendments for efficiency reasons. The senator suggests that a more decentralized, open amending process would help improve the functionality of the chamber.

All four essays also point to other procedural tools as being either problematic or potentially helpful in reforming Congress.

Similar to Lee, many of the House members also called for a more open amending process. Barrow argues changing the powerful Rules Committee might be a good place to start reforms. If the minority has the ability to offer real substantive amendments or offer alternatives to the majority, perhaps more bipartisan legislation will receive a vote on the floor. While Barrow also concedes problems stemming from “messaging” amendments, he suggests that reforming structured rules could help mitigate these issues. Titus also suggests limited floor amending opportunities are compromising bipartisanship. In so many words, members of Congress are concerned about the positive and negative agenda control asserted by party leadership (Cox and McCubbins Reference Cox and McCubbins1993).

All four essays also point to other procedural tools as being either problematic or potentially helpful in reforming Congress. Representative Barrow thinks reforms to the discharge petition could help. This procedure was recently used to bring the Export-Import Bank legislation to the floor. Representative Price points out that the “filibuster and other non-majoritarian features of Senate operations have erected formidable obstacles to legislative action, even in periods of unified party control.” Representative Titus suggests the usage of the motion to recommit as a minority messaging tool has been problematic, and that the ban on earmarks has weakened leaders’ abilities to build broader coalitions. And Senator Lee calls for a reformed budget process that would eliminate the hard “cliff” deadlines used to justify barring amendments.

CONCLUDING THOUGHTS

The goal of the symposium is for members of Congress to reflect on how power has flowed away from the legislative branch. In doing so, we hope the essays will provide legislative scholars with avenues for future research that might be helpful to both scholars and practitioners. We believe these essays have been very successful in that regard. In this section, we build off of the essays and highlight avenues for future research.

First, the essays demonstrate the difficulties inherent in trying to disentangle concepts like “party” and “ideology.” This is an issue quite familiar to scholars of legislative politics (see Lee Reference Lee2009). Do we view ideology as a theoretically consistent concept that guides member views on policy or is it a concept used to measure latent member behavior? Both scholars and members often discuss it theoretically using the former definition, but evaluate it using the latter.

Students of legislative behavior are aware that many bills, amendments, and procedures that generate roll-call votes have no substantive policy implications. These proposals are not meant to become law or improve existing laws. However, we often treat aggregate roll-call behavior as being representative of a member’s ideology. And we commonly conflate ideological labels like “conservative” or “liberal” with “Republican” or “Democrat.” Footnote 6 This leads us to infer that partisan tools—like structured rules—are used to advantage more ideological members of a party’s constituency. Indeed, several of the essays suggested that one solution to centralization would be for moderate Republicans to “revolt” against the Speaker’s powers. While this is consistent with some scholarly work, it is by no means settled. An alternative view is that centralization has benefited moderate Republicans in the sense that it has saved them from having to vote against more conservative amendments that might leave them vulnerable to primary challenges. Footnote 7

Second, and relatedly, there are practical reasons for centralization to which both the members and scholars have not devoted enough attention. As the members correctly point out, centralization in the House is not new. Footnote 8 However, there are clearly changes in Congress that influence legislative efficiency in ways that did not exist in previous congresses. Workload has increased, leading to greater time demands on leaders. These demands are aggravated by members who—by necessity—are spending more time back in the district and raising money.

Open amending processes marked by large numbers of roll-call votes are very time consuming. New Speaker Paul Ryan (R-WI) demonstrated his frustration on this point by gaveling closed a vote on a bill tightening oversight of Iran’s nuclear program after the allotted 15 minutes were up. Vote time is often extended and 137 members did not register their votes before the voting was closed. Footnote 9 Moreover, the utility of messaging amendments has increased sharply in recent years as congressional control fluctuates and more money is spent highlighting member votes. Footnote 10 This has led to a sharp increase in proposed amendments.

As Senator Lee notes, this can create “tough votes” for members and often has little to no influence on policy. However, while members are correct in noting that we are transitioning to an era of greater transparency, where more information is available to voters, it is unclear whether more information translates to better information. The scholarly work on messaging bills and amendments is still developing. Footnote 11 And the broader debate over transparency and effective governance is a long-standing one. For example, during the Constitutional Convention, the Founders were at odds over publicizing votes. One member, Nathaniel Gorham, opposed recorded voting, fearing it would lead to members “stuffing the Journals with roll calls on frivolous occasions” in an effort to “mislead the people.” Footnote 12 Indeed, more scholarly work in this area would likely to be beneficial.

Finally, the essays highlight the gap between executive and legislative scholarship on specific procedural tools. In general, scholars of executive politics have done a better job describing and contextualizing the use of specific presidential tools than legislative scholars. This is not to say good work is absent in this area. However, in recent decades scholars have focused on broader theoretical implications of legislative behavior, as opposed to answering narrower questions about how a given procedural tool is employed. This limits our abilities to draw inferences for reform.

In closing, we believe the essays written by members of the legislative branch will help provide new directions for scholars moving forward. While it is important for students of Congress to maintain a professional distance from the subject at hand, there is much to be gained from listening to the concerns from individuals who operate daily in the House and Senate. Scholars, practitioners, and the general public all benefit from a more functional Congress.

Footnotes

1. For example, as a consequence of congressional failure to act, Representative Titus argues that states are stepping into policy domains that were once the purview of the federal government. We see this when states pass their own immigration bills or increase their own gas tax to fix crumbling infrastructure.

2. See e.g. McCarty, Poole, and Rosenthal (Reference McCarty, Poole and Rosenthal2006); Carson et al. (Reference Carson, Crespin, Finocchiaro and Rohde2007); Poole and Rosenthal (Reference Poole and Rosenthal2007); Bonica (Reference Bonica2014); Theriault (Reference Theriault2006); Hetherington and Rudolph (Reference Hetherington and Rudolph2015).

3. See e.g. Binder and Smith (Reference Binder and Smith1997); Binder, Madonna, and Smith (Reference Binder, Madonna and Smith2007); Madonna (Reference Madonna2011); Wawro and Schickler (Reference Wawro and Schickler2006).

4. See MacDonald (Reference MacDonald2010) for a political science discussion of the effect of policy riders.

5. The centralization in the Gingrich Congress solidified changes that began in the 1970s when the Democrats enabled secret ballots to elect committee chairs.

6. See e.g. Crespin and Rohde (Reference Crespin and Rohde2010); Cox and Poole (Reference Cox and Poole2002); Dougherty et al. (Reference Dougherty, Lynch and Madonna2014); Lee (Reference Lee2009); Noel (Reference Noel2013).

7. See Lynch, Madonna and Roberts (Reference Lynch, Madonna and Roberts2016) for work on how there are more amending opportunities afforded to centrists under structured rules.

8. For example, when complaining about then-Speaker Joseph Gurney Cannon (R-IL)’s usage of special rules in 1905, House Minority Leader John Sharp Williams (D-MS) observed that he had “never seen a time in [his] life when the majority of the majority was not willing to trust the minority of the majority (Congressional Record, 58 th Congress, February 17, 1905, 2788).”

9. The vote was later vacated and taken again (see Dick Reference Dick2016).

10. Scholars generally agree that highlighting roll-call behavior is an effective technique in elections. See e.g. Ansolabehere and Jones (Reference Ansolabehere and Jones2010); Bovitz and Carson (Reference Bovitz and Carson2006); Canes-Wrone et al. (Reference Canes-Wrone, Brady and Cogan2002); Lipinski (Reference Lipinski2001).

12. See e.g. Binder (Reference Binder1997); Lynch and Madonna (Reference Lynch and Madonna2013); Madonna and Kosar (Reference Madonna and Kosar2015).

References

REFERENCES

Ansolabehere, Stephen and Jones, Philip E.. 2010. “Constituents’ Responses to Congressional Roll Call Voting.” American Journal of Political Science. 54: 583–97.Google Scholar
Bonica, Adam. 2014. “The Punctuated Origins of Senate Polarization.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 39 (1): 526.Google Scholar
Bovitz, Gregory L. and Carson, Jamie. 2006. “Position-Taking and Electoral Accountability in the U.S. House of Representatives.” Political Research Quarterly. 59 (2): 297312.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. 1997. Minority Rights, Majority Rule. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. and Smith, Steven S.. 1997. Politics or Principle? Filibustering in the United States Senate. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A., Madonna, Anthony J. and Smith, Steven S.. 2007. “Going Nuclear, Senate Style.” Perspectives on Politics. 5 (4): 729–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Brady, David W., and Cogan, John. 2002. “Out of Step, Out of Office: Electoral Accountability and House Members’ Voting.” American Political Science Review. 96 (1): 127140.Google Scholar
Carson, Jamie, Crespin, Michael, Finocchiaro, Charles, and Rohde, David. 2007. “Redistricting and Party Polarization in the U.S. House of Representatives.” American Politics Research 35 (6): 878904.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. and Poole, Keith T.. 2002. “On Measuring Partisanship in Roll Call Voting: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1877–1999.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (3): 477489.Google Scholar
Crespin, Michael and Rohde, David W.. 2010. “Dimensions, Issues and Bills: Appropriations Voting on the House Floor.” Journal of Politics 72 (4): 976989.Google Scholar
Crespin, Michael, Hayden, Jessica, Madonna, Anthony, and Shen, Ivy. 2016. “Building an Electoral Record: The Increase in Procedural Traceability in Congress.” Paper presented at the Southern Political Science Association Annual Meeting, San Juan, PR.Google Scholar
Curry, James M. 2015. Legislating in the Dark: Information and Power in the House of Representatives. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dick, Jason. 2016. “The Ryan Speakership Will be On Time.” Roll Call, January 13.Google Scholar
Dougherty, Keith L., Lynch, Michael S. and Madonna, Anthony J.. 2014. “Partisan Agenda Control and the Dimensionality of Congress.” American Politics Research 42: 600627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hetherington, Marc J. and Rudolph, Thomas J.. 2015. Why Washington Won’t Work: Polarization, Political Trust, and the Governing Crisis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lee, Frances E. 2009. Beyond Ideology: Politics, Principles, and Partisanship in the U.S. Senate. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lynch, Michael S. and Madonna, Anthony J.. 2013. “Viva Voce: Implications from the Disappearing Voice Vote, 1865–1996.” Social Science Quarterly. 94: 530550.Google Scholar
Lynch, Michael S., Madonna, Anthony J., and Roberts, Jason M.. 2016. “The House Majority Party and the Rules Committee: Bargaining over Chamber Procedure.” Legislative Studies Quarterly, Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Lipinski, Daniel. 2001. “The Effect of Messages Communicated by Members of Congress: The Impact of Publicizing Votes.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 26 (1): 81100.Google Scholar
MacDonald, Jason A. 2010. “Limitation Riders and Congressional Influence over Bureaucratic Policy Decisions.” American Political Science Review. 104 (04): 766782.Google Scholar
Madonna, Anthony. 2011. “Institutions and Coalition Formation: Revisiting the Effects of Rule XXII on Winning Coalition Sizes in the U.S. Senate.” American Journal of Political Science. 55: 276288.Google Scholar
Madonna, Anthony J. and Kosar, Kevin R.. 2015. “An Open Amending Process in the Modern U.S. Senate: An Appraisal,” R Street Policy Study No. 42, October. http://www.rstreet.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/RSTREET42.pdf Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan M., Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 2006. Polarized America, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Noel, Hans. 2013. Political Ideologies and Political Parties in America. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard. 2007. Ideology and Congress. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Rohde, David W. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Theriault, Sean M. 2006. “Party Polarization in the US Congress Member Replacement and Member Adaptation.” Party Politics 12 (4): 483503.Google Scholar
Wawro, Gregory and Schickler, Eric. 2006. Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the US Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar