Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b6zl4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T12:46:55.056Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Desirability of Gender Quotas: Considering Context and Design

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 March 2006

Mark P. Jones
Affiliation:
Rice University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

October 3, 2005, marks a dozen years since Argentina started the quota ball rolling via the first use of gender quota legislation applying to all parties for the election of national legislators. For the October 3, 1993, Argentine Chamber of Deputies election, all political parties were required to present closed party lists on which women accounted for a minimum of 30% of the candidates, and furthermore, a comparable proportion of these women had to be placed in “electable” positions on the lists (Jones 1996). Although the initial implementation process was not free of problems (Durrieu 1999), in a short time the gender quota became an established fixture of the Argentine political system. The impact of the quota legislation on the representation of women in the Argentine congress was nothing short of dramatic, with women now accounting for 34% and 44% of the seats in the Argentine Chamber of Deputies and Senate, respectively, a marked contrast to the situation prior to the adoption of the quota legislation, when women on average held a mere 5% of the seats in both legislative bodies.

Type
CRITICAL PERSPECTIVES ON GENDER AND POLITICS
Copyright
© 2005 The Women and Politics Research Section of the American Political Science Association

October 3, 2005, marks a dozen years since Argentina started the quota ball rolling via the first use of gender quota legislation applying to all parties for the election of national legislators.1

Prior to this date, the world's experience with quotas had been limited to intraparty quota rules and token reserved seats. For a cogent discussion of the distinction between quota legislation, reserved seat legislation, and intraparty quota rules, see Norris (2001).

For the October 3, 1993, Argentine Chamber of Deputies election, all political parties were required to present closed party lists on which women accounted for a minimum of 30% of the candidates, and furthermore, a comparable proportion of these women had to be placed in “electable” positions on the lists (Jones 1996). Although the initial implementation process was not free of problems (Durrieu 1999), in a short time the gender quota became an established fixture of the Argentine political system. The impact of the quota legislation on the representation of women in the Argentine congress was nothing short of dramatic, with women now accounting for 34% and 44% of the seats in the Argentine Chamber of Deputies and Senate, respectively, a marked contrast to the situation prior to the adoption of the quota legislation, when women on average held a mere 5% of the seats in both legislative bodies.

Over the past dozen years, a host of other countries have adopted quota legislation. While the effectiveness of this quota legislation in enhancing the presence of women in the legislature has varied, with far more negative than positive experiences (Htun and Jones 2002; Krook 2005), we can identify several other “success” stories, such as Belgium (Meier 2004), Costa Rica (Jones 2004), and Mexico (Baldez 2004). Here, however, my goal is not to explain the success or failure of different forms of quota legislation, or to analyze the effect of increases in the number of female legislators on public policy. Instead, I will endeavor to answer the three questions posed by the editors for the authors in this Critical Perspectives on Gender and Politics section: 1) Are quotas a good idea? 2) Should more countries adopt them? 3) Should the United States consider them?

Are Gender Quotas a Good Idea?

My answer to this question is context and quota contingent. By context, I refer to existing barriers to women's equal representation in a country (or state or municipality). By quota, I refer to the specifics of the quota legislation being discussed.

Quotas are a good idea in instances where women are significantly underrepresented in proportion to their presence in the general population (i.e., approximately 50%).2

I do not address the issue regarding what constitutes “significant” underrepresentation, since what is considered significant will depend in part on context-specific factors, such as age of the democracy, the status of women in society, political culture, etc.

This significant underrepresentation constitutes a very strong signal that there are cultural, economic, institutional, and/or societal factors that combine to unfairly limit women's access to equal representation in public office. And in virtually all instances, the only method that will redress this underrepresentation in the short or medium term is the adoption of effective gender quotas.

For example, a country like Denmark, which has neither a national quota law nor relevant political parties that possess intraparty quota rules (International IDEA and Stockholm University 2005), and yet where women account for 37% of the unicameral national legislature (Folketinget), is a place where I would suggest that the adoption of gender quotas is not a particularly good idea. On the basis of the current gender distribution of legislative seats, it would appear that significant barriers to the election of women legislators do not exist, and that the political costs of gender quota legislation outweigh the marginal representational benefits that would be achieved by this legislation.

In contrast, a country like Japan, which has neither a national quota law nor relevant political parties that possess intraparty quota rules (International IDEA and Stockholm University 2005), and where women account only for 7% of the national lower house (Shugiin), is a place where I would suggest that the adoption of gender quotas is a good idea. Clearly, the Japanese political system possesses a variety of cultural, economic, institutional, and/or societal barriers that combine to severely limit the election of female legislators.

As I mentioned, my response to this question also depends on the type of gender quota that is being proposed. All quota legislation is not equally effective in the goal of facilitating the election of a substantial proportion of female legislators (Htun and Jones 2002; Jones 2004; Krook 2005). The most effective quota laws generally contain all of the following features: placement mandates (in concert with closed party lists), a high minimum percentage of women candidates (or low maximum percentages for either sex), application to all legislative seats (and not, for instance, to only a modest proportion of the seats), the employment of quotas within a context of moderate-to-large multimember electoral districts (i.e., districts that elect a moderate to large number of legislators), and adequate enforcement of compliance with the quota legislation.3

Quota legislation can potentially be successful in concert with relatively small electoral districts, assuming an ideal configuration of the rules regarding placement mandates, minimum quota percentages, compliance, and seat allocation.

Quota legislation that lacks one or more of these features often will be ineffective.

Quota legislation that is likely to be effective—that is, it will result in the election of a substantial proportion of women legislators—is a good idea. In contrast, quota legislation that is likely to be ineffective is not a good idea. The latter legislation will in most instances not have the desired effect (i.e., the election of a substantial proportion of female legislators). At the same time, it will allow the primarily male establishment to claim to have supported legislation to enhance women's representation (and, hence, not to feel as much pressure to support other legislation in the future that would be beneficial for women, perhaps even an effective gender quota law). It is also likely to weaken a country's most prominent feminist leaders (assuming they were key advocates of the adopted quota legislation), who, following election after election in which the proportion of women elected does not significantly increase, will be compelled to explain the quota legislation's failure to their constituents.

One caveat to the preceding statement that the adoption of ineffective quota legislation is a bad idea is the following. It is possible for quota activists to employ a two-stage quota legislation adoption strategy. Under this strategy, quota activists agree to the adoption of inferior legislation (the first stage) under the logic that at that point in time, they have two choices: the inferior quota legislation or no quota legislation at all. At the same time, the antiquota establishment is content with the ineffective legislation because it realizes that it will, in practice, not have a salient impact on the electoral process. Then, once this adopted quota legislation fails to have its “promised” effect of electing a significant proportion of women, quota activists can use the gap between the legislation's “promise” of enhanced female representation and the legislation's “reality” of limited female electoral gains to pressure the antiquota establishment, via the courts and public opinion, to adopt effective quota legislation (the second stage).

Should More Countries Adopt Gender Quotas?

The answer to this question follows directly from the discussion in the previous section. If a country finds itself in a situation where women are significantly underrepresented in its legislative bodies (national, state, municipal), and at the same time the type of quota legislation proposed is likely to be effective, then that country should by all means adopt quota legislation. Quota legislation represents the only method by which to substantially increase the percentage of female legislators in a country in the short to medium term.

If, on the other hand, a country finds itself in a situation where women are not significantly underrepresented in its legislative bodies, then that country should not adopt quota legislation. Similarly, even if a country finds itself in a situation where women are significantly underrepresented in its legislative bodies, but the quota legislation proposed is unlikely to be effective, then quotas are not a good idea (unless, perhaps, as part of a well-planned two-stage “bait and switch” strategy, such as that described in the previous section).

Should the United States Consider Adopting Gender Quotas?

The anemic representation of women in the U.S. House of Representatives (15%) and U.S. Senate (14%) is a national embarrassment. As of June 30, 2005, the Inter-Parliamentary Union's ranking of women in the lower/unicameral legislature of the world's nations placed the United States sixtieth (Inter-Parliamentary Union 2005). While this ranking is somewhat misleading, since several of the legislatures ranked ahead of the United States are oppressive dictatorships (e.g., Cuba) where the national legislature performs a purely decorative function and has scant political or policy relevance, the fact remains that the percentages of women in the U.S. House of Representatives and Senate are comparatively very low. Furthermore, this low level of female legislative presence is repeated in the country's state legislatures where, as of 2005, a mere average of 23% of state legislators were women, with the state with the greatest presence of female legislators (Maryland) possessing a legislature (General Assembly and Senate) in which only a third (34%) of the members were women (Center for American Women in Politics 2005).

This significant underrepresentation of women would at first glance make the United States an excellent candidate for gender quotas. Furthermore, the United States already has substantial experience with implicit racial and ethnic quotas, that is, majority-minority districts (Lublin 1999) designed to increase the descriptive representation of racial and ethnic minorities (principally African Americans and Latinos, but also Native Americans and Asian Americans).4

Although there is no legislation requiring majority-minority districts to be represented by legislators who belong to the minority group that is the majority (or plurality) in the district, empirically there are relatively few cases in which Anglos (or other nonmembers of the minority group) are elected in majority-minority districts (Lublin 1999).

The United States also is not without experience with gender quotas, as the Democratic Party employs gender quotas for the selection of delegates to its quadrennial national convention. In 2004, the party's rules mandated that the rank-ordered closed party lists used for the election of delegates at the state/district level alternate women and men on the list (i.e., a zipper system).

However, unlike the case for the selection of delegates to the Democratic National Convention, all members of the U.S. House of Representatives and U.S. Senate are selected from single-member districts. In a similar vein, an overwhelming majority of U.S. state legislators also are chosen from single-member districts. Furthermore, the most popular electoral reform being advocated today in the United States (instant runoff voting/the alternative vote) would not alter the single-member district aspect of elections at the national, state, and local level.

Finally, the successful creation of majority-minority electoral districts depends in large part on residential housing segregation based on race and ethnicity. The lack of gender-based housing segregation, combined with the relative absence of gender-polarized voting, indicates that the majority-minority district model is not an option for the enhancement of women's representation in the United States. At the same time, the options of mandating that specific congressional districts only elect women or that a political party present a set of congressional candidates of which women represent a minimum percentage (e.g., no more than 67% of a party's U.S. House candidates can be of the same sex) are sufficiently at odds with political and constitutional reality in the United States that it is unrealistic even to consider them as potential remedies.

In sum, while the United States clearly represents a case where women are significantly underrepresented in the country's most prominent legislative bodies, it is not a good case for the adoption of quotas, inasmuch as quota legislation is incompatible with the combination of the electoral rules (i.e., single-member districts) employed to select all national and most state legislators and the country's weak political party system in which individual politicians, not the national or state political parties, are the relevant political unit. In addition, any reform of the current single-member plurality (or majority runoff) districts employed for the election of all national and most state legislators is unlikely in the immediate future. And in any event, the most likely electoral reform (instant runoff voting) would not alter the single-member district nature of the system.

While the probability of the creation of multimember districts for the election of members of the U.S. House of Representatives and Senate is extremely unlikely in at least the short to medium term, quotas do represent a potential viable option for the United States at the state level in two rare instances: for the election of legislators to the handful of state legislative chambers that presently employ multimember districts for the election of a large percentage of their legislators (e.g., at least two-fifths of the chamber) and to the one state legislative chamber in which there exists a realistic (albeit still remote) possibility of adopting multimember districts along with a semiproportional form of seat allocation (i.e., cumulative voting).

Eleven state legislative chambers (10 lower houses and one senate) elect their members (in all cases more than half) from multimember districts (with the most common size for these districts being two legislators) (Squire and Hamm 2005).5

Two of the chambers (the Idaho House and the Washington House) possess two-member districts in which citizens cast a single ballot in two separate races within their district (i.e., the “post or place” system) (Squire and Hamm 2005). The remaining nine chambers employ the plurality rule, with voters allowed to vote for multiple candidates (but not allowed to cast multiple votes for the same candidate).

In these states, the adoption of effective quota legislation is eminently feasible. For example, legislation could be adopted that specifies that no more than 50% of the candidates in a district with an even number of legislators can be of the same sex (with a one-candidate gender difference allowed in districts with an odd number of legislators).6

In a district that elects three members (or where a party has three candidates, if, for instance, it does not present a full slate), a party would have to present at least one female candidate, while in a district with five members, a party would have to present at least two female candidates, etc.

However, in some of these chambers (where multimember districts are employed), quota legislation may not be advisable due to the substantial proportion of women elected to office at present (without quota legislation), such as the Idaho House (36% female), Maryland House (35%), Arizona House (33%), and Vermont Senate (33%). In contrast, quota legislation would clearly be advisable in some of the other chambers, such as the South Dakota House (20% female), North Dakota House (19%), West Virginia House (18%), and New Jersey House (16%).

For instance, the New Jersey House (General Assembly), North Dakota House, and South Dakota House elect all of their members from two-member districts (every political party can nominate two candidates, and voters are provided with two, noncumulative, votes). If gender quota legislation were adopted, requiring each political party to nominate one person of each sex for elections in every district, the percentage of women elected would increase dramatically. This increase would be especially large in New Jersey, where in July 2005, only three districts had legislators from different parties (one Democrat and one Republican), while the 37 other districts had legislators from the same party (i.e., both were either Democrats or Republicans).7

The adoption of similar legislation for the North Dakota House and the South Dakota House would likely have a comparable (though perhaps slightly weaker) effect on women's representation. As of July 2005, 36 of North Dakota's 47 two-member districts are represented by legislators from the same party, while 28 of South Dakota's 34 two-member districts are represented by legislators from the same party (one of South Dakota's districts is presently split into two single-member districts in order to create a majority–minority district for Native Americans).

Assuming that partisanship would continue to dominate vote choice more than would gender (which is the case in most instances), the adoption of a 50% quota would substantially increase (to somewhere between 35% and 50%) the percentage of women in the New Jersey General Assembly.

The other potential avenue for the implementation of effective quota legislation would exist in Illinois if the state returns to the use of cumulative voting to elect the members of its House of Representatives (between 1870 and 1980, the Illinois House was elected using cumulative voting). Under the proposed system, each district would elect three representatives. Were cumulative voting to be adopted in Illinois, political parties could be required (via the adoption of gender quota legislation) to present lists at the district level in which no sex accounted for more than 67% of the candidates, if the party runs three candidates, or 50% of the candidates, if the party runs two candidates. However, the adoption of quota legislation might not be considered necessary in Illinois at the present time, since women now account for 30% of House members, and the adoption of quota legislation, such as suggested here, would be unlikely to increase this percentage by more than 10% at best.

Conclusion

Gender quotas are a good idea in principle. However, when considering the adoption of gender quotas in a country, state, or municipality, the context of women's representation and the details of the quota legislation to be adopted (including how it interacts with the existing electoral rules) are of paramount importance. Quotas are only a good idea in the context of significant underrepresentation of women in the targeted legislative bodies, combined with quota legislation that is likely to be effective (i.e., to result in a substantial increase in the percentage of women elected). Absent a significant underrepresentation of women or quota legislation that is likely to be effective, quotas are in most instances not a good idea, since either they are unnecessary or they are destined to fail to result in a noteworthy increase in the percentage of women elected.

References

Baldez, Lisa. 2004. “Elected Bodies: The Gender Quota Law for Legislative Candidates in Mexico.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 29 (May): 23158.Google Scholar
Center for American Women, and Politics. 2005. Women in State Legislatures 2005. New Brunswick, NJ: Eagleton Institute of Politics, Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey Press.
Durrieu, Marcela. 1999. Se Dice de Nosotras. Buenos Aires: Catálogos Editora.
Htun, Mala N., and Mark P. Jones. 2002. “Engendering the Right to Participate in Decision-making: Electoral Quotas and Women's Leadership in Latin America.” In Gender and the Politics of Rights and Democracy in Latin America, ed. Nikki Craske and Maxine Molyneux. New York: Palgrave, 3256.
International IDEA, and Stockholm University. 2005. Global Database of Quotas for Women. Stockholm: International IDEA. 〈http://www.quotaproject.org〉.
Inter-Parliamentary Union. 2005. Women in National Parliaments. Geneva: Inter-Parliamentary Union. 〈http://www.ipu.org〉.
Jones, Mark P. 1996. “Increasing Women's Representation Via Gender Quotas: The Argentine Ley de Cupos.” Women & Politics 16 (December): 7598.Google Scholar
Jones, Mark P. 2004. “Quota Legislation and the Election of Women: Learning from the Costa Rican Experience.” Journal of Politics 66 (November): 120323.Google Scholar
Krook, Mona Lena. 2005. Politicizing Representation: Campaigns for Candidate Gender Quotas Worldwide. Ph.D. diss. Columbia University.
Lublin, David. 1999. The Paradox of Representation: Racial Gerrymandering and Majority Interests in Congress. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Meier, Petra. 2004. “The Mutual Contagion Effect of Legal and Party Quotas.” Party Politics 10 (September): 583600.Google Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 2001. “Breaking the Barriers: Positive Discrimination Policies for Women.” In Has Liberalism Failed Women? Assuring Equal Representation in Europe and the United States, ed. Jyette Klausen and Charles S. Maier. New York: Palgrave, 89110.
Squire, Peverill, and Keith E. Hamm. 2005. Congress, State Legislatures, and the Future of Legislative Studies. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.