Primary elections are an important—though overlooked—step in the American electoral process, particularly in Congressional elections. Most candidates who wish to run in a general election must first be nominated by their political party, and the outcomes of primaries do a great deal to set the stage for general elections. However, there is little attention given to primaries in empirical research and scant evidence of the relationship between the preferences of primary electorates and the ideologies of the candidates they elect.
Primaries tend to draw participation from activist voters who are more ideologically extreme than general election voters at large or even general election voters of the same party affiliation (Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman Reference Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman2003). However, because there are few ways of consistently measuring the ideological preferences of candidates who participate in primaries, scholars have been left guessing whether the preferences of candidates who win primaries more closely match the preferences of their primary electorate or their general electorate.
Our study addresses this lapse in the literature. We use new measures of the ideal points of primary candidates to analyze whether the ideology of a primary electorate influences the ideologies of the candidates who run in primaries. Examining data from the 2008 and 2010 elections for the US House of Representatives, we find that the ideologies of primary and partisan general electorates are significant predictors of a candidate’s ideological views. This result holds when we control for incumbency, primary type, and multiple measures of electoral competitiveness. These ideological influences help determine which candidate wins the primary, as primary electorate extremity correlates positively with the primary winner’s extremity. We also find differences in the electoral constituencies to which Republican and Democratic candidates respond.
Candidates and Constituencies
Within the literature on elections, primaries have not received the same attention as general elections. Nevertheless, they are a vital part of the election process. Primary elections became popular in the early 20th century as a way to give ordinary citizens more control over elections; previously, candidates were largely selected by political parties. In this study we focus on primaries for the US House of Representatives.
House members require electoral support from many constituencies (Fenno Reference Fenno1978). Members of Congress are incentivized to be responsive to their constituents because it helps ensure their ultimate goal of re-election (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974). We propose that primary electorates are a crucial constituency for congressional candidates because members can only run for re-election if they are first nominated in the primary.
Primary voters differ from general voters in their demographics, political preferences, and engagement levels. Primaries lack party cues and attract less media coverage, so they tend to attract more politically engaged, partisan, and ideologically extreme voters than do general elections (Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman Reference Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman2003; Fiorina, Abrams and Pope Reference Fiorina, Abrams and Pope2006; Abramowitz and Saunders Reference Abramowitz and Saunders2008). These primary voters may draw candidates’ attention because elected officials tend to represent the interests of engaged constituents more than disengaged constituents (Burden Reference Burden2004; Bafumi and Herron Reference Bafumi and Herron2010).
Politicians are strategic in appealing to their constituents (Fenno Reference Fenno1978) and seek to maximize their chances of winning (Jacobson and Kernell Reference Jacobson and Kernell1983). Thus, politicians are incentivized to appeal to primary voters rather than more moderate general election voters (King Reference King2003; Keele and Stimson Reference Keele and Stimson2005; Brady, Han and Pope Reference Brady, Han and Pope2007). As primary voters become more ideological, parties may respond by running more ideological candidates (Jacobson Reference Jacobson2004). This could encourage more extremity in primary electorates because moderate voters would be less motivated to turn out if there were no ideologically proximate candidates to vote for (Callender and Wilson Reference Callender and Wilson2007).
In addition to electorate ideology, primary type may play a role in determining candidate ideology. Prior studies have argued that primary rules affect political party platforms (Brady and Schwartz Reference Brady and Schwartz1995; Gerber and Morton Reference Gerber and Morton1998; Besley and Case Reference Besley and Case2003; Westley, Calcagno and Ault Reference Westley, Calcagno and Ault2004) and the types of voters who participate in the primary (Jewell Reference Jewell1984; Calcagno and Westley Reference Calcagno and Westley2008). The relationship between primary rules and candidate ideology follows the logic of spatial voting laid out by Downs (Reference Downs1957): closed primaries feature more partisan electorates and attract more ideologically extreme candidates, whereas the ideologically diverse electorates of open primaries attract more moderate candidates (Fiorina Reference Fiorina1999; Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart, III2001; Burden Reference Burden2004). However, other scholars argue that this relationship is not as clear as the Downsian story predicts and that different rules may lead to outcomes that defy Downsian logic (Kanthak and Morton 2001; McGhee et al. Reference McGhee, Masket, Shor, Rogers and McCarty2014).
Knowing which constituency candidates are more responsive to is the first step toward understanding how candidates campaign in general elections. Few studies have examined the relationship between a primary candidate’s ideology, the electorate’s ideology, and which candidate wins the primary. Brady, Han and Pope (Reference Brady, Han and Pope2007) find that ideologically extreme primary incumbents have higher margins of victory and that moderate incumbents are more likely to draw primary challengers. Brady, Han and Pope (Reference Brady, Han and Pope2007) represents an important systematic look at the role of primaries but does not address the role of primary electorate ideology.
Our main goal is to examine whether a candidate’s primary electorate has an independent effect on his or her ideological orientation. We argue that because primaries have become a necessary jumping-off point to electoral success, candidates will strategically appeal to their primary constituents. In order to prove that primary electorates have a distinct effect on the ideological orientation of their candidates, we posit two hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1 Ideologically extreme primary electorates are correlated with ideologically extreme primary election candidates.
If candidates are strategic about aligning toward their primary constituents, then extreme primary electorates should generate extreme primary candidates. We also test whether primary electorates are choosing candidates based on their relative ideological extremity. This leads to our second hypothesis:
Hypothesis 2 Ideologically extreme candidates are more likely to win the primary election than moderate candidates.
We expect that highly ideological candidates have a better chance of winning their primaries. If primary electorates do indeed tend to be ideologically extreme, then these electorates should select similarly ideologically extreme primary winners.
Data and Methods
Until recently our hypotheses had been difficult to test. District-level primary election survey data is scarce and has not been representative enough to study multiple congressional districts. Previous studies have relied on samples of congressional districts that are not nationally representative (Gerber and Lewis Reference Gerber and Lewis2004). Ideal point estimations for congressional candidates are also limited. Ideology measures like DW-NOMINATE are available only for officeholders, not for candidates who ran for election but did not win. Other scholars have tried to address this by using self-reported measures of candidate ideology (Burden Reference Burden2004) or estimating ideology measures themselves (Stone, Maisel and Lowman Reference Stone, Maisel and Lowman2012). Both methods are subject to bias, do not provide a consistent measure of ideology across districts and elections, and do not incorporate the ideologies of candidates’ electoral constituencies.
We use new data sources that address all of these shortcomings and allow us to explore the relationship between primary electorates and candidates in a more rigorous fashion.
First, we measure the ideology of primary candidates using data from Bonica (Reference Bonica2013). His Item Response Theory (IRT) count model uses joint maximum likelihood estimation to estimate ideology scores for candidates who received money from at least 30 unique contributors during their election cycle. These candidate ideology scores are estimated based on the ideology of the campaign contributors. Like DW-NOMINATE scores, the Bonica ideology estimates map candidates onto a liberal-conservative scale from −3 (most liberal) to +3 (most conservative) using data on individual contributions from the Federal Election Commission.Footnote 1 The Bonica ideology scores presume that political actors prefer ideologically proximate outcomes to non-proximate outcomes; other spatial models of political preferences, like DW-NOMINATE, make this same assumption. The Bonica ideology scores are ideal for use in our study because they give us data on a wide range of congressional candidates, not just those who won. By including all candidates for party nomination in our data set rather than just candidates who eventually won their elections, we improve the explanatory power of our model over previous models.
We measure the ideology of a candidate’s different electoral constituencies using survey data from the 2008 and 2010 Cooperative Congressional Election Study (CCES). The CCES asked a variety of questions, including the respondent’s self-reported ideology on a seven-point scale and whether the respondent voted in a party primary and the general election, to a nationally representative sample of 30,000 respondents in 2008 and 55,000 respondents in 2010. The large CCES sample sizes allow us to aggregate respondents’ ideology scores in each congressional district for the following groups:Footnote 2
-
∙ Primary electorate extremity: average ideology of the people who voted in the candidate’s partisan primary election.
-
∙ Partisan general electorate extremity: average ideology of the people of the candidate’s party who voted in the general election.
-
∙ General electorate extremity: average ideology of all people who voted in the general election in the candidate’s district, or the district’s median voter.
Most of our analysis uses the absolute values of the Bonica candidate ideology scores and the district ideology scores; this allows us to compare relative ideological extremity regardless of the direction of the extremity.
We include a series of control variables in our models.Footnote 3 These control variables account for candidate type (Jacobson and Kernell Reference Jacobson and Kernell1983; Jacobson Reference Jacobson1990) by measuring whether the candidate is an incumbent, a challenger, or in an open seat electionFootnote 4 and whether the candidate has previously held elected office.Footnote 5 We control for open and closed primaries;Footnote 6 the district’s Cook Partisan Voting Index (PVI) score and the competitiveness of the primary election;Footnote 7 and the candidate’s party identification, a binary variable indicating whether the candidate is a Republican.
We use regression analysis to evaluate whether primary electorate ideology influences a candidate’s ideology and probit regression analysis to assess whether ideologically extreme candidates are more likely to win their party’s nomination. These results allow us to evaluate primary election dynamics and how they influence general elections.
Findings
We first examine the ideologies of candidates for US Congress in Figure 1, which shows differences between candidates who run for primaries, those who win primaries, and those who eventually win general elections. This figure compares Democratic and Republican candidate ideologies in the 2008 and 2010 House elections. For Democrats, primary election candidates and winners are significantly more ideologically extreme than general election winners. Elected Democrats are 0.12 points more centrist than primary winners(p<0.01). The differences between Republican candidates are less noticeable; Republican general winners are 0.04 points more centrist than primary winners and candidates. Republicans are slightly more extreme than Democrats, particularly general election winners (Republicans 0.11 points more extreme than Democrats). This figure demonstrates that primary candidates and winners are more ideological than general election winners. In addition, for both parties, the primary winners are significantly more ideologically extreme than the general election winners (p<0.01).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20170409043245-94027-mediumThumb-S2049847015000606_fig1g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Fig. 1 Ideology of different candidates split by primary type
Figure 2 compares the ideologies of primary candidates and winners and general winners according to what type of election they ran in. While some literature (Gerber and Morton Reference Gerber and Morton1998; Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman Reference Kaufmann, Gimpel and Hoffman2003) concludes that open primaries have a moderating effect on candidates, we find the opposite. Closed primaries produce the most moderate Democratic and Republican candidates, and open systems produce more ideologically extreme candidates. Our findings confirm previous research (McGhee et al. Reference McGhee, Masket, Shor, Rogers and McCarty2014), which finds that open primaries do not, in fact, produce more politically moderate candidates because there are very few people who actually choose to cross over and vote in another party’s primary election. Among primary winners, closed primaries attract more moderate candidates, whereas among primary losers, candidates in mixed system appear to be more extreme. This result may seem counter-intuitive, given conventional wisdom about closed primaries restricting the electorate to a more insular and activist party base. Hassell (Reference Hassell2012) posited that party elites exert more influence over candidate selection in closed primaries. Given that party elites are primarily concerned with winning and support candidates close to the median voter, closed primaries may generate less extreme candidates. Parties may exert less control over primary losers, which may explain why there is significant variation in the extremity of losing candidates by primary type.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20170409043245-27485-mediumThumb-S2049847015000606_fig2g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Fig. 2 Ideology of different candidates split by primary type
We next use ordinary least squares (OLS) regression analysis in Table 1 to address our hypothesis that there is a positive correlation between primary electorate and primary candidate ideology. Model 1 shows findings for all candidates, Model 2 shows the results for Republicans, and Model 3 shows the results for Democrats.Footnote 8 The independent variables in these models are the three electoral ideology variables and the control variables described in the Data and Methods section. This table shows that the ideology of a district’s primary electorate has a statistically significant influence on the ideology of primary election candidates. A 1 point increase in the district’s primary electorate ideology results in a 0.074 point increase in a primary candidate’s ideology score—as the primary electorate’s ideology becomes more extreme, so does the candidate’s ideology (p<0.05). However, other factors have larger effects on primary candidate extremity—the partisan general electorate extremity, incumbency, and the candidate’s party. The negative coefficient on the latter variable is likely the result of the ideological uniformity of Republican candidates. Figure 3 shows a bar graph comparison of mean candidate extremity scores and their standard deviations broken down by Republicans and Democrats. The Republican candidates’ mean is higher than the Democratic mean, but the standard deviation is much lower (p<0.001), reflecting a lack of ideological diversity among Republican candidates.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20170409043245-92923-mediumThumb-S2049847015000606_fig3g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Fig. 3 Means and standard deviations of Republican and Democratic candidate extremity scores
Table 1 Regression of Candidate Extremity Scores on Electoral Variables for 2008 and 2010 Elections
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20170409043245-00833-mediumThumb-S2049847015000606_tab1.jpg?pub-status=live)
Note: SE in parentheses.
PVI=Partisan Voting Index.
*p<0.05, **p<0.01.
In addition to the district ideology variables, there were other statistically significant control variables in Table 1. We found a small positive correlation between a candidate’s ideology and the district’s Cook PVI scoreFootnote 9 and a slight negative correlation with closed primaries, which reflects the results in Figure 2. Primary electorates exert only a small influence on candidate ideology, but it is nonetheless statistically significant in the face of other control variables. Primary candidates respond to their primary electorate’s ideology even once the ideologies of their general electorates are accounted for. This finding provides evidence supporting Hypothesis 1 and shows that there is a statistically significant and positive relationship between the primary electorate’s ideology and a primary candidate’s ideology.
However, the nature of this relationship depends on the electorate’s and candidate’s partisanship. We show this by running separate models for Republican and Democratic candidates in Table 1. Our results show that Democratic candidates respond to their primary and partisan general electorates, whereas Republican candidates respond only to their partisan general electorates. In addition, Republican party electorates have a 50 percent larger influence on their candidates than Democratic electorates. The ideology of the general electorate as a whole is not significant in either model. Incumbency is significant in both models and has a moderating effect on a candidate’s ideology. In addition, several other control variables are statistically significant in the Republican model.
The most interesting question arising from Table 1 is why Republican candidates are responsive only to their partisan general electorate, whereas Democrats are responsive to both their primary and partisan general electorate. The answer may be found in Figure 4, which shows the distributions of the four ideology variables split between Democrats and Republicans. The panels displaying the distributions for primary electorates, partisan general electorates, and candidates show sharp distinctions between Republicans and Democrats. The median Republican electorate scores are nearly 1 point higher than the median Democratic scores, and the median Republican general electorate is 0.5 points more extreme than the median Democratic general electorate. Republicans also have a far lower standard deviation in each of these distributions than Democrats. There are also differences between candidate ideologies. Democratic candidates have a median ideology score of −1, and Republican candidates have a median ideology score of +1, but Republican candidates have a far smaller standard deviation than Democrats. For Republican electorates and candidates, there simply is not much variance for our models to explain. These results indicate that Republican candidates and electorates are more stringently ideological when compared with Democrats.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20170409043245-78122-mediumThumb-S2049847015000606_fig4g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Fig. 4 Distribution of candidate and electorate extremity
As we have found evidence in favor of Hypothesis 1, we now turn to Hypothesis 2, which posits that extreme candidates are more likely to win in primaries. The results of a probit regression model to test this hypothesis are shown in Table 2. Footnote 10 The dependent variable in these models measures whether the candidate won the primary, and the independent variables measure the candidate’s ideology, whether the candidate has previously held elected office and is a challenger or incumbent (with open seats being the excluded category), and the candidate’s campaign spending relative to their opponents.Footnote 11
Table 2 Probit Model of Primary Win on Electoral Variables for 2008 and 2010 Elections
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20170321101213877-0789:S2049847015000606:S2049847015000606_tab2.gif?pub-status=live)
Note: SE in parentheses.
*p<0.05, **p<0.01.
We find partial support for Hypothesis 2. In Model 1 of Table 2, the candidate ideology measure is not statistically significant, whereas other variables (incumbency, previous elected office, relative campaign spending) are. In other words, incumbents, prior officeholders, and heavy spenders tend to win their primaries. However, candidate ideology is significant in the Republican model, and the coefficient is positive and fairly large. This indicates that more ideological Republican candidates are more likely to win their primaries. However, we do not find the same effect among Democrats. This finding makes sense in light of the analysis in Table 1 and Figures 3 and 4, which show that Republicans and Democrats demonstrate different ideological patterns. As Republican electorates and candidates tend to be more extreme than their Democratic counterparts, ideological extremity matters more to winning party nomination for Republicans than for Democrats. While Republican primary electorates care more about the ideological purity of their candidates, Democratic primary electorates appear to select their nominees using a different set of qualifications.
Discussion and Conclusions
We show that primary electorate ideology is a significant predictor of a candidate’s ideology. Furthermore, Democratic and Republican candidates and voters show different ideological patterns: Republicans are more extreme than Democrats, and there is little ideological diversity among the party’s candidates or electorates. Republican candidates tend to be ideologically responsive to their partisan general electorate, whereas Democratic candidates are responsive to their primary and partisan general electorates. Finally, more ideologically extreme Republican candidates are more likely to win their party’s nomination in the primary election.
We recognize that the 2008 and 2010 elections represent an extremely polarized era (Jacobson Reference Jacobson2012). It is possible that our results are partly driven by this polarization, especially among Republican candidates. The lack of ideological diversity among Republican candidates reflects the relative ideological extremity of Republican voters, especially primary voters. It is possible that if this study was run in an era of more ideological diversity within the Republican electorate, we might have seen more responsiveness among Republican candidates to their primary constituencies. In addition, these results might change if the nature of the electorate and the candidates it attracts changes in the future.
Given the nature of our study, it is difficult to determine whether politicians are prospective in adjusting their platforms to relevant electorates or whether electorates are a signal that encourages more like-minded candidates to seek office. Given trends in polarization among long-term incumbents and a general polarization among candidates who seek office, it is likely that electorates influence candidate positioning in a combination of these ways. The incorporation of more data over more years would allow researchers to examine this question in more detail.
These findings indicate that candidates for Congress tend to respond only to the ideological leanings of voters from their party instead of paying attention to voters from the other party, which may have troubling implications for how members of Congress represent their constituents. The trend of primary electorates choosing extreme candidates could lead to a lack of ideological congruence between members of Congress and their general election constituencies (Bafumi and Herron Reference Bafumi and Herron2010) as moderate voters are disincentivized from voting (Callender and Wilson Reference Callender and Wilson2007), thus further reinforcing recent trends toward political polarization among both elected officials and rank-and-file voters (Stone, Maisel and Lowman Reference Stone, Maisel and Lowman2012).
Our findings emphasize the importance of primaries in determining the electoral environment of the general election. Primaries determine which candidates run in the general election and which electoral constituency the candidates appeal to. In some congressional districts that are dominated by one party, primaries are essentially the only way the electorate can hold elected officials accountable for their conduct. While the CCES has made strides toward providing primary election data, the discipline’s understanding of primary elections will increase only if future surveys ask questions regarding voters’ behavior in primaries. Studies that use only general election data are not capturing the full picture of electoral dynamics in the United States.
Supplementary Material
To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2015.60